Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 24

Business & Company Resource Center

Management International Review, April 1998 v38 n2 p95(13)

The first multinationals: Assyria circa 2000 B.C.

Karl Moore, David Lewis

Abstract: Using the eclectic paradigm as a model to analyze ancient


international trade this article presents evidence suggesting that the first
recorded multinational enterprises (MNEs) appeared in the old Assyrian
kingdom shortly after 2000 B.C. Characteristics found in modern MNEs
such as a hierarchical organization, foreign employees, common stock
ownership, resource and market-seeking behavior, were present in these
ancient firms. This article presents evidence that the first recorded
multinational enterprises appeared in the old Assyrian kingdom shortly after
2000 B.C. (Reprinted by permission of the publisher.)

Full Text: COPYRIGHT 1998 Gabler Verlag (Germany)


Introduction

In his recent massive work on MNEs Dunning states that, "... earlier
examples of embryonic MNEs can, most surely, be found in the colonizing
activities of the Phoenicians and the Romans, and before that, in the more
ancient civilisations ... However, this sort of history ... remains to be written"
(1993, p. 96). Considerable literature has recorded the evolution of MNEs in
Europe since the early Middle Ages (Rostow 1978, North 1981, Chandler
1990, Powelson 1994). There have also been a number of books and articles
written on the economic history of the ancient world (e.g. Orlin 1970, Larsen
1976, Aubet 1987). However, little has been written concerning the earliest
recorded MNEs.

In an effort to shed light on embryonic MNEs in ancient civilisations this


article brings together a modern theory of the MNE and literature on ancient
Assyria. This article uses the eclectic paradigm as a model to analyze ancient
international trade and attempts to show that the major characteristics of
MNEs were a part of the Assyrian business organizations of the time.

Characteristics of an MNE - The Eclectic Paradigm

The definition of MNE used in this article is that accepted by the


Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) and the
United Nations Center for Transnational Corporations (UNCTC), "an
enterprize that engages in foreign direct investment (FDI) and owns or
controls value-adding activities in more than one country" (Dunning 1993, p.
3).

Though there exist competing theories with different perspectives(1)


seeking to explain international production, this article adopts the eclectic
paradigm in examining potential MNE behavior in ancient Assyria. The
eclectic theory or paradigm offers a framework for determining the extent
and pattern of foreign owned activities, it may be handily summarized by the
acronym OLI, or ownership, location and internalization advantages
(Dunning 1993). It is the configuration of these advantages, ownership,
location and internalization, which either encourage or discourage a firm to
undertake foreign activities and become an MNE.

Ownership advantages are firm-specific-advantages (FSAs) which are


owned or controlled by a firm. Country-specific advantages are ones which
are based on the location of the enterprise (Buckley/Casson 1976, Ietto-
Gillies 1992). Finally, internalization advantages are those which accrue to a
firm when it internalizes or brings inside the hierarchy of the firm activities
which could be performed by the market. The following paragraphs provide
greater detail on the eclectic paradigm. Readers familiar with the paradigm
may wish to skip this section. It is provided since this article may be of
interest to at least two groups: international business researchers and
historians, the latter group not generally being as familiar with the eclectic
paradigm.

Internalization advantages are based on the hypothesis that MNEs grow


"by replacing imperfect (or non existent) external markets by internal ones"
Buckley (1993, p.198). Several important ideas are contained in this
definition. The first is that MNEs can be the most efficient means of
international production when imperfect markets exist. The most important
imperfect market for MNEs is the pricing of proprietary information which
is generated by a firm but has many of the attributes of a public good.

Proprietary information can include knowledge developed by the firm by


R&D (both technical and marketing), managerial experience, new
production techniques, production differentiation and market knowledge
(Ietto-Gillies 1992, Dunning 1993). A public good is "a good for which
consumption by one party does not reduce the consumption of others.
Knowledge is a public good in this theoretical sense because it can be
applied by any person or organization to a specific problem without
destroying the ability to apply the knowledge to another use" (Rugman 1980,
p. 26). The price of a public good is zero: the market cannot price a public
good. Thus, in order to profit from investment in knowledge development,
the firm "internalizes", using its internal market to monitor and control the
use of the knowledge in a way the market is unable. Knowledge is an
intermediate product, and the profit to the firm accrues from the sale to a
customer of the final product or service. This use of "intermediate product"
expands the traditional definition of intermediate products as ordinary semi-
processed materials to include knowledge inputs(2) (Buckley/Casson 1976).

Other market imperfections include government regulations, taxes,


controls, tariffs, non-existent futures markets, and inequality between
buyers' and sellers' knowledge of the value and quality of the product. All of
these distort market prices and act as additional incentives to utilize internal
markets (Rugman 1980, Casson 1987, Ietto-Gillies 1992).

Rugman and Gestrin define FSAs as "the competitive strengths of the


company; they can be either production-based (cost or innovation
advantages) or marketing-based (customization advantages)" (1993, p. 19).
Dunning (1990) suggests a number of potential FSAs: those associated with
the size of the firm (e.g., economies of scale, product diversification);
management of organizational expertise; the ability to acquire and upgrade
resources; labor or mature small-scale intensive technologies; product
differentiation; marketing economies; and access to domestic markets. He
also lists the ability to foresee and take advantage of global production and
marketing opportunities; capital availability and financial expertise; access
to natural resources; and the ability to adjust to structural changes.

CSAs are defined as "the national factor endowments of a nation -


basically the variables in its aggregate production function"
(Rugman/Gestrin 1993, p. 19). Dunning (1990) suggests a number of
potential CSAs: input costs (such as labor wages and national resources);
labor productivity; the size and character of markets; transport costs; and the
psychic distance from key markets and the home country of the MNE. There
are also tariff barriers, the taxation structure, risk factors, attitudes toward
FDI, and the structure of competition. Having finished this brief introduction
of the central ideas of the eclectic paradigm this article now considers events
from almost 4000 years ago in the Assyrian empire.

Assyrian International Trade

The ancient city of Ashur, around 100 km south of the modern Iraqi city
of Mosul, was situated on the banks of the river Tigris at the intersection of a
number of important long-distance trade routes. At the beginning of the
second millennium B.C. it became self governing, following the collapse of
the so-called Third Dynasty of Ur, to which it had belonged. Early rulers,
such as Ilu-shuma and his son Erishum I (c. 1939-1900 B.C.), did much to
exploit the commercial potential offered by the geographic location of
Ashur. Inscriptions have been recovered which record the granting of tax
and other concessions to traders from the more southerly cities of
Mesopotamia.
However, the richest source of documentation comes not for Ashur itself
but from a city 1200 km. away: the ancient site of Kanesh, chief city of what
was later known as the kingdom of Cappadocia, near the modern Turkish
city of Kayseri. Nearly 20,000 clay tablets with texts in Assyrian cuneiform
have been unearthed at the site. Of the documents which have been
published from Kanesh, over 85% are of an economic nature, attesting to the
existence of a thriving trade center, active between around 1910 and 1830
B.C. (Veenhof 1995).

Not merely a way station for traders, the lower city of Kanesh was largely
given over to a permanent settlement of international businesspeople,
especially Assyrian businesspeople from Ashur (Veenhof 1995).
Archaeological evidence elsewhere from this period, states Veenhof, "at
Acemhuyuk; ancient Puruskhanda, south of the Salt Lake - reveal business
connections with Mari and Karkamish on the Euphrates as well ... [it was] a
great trading city with a network of international relations" (1995, p. 862). It
is this network of international activity to which we will return presently.

A key economic element of the region was tin, which had probably been
imported to Ashur from Afghanistan. It was wrapped in saleable textiles and
transported by donkey caravan for the five- or six-week journey to Kanesh,
where it, the textiles and the donkeys were sold for silver, copper and
finished bronze goods. The tablets record the day-to-day business
transactions of the Ashur merchants and others involved in this trade.
Assyria was chosen as the subject for this article because there is more
evidence that MNEs existed in this region than for other nations of antiquity.
The first known human system of writing was invented in Southern
Mesopotamia around 3100 B.C. (Hawkins 1979) in order to record
economic and accounting transactions. Several even more ancient sites than
Kanesh have produced an abundance of tablets (Adams/Nissen 1972).
However, the site of Kanesh provides the first detailed evidence of large-
scale multinational private enterprise, albeit with some "state assistance".(3)

This period in history is known as "The Middle Bronze Age". As


suggested by the name, a central feature of this period was the ubiquitous
use of bronze, an alloy of copper and tin, a superior metal to its predecessor,
arsenical bronze. A superior supply of tin was central to the entry of this part
of the world into the Middle Bronze Age. Historians suggest that the better
supply of tin was made available due to a "major evolution in commercial
techniques ... the startling phenomenon of the Old Assyrian commercial
expansion marks a major step in the evolution of commerce" (Larsen 1976,
p. 86). This article argues that part of this evolution was the beginning of
early MNEs.(4) Central characteristics of Old Assyrian commercial systems
were long-term partnerships or firms, permanent representation in foreign
towns and cities and formal agreements or treaties with local political
powers (Larsen 1976), characteristics which they share with modern MNEs.

Historians have suggested that, while writing does not create or cause
social complexity it does act as an enabling factor, in this case perhaps
allowing for more complex business forms to arise (Gough 1968). As noted
previously, a large number of clay tablets with texts in Assyrian cuneiform
have been uncovered at Kanesh, of the documents which have been
published from this site over 85% are of an economic nature. The result is
that, "... we know a great deal about the procedures involved in the long
distance trade conducted between the mother-city Ashur(5) and the [trade]
colonies.(6) It was trade conducted by private persons and firms" (Larsen
1976, p. 376).

For Assyria, international trade was essential. Similar to many modern


industrialized societies, "Ashur had to rely on foreign trade simply in order
to ensure its own existence" (Larsen 1976, p. 85). The city of Ashur was
situated on the fringe of a rainfall zone and lacked an extensive nearby
agricultural base to feed its population. It appears to have existed due to its
strategic position as a fortress and transit town on the network of caravan
roads which criss-crossed the ancient Near Eastern world and the main
Mesopotamian distribution center for the vital tin trade.

Following this more general introduction of Assyrian trade this article


now turns to consider the trade through the lens of the eclectic paradigm.

Location and Internalization Advantages

Firms located at this ancient city center could be considered to enjoy a


location advantage, to use the terms of the eclectic paradigm. As a fortress it
could provide security which enabled a firm to hire a long term work force.
Outside a fortress constant danger of bandits and warring parties would
effectively preclude the development of a long term and trained workforce.
An additional location advantage was the city's position on the caravan
routes, which allowed for a steady flow of potential trading partners and
over time for relationships of trust to be developed (Larsen 1976, Casson
1995) which could reduce transaction costs compared to pure market
transactions.

Reducing transaction costs is central to the internalization dimension of


the OLI model. As pointed out by Casson (1995) trust is a central issue in
the development of common ownership structures. In this case it is possible
that as trading relationships grew, trust developed and as traders grew into
old age, they were willing to settle down and act as sole agents for their
former trading partners in far flung corners of the empire, suggesting the
introduction of a hierarchy, a key tenet of the eclectic paradigm.
Considerable evidence exists of hierarchical levels within Assyrian society.
It is not a far leap to suggest that hierarchies would also been adopted in the
business sector. Larsen makes a revealing statement, "The finances and the
technical organization of the firms were highly complex" (1976, p. 368).

Ashur enjoyed a location advantage of smaller tariffs over competitors


from outside the kingdom, for example when Erishum (circa 1940-1900
B.C.) established a freer market for silver, gold, copper, tin, barley, and wool
(Veenhof 1995). One piece of evidence of tariffs and taxes in this period is
from the code of Hammurabi (1792-1759 B.c.) which shows the Babylonian
palace imposing taxes on commerce, granting credits and maintaining
mechanisms for controlling trade (Aubet 1987).

A final potential location advantage could be deduced from the Assyrians'


achievement of somehow monopolizing the importation of tin from
Mesopotamia into Anatolia. Veenhof (1995) suggests this was "through the
institution of a well-administered, efficient caravan system" (p. 865).

Ownership Advantages

Today most historians agree that Assyria's tin came from Afghanistan,
several thousand kilometers away. This argues for some type of ownership
advantage or market-seeking behavior to support the necessity of
transporting metal considerable distances both to Ashur and then again for
export from Ashur to other places. Indeed the need to acquire resources or
markets is one of the three critical factors suggested by Dunning (1993, p.
96) as central drivers for "international value-adding activity to occur."

The trade between Ashur and Anatolia consisted primarily of large


quantities of tin and textiles being shipped from Ashur to Anatolia and in
return silver, gold and bronze in the form of manufactured goods, usually
household utensils being shipped from Anatolia to Ashur (Veenhof 1972).
Here we see evidence of value being added to the tin being shipped from
Ashur and then sold back to Ashur. The skills to turn tin into bronze and
from bronze into manufactured goods were jealously guarded processes
which constituted ownership advantages. The importance of these type of
skills is highlighted by the lack of natural resources in the area. According to
Orlin (1970), "it [this region] contains no deposits of stone or metals, nor is
there good timber available for building ... from the earliest times in its
history the inhabitants ... had to import vital materials from neighboring
countries" (p. 49). The importance of these skills was recognized by the
development of special associations or guilds of workmen, one of which was
the tamkarum or professional trader (Mendelsohn 1940, Orlin 1970),
suggesting the development of early knowledge workers. As noted earlier,
ownership advantages include proprietary information which can include
knowledge developed by the firm by R&D (both technical and marketing),
managerial experience, new production techniques, production
differentiation and market knowledge (Ietto-Gillies 1992, Dunning 1993).

Market knowledge, both of the tin and bronze markets in Ashur and
Anatolia but also in other countries-another ownership advantage-was also
highly valued in these cities. Aubet (1987) indicates that market and price
fluctuations existed from at least the end of the fourth millennium B.C. With
these market fluctuations market knowledge became even more valuable.
The historical record indicates that Sumerian writing developed in response
to the need to keep business inventories, indicating the value of market
knowledge in ancient times. The textiles shipped from Ashur to Anatolia
were most probably produced in Ashur from imported wool (Larsen 1976),
suggesting the possibility that the specific skills necessary for textile
manufacture necessitated the shipment of wool to Ashur and then from
Ashur to other locales, rather than directly to these other locales, again
indicating both ownership and location advantages at Ashur.

Another potential ownership advantage is suggested by Larsen's comment


that, "since tin is a quite rare metal, it is likely that those who controlled
such mines held a powerful international position" (1976, p. 87). Though we
do not know who owned or exploited the tin mines it does nevertheless
demonstrate one of the four of Dunning's (1993) main types of foreign
production, resource-seeking behavior.
Pusu-ken, Son of Sueyya

This section focuses on the activities of one businessperson, Pusu-ken of


Ashur, and his family.(7) He appears to have lived around the time of King
Ikunum of Assyria, somewhere between approximately 1900 and 1875 B.C.
by the Middle Chronology.(8) Evidence suggests his was the first generation
to move from Ashur to take up permanent residence in Kanesh. In a parallel
with modern day life, records suggest that Pusu-ken's wife, Lamassi, spent
her married life living in the capital while her spouse spent all his time in a
foreign country. The growing importance of their foreign activities is
suggested by a change in the living arrangements of several of their four
sons, Sueyya II, Ashur-muttabbil, Buzazu and Iku-pasha, who either brought
their wives with them from Ashur or married a local from an important
family.

The importance of the family's business activities in society are evidenced


by the considerable correspondence between Pusu-ken and King Sargon I.
By having important family members move to a "foreign" location one sees
early efforts to internalize international business activities within the
hierarchy of the firm.(9) Additional evidence is presented by Veenhof
(1972) who suggests that Ashur's textile production was largely performed
by women of the merchant houses, many of whom had husbands who
worked in Anatolia. In this context the family may be seen as an early
business network. Within this family historians have found evidence of
occasional strained relationships. For example, the sons and daughter of
Pusu-ken brought a dispute over his will before the city-assembly of Ashur
(Goitein 1967). A relevant ancient Arabic saying is Tahababu wa-tahasabu,
"love each other, but make accounts with each other" (Goitein 1967).

Pusu-ken appears to have been a sedentary merchant who traveled little,


while having a large staff of employees or subordinates in Anatolia. This
hierarchy managed the day-to-day affairs of the firm, as was the case with
other firms, sending employees and other agents to cities throughout the
Anatolian region for extended periods, again demonstrating one of
Dunning's (1993) four main types of foreign production, market-seeking
behavior.

As was typical of firms in this age, non-Assyrian natives of the area, from
Pusu-ken's view foreigners, were usually limited to inferior and peripheral
jobs (Orlin 1970, Lasswell/Kaplan 1950). In contrast, Assyrians residing in
Anatolia were allowed the same rights and status as if they had resided in
Assyria proper (Orlin 1970), in a manner similar to many of today's
expatriates. Evidence is found in the cuneiform tablets of the era of
businesspeople of varied origins, including Syrian and Eblaite, suggesting
the possibility of a multi-cultural workforce.

Financing of the enterprise was most likely provided by a partnership


based on a naruqqum, essentially a capital fund invested by several investors
for a merchant active in foreign trade. The naruqqum was similar to a long-
term partnership entered into by a group of people and provided a
considerable amount of capital for the firm operated by the merchant. The
single contract which has to date been unearthed is that of Amur-Ishtar who
himself invested 4 minas of gold in the "sack" or partnership and fourteen
others who invested an additional 26 minas of gold. The agreement
stipulated he would conduct business with these 30 minas for a period of
twelve years, and also included provisions for the distribution of profits and
a penalty for early withdrawal of funds from the investment pool (Larsen
1976). This suggests an early type of stock market complete with
shareholders, shareholders rights, a long term perspective and obligations
and a "professional manager". In this case the manager, Amur-Ishtar
received one-third of the profits, a handsome reward, even by today's
standards.

In common with today's businesspeople, Pusu-ken had to deal with


governmental involvement in his business activities. The Ashur city
assembly imposed strict controls on the import of textiles from Anatolia to
Ashur. Documentary evidence shows that Pusu-ken was fined for trying to
circumvent the protectionist policies of the government (Larsen 1976).

Issues of Contemporary Relevance in Assyria

The current relevance of ancient issues inspires some reflection. For


example, Aubet (1987) discusses the role of government and private
enterprise in ninth and eighth century B.C. Phoenicia: "... this whole
scenario underwent substantial changes. Stemming from the Assyrian
expansion, we witness the massive arrival in western Asia of the private
element in the sphere of commerce, coinciding, in the opinion of some
authors with a considerable decline in the part played by the Phoenician
palace and monarchy in economics activity" (p. 95). As mentioned above,
business found itself fined by government when violating its protectionist
policies. Veenhof (1995) relates how King Ilushuma (circa 1950 B.C.) took
measures to attract foreign trades from the south (Akkad) to Ashur markets.
He points to this governmental policy as one possible explanation for the
monopoly on the tin trade enjoyed by Ashur between the mines and
Anatolia, in today's terms, providing help for infant industries.

The importance of infrastructure (Porter 1990) and government's


contribution to building an environment for international business has been
the subject of considerable debate in recent years (e.g. Porter 1991). It is
perhaps enlightening to realize that historians believe that without peace and
the ability of merchants and their governmental agencies to cooperate with
authorities in foreign countries, trade would not have grown to the degree it
did in the Assyrian Empire (Larsen 1976). The importance of industry
clusters (Porter 1990) may be seen in the tin industry in Ashur and Anatolia.
Ashur was a center of distribution for raw tin and Anatolia a center for
distribution as well as value-adding processes, such as bronze production
and manufacturing of bronze objects. The availability of early training
centers and hence a trained workforce as well as merchant's knowledge of
the tin market were important reasons for the recognition of Ashur as a
center of the tin industry (Larsen 1976).

The question of which form of capitalism is "best" remains an area of


controversy today with a consensus of many researchers and writers
suggesting a contingency model of capitalism, dependent upon the culture
and history of a country (Hofstede 1991, Hampden-Turner/Trompenaars
1993, Redding 1995). In light of the success of Chinese family style
capitalism (Redding 1995), perhaps we can view ancient Assyrian family
capitalism in a similar positive light. Our focus on family firms in the old
Assyrian Kingdom may be a result of possible bias in the archaeological
artifacts; thus far the records uncovered in Anatolia have been almost
exclusively from private homes (Larsen 1976). Given that only an estimated
third of the records have been published it is possible evidence from a more
diverse set of sources may come to light in the future.

The Assyrian treatment of foreign employees and their general assignment


to inferior and peripheral jobs (Orlin 1970, Lassweel/Kaplan 1950) echoes
today's debate on the role of the subsidiary within the MNE and especially
on the means of providing interesting strategic roles within a globalizing
MNE (Bartlett/Ghoshal 1989, Moore 1997). Today we find a considerable
literature (Graham/Sano 1989, Adler 1991, Cox 1993) to help guide
managers through the challenges of a multi-cultural workforce. As
mentioned earlier, evidence is found in the cuneiform tablets of the era of
businesspeople of varied origins, including Syria. People from Ebla are also
mentioned, suggesting the possibility of a multicultural workforce and all the
management complexities associated with such a group.

Conclusion

In an effort to fill an important gap in the literature on the history of


MNEs this article presented evidence suggesting that the first recorded
MNEs appeared in the Old Assyrian Kingdom shortly after 2000 B.C. Using
the eclectic paradigm as a model to analyze ancient international trade it
demonstrates that the major characteristics of MNEs were a part of the
Assyrian business organizations of the time. The definition of MNE
accepted by the OECD and the UNCTC, "an enterprize that engages in
foreign direct investment (FDI) and owns or controls value-adding activities
in more than one country" (Dunning 1993, p. 3), leads us to conclude that
there were MNEs in ancient Assyria around 2000 B.C. Characteristics found
in modern MNEs such as: hierarchical organization, foreign employees,
value-adding activities in multiple regions, common stock ownership,
resource and market seeking behavior, were present in these ancient firms.
These early MNEs successfully operated considerable business empires in
multiple foreign locations from their corporate headquarters in the capital of
Ashur. Undoubtedly more will be learnt about the commerce of the old
Assyrian kingdom, as records from archaeological finds continue to be
translated and new finds uncovered. Larsen (1976) estimates that only "25 %
of present excavated material is available for study" (p. 51).

Were there early MNEs or "proto-MNEs" earlier than the Assyrian


empire? There may well have been. However, practical difficulties arise due
to the lack of archaeological evidence from other nations and empires in
earlier epochs. One looks forward to the work of other scholars to shed light
on this interesting issue.

Notes

1 Two other important theories which seek to explain foreign activities of


firms are the internationalization theory of the MNE (Buckley/Casson 1976;
Hennart 1982) and the macro-economic theory of foreign direct investment
(Kojima 1973, 1990).
2 Taking a broader view of what constitutes an advantage is key to the
argument of this article: that MNEs existed in Assyria before 2000 B.C. The
evidence from these ancient times is quite fragmentary, a phenomena which
historians are typically accustomed to, this is less the experience of
international business scholars. By including knowledge inputs in our
discussion we are more apt to "allow in" the type of evidence which
archaeology is able to provide.

3 We do not believe that state assistance is something which should


preclude an organization from being considered a firm, given the state
assistance is provided in many countries today to MNEs and local firms. For
example, one just needs to consider subsidies give to some European firms
which are an issue of considerable contention in the EU today (Taylor 1996).

4 Were there early MNEs or "proto-MNEs" prior to the Assyrian empire?


There may well have been, however, practical difficulties arise due to the
lack of archaeological evidence from other nations and empires in earlier
epochs.

5 The spelling of the name of the capital is generally accepted today as


Ashur, some of the quotes used the spelling of their day.

6 Though Larsen called them trade colonies they were settlements of


Assyrian and other nationality businesspeople in foreign kingdoms in this
case Cappadocia.
7 This section on Pusu-ken and his life is adapted from Larsen (1976) who
draws on the work of various archaeologists.

8 It is difficult to accurately date events in this time period, according to


the Cambridge Ancient History (1970), "the chronology in ancient western
Asia bristles with problems" (p. 193). The chronology given is the most
popular one among historians.

9 At this juncture in history firms were on often based to a large degree on


familial relationships, making an interesting parallel with Redding's view on
Chinese capitalism (Redding 1995).

References

Adams, R./Nissen, J., The Uruk Countryside: The Natural Setting of


Urban Societies, Chicago: Chicago University Press 1972.

Adler, N., International Dimensions of Organizational Behavior, Belmont,


CA: Wadsworth 1991.

Aubet, M., The Phoenicians and the West: Politics, Colonies and Trade,
translated from the Spanish by Mary Turton, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press 1987.

Bartlett, C./Ghoshal S., Managing across Borders: The Transnational


Solution, Boston: Harvard Business School Press 1989.
Buckley, P./Casson, M., The Future of the Multinational Enterprise,
London: Macmillan 1976.

Buckley, P., The Role of Management in Internalisation Theory,


Management International Review, 33, 3, 1993, pp.197-207.

Cambridge Ancient History, Prolegomena and Prehistory, 3rd edition, 1,1,


Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 1970.

Casson, M., The Firm and the Market, Oxford: Basil Blackwell 1987.

Casson, M., The Organization of International Business: Studies in the


Economics of Trust, Aldershot, U.K.: Edward Elgar 1995.

Chandler, A., Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism,


Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press 1990.

Cox, T., Cultural Diversity in Organizations: Theory, Research &


Practice, San Francisco: Berrett-Koehler 1993.

Dunning, J., The Globalization of Firms and the Competitiveness of


Countries; Some Implications for the Theory of International Production, in
Globalization of Firms and The Competitiveness of Nations, Luanda,
Sweden: Lurid University Press 1990, pp. 9-57.

Dunning, J., Multinational Enterprises and The Global Economy,


Wokingham, England: Addison-Wesley 1993.
Goitein, S., A Mediterranean Society, Berkeley, CA: University of
California Press 1967.

Gough, K., Implications of Literacy in Traditional China and India, in


Goody, J. (ed.), Literacy in Traditional Societies, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press 1968, pp. 27-68.

Graham, J./Sano, H., Smart Bargaining: Doing Business With the


Japanese, New York: Harper Business 1989.

Hampden-Turner, C. and Trompenaars, F., The Seven Cultures of


Capitalism, London: Piatkus 1993.

Hawkins, D., The Origin and Dissemination of Writing in Western Asia,


in Moorey, P. (ed.), The Origins of Civilisation, Wolfson College Lectures
1978, Oxford: Clarendon Press 1979, pp. 128-166.

Hennart, J.F., A Theory of Multinational Enterprize, Ann Arbor, MI:


University of Michigan Press 1982.

Hofstede, G., Cultures and Organizations: Software of the Mind, New


York: McGraw-Hill 1991.

Ietto-Gillies, G., International Production: Trends, Theories, Effects,


Oxford: Blackwell 1992.
Kojima, K., Reorganization of North-south Trade: Japan's Foreign
Economics Policy for the 1970's, Hitosubashi Journal of Economics, 23,
1973, pp. 630-40.

Kojima, K., Japanese Direct Investment Abroad, Tokyo: International


Christian University, Social Science Research Institute Monograph Series 1,
1990.

Larsen, M., The Old Assyrian City-State and Its Colonies, Copenhagen:
Akademisk Forlag 1976.

Lasswell, H. and Kaplan, A., Power and Society, New Haven 1950.

Mendelsohn, I., Guilds in Babylonia and Assyria, The Journal of the


American Oriental Society, 60, 1940, pp. 68-72.

Moore, K., A Globalization Strategy for Subsidiaries: Subsidiary Specific


Advantage, Journal of International Business Studies, 28, 1, 1997 pp. 217-
218.

North, D., Structure and Change in Economic History, New York: W.W.
Norton 1981.

Orlin, L., Assyrian Colonies in Cappadocia, The Hague: Mouton 1970.

Porter, M., The Competitive Advantage of Nations, Boston: Free Press


1990.
Porter, M., Canada At The Crossroads: The Reality of a New Competitive
Environment. A study prepared for the Business Council on National Issues
and the Government of Canada. Ottawa: Business Council on National
Issues 1991.

Powelson, J., Centuries of Economic Endeavor, Ann Arbor, MI: The


University of Michigan Press 1994.

Redding, G., Overseas Chinese Networks: Understanding the Enigma,


Long Range Planning, 28, 1995, pp. 61-69.

Rostow, W., The World Economy: History and Prospect, Austin, TX:
University of Texas Press 1978.

Rugman, A., A New Theory of the Multinational Enterprise:


Internationalization Versus Internalization, Columbia Journal of World
Business, Spring 1980, pp. 23-29.

Rugman, A./Gestrin, M., The Strategic Response of Multinational


Enterprises to NAFTA, Columbia Journal of World Business 28, 4, 1993,
pp. 18-28.

Taylor, A., Finns Break Into Growing Market Dominated by Italians,


Financial Times, December 5, 1996, pp. 7.
Veenhof, K., Aspects of Old Assyrian Trade and Its Terminology, Leiden:
Free University 1972.

Veenhof, K., Kanesh: An Assyrian Colony in Anatolia, in Sasson,


J./Barnes, J./Beckman, G./Rubinson, K. (eds.), Civilisations of the Ancient
Near East New York: Simon & Schuster MacMillan 1995, 2, pp. 859-871.

Authors

Karl Moore, Fellow in Strategic Management and International Business,


Templeton College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK.

David Lewis, Visiting Academic, Templeton College, Oxford University,


Oxford, UK.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi