Explorer les Livres électroniques
Catégories
Explorer les Livres audio
Catégories
Explorer les Magazines
Catégories
Explorer les Documents
Catégories
15
Investment,
Time, and
Capital Markets
Prepared by:
Fernando & Yvonn
Quijano
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
CHAPTER 15 OUTLINE
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
2 of 34
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
3 of 34
15.1
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
4 of 34
15.2
interest rate
$1
(1 R)
$1
PDV of $1 paid after 2 years =
(1 R) 2
$1
PDV of $1 paid after 3 years =
(1 R)3
$1
PDV of $1 paid after n years =
(1 R) n
PDV of $1 paid after 1 year =
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
5 of 34
15.2
Table 15.1 shows, for different interest rates, the present value of $1
paid after 1, 2, 5, 10, 20, and 30 years. Note that for interest rates
above 6 or 7 percent, $1 paid 20 or 30 years from now is worth very
little today. But this is not the case for low interest rates. For
example, if R is 3 percent, the PDV of $1 paid 20 years from now is
about 55 cents. In other words, if 55 cents were invested now at the
rate of 3 percent, it would yield about $1 after 20 years.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
6 of 34
15.2
Which payment stream in the table above would you prefer to receive?
The answer depends on the interest rate.
$100
PDV of Stream A $100
(1 R)
$100
$100
PDV of Stream B $20
(1 R) (1 R) 2
For interest rates of 10 percent or less, Stream B is worth more; for interest rates of
15 percent or more, Stream A is worth more. Why? Because even though less is
paid out in Stream A, it is paid out sooner.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
7 of 34
15.2
(1 R )
(1 R) 2
W0 (1 g ) 7 (1 m7 )
(1 R)7
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
8 of 34
15.3
PDV =
$100
$100
$100
(1 R ) (1 R )2
(1 R)10
$1000
(1 R)10
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
(15.1)
9 of 34
15.3
Perpetuities
PDV =
$100
$100
$100
$100
2
3
4
(1 R) (1 R) (1 R) (1 R)
PDV =$100 / R
(15.2)
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
10 of 34
15.3
Effective Yield
Suppose the market priceand thus the valueof the perpetuity is P. Then
from equation (15.2), P = $100/R, and R = $100/P. Thus, if the price of the
perpetuity is $1000, we know that the interest rate is R = $100/$1000 = 0.10,
or 10 percent. This interest rate is called the effective yield, or rate of return.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
11 of 34
15.3
Effective Yield
Figure 15.2
Effective Yield on a Bond
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
12 of 34
15.3
The yield on the General Electric bond is given by the following equation
98.77
5.0
5.0
5.0
5.0
(1 R) (1 R) 2 (1 R)3
(1 R)6
100
(1 R) 6
To find the effective yield, we must solve this equation for R. The solution is
approximately R* = 5.256 percent.
The yield on the General Electric bond is given by the following equation
92.00
8.875 8.875
8.875
8.875
(1 R) (1 R) 2 (1 R)3
(1 R)15
100
(1 R)15
R* = 9.925 percent.
The yield on the Ford bond was much higher because the Ford bond was much
riskier.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
13 of 34
15.4
NPV = C +
10
1
2
(1 R) (1 R) 2
(1 R)10
(15.3)
where R is the discount rate that we use to discount the future stream of
profits. Equation (15.3) describes the net benefit to the firm from the
investment. The firm should make the investment only if that net benefit is
positivei.e., only if NPV > 0.
discount rate Rate used to determine the value today of a dollar
received in the future.
Determining the Discount Rate
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
14 of 34
15.4
(1 R) (1 R ) 2 (1 R )3
.96
1
(1 R) 20 (1 R) 20
NPV= 10+
(15.4)
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
15 of 34
15.4
Figure 15.3
Net Present Value of a Factory
For discount rates below 7.5 percent, the NPV is positive, so the firm should
invest in the factory. For discount rates above 7.5 percent, the NPV is
negative, and the firm should not invest. R* is sometimes called the internal
rate of return on the investment.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
16 of 34
15.4
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
17 of 34
15.4
(1 R) (1 R) 2 (1 R)3 (1 R) 4 (1 R)5
.96
1
(1 R )20 (1 R) 20
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
18 of 34
15.5
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
19 of 34
15.5
ri rf ( rm rf )
(15.6)
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
20 of 34
15.5
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
21 of 34
15.5
93.4
56.6
40
(1 R ) (1 R )2 (1 R)3
40
40
(1 R )4
(1 R )15
NPV= 120
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
22 of 34
15.5
R 0.04 1(
At this discount rate, the NPV is clearly negative, so the investment does
not make sense.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
23 of 34
15.6
(1 R) (1 R) 2
(S E )
4000
L
(1 R)6 (1 R )6
What discount rate R should the consumer use? The consumer
should apply the same principle that a firm does: The discount rate is
the opportunity cost of money, the return that could be earned by
investing the money in another asset.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
24 of 34
15.6
PDV = Ci OCi
OCi
OCi
OCi
(1 R) (1 R ) 2
(1 R )8
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
25 of 34
15.7
NPV = 40
40
40
40
20
20
(1 R) (1 R ) 2 (1 R)3 (1 R) 4
(1 R) 23
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
26 of 34
*15.8
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
27 of 34
*15.8
Figure 15.4
Price of an Exhaustible
Resource (Part I)
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
28 of 34
*15.8
Figure 15.4
Price of an Exhaustible
Resource (Part II)
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
29 of 34
*15.8
User Cost
user cost of production Opportunity cost of
producing and selling a unit today and so making
it unavailable for production and sale in the future.
In Figure 15.4, user cost is the difference between
price and marginal production cost. It rises over time
because as the resource remaining in the ground
becomes scarcer, the opportunity cost of depleting
another unit becomes higher.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
30 of 34
*15.8
(MR t 1 c ) = (1 R )(M
If marginal revenue less marginal cost rises at the rate of interest,
price less marginal cost will rise at less than the rate of interest. We
thus have the interesting result that a monopolist is more
conservationist than a competitive industry. In exercising monopoly
power, the monopolist starts out charging a higher price and depletes
the resource more slowly.
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
31 of 34
*15.8
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
32 of 34
15.9
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
33 of 34
15.9
Copyright 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Microeconomics Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e.
34 of 34