Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 27

Two Alternative Binomial Option Pricing Model Approaches to

Derive Black-Scholes Option Pricing Model


1
CHENG-FEW LEE
Department of Finance and Economics, Rutgers Business School
Rutgers University, New Brunswick
New Jersey, U.S.
CARL S. LIN
Department of Economics
Rutger University, New Brunswick
New Jersey, U.S.
Abstract
In this chapter, we review two famous models on binomial option pricing, Rendleman and
Barter (RB, 1979) and Cox, Ross, and Rubinstein (CRR, 1979). We show that the limiting
results of the two models both lead to the celebrated Black-Scholes formula. From our
detailed derivations, CRR is easy to follow if one has the advanced level knowledge in
probability theory but the assumptions on the model parameters make its applications limited.
On the other hand, RB model is intuitive and does not require higher level knowledge in
probability theory. Nevertheless, the derivations of RB model are more complicated and
tedious. For readers who are interested in the binomial option pricing model, they can
compare the two different approaches and find the best one which fits their interests and is
easier to follow.
1. Introduction
The main purpose of this chapter is to review two famous binomial option pricing
model: Rendleman and Barter (RB, 1979) and Cox, Ross, and Rubinstein (CRR, 1979).
First, we will give an alternative detailed derivation of the two models and show that
the limiting results of the two models both lead to the celebrated Black-Scholes
1
Section 3 of this chapter is essentially drawing from the paper by Lee et al.(2004).
1
formula. Then we will make comparisons of the two different approaches and analyze
the advantages of each approach.
Hence, this chapter can help to understand the statistical aspects of option pricing
models for Economics and Finance professions. Also, it gives important financial and
economic intuitions for readers in statistics professions. Therefore, by showing two
alternative binomial option pricing models approaches to derive the Black-Scholes
model, this chapter is useful for understanding the relationship between the two
important optional pricing models and the Black-Scholes formula.
2. The Two-State Option Pricing Model of Rendleman and Bartter
In Rendleman and Bartter (1979), a stock price can either advance or decline during the
next period. Let
T
H
+
and
T
H

represent the returns per dollar invested in the stock if the


price rises (the + state) or falls (the - state), respectively, from time T-1 to time T. And
T
V
+
and
T
V

the corresponding end-of-period values of the option.


Let R be the riskless interest rate, Rendleman and Bartter (1979) show that the price
of the option can be represented as a recursive form
2
1
(1 ) ( 1 )
( )(1 )
T T T
T
T T
V R H V H R
P
H H R
+ +

+
+ +

+
that can be applied at any time T-1 to determine the price of the option as a function of
its value at time T.
2.1 The Discrete Time Model
From the above equation, the value of a call option at maturing date T-1 is given by
1
(1 ) ( (1 ))
( )(1 )
T T
T
W R H W H R
W
H H R
+ +
+
+ + +

+
(2.1)
Similarly,
1 1
2
(1 ) ( (1 ))
( )(1 )
T T
T
W R H W H R
W
H H R
+ +

+
+ + +

+
(2.2)
Substituting (2.1) into (2.2) can get,
2 2 2
( (1 ) ( (1 )))(1 )
( ) (1 )
T T
T
W R H W H R R H
W
H H R
++ + +
+
+ + + +

+

2 2
( (1 ) ( (1 )))( (1 ))
( ) (1 )
T T
W R H W H R H R
H H R
+ + +
+
+ + + + +
+
+
(2.3)
Noting that
T T
W W
+ +
, so (2.3) can be simplified as:
2 2
2 2 2
( (1 ) 2 ( (1 )))(1 ) ( (1 ))
( ) (1 )
T T T
T
W R H W H R R H W H R
W
H H R
++ + + +
+
+ + + + + +

+

(2.4)
3
We can use this recursive form to get
0
W
:
Since after T periods, there are
0
T _

,
ways that a sequence of (T) pluses can occur,
1
T _

,
ways that (T-1) pluses can occur,
2
T _

,
ways that (T-2) pluses can occur, and so
on.
Hence, by Binomial Theorem
0
W
can be represented as:
0
W
...... 0
...... 1 1
..... 2 2
.... 1 1
...... 0
[ (1 ) ( (1 ))
0
(1 ) ( (1 ))
1
(1 ) ( (1 ))
2
(1 ) ( (1 ))
1
(1 ) ( (1
T
T
T
T
T
T
T
T
T
T
W R H H R
T
W R H H R
T
W R H H R
T
W R H H R
T
T
W R H H
T
+ + +
+ +
+ +
+ +
+
_
+ +

,
_
+ + +

,
_
+ + +

,
_
+ + +

,
_
+ + +

,
M
)) ]
[( )(1 )]
T
T
R
H H R
+
+
(2.5)
Next to determine the value of the option at maturity. Suppose that stock increases i
times and declines
( ) T i
times, then the price of the stock will be
0
i T i
S H H

+
on the
expiration date. So the option will be exercised if
4
0
i T i
S H H X

+
>
The maturity value of the option will be

0
i T i
T
W S H H X

+
(2.6)
Let
a
denote the minimum integer value of i in (2.6) for which the inequality is
satisfied.

0
ln( ) ln( )
1
ln ln
X
T H
S
a INT
H H

+
1

1
+
1

1
]
(2.7)
where
[ ] INT
is the integer operator.
i.e., taking natural logarithm of RHS of (2.6),
0
0
0
ln ln ( ) ln ln
ln ln ln( ) ln
ln( ) ln
ln ln
S i H T i H X
X
i H i H T H
S
X
T H
S
i
H H
+
+

+
+ +

Hence, the maturing value of the option is given by



0
0
i T i
T
T
W S H H X if i a
W if i a

+

<
K K
K K
(2.8)
Substituting (2.8) into (2.5), then the generalized option pricing equation for the
5
discrete time is

0
0
( )(1 ) ( (1 ))
( ) (1 )
i T i
T
i T i
i a
T T
T
S H H X R H H R
i
W
H H R

+ +

+
_
+ +

,

(2.9)
2.2 The Continuous Time Model
For (2.9), we can write is as:
0
0
0
( )(1 ) ( (1 )) (1 ) ( (1 ))
( ) (1 )
[ (1 )] [ ( 1 )]
( ) (1 )
(1 ) ( (1 ))
(
i T i
T T
i T i i T i
i a i a
T T
T
i T i
i a
T T
T
i T i
i a
T T
S H H R H H R X R H H R
i i
W
H H R
T
S H R H H H R
i
H H R
T
X R H H R
i
H

+ + +

+
+ +

+
+

+
_ _
+ + + +

, ,

+
_
+

,

+
_
+ +

,

0
) (1 )
(1 ) ( 1 )
(1 )( ) ( )(1 )
(1 ) ( 1 )
(1 ) ( ) ( )
T T
i T i
T
i a
i T i
T
T
i a
H R
T
R H H H R H
S
i R H H H H R
T
X R H H R
i R H H H H

+ +
+ +

+
+ +

+
1 1 _ +

1 1
+ +
, ] ]
1 1 _ +

1 1
+
, ] ]

(2.10)
Since
(1 )
(1 )( )
R H H
R H H
+
+
+
+
+
( 1 )
1
( )(1 )
H R H
H H R
+
+

+
,
(1 ) ( 1 )
1
( ) ( )
R H H R
H H H H
+
+ +
+
+

,
therefore, can interpret it as pseudo probability.
Let
(1 )
(1 )( )
R H H
R H H

+
+
+

+
and
(1 )
( )
R H
H H

+
+

, we can restate (2.10) as:


6

0 0
( , , ) ( , , )
(1 )
T
X
W S B a T B a T
R

+
(2.11)
where
( , , ( )) B a T
is the cumulative binomial probability function, the number of
successes will fall between
a
and T after T trials.
As T ,
0 0 1 1 2 2
( , ) ( , )
(1 )
T
X
W S N Z Z N Z Z
R

+
:
(2.12)
where
( , ) N Z Z
is the probability of a normally distributed random variable with zero
mean and variance 1 taking values between a lower limit Z and a upper limit Z . And
by the property of binomial pdf,
1 1
2 2
,
(1 ) (1 )
,
(1 ) (1 )
a T T T
Z Z
T T
a T T T
Z Z
T T










Thus,
0 0 1 1 2 2
(lim , lim ) (lim , lim )
lim(1 )
T
T T T T
T
X
W S Z Z N Z Z
R


+
(2.13)
Let
1
r
T
R e +
, then
lim(1 )
T r
T
R e

+
. And since 1 2
lim lim
T T
Z Z


, the remaining
things to be determined are 1
lim
T
Z

and 2
lim
T
Z

.
From equation (10) and (11) of the text in the Rendleman and Bartter (1979),
7
(1 )
( )
( )
(1 )
T
T
T
T
H e
H e

+
+

substituting
H
+
and
H

into (2.7), so
0
1
ln( )
1
1
(1 )
(1 ) (1 )
X
T
S
INT T
T
a T
Z
T T


1
+
1

1
+
1
1

]


In the limit, the term
1 [ ] INT +
will be simplify to
[ ]
. So,
0
1
0
0
0
ln( )
1 1
1
(1 ) (1 )
(1 ) (1 )
ln( )
1
1
(1 ) (1 ) (1 )
(1 )
(1 )
ln( )
1
(1 ) (1 ) (1 )
(1 )
(1 )
ln( )
(1 )
1
(1 )
(1 )
X
T
S
Z
T T
T T
X
T
S T
T T
T
X
T
S T
T T
T
X
T T
S
T

:
:
:
:
0
(1 ) (1 )
ln( )
( )
(1 ) (1 )
(1 )
T
T
X
S T

:
(2.14)
8
Substituting
H
+
,
H

and
1
r
T
R e +
into

,
1
( ) ( )
1
1
( ) ( )
1
1
( ) ( )
1
1
( ) ( )
1
1 1
( ) ( ) ( )
1
(1 )
(1 )( )
r
T T T T T
r
T T T T T
r
T T T T
r
T T
T
r
T T T T T
R H H
R H H
e e e
e e e
e e e
e e e
e e














+
+

+
1
1
1
]

1
1
1
]
1
1
1
]

1
1
1
]

1
( ) ( )
1
1 1
( ) ( )( )
1
1 1
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
1 1
T T
r
T T T T
T T T T
e e
e e
e e e e










1
1
1
]
1
1
1
]
1 1
1 1
1 1
] ]

1 1
1 1
1 1
] ]
Now expanding in Taylors series in T,
9
2 2
2 2
2
1
( )
1
1 1 1 1
( ) ( ) ( )
1 2 1
1 1
( ) ( )
2 1
1 1 1 1
( ) ( ) ( )
1 2 1
1
( )
1
2 1
1 1 1 1
( ) ( )( ) ( )
1 2 1
1
1 1
( ) ( )(
1 2
T o
T
T o
T T
r O
T
T o
T T
r
T
o
T T
T

1

+ + +
1

]
+ +

+
1

+ + +
1

]
+


+ + +

+ +

1
( )
1 1
) ( )
1
o
T
o
T


+
1

+
1

]
where,
2
3
2
1 1 1
1
2!
1 1
3!
1 1 1
1
2
H
T T
T T
T T
o
T T T T




+
_ _

+ + + +


, ,
_

+ + +


,

_ _
+ + + +

, ,
L
and
2
3
2
1
1
1 2! 1
1
3! 1
1
1
1 2 1
H
T T
T T
T T
o
T T T T


_ _
+ +



, ,
_
+ +

,
_ _
+ + + +


, ,
L
10
where
1
( ) o
T
denotes a function tending to zero more rapidly than
1
T
.(when we
expanding in Taylors series in T, the rest of the terms tending to zero more rapidly than
1
T
so regard them as a function
1
( ) o
T
.) Hence,
2
1 1
lim (1 )
1
1
1
(1 )
1
T

and,
11
2 2
2
2 2
2
lim ( )
1
( )
1
2 1
lim [
1 1 1 1
( ) ( )( ) ( )
1 2 1
1
1
( )]
1 1 1 1
( ) ( )( ) ( )
1 2 1
1
( )
2 1
lim[
1 1 1 1
( ) ( )( ) ( )
1 2 1
T
T
T
T
r
T
T
o
T T
o
T
o
T T
r
T
o
T
T
T



+ + +


1

+ + +
1

]
+



+ + +

2
2
2 2
2
1
1
( )]
1 1 1 1
( ) ( )( ) ( )
1 2 1
1 1 1 1
( ) ( )( ) ( )
1 2 1 1
lim
1 1 1 1
( ) ( )( ) ( )
1 2 1
1
( )
2 1
1 1 1
( ) ( )( ) (
1 2 1
T
To
T
o
T
T
T o T
T T
o
T T
r
o
T

1

+ + +
1

]
1

+ + +
1

]


+ + +

+


+ + +

2 2 2
2 2
2 2 2
2 2 2
2 2 2 2
1
( )
1
)
1 1 1
( ) ( ( ) )
2 1 2 1
1
( )
1
1 (1 ) 1
( ) ( )
2 (1 ) 2 1
1
(1 )
1 1 2 1
( ) ( )
2 1 2 1
1
(1 )
1 1 1 1
( ) ( ) ( )
2 1 2 1 2 1
1
(1 )
To
T
T
r
r
r
r




+ +

+ +

+ +

12
After canceling terms,
2
1
(1 )( )
2
lim ( )
T
r
T

+

Now substituting
lim
T

for

and
lim ( )
T
T

for ( ) T into (2.14),


2
0
1
2
0
1
ln( )
(1 )( )
2
lim
(1 ) (1 )
(1 )
1
ln( )
2
T
X
r
S
Z
X
r
S

Similarly,
2
0
2
1
ln( )
2
lim
T
X
r
S
Z

Since
( , ) ( , ) N Z N Z
, let 1 1
lim
T
D Z


, 2 2
lim
T
D Z


, the continuous time
version of the two-state model is obtained:
0 0 1 2
2
0
1
2 1
( , ) ( , )
1
ln( )
2
r
w S N D Xe N D
X
r
S
D
D D


+ +


The above equation is identical to the Black-Scholes model.
13
3. The Binomial Option Pricing Model of Cox, Ross and Rubinstein
In this section we will concentrate on the limiting behavior of the binomial option
pricing model proposed by Cox, Ross and Rubinstein (CRR, 1979).
3.1 The Binomial Option Pricing Formula of CRR
Let S be the current stock price, K the option exercise price, 1 R the riskless rate. It
is assumed that the stock follows a binomial process, from one period to the next it can
only go up by a factor of
u
with probability
p
or go down by a factor of d with
probability
) 1 ( p
. After n periods to maturity, CRR showed that the option price C is:
. ] , 0 [ ) 1 (
)! ( !
! 1
0

n
k
k n k k n k
n
K S d u Max p p
k n k
n
R
C
(3.1)
An alternative expression for C, which is easier to evaluate, is
). , ; ( ) , ; (
] ) 1 (
)! ( !
!
[ ] ) 1 (
)! ( !
!
[
p n m B
R
K
p n m SB
p p
k n k
n
R
K
R
d u
p p
k n k
n
S C
n
n
m k
k n k
n
n
m k
k n k
k n k

(3.2)
where
) 1 ( ) , ; (


n
m k
k n k
k n
p p C p n m B
and m is the minimum number of upward
stock movements necessary for the option to terminate in the money, i.e., m is the
14
minimum value of k in (3.1) such that 0. X - S d
m - n m
> u
3.2 Limiting Case
We now show that the binomial option pricing formula as given in Equation (3.2) will
converge to the celebrated Black-Scholes option pricing model. The Black-Scholes
formula is
) ( ) (
1 1
t d N X e d N S C
rt


(3.3)
where
2
) log(
1
t
t
XR
S
d
t

+

(3.4)
2
= the variance of stock rate of return
t = the fixed length of calendar time to expiration date, such that
n
t
h .
We wish to show that Equation (3.2) will coincide with Equation (3.3) when
n
.
In order to show the limiting result that the binomial option pricing formula
converges to the continuous version of Black-Scholes option pricing formula, we
suppose that h represents the lapsed time between successive stock price changes.
Thus, if t is the fixed length of calendar time to expiration, and n is the total number of
15
periods each with length h, then
n
t
h . As the trading frequency increases, h will get
closer to zero. When 0 h , this is equivalent to
n
.
Let
R
be one plus the interest rate over a trading period of length h. Then, we will
have
t T
R R
(3.5)
for any choice of n. Thus,
n
t
R R

, which shows that


R
must depend on n for the total
return over elapsed time t to be independent of n. Also, in the limit,
n
r

+ ) 1 ( tends to
rt
e

as
n
.
Let S
*
be the stock price at the end of the nth period with the initial price S. If there
are j up periods, then
d n
d
u
j d j n u j
S
S
log ) log( log ) ( log log
*
+ + (3.6)
where j is the number of upward moves during the n periods.
Since j is the realization of a binomial random variable with probability of a success
being q, we have expectation of log (S
*
/S)
, ] log ) log( [ ) (log
*
n n d
d
u
q
S
S
E + (3.7)
and its variance
16
. ) 1 ( )] [log( ) (log
2 2
*
n n q q
d
u
S
S
Var (3.8)
Since we divide up our original longer time period t into many shorter subperiods of
length h so that hn t , our procedure calls for making n longer, while keeping the
length t fixed. In the limiting process we would want the mean and the variance of the
continuously compounded log rate of return of the assumed stock price movement to
coincide with that of actual stock price as
n
. Let the actual values of
n
and
n
2
respectively. Then we want to choose u, d, and q in such a manner that
t n
and t n
2 2
as
n
. It can be shown that if we set
,
n
t
e u

,
n
t
e d

(3.9)
,
2
1
2
1
n
t
q

,
_

then
t n
and t n
2 2
as
n
. In order to proceed further, we need the
following version of the central limit theorem.
Lyapounovs Condition. Suppose , ,
2 1
X X are independent and uniformly bounded
with
0 ) (
i
X E
,
,
1 n n
X X Y + +
and ). ( ) (
2 2
n n
Y Var Y E s
17
If
0
1
lim
1
2
2

+
+

n
k
k
n
n
X E
s

for some
, 0 >
then the distribution of
n
n
s
Y
converges to
the standard normal as
n
.
Theorem 1. If
3 3
3
log (1 ) log
0 as

p u p d
n
n

+
(3.10)
then
) (

) log(
Pr
*
z N z
n
n
S
S

1
1
1
1
]
1

(3.11)
where N(z) is the cumulative standard normal distribution function.
Proof. See Appendix.
It is noted that the condition (3.10) is a special case of the Lyapounovs condition
which is stated as follows. When
, 1
we have the condition (3.10).
This theorem says that when the fixed length t is divided into many subperiods, the
log rate of return will approach to the normal distribution when the number of
subperiods approached infinity. For this theorem to hold, the condition stated in
Equation (3.10) has to be satisfied. We next show that this condition is indeed satisfied.
We will next show that the binomial option pricing model as given in Equation (3.2)
18
will indeed coincide with the Black-Scholes option pricing formula as given in
Equation (3.3). Observe that
n
R

is always equal to
t
R

, as evidenced from Equation


(3.5). Thus, comparing the two option pricing formulae given in Equations (3.2) and
(3.3), we see that there are apparent similarities. In order to show the limiting result,
we need to show that as
n
,
) ( ) , ; ( x N p n m B
and ). ( ) , ; ( t x N p n m B
In this section we will only show the second convergence result, as the same
argument will hold true for the first convergence. From the definition of
) , ( pm n B
, it is
clear that
).
) 1 (
1
) 1 (
Pr(
) 1 Pr( ) , ; ( 1
p np
np m
p np
np j
m j p n m B


(3.12)
Recall that we consider a stock to move from S to uS with probability p and dS with
probability (1-p). During the fixed calendar period of t=nh with n subperiods of length
h, if there are j up moves, then
d n
d
u
j
S
S
log ) log( log
*
+ . (3.13)
The mean and variance of the continuously compounded rate of return for this stock
are
P

and
2

P
where
19
d
d
u
p
P
log ) log( + and ) 1 ( )] [log(
2 2
p p
d
u
P
.
From Equation (3.13) and the definitions for
P

and
2

P
, we have
n
n
S
S
p np
np j
P
P

) log(
) 1 (
*

. (3.14)
Also, from the binomial option pricing formula we have
, log / ] log [log
) log(
) log(
1



d
u
d n
S
X
d
u
Sd
X
m
n
where is a real number between 0 and 1.
From the definitions of
P

and
2

P
, it is easy to show that
.

) log( ) log(
) 1 (
1
n
d
u
n
S
X
p np
np m
P
P


Thus from Equation (3.12) we have
).

) log( log

log
Pr( ) , ; ( 1
*
n
d
u
n
S
X
n
n
S
S
p n m B
P
P
P
P


(3.15)
20
We will now check the condition given by Equation (3.10) in order to apply the
central limit theorem. Now recall that
d u
d r
p

,
with
n
t
r r
, and d and u are given in Equation (3.9).
We have
log
3
2
2
3
2
2
1
1
1 log [1 ] ( )
2

1 [1 ] ( )
1
log
1 1
2
[ ] ( ). (3.16)
2 2
t t
r
n n
t t
n n
e e
p
e e
t t t
r O n
n n n
t t
O n
n n
r
t
O n
n

+ + +

+ +

+ +
Hence, the condition given by Equation (10) is satisfied because
. as , 0
) 1 (
) 1 (

| log | ) 1 ( | log |
2 2
3
3 3

+
n
p np
p p
n
d p u p
p
p p


Finally, in order to apply the central limit theorem, we have to evaluate
n
p

,
n
p
2


and ) log(
d
u
as
. n
It is clear that
21
t n t r n
p p
2 2 2
, )
2
1
(log and 0 ) log(
d
u
.
Hence, in order to evaluate the asymptotic probability in Equation (3.12), we have
.
)
2
1
(log ) log(

) log( ) log(
2
t
t r
S
X
z
n
d
u
n
S
X
p
p




Using the fact that
) ( ) ( 1 z N z N
, we have, as
n
). ( ) ( ) , ; ( t x N z N p n m B
Similar argument holds for
) ' , ; ( p n m B
, and hence we completed the proof that the
binomial option pricing formula as given in equation (3.2) includes the Block-Scholes
option pricing formula as a limiting case.
4. Comparison of the Two Approaches
From the results of last two sections, we show that both RB and CRR models lead to
the celebrated Black-Scholes formula. The following table shows the comparisons of
the necessary mathematical and statistical knowledge and assumptions for the two
models.
Model Rendleman and Bartter (1979) Cox, Ross and Rubinstein (1979)
22
Mathematical
and
Probability
Theory
Knowledge
Basic Algebra
Taylor Expansion
Binomial Theorem
Central Limit Theorem
Properties of Binomial Distribution
Basic Algebra
Taylor Expansion
Binomial Theorem
Central Limit Theorem
Properties of Binomial Distribution
Lyapounovs Condition
Assumption 1. The distribution of returns of the
stock is stationary over time and the
stock pays no dividends.(Discrete
Time Model)
2. The mean and variance of
logarithmic returns of the stock are
held constant over the life of the
option.(Continuous Time Model)
The stock follows a binomial process
from one period to the next it can
only go up by a factor of u with
probability p or go down by a
factor of d with probability 1-p.
In order to apply the Central Limit
Theorem, u, d, and p are
needed to be chosen.
Advantage
and
Disadvantage
1. Readers who have undergraduate
level training in mathematics and
probability theory can follow this
approach.
2. The approach of RB is intuitive.
But the derivation is more
complicated and tedious than the
approach of CRR.
1. Readers who have advanced level
knowledge in probability theory can
follow this approach; but for those
who dont, CRR approach may be
difficult to follow.
2. The assumption on the parameters
u, d, p makes CRR approach
more restricted than RB approach.
Hence, like we indicate in the table, CRR is easy to follow if one has the advanced
level knowledge in probability theory but the assumptions on the model parameters
make its applications limited. On the other hand, RB model is intuitive and does not
require higher level knowledge in probability theory. However, the derivation is more
complicated and tedious.
For readers who are interested in the binomial option pricing model, they can
compare the two different approaches and find the best one which fits their interests and
is easier to follow.
23
Appendix
The Binomial Theorem
0
( )
n
n k n k
k
n
x y x y
k

_
+

,

Lindberg-Levy Central Limit Theorem


If
1
,...,
n
x x
are a random sample from a probability distribution with finite mean

and
finite variance
2
and
1
1
( )
n
i
i
x x
n


, then
2
( ) 0,
d
n
n x N 1
]
Proof of Theorem 1.
Since
3 3
3
3
log log log log (1 ) log
u u
p u p u p d p p
d d

And
3 3
3
3
(1 ) log (1 ) log log log (1 ) log ,
u u
p d p d p d p p
d d

24
We have
3
3 3
2 2
log (1 ) log (1 )[(1 ) ] log
u
p u p d p p p p
d
+ .
Thus
3 3
3
3
2 2
3
2 2
log (1 ) log

(1 )[(1 ) ] log
( (1 ) log( ))
(1 )
0 as .
(1 )
p u p d
n
u
p p p p
d
u
p p n
d
p p
n
np p

Hence the condition for the theorem to hold as stated in Equation (3.10) is satisfied.
References
Amram, M. and N. Kulatilaka, Real Options, Oxford University Press, USA, 2001.
Banz R. and M. Miller. Prices for State Contingent Claims: Some Estimates and
Applications, Journal of Business, Vol. 51 (1978, pp. 653-72).
Bhattachayra, M. Empirical Properties of the Black-Scholes Formula under Ideal
Conditions, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 15 (December 1980,
pp. 1081-1105).
Bhattacharya, R. N. and R. R. Rao. Normal Approximations and Asymptotic
Expansions, New York: Wiley. 1976.
Black, F. Capital Market Equilibrium with Restricted Borrowing, Journal of
Business, 45 (July 1972, pp. 444-45)
Black, F. and M. Scholes. The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities, Journal
of Political Economy, 31 (May-June 1973, pp. 637-59).
25
Bookstaber, R. M. Option Pricing and Strategies in Investing (Reading, MA: Addison-
Wesley, 1981).
Cox, J. c., and M. Rubinstein. Option Markets (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall,
1985).
Cox, J., S. A. Ross and M. Rubinstein. Option Pricing: A Simplified Approach.
Journal of Financial Economics, 7 (1979, pp. 229-263.)
Finnerty, J. The Chicago Board Options Exchange and Market Efficiency, Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 13 (March 1978, pp. 29-38).
Galai, D. and R. W. Masulis. The Option Pricing Model and the Risk Factor of Stock,
Journal of Financial Economics, 3 (1976, pp. 53-81).
Hull, J., Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives (Sixth ed), Prentice Hall, 2005.
Jarrow R. and Turnbull S., Derivatives Securities (Second ed), South-Western College
Pub, 1999.
Liaw, K.T. and R. L. Moy, The Irwin Guide to Stocks, Bonds, Futures, and Options,
McGraw-Hill Companies, New York, 2000.
Lee, Cheng F., and Alice C. Lee, Encyclopedia of Finance, Springer, New York, New
York, 2006.
Lee, Cheng F., Handbook of Quantitative Finance, Springer, New York, New York, 2009.
Lee, Jack C., C. F. Lee, R. S. Wang and T. I. Lin. On the Limit Properties of Binomial
and Multinomial Option Pricing Models: Review and Integration. Advances in
Quantitative Analysis of Finance and Accounting New Series Volume 1. Singapore:
World Scientific 2004.
MacBeth, J. and L. Merville. An Empirical Examination of the Black-Scholes Call
Option Pricing Model, The Jollrnal of Finance, 34 (December 1979, pp. 1173-86).
26
McDonald, R.L., Derivatives Markets (Second ed.), Addison Wesley, Boston,
Massachusetts, 2005.
Rendleman, R. J., Jr., and B. J. Barter. Two-State Option Pricing, Journal of Finance,
24 (1979, pp.1093-1110).
Ritchken, P. Optiom: Theory, Strategy, and Applications (Glenview, IL: Scott,
Foresman 1987).
Summa, J.F. and J.W. Lubow, Options on Futures, John Wiley & Sons, New York,
2001.
Trennepohl, G. A Comparison of Listed Option Premia and Black-Scholes Model
Prices: 1973-1979, Journal of Financial Research, (Spring 1981, pp. 11-20)
Zhang, P.G., Exotic Options: A Guide to Second Generation Options (Second ed),
World Scientific Pub Co Inc, 1998.
27

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi