Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 16

No.

362 December 1, 1999

Milking the Sacred Cow


A Case for Eliminating the Federal Dairy Program
by Kevin McNew

Executive Summary

Rich in calcium, protein, and vitamins, milk is number of marketing orders, recalculate the
one of the most nutritious items in the American price differentials among classes of milk, and
diet. Unfortunately, most consumers do not realize create a new way of setting price differentials
when they drink milk or scoop up tasty ice cream that would resemble the failed mechanism used
that the federal government artificially inflates milk in the old Soviet Union. FAIR also created what
prices. In 1995 American dairy farmers received as was supposed to be a temporary Northeast
much as $8 billion in assistance through various Compact of six New England states that was
price-distortion mechanisms. allowed to set a floor below which the price of
Today’s dairy policy is an outdated relic of the fluid milk could not drop. Congress considered
original Depression-era legislation. The U.S. letting the compact expand to include Maryland,
Department of Agriculture divides the country New Jersey, New York, and Pennsylvania and
into marketing order regions and establishes allowing the creation of a 16-state Southern
price differentials between classes of milk used Compact. Federal courts have been brought into
for drinking and for making such products as that battle. Further, Congress also considered
butter and cheese. Processors must purchase adopting so-called Option 1-A price differentials
milk at those different prices from farm cooper- that would be worse than the USDA changes.
atives in each region. But those policies actually Whether the agriculture secretary’s new
harm many farmers. The most efficient farmers approach stands or one of the alternatives is
in some marketing order regions produce more adopted, the price of milk will likely remain high,
milk than can be sold for high-priced liquid uses, harming consumers, and price distortions in the
and thus the excess must be sold for lower-priced future could require the federal government to
processed uses. Further, the federal government pay out increased subsidies to dairy farmers,
at various times purchases certain dairy prod- harming taxpayers. Instead of pursuing a com-
ucts to help prop up prices. plex, convoluted, and costly dairy policy,
Pursuant to the 1996 Federal Agricultural Congress could help consumers and efficient
Improvement Reform (FAIR) Act, the secretary farmers by eliminating the federal dairy pro-
of agriculture in 1999 proposed to reduce the gram.

___________________________________________________________________________________________

Kevin McNew is an assistant professor in the department of agricultural and resource economics at the University
of Maryland, College Park.
Milk supplies Prelude to Regulation hibited price fixing. In 1922 the Capper-
tend to be highest Volstead Act resolved the dispute by giving
The American dairy industry has a history dairy cooperatives antitrust immunity, allow-
in the spring and of regulation dating back to the 1930s. ing farmers to collude and participate in
summer and low- Although a number of different policy mech- price-setting behavior.1
anisms have been used over the years, the two The cooperatives, however, faced a diffi-
est in the fall and mainstays of dairy policy have been Federal cult challenge in pricing their members’ milk.
winter, while Milk Marketing Orders and dairy price sup- First, there was (and still is) a natural imbal-
consumption pat- ports. To provide a context for understand- ance between the seasonal nature of milk
ing today’s regulations, it is useful to consid- supply and demand. Milk supplies tend to be
terns of fluid er the conditions that existed prior to the highest in the spring and summer and lowest
milk are the 1930s. in the fall and winter, while consumption
reverse: highest In the late 1800s, the dairy sector, like patterns of fluid milk are the reverse: highest
other sectors of the American economy, ben- during the fall and winter (when schools are
during the fall efited from the expansion of the railroad sys- in session) and lowest during the spring and
and winter (when tem and later from the development of roads. summer. Second, milk is a highly perishable
Milk is a highly perishable commodity, com- product that could not be stored, which lim-
schools are in ses- posed of 85 percent water. Earlier in the ited the bargaining power of cooperatives,
sion) and lowest country’s history, dairy farmers lived close to especially in times of surplus. Third, milk
during the spring the cities where their customers lived. Those used in fluid form had to meet tougher sani-
farmers would provide not only milk for tary standards than milk used in processed
and summer. drinking but also such dairy products as but- products, leading to higher production costs
ter and would spend a great deal of time mar- for farmers. Under federal regulations, Grade
keting those products to urban consumers. A milk, the highest standard for milk, can be
Improved transportation meant that milk used for drinking or for the manufacture of
could be shipped quickly to more distant dairy products; Grade B milk can be used
locations. As a result, dairy farmers began to only in manufactured dairy products.
move farther away from cities and to special- After several different pricing methods
ize in the production of milk. More and more were tried, many cooperatives early in the
firms known as “handlers” took up tasks tra- 20th century settled on a classified pricing
ditionally performed by the farmers them- plan. With classified pricing, a commodity is
selves. Those firms specialized in the buying, priced on the basis of what it is used to pro-
processing, and distribution of fluid milk. duce. Therefore, dairy processors had to pay a
Furthermore, the handlers usually had the different price for milk, depending on
capacity to manufacture other dairy prod- whether it was used as fluid milk or to make
ucts, such as butter and cheese, with surplus such products as cheese, butter, or dry milk.
milk. That system was meant to reflect the addi-
Over time, economies of scale in milk proc- tional costs of producing Grade A, as
essing and distribution resulted in larger but opposed to Grade B, milk. Fluid milk thus
fewer handlers to whom dairy farmers could received the highest price, while milk used to
sell their milk, and, as a result, farmers began make other products was priced lower.
to question the equity and fairness of the Farmers, however, shared collectively in
prices they received. To try to offset that the benefits of each market, since the pro-
imbalance of power, many dairy farmers ceeds from all sales were divided equally
formed milk-marketing cooperatives in order among the farmers. All farmers received the
to bargain collectively for better prices on same average, or “blend,” price, regardless of
behalf of their members. In turn, the handlers how their milk was actually used. That blend
claimed that the cooperatives violated the price was below the price farmers would
Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890, which pro- receive for Grade A fluid milk.

2
By the 1920s, the classified pricing plan ed under an order, although farmers receive
was beginning to break down. Cooperatives the ultimate benefits of regulation.
did not have monopoly control over all milk, The objectives of the original legislation
so fluid-milk handlers could negotiate with were to
independent farmers to purchase their milk
for slightly above the blend price. Such trans- • establish orderly marketing conditions,
actions were worthwhile for independent • ensure an orderly flow of the milk sup-
farmers, because they could receive a higher ply to market throughout the year, and
price than the blend price they received from • avoid unreasonable fluctuations in sup-
a cooperative. Further, the fluid-milk handler plies and prices.
would be able to pay less than the coopera-
tive-established price for Grade A fluid milk. Over the years, those objectives have been
That situation tended to undermine the amended somewhat. For example, a 1962
monopolistic control that cooperatives were report by the Federal Milk Order Study
trying to gain and led to instability in prices Committee, appointed by Secretary of
and availability of milk supplies in parts of Agriculture Orville Freeman, came up with
the country.2 the following objectives for Federal Milk
The Great Depression reduced consumer Marketing Orders:3 Dairy processors
purchasing power and took its toll on milk had to pay a dif-
demand, leading to a severe drop in prices. • to promote orderly marketing and there- ferent price for
Farmers who did not belong to a cooperative by improve farm income in the long run;
contributed to the price instability by under- • to equalize the market power of buyers milk, depending
cutting existing milk prices in an attempt to and sellers; on whether it was
sell their product. Furthermore, there were • to ensure consumer access to adequate
periods when there was not enough milk to and dependable supplies of high-quality
used as fluid milk
meet fluid-consumption needs. milk; or to make such
• to complement farm organizations in products as
maintaining economic order through
Federal Milk coordination of prices and marketing cheese, butter, or
Marketing Orders practices geographically and among dry milk.
products;
To ameliorate the situation, Congress • to secure equitable treatment of all par-
passed the Agricultural Adjustment Act of ties throughout the system; and
1933 and the Agricultural Marketing • to protect established farmers against
Agreement Act of 1937. Those acts author- loss of outlets, while maintaining free-
ized the Federal Milk Marketing Order pro- dom of choice for buyers and sellers.
gram that exists today. The program divided
the country into regions, and within those Although milk marketing orders are jus-
regions, class milk prices could be set admin- tified as a way to control the power of han-
istratively by the federal government. Milk dlers and to provide market stability, in
handlers and processors must pay the price actuality the orders are a way to administer
that is set in their regions, in effect forcing a price-discrimination policy for dairy
them to buy only from local farmers. farmers. Price discrimination in this con-
However, two-thirds of milk producers in a text is a monopolistic tactic to extract high-
given region must vote to place themselves er returns by charging identifiable seg-
under the marketing order regime. If they do ments of the market different prices.
not so vote, the federal system does not apply. Federal Milk Marketing Orders allowed
Note that it is the milk handlers, or first buy- dairy farmers to impose a monopolistic sys-
ers, not the producers, who are most regulat- tem that would have been unenforceable in

3
the freer market that existed before the state’s having some of the highest retail milk
Depression. prices in the country.
The Federal Milk Marketing Order system There are two pervasive state policies that
established price differentials between differ- adversely increase milk prices. The first is a
ent classes of milk. Class I, which received the law that prohibits the sale of milk not meet-
highest price, was for milk used in fluid form; ing California’s various milk standards. This
Class II milk was used for soft dairy products effectively prohibits sales by out-of-state milk
like yogurt, cream cheese, and ice cream; and suppliers because of the significant costs of
Class III, the lowest-priced milk, was for use in processing milk separately, using different
the production of cheese, butter, and dry milk. packaging, and segregating inventory to
Instead of determining the class price in each meet California’s standards. That law was
federal order independently, the federal order recently challenged by Arizona-based
system establishes Class I and Class II differ- Shamrock Foods Company, which tried to
entials for each order. Those differentials are sell milk in California that did not meet the
added on to the Class III price to establish required standards but instead met the feder-
regional class prices. Although the Class III al composition standards for all other states.
price is supposed to be a free-market price, In August 1999, the California Appellate
reflecting the value of manufacturing-grade Court ruled in favor of Shamrock, giving the
milk, it has been influenced by the dairy price company (and other out-of-state dairy
support program (see below). processors) the right to sell in California milk
The federal government uses a complex that meets federal standards, provided it is
formula, based in part on the distance of labeled in accordance with federal law. The
producers from Eau Claire, Wisconsin, the issue is not closed, however, as the state of
place where milk is supposed to be pro- California is asking its supreme court to retry
duced at the lowest cost, to calculate the the case.
prices for each milk order. The Appendix, at The second regulation influencing
the end of this paper, provides an economic California’s retail milk prices prohibits retail-
explanation of price discrimination within ers from offering milk at a discounted sale
the context of the Federal Milk Marketing price. Originally intended to help protect
Order system. independent grocers from large retail chains
using milk as a loss leader, the law has instead
Although milk led to higher milk prices at the retail level, with
Areas Not Regulated by no competition among retail distributors.
marketing orders the Federal Orders According to Mad About Milk, a
are justified as a California-based consumer advocacy group,
Although Federal Milk Marketing Orders the full cost of these state milk regulations to
way to control the dictate prices for over 60 percent of all milk California’s consumers has been more than
power of handlers produced in the United States, there are some $600 million per year.4 Indeed, these policies
and to provide parts of the country that are not under that not only cost consumers significantly but
system (see Figure 1). Most notable is also harm the state’s dairy farmers. Because
market stability, California, which is the largest milk-produc- retail milk prices in California are among the
in actuality the ing state in the country. Although California highest in the country, that state’s per capita
is not part of the federal system, the state milk consumption is below the U.S. average
orders are a way
milk-pricing regulations have many similari- and far below consumption in nearby states
to administer a ties to that system, including price discrimi- and regions with lower retail prices. If those
price-discrimina- nation for milk used for different purposes. policies were eliminated, allowing retail milk
However, unlike the federal system, prices to come down, this would lead to high-
tion policy for California imposes further layers of regula- er milk sales, increasing revenue for
dairy farmers. tion on milk pricing, which has led to the California’s dairy farmers.

4
Figure 1
New Consolidated Federal Milk Marketing Orders

Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture, “Agricultural Marketing Service Dairy Programs,” March 1999.

Note: Differences in shading serve merely to differentiate among marketing areas. Areas in white are not underthe
Federal Milk Marketing Order system.

dairy products—as compared with an unreg-


Winners and Losers ulated milk market. In the aggregate, The federal gov-
Helmberger and Chen calculate the losses to ernment uses a
Economists have long recognized that the fluid-milk consumers at just over $1 billion complex formula,
Federal Milk Marketing Order program per year; consumers of cheese, butter, and
increases milk prices for farmers at the dry-milk dairy products gain only $600 mil- based in part on
expense of consumers. The effects, however, lion, making an annual net loss to consumers the distance of
are more complicated than that, because con- of $400 million.5
sumers and farmers are affected differently In part, this $400 million is a redistribu- producers from
under the program. Consumers who buy tion from consumers to producers. However, Eau Claire,
fluid milk products for drinking lose the just as consumers are not treated equally in Wisconsin, the
most from price discrimination, while con- the price-discrimination scheme, farmers do
sumers of manufactured dairy products not share equally in the benefits of price dis- place where milk
actually pay lower prices. However, the high crimination. Indeed, some farmers are worse is supposed to be
cost of fluid milk far outweighs any benefits off as a result of the discrimination, because
gained by lower prices for cheese, butter, and they are located in excess-supply regions with
produced at the
dry milk. Economists Peter Helmberger and heavy production of manufactured dairy lowest cost, to
Yu-Hui Chen estimate that in 1990 the products. Through the Federal Milk calculate the
Federal Milk Marketing Order system led to Marketing Order system, farmers within a
13 percent higher prices for fluid milk and milk marketing order receive the same blend prices for each
only 6 percent lower prices for manufactured price, but that price can vary dramatically milk order.

5
from region to region, depending in part on Order system, the dairy price support pro-
the class prices established for milk but also gram has been costly for consumers and, ulti-
on a particular order’s use of milk in various mately, a benefit for producers. In 1949 the
classes. Agricultural Adjustment Act was passed in
For example, in January 1999, the Upper an attempt to provide price supports to the
Midwest Federal Order used only 13 percent dairy industry. The price support program,
of its milk as fluid milk, with the remaining which is handled by the Commodity Credit
87 percent going to the production of lower- Corporation of USDA, establishes support
priced manufactured dairy products. prices for butter, cheese, and nonfat dry milk.
Without federal orders, farmers in the Upper To support the market, the government
Midwest would have received a higher price becomes a willing buyer of any dairy prod-
on the 87 percent of their milk that was used ucts at the prevailing support prices. The gov-
for manufacturing and a lower price on only ernment, through CCC operations, stores
the 13 percent of their milk used in fluid dairy commodities during periods when
form—on net they would be better off with- prices are at or near the price support level
out federal orders. and eventually disposes of the products
Conversely, for those dairy farmers in the through food-assistance programs or by sell-
In the aggregate, parts of the country with more milk used in ing the products on the open market if prices
Helmberger and fluid form, the benefits of federal orders are move above the support level. By supporting
Chen calculate positive and quite large. The South and East the prices of dairy products, the government
tend to be the areas of highest fluid-milk use. supports the price of milk used in manufac-
the losses to In January 1999, the Florida Milk Order used turing and, ultimately, the price paid to all
fluid-milk con- nearly 87 percent of all production in fluid dairy farmers for all classes of milk.
form, while the remaining 13 percent went Like the Federal Milk Marketing Order
sumers at just into manufactured dairy products, the exact system, the dairy price support program has
over $1 billion reverse of the Upper Midwest Order. If feder- had multiple objectives that have changed
per year. al orders were eliminated, 87 percent of the over time. But the two basic reasons usually
milk in Florida would be priced lower, there- given in support of the program have been to
by reducing farm milk prices in this region. provide an adequate supply of high-quality
Using the price changes estimated by milk and to foster price stability. While it has
Helmberger and Chen, elimination of the certainly met those goals (though a free mar-
federal order system would reduce milk ket would have done so more efficiently), the
prices for dairy farmers in the Florida price support program has likely done more
Marketing Order by 10 percent, but farmers to enhance producer incomes, since overly
in the Upper Midwest Order would see high- high price supports have at times led to bur-
er milk prices by nearly 4 percent on average.6 densome expenditures by the CCC.
Clearly, this has been a divisive result of In the early years of the dairy price sup-
dairy policies. The federal order system has ports and into the 1970s, the direct cost of
benefited some dairy farmers and harmed the program to taxpayers ranged annually
others. It is not surprising that dairy policies from $69 million to $612 million, with an
come under attack not only from consumers average of $325 million. The 1970s brought
but also from dairy farmers located in areas higher inflation and strong pressure from
of the country with heavy production of dairy lobbyists to increase milk price sup-
manufactured dairy products. ports. Although that policy may have seemed
like a rather sensible prescription to help
dairy farmers at the time, higher milk price
Dairy Price Support Policies supports would eventually lead to excessive
costs to the government, as illustrated in
In addition to the Federal Milk Marketing Figure 2. By the 1980s, high price supports

6
Figure 2
Milk Price Support, Manufactured Milk Price, and CCC Expenditures

$18
$18 $4,000
$4,000

$16
$16 Milk Price $3,500
$3,500
Milk Price
$14
$14 $3,000
$3,000

$12
$12
$2,500
$2,500
$10
$10
$2,000
$2,000
$8
$8
Price
PriceSupport
Support $1,500
$1,500
$6
$6
CCC
CCCExpenditures
Expenditures $1,000
$1,000
$4
$4

$2
$2 $500
$500

$0
$0 $0
Jan-70 Jan-75 Jan-80 Jan-85 Jan-90 Jan-95

Source: Source:
U.S. Department of Agriculture, “USDA-FSA Commodity Fact Sheet Dairy Price Support
USDA-FSA Commodity Fact Sheet Dairy Price Support Program, Various Issues.
Program,” various issues.

resulted in the CCC’s spending $1 billion per has produced clear winners and losers.
year to support dairy prices. In 1983 the CCC Consumers and taxpayers are clearly losers
spent a record $2.6 billion to purchase 16.8 under price supports, because all dairy and
billion pounds of milk products—more than milk prices are kept high and do not fall dur-
12 percent of total U.S. milk production. ing periods of excess supplies. All dairy farm-
By the mid-1980s, dairy price supports ers are clear winners under price supports.
were lowered, but even that was not enough Helmberger and Chen estimate that in 1990
to overcome the excessive stocks of dairy the dairy price support program cost con-
products and the oversupply of milk. As a sumers about $660 million as a result of The federal order
result, the Milk Diversion Program, enacted higher prices for milk and dairy products.7
in 1983, offered direct payments of $10 per That is in addition to the costs and wealth system has bene-
hundredweight to dairy farmers to reduce transfers that resulted from the Federal Milk fited some dairy
their milk production. Later the Food Marketing Orders. To get an idea of the mag- farmers and
Security Act of 1985 authorized the Dairy nitude of the total costs of the government
Termination Program, which paid dairy farm- milk-regulatory regime, Frederick J. Nelson, harmed others.
ers not to produce milk for five years. By 1990 of the USDA, estimated in a World Trade
the federal government had set an invariable Organization briefing paper that in 1995
price-support level and disposed of surplus American dairy farmers received $8 billion in
dairy products. Further, production leveled assistance through various price-distortion
off, and the market was able to clear with a mechanisms, including trade barriers, that
price above the support price, leading to the are usually not factored into estimates of the
virtual elimination of the CCC payments. effects of the federal dairy program on
Unlike the Federal Milk Marketing Order American consumers.8
program, the dairy price support program Often overlooked in the milk-policy debate

7
In 1990 the dairy is the effect price regulation has on nutrition. ture to make changes to existing milk policies.
price support Milk is an important source of calcium, which At a minimum, the act required a consolida-
can prevent osteoporosis and help maintain tion of the number of milk marketing orders,
program cost optimal blood pressure levels. Milk and milk but it also left open the option for further
consumers about products provide about 75 percent of the cal- reforms or even complete elimination of the
cium in the American food supply, and the program. Three years after the passage of that
$660 million as a federal government identifies low calcium legislation, the secretary announced his Final
result of higher intake as a major nutritional priority. The Rule on federal order reform (also referred to
prices for milk USDA dietary guidelines encourage most as Option 1-B), which would make only
Americans to increase their daily calcium superficial changes to the system that had
and dairy intake and recommend two to three servings a been in place for the past 60 years. The basic
products. day of milk, yogurt, and cheese. Yet USDA’s changes would include the following:
food intake survey data indicate that the aver-
age consumption level of dairy foods was only 1. consolidating the 31 orders of the
1.5 servings per day in 1994–96.9 Because Federal Milk Marketing Order program
higher milk prices discourage consumption into 11 orders,
and therefore limit important sources of calci- 2. changing the price differentials for
um, price regulations are in part responsible Class I milk (used for fluid consump-
for the inadequate calcium intake of tion),
American consumers. In an article in the 3. creating a new milk class for butter and
Journal of Consumer Affairs, Dale Heien and dry milk (Class IV), and
Cathy Wessells find that if the dairy price sup- 4. developing new methods for comput-
port program and the Federal Milk Marketing ing class prices.
Order program were eliminated, thereby low-
ering the price of milk, milk consumption and To dairy farmers, the most contentious
calcium intake would increase above the rec- issue concerns the changes in Class I price
ommended dietary allowances.1 0 Ironically, differentials, which are established on a
the federal government attempted to offset regional basis. As mentioned earlier, farmers
the high prices caused by its own policies by do not share equally in the benefits of price
giving lower-income people food stamps and discrimination, and herein lies the source of
surplus dairy products. discontent between farmers in low Class I use
The dairy price support policies of the areas as compared with those in high Class I
past 30 years have been extremely costly. The use areas. Table 1 shows the 11 consolidated
lesson of those policies is that it is unrealistic orders and the respective Class I differentials
to expect government regulations and prices prior to the 1999 reform as well as USDA’s
to send the appropriate market signals to the Final Rule (denoted as USDA-F in Table 1).
dynamically changing dairy industry. The Also shown in the table is Option 1-A, an
government has ineffectively managed this alternative that USDA considered prior to its
balance through the use of price supports Final Rule. Option 1-A was passed by the
and other programs, ultimately imposing House of Representatives but so far has failed
stiff price tags on consumers and taxpayers. to pass the Senate.
Not surprisingly, many dairy farmers dis-
liked the lower prices under the USDA’s Final
The 1999 Reform: Trying to Rule. For example, the new average Class I dif-
Patch Broken Policies ferential is only $2.21 as compared to $2.46 prior
to the reform. However, it should be noted that
In 1996 Congress passed the Federal this masks some of the regional shifts in Class I
Agricultural Improvement Reform (FAIR) differentials. Dairy farmers in the East and
Act, which directed the secretary of agricul- South face lower Class I milk prices, while farm-

8
Table 1
Summary of Class I Milk Price Differentials: Pre-1999 Reform, USDA Final Rule, and
Option 1-A

Class I Use Class I Differentials ($/cwt)


Federal Orders (% of milk production) Prereform USDA-F Option 1-A

Northeast 48.6 $3.00 $2.38 $2.93


Appalachian 85.0 $2.65 $2.25 $2.70
Florida 90.6 $3.88 $4.25 $4.00
Southeast 85.6 $3.08 $2.90 $3.10
Mideast 58.9 $1.83 $1.87 $1.92
Upper Midwest 24.1 $1.30 $1.78 $1.75
Central 50.1 $1.97 $1.92 $2.04
Southwest 53.4 $2.76 $1.93 $2.55
Arizona–Las Vegas 46.3 $1.70 $1.43 $1.75
Western 32.5 $2.52 $1.55 $2.35
Pacific Northwest 35.6 $1.90 $1.45 $1.90
Average* $2.46 $2.21 $2.50
Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture, “Final Regulatory Impact Analysis of Federal Milk Market-
ing Order Consolidation and Reform,” Agricultural Marketing Service, March 1999.
*The average Class I differentials are weighted averages using each order’s Class I milk supply (not
reported here) as a weight.

ers in the Upper Midwest receive higher prices. The reformed Federal Milk Marketing
As a result, many dairy supporters backed the Order system, like its predecessor, attempts
Option 1-A alternative, which would have left to emulate what a free-market system would
Class I differentials virtually the same as they provide—higher prices in milk-deficit regions Because higher
were before the reform. However, Option 1-A and lower prices in surplus regions so that milk prices dis-
drew significant criticism from representatives surplus milk could be shipped to deficit
from Upper Midwest dairy states. areas. But that system still creates market dis- courage con-
On the surface, it may seem that Upper tortions. If there were no federal orders and sumption and
Midwest dairy farmers would find equally prices were free to respond to market signals, therefore limit
acceptable Option 1-A and USDA’s Final milk would still move from surplus to deficit
Rule, since both policies lead to similar Class regions of the country, just like any other important
I differentials ($1.78 versus $1.75). However, commodity in the United States. Because sources of calci-
what Upper Midwest dairy farmers recognize milk production and consumption exhibit
is that Option 1-A would lead to significant- strong seasonal patterns and because trans-
um, price regula-
ly higher Class I prices in other regions of the portation costs can change markedly in a tions are in part
country, which would result in higher pro- short time period, it seems likely that a feder- responsible for
duction in those regions, with more milk ally regulated price base will fail to meet the
flowing into the production of manufac- efficient outcome of a market. the inadequate
tured dairy products. The outcome would be The 1999 USDA reforms also institute a calcium intake of
lower prices for Class III milk, the dominant new method for calculating class milk prices.
form of milk producted in the Upper Historically, the price of milk used in the pro-
American con-
Midwest. duction of butter, cheese, and dry milk was sumers.

9
based on the price for Grade B milk. Since butter and dry milk. Second, the Class III and
Grade B milk can be used only for the pro- Class IV prices will be based on a survey of
duction of those products and does not fall wholesale prices for butter, cheese, and dry
under the federal order regulations, that milk instead of on a survey of Grade B prices.
price was supposed to represent a free-market Doing so requires a formulation of how the
approach to pricing (although it is influ- prices of the dairy products will be converted
enced by dairy price supports). Specifically, into the prices of raw milk. Such a conversion
the government used the price that Grade B must factor in the amount of milk it will take
milk producers received in the Minnesota- to make the various products, as well as the
Wisconsin region to establish the federal cost of processing. This is problematic
order price for Class III, the price on which because the amount of milk required to
the price differential for other classes was make a specific amount of dairy product can
based. In 1960 Grade B milk production vary, as can the cost of processing the prod-
accounted for 33 percent of total U.S. milk uct. The approach looks like the one used in
production, but by 1998 Grade B production communist countries to price goods and ser-
was a negligible 3 percent of total U.S. milk vices by using some sort of calculation—for
output. 11 (This was attributable to the fact example, the amount of coal, electricity, iron,
If there were no that the costs of meeting Grade A standards and man-hours needed for making a certain
federal orders have come down so much in past decades quantity of steel. Worse, the USDA will be
and prices were that most milk now falls into that category.) working backward, attempting to set the
Thus, there was a concern that the survey price for the raw product, fluid milk, on the
free to respond to price for Grade B milk was too small a part of basis of the supposed market price of the
market signals, the market on which to base the prices of the products derived from it. Thus, under this
classes of milk. system—unlike under a market system—the
milk would still In 1995 USDA began to use the Basic government is regulating profit margins for
move from sur- Formula Price to determine the value of Class dairy processors.
plus to deficit III milk. Although that price was based in In August 1999, two-thirds of dairy farm-
part on the Grade B survey price, it also ers in the 11 new marketing order regions
regions of the depended on the prices of butter, cheese, and accepted USDA’s Final Rule by a referendum
country. dry milk. This too drew criticism; dairy farm- vote, thereby continuing the process of regu-
ers argued that large-scale dairy manufactur- lation and price discrimination. Whether or
ers, especially manufacturers of cheese, not Congress adopts the Option 1-A alterna-
manipulate product prices. Willard Mueller tive, what is clear is that the government’s
et al. contended that at the National Cheese role in milk pricing has become more, not
Exchange Kraft General Foods manipulated less, important. In addition to establishing
cheese prices that were used in the computa- regional prices for fluid milk, the govern-
tion of the Basic Formula Price.1 2 Bruce ment now finds itself establishing profit
Gardner questioned that analysis, however, margins in the dairy-processing sector. Just as
finding little evidence that this in fact hap- dairy price supports in the 1980s created seri-
pened.13 In any case, this debate accentuates ous market distortions, one suspects that a
the problems with the federal order system, small misalignment in profit margins for
which must, with price discrimination, rely dairy manufacturing could lead to similar
on the prices of processed products, such as calamities in the future.
cheese, to determine the value of raw milk.
The 1999 reform brings about several
changes in this regard. First, while keeping Dairy Compacts: Wrong
Class I for fluid milk and Class II for soft Policies at the Wrong Time
dairy products, the reform Class III was kept
for cheese, and a new Class IV was created for In addition to the fight over the USDA’s

10
new pricing system and Option 1-A, a new inception in July 1997, the Northeast Dairy
problem threatens to make milk markets Compact has maintained the minimum
even worse for consumers and many farmers: Class I price at $16.94 per hundredweight. In
the expansion of dairy compacts. other marketing order areas, the price of
With the end of high dairy price supports Class I milk is tied to prices for other classes
in the 1980s, there was a painful adjustment and, thus, can rise and fall. The minimum
in the dairy sector. Those high price supports guaranteed price in the Northeast Compact
had encouraged overproduction of milk and holds Class I prices high no matter what fluc-
led to large government stocks of dairy prod- tuations occur in market demand.
ucts. As price supports were lowered in the Although this policy is clearly a way to
late 1980s and early 1990s, dairy farmers inflate the price paid to dairy farmers, sup-
began to feel the pain of that adjustment. porters of dairy compacts contend that this is
Low prices persisted for several years as the a policy that will benefit consumers. For
large government stocks of dairy products example, the Northeast Dairy Compact
moved into the marketplace. The result was Commission states that “stable farm milk
that a significant portion of dairy farmers prices for Class I fluid milk will result in price
exited the industry. By the mid-1990s, the stability—and potential price decreases—in
excess capacity had been eliminated in the Class I milk at the retail level for con- In addition to
dairy industry, setting the stage for record- sumers.”1 4 The commission further contends establishing
high dairy prices in 1996 and again in 1998. that this regulation was likely to have a regional prices
In the 1996 FAIR Act, Congress allowed “downward pressure on retail prices.”
for the creation of the Northeast Dairy Therefore, the commission suggests that for fluid milk,
Compact. That compact was formed by the consumers will be better off with the com- the government
six New England states, Connecticut, Maine, pact regulation because it will assure them
Massachusetts, New Hampshire, Rhode lower and more stable milk prices.
now finds itself
Island, and Vermont, whose farmers were Unfortunately, the Northeast Dairy establishing prof-
particularly hard hit during the transition Compact Commission was wrong on both it margins in the
and who had seen their costs, especially of counts. First, retail milk prices have
land values, rise significantly. (Many smaller- increased, not decreased, as a result of the dairy-processing
scale milk producers in New England and compact’s regulation. Table 2 provides retail sector.
elsewhere took advantage of high land prices whole-milk prices from Boston and
to sell their farms to other producers or for Hartford, which are regulated by the
other uses such as housing developments. Northeast Dairy Compact. The regulated
Other farmers, however, wanted to hang on price from the compact went into effect in
to their farms and subsidies to have the high- July 1997 and clearly led to an increase of
er costs offset through another price-distor- almost 20 cents per gallon. Although the
tion program.) The usual excuses were given Boston price has dipped somewhat lower,
as the purpose of the compact: to ensure the both prices are clearly well above where they
viability of dairy farming in New England were before the regulation. Thus, stable
and to provide an adequate supply of reason- prices have not meant lower prices, as was
ably priced milk to consumers. The enabling suggested by the compact commission.
legislation intended for the compact to be a The second argument made by the com-
temporary measure that would be eliminated pact commission was that consumers would
after the federal order reform was completed fare better with stable prices. Unfortunately,
in 1999. economic theory provides little evidence
Compacts establish a minimum price for about how consumers would respond to sta-
Class I milk in their regions. That price is ble, versus unstable, prices. However, if con-
usually above the one in effect under the sumers value stable prices, they should be
Federal Milk Marketing Orders. Since its willing to buy a greater quantity of milk at

11
Table 2 found that consumers tended to buy more,
Retail Whole-Milk Prices, January 1996 to not less, milk during times of volatile prices.
May 1998 (in cents per gallon) One reason for that behavior might be that
consumers, believing they are getting a bar-
Month-Year Boston Hartford gain, purchase more milk when prices fall.
Thus, the argument that consumers would
Jan. 1996 237 238 be better off with stable prices seems to have
Feb. 1996 238 240
no support from empirical data.
Mar. 1996 241 241
Although it seems clear that consumers
Apr.1996 240 240
May 1996 239 240
will bear the burden of the compact regula-
June 1996 241 242 tion, what about the effect on dairy farmers?
July 1996 243 244 One of the motivating factors in establishing
Aug. 1996 238 246 dairy compacts was to save small, family-run
Sept. 1996 239 245 dairy farms. Table 3 provides information on
Oct. 1996 243 246 how dairy farmers have responded as a result
Nov. 1996 245 250 of the 1997 compact regulation. This table
Dec. 1996 241 250 looks at dairy farms in Vermont, the largest
Jan. 1997 242 251 dairy-producing state in the Northeast
Feb. 1997 245 249 Compact, and in Pennsylvania, a state with
Mar. 1997 245 249
economic circumstances similar to
Apr. 1997 245 249
Vermont’s but not part of the Northeast
May 1997 245 249
June 1997 244 249
Compact. Prior to the compact’s formation
in 1997, there were 2,100 dairy farms in
July 1997 * 264 268
Vermont, each farm having an average herd
Aug. 1997 * 263 268 size of 74 cows. By 1998 the number of farms
Sept. 1997* 263 268 had fallen to 1,900 (a loss of nearly 10 per-
Oct. 1997* 262 268 cent), but the average herd size had increased
Nov. 1997 * 263 268 to 85 cows per farm, a 15 percent increase. By
comparison, over that same time period, the
Dec. 1997* 263 268
number of dairy farms in Pennsylvania fell
Jan. 1998* 260 268 by 3 percent, from 11,300 to 10, 900, but the
Feb. 1998 * 259 268 average herd size increased only slightly,
Mar. 1998* 260 268 from 56 cows per farm in 1996 to 57 cows
Apr. 1998 * 260 268 per farm in 1998.
May 1998 * 260 268 The Northeast Dairy Compact has done
little to keep small-scale dairy farmers in
Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Agricultural business, but it has provided financial incen-
Marketing Service, unpublished data tives for the remaining dairy farms to get big-
*Compact regulations in effect.
ger. Although 1999 data on the number of
dairy farms are not available, the number of
cows in each state suggests that the trend
Retail milk prices any given price during periods when prices will continue. Vermont had 1,000 more cows
have increased, are stable. Leigh Maynard tested that propo- in June 1999 than in 1998, while
not decreased, as sition using retail-scanner data from house- Pennsylvania had 9,000 fewer cows over the
hold purchases of milk between 1996 and same time period. Since farm numbers in
a result of the 1998.1 5 Although the results do suggest that 1999 will likely be lower or about the same as
compact’s price volatility can affect fluid-milk demand, they were in 1998, Vermont farms are likely
the fluctuation was not in the direction sug- to continue to get larger.
regulation. gested by the commission. Instead, Maynard The Northeast Compact was mandated in

12
Table 3
Dairy Farms, Cows, and Cows per Farm: Vermont and Pennsylvania
Vermont Pennsylvania

Cows Dairy Cows per Cows Dairy Cows per


Year (1,000 head) Farms Farm (1,000 head) Farms Farm

1992 167 2,500 67 652 13,300 49


1993 162 2,500 65 640 12,300 52
1994 158 2,300 69 639 12,200 52
1995 157 2,100 75 636 11,800 54
1996 156 2,100 74 634 11,300 56
1997* 160 2,000 80 629 11,300 56
1998* 161 1,900 85 623 10,900 57
1999* 162 NA NA 614 NA NA
(June)

Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural Statistics Service, Milk Production, various issues.

*Compact regulations in effect.

the FAIR Act to end when the new USDA fed- produce lower-valued manufactured prod-
eral order reform takes effect. Yet Congress ucts like cheese, butter, and dry milk, leading
considered not only extending the life of that to lower prices for those products. Moreover,
compact but also adding to its membership the farmers not in a compact state will see
Maryland, New Jersey, New York, and lower milk prices because of the excess pro-
Pennsylvania. Worse, Congress considered duction of dairy products. In a briefing paper
the creation of a Southern Dairy Compact published by the University of Wisconsin,
modeled on its Northeast neighbor. The Tom Cox, Bob Cropp, and Will Hughes find
Southern Compact would include Alabama, that the combined Northeast and Southern
Arkansas, Florida, Georgia, Kansas, Compacts would likely reduce farm milk
Kentucky, Louisiana, Mississippi, Missouri, prices by $0.20 per hundredweight in areas
North Carolina, Oklahoma, South Carolina, that are not included in the compacts.1 6 Even
Tennessee, Texas, Virginia, and West Virginia. more problematic is the fact that with higher
That would put 26 states under the umbrella production of dairy products, expanded The Northeast
of compact regulations, accounting for one- compacts will likely significantly increase
third of the milk production in the United CCC expenditures at considerable cost to the
Dairy Compact
States. Furthermore, a federal court recently U.S. government and taxpayers. has done little to
delayed the date when the Northeast In short, dairy compacts further exacer- keep small-scale
Compact was due to expire. bate interregional price distortions for the
What can be expected if the dairy com- benefit of a few dairy farmers at the expense dairy farmers in
pacts persist in the future, with more states of other farmers and consumers. In all like- business, but it
included? In addition to the associated costs lihood, the compacts will do little to stem
of high milk prices for more consumers, the the tide of dairy farmers’ choosing to exit
has provided
existence of artificially high prices in those the industry. Instead, through higher financial incen-
states will lead to greater milk production. prices, dairy compacts have encouraged tives for the
Because of higher retail milk prices, there will remaining dairy farmers to increase the
be less consumption of fluid milk at a time sizes of their farms. Finally, with more remaining dairy
when farmers will be producing more milk. states joining compacts, it seems clear that farms to get bigger.
This excess milk production will be used to the entire American dairy industry is head-

13
Dairy compacts ing for a return to the 1980s of excess milk giving farmers significantly greater bar-
further exacerbate production, with ballooning stocks of dairy gaining power.1 7 It is unlikely that removal
products and persistently high CCC expen- of the federal order system would lead to
interregional ditures to support dairy prices. Those dairy undue influence of the milk handlers over
price distortions farmers who are not part of a compact will the farmers. The power struggle between
face persistently lower milk prices, leading farmers and processors is no different from
for the benefit of to an accelerated exit of smaller, family- the struggles in other unregulated agricul-
a few dairy farm- operated farms in the future. tural commodities and is not a good
ers at the expense premise for regulation.
The 1996 FAIR Act, instead of improving
of other farmers Why Dairy Farm Policies dairy policy, has set the stage for potentially
and consumers. Are Not Needed harmful policy changes. First, by maintain-
ing the current federal order system, the fed-
American agricultural commodities, eral government must not only carry out a
including milk, have been regulated, sup- regionalized price-discrimination policy, but,
ported, and subsidized by the federal gov- starting with the 1999 federal order reform, it
ernment since the Depression. However, the must also begin to establish the appropriate
past decade has seen a trend of less govern- processing costs for the dairy sector. If those
ment intervention in agriculture. Most costs are set improperly, as will likely be the
recently, the 1996 FAIR Act began to phase case, the result will be over- or underproduc-
out many of the supply-management pro- tion of dairy products. It seems highly unlike-
grams for many farm commodities. ly that the government can adequately mimic
Unfortunately, the Federal Milk Marketing the free-market conditions that would ensure
Order system in place today is virtually efficient regional milk prices, as well as the
identical with the one created in the 1930s. proper incentives for processing dairy prod-
Supporters of the system contend that ucts. Now, some 60 years into dairy price reg-
milk’s perishable nature warrants govern- ulation, the government finds itself getting
ment intervention. But federal orders do lit- deeper into the business of pricing milk and
tle to enhance or change the efficient flow dairy products when it should be letting the
of milk from farmers to consumers. free market work efficiently.
Technology has significantly changed the Second, the creation of the Northeast
production, transportation, refrigeration, Compact by the FAIR Act has created a mon-
and processing of milk during the past 60 ster that could now sprawl into more states,
years—without the aid of the federal orders. as well as spawn a southern sibling. The
Federal orders are a way for dairy farmers to increased production that is likely to result
capture the benefits of price discrimina- will lead to lower prices—incentives for other
tion. If that system were elminated, the free- states to seek compacts to maintain high
market system would function just as dairy prices and rising CCC expenditures.
smoothly—but without price distortions. Dairy policies represent a classic case of
Many supporters of federal dairy policy government regulations that serve special
still argue that large-scale milk handlers interests but harm the public interest.
have the ability to manipulate farm milk Eliminating the Federal Milk Marketing
prices to their advantage without the aid of Order system would level the playing field for
the Federal Milk Marketing Orders. dairy farmers and likely put an end to the
However, in the 1930s, just less than 50 per- regional divisions that have ultimately led to
cent of farm milk was marketed through dairy compacts. Until then, however, it seems
2,270 cooperatives of dairy farmers. Today, that American consumers will be forced to
fewer than 240 cooperatives market more live with the legacy of Depression-era dairy
than 85 percent of the nation’s milk supply, policies guiding their milk prices.

14
the demand for manufactured milk (DM) in
Appendix: the middle panel, and the total supply of
Federal Milk Marketing farm milk (S) in the right panel. The price is
represented on the y-axis, and the quantity
Orders as a Price- on the x-axis. Consider first the case in which
Discrimination Device there is no price discrimination, implying
that milk, regardless of its use in either fluid
The Federal Milk Marketing Orders pro- or manufactured form, is charged the same
gram establishes a higher price for milk that price, which is denoted as PC for the price in
is used in fluid form and a lower price for a competitive setting. At that price, dairy
milk that is used in the production of manu- farmers would supply a total quantity (QCT),
factured dairy products. This strategy plays of which (QM) C
is used in the production of
on the different consumer demand for fluid manufactured milk products and QCF is used
milk and manufactured dairy products. for fluid milk. Note that QTC = (QMC + QCF).
Because there are few if any good substitutes With a price-discrimination policy, a high-
for fluid milk, the demand for fluid milk is er price is charged for milk used in the fluid Because the fluid
very inelastic, implying that with higher market (PF), while a lower price is charged for market is very
prices consumers tend to drop their con- milk used in the manufacturing market (PM).
sumption only modestly. Conversely, manu- Because the fluid market is very inelastic (i.e.,
inelastic, a signif-
factured dairy products, such as butter, the demand schedule is steeper), a signifi- icantly higher
cheese, and dry milk, have more elastic cantly higher fluid-milk price will lead to fluid-milk price
demand, implying that any price increases only a small decline in fluid-milk consump-
will lead consumers to cut back consumption tion (from QFC to QFD). At the same time, a will lead to only a
levels rather sharply. marginally lower manufactured-milk price small decline in
The effect of a price-discrimination policy can lead to a sizable increase in manufac-
is illustrated in Figure 3. This shows the
fluid-milk con-
tured-milk consumption (from QM to QM );
demand for fluid milk (DF) in the left panel,
C
at the aggregate level, total milk supply
D
sumption.

Figure 3
Effects of Discriminatory Pricing

Fluid-Milk Market Manufactured-Milk Market Total Milk Market


Gain to dairy farmer
PF Gain to PB
Loss to fluid- manufactured- S
milk milk consumers
consumers
PC
PM

DM
DF

QF QF QM QM QT QT
D C C D C D

15
The net cost for increases. Farmers are paid the blend price Agricultural and Resource Economics 19 (December
1994): 225–38.
consumers is (PB), which is a use-weighted average of the
fluid price and the manufactured price for 6. This calculation ignores the effect of changes
greater than the milk and is higher than the competitive price.
in milk production or milk use that would likely
occur if the federal order system were eliminated.
net gain of farmers. The shaded areas show the effect of the Those changes are small enough to ignore for the
price-discrimination policy on each market purposes of this example.
group. Fluid-milk consumers will lose as a 7. Helmberger and Chen.
result of higher prices and lower consump-
8. Frederick J. Nelson, “Measuring Domestic Sup-
tion. That loss can be fairly sizable because of port for U.S. Agriculture.” WTO Briefing Paper,
the inelastic nature of their demand and of the Markets and Trade Division, USDA, Economic
large price increase. However, consumers of Research Service, November 1997.
manufactured dairy products (such as cheese, 9. Shirley Gerrior, Judy Putnam, and Lisa Bente,
butter, and dry milk) do benefit from price dis- “Milk and Milk Products: Their Importance in
crimination because of lower prices. This ben- the American Diet,” Food Review (May–August
1998): 29–37.
efit could be relatively small, however, since
under a discrimination policy the manufac- 10. Dale Heien and Cathy R. Wessells, “The Nutrition-
tured-milk price is only marginally lower than al Impact of the Dairy Price Support Program,”
Journal of Consumer Affairs 22 (Winter 1988): 201–19.
the competitive market price. Farmers gain
because they are able to sell more milk at the 11. It is somewhat interesting to note that the
government hasn’t worried about the competitive
higher blend price than they could sell at the position of Grade B farmers even though their
competitive price. The net transfer from con- market share has dwindled significantly in the
sumers to producers, however, is not perfect past 30 years.
because of the distortions created by price dis- 12. Willard F. Mueller et al., “Cheese Pricing: A
crimination. Economists refer to this as a Study of the National Cheese Exchange,” Report
dead-weight loss, which means that the net of the Food Systems Research Group, University
cost for consumers is greater than the net gain of Wisconsin, March 1996.
of farmers. Stated another way, consumers 13. Bruce L. Gardner, “Prices on the National
lose more than farmers gain from policy inter- Cheese Exchange as an Indicator of Supply-
Demand Conditions,” Department of Agricultur-
vention. al and Resource Economics, University of
Maryland, October 1996.
Notes 14. Northeast Dairy Compact Commission,
1. E. M. Erba and A. M. Novakovic, “The Evolution “Compact Over-Order Price Regulation and
of Milk Pricing and Government Intervention in Results of Producer Referendum,” Federal Register
Dairy Markets,” Cornell Program on Dairy Markets 62, no. 104, May 30, 1997, p. 29625.
and Policy, E.B. 95–05, February 1995. 15. Leigh J. Maynard, “Does Retail Milk Price
2. Robert M. Gordon and Steve H. Hanke, “Federal Volatility Affect Consumer Demand?” Proceedings of
Milk Marketing Orders: A Policy in Need of Conference on Price Instability and Risk Management in
Analysis,” Policy Analysis 4 (Winter 1978): 23–31. the Dairy Industry, Alexandria, Virginia, August 1998.

3. Federal Milk Order Study Committee, Report to 16. Tom Cox, Bob Cropp, and Will Hughes,
the Secretary of Agriculture (Washington: Government “Interregional Analysis of Interstate Dairy
Printing Office, April 1962). Compacts,” Department of Agricultural and Applied
Economics, University of Wisconsin, Marketing
4. John A. Schnittker and John M. Schnittker, and Policy Briefing Paper no. 69, July 1999.
“How to Reduce Retail Milk Prices in California,”
Mad About Milk, August 1999. 17. Alden C. Manchester and Don P. Blayney, “The
Structure of Dairy Markets: Past, Present, Future,”
5. Peter Helmberger and Yu-Hui Chen, “Economic USDA, Economic Research Service, Agricultural
Effects of U.S. Dairy Programs,” Journal of Economic Report no. 757, September 1997.

Published by the Cato Institute, Policy Analysis is a regular series evaluating government policies and offer-
ing proposals for reform. Nothing in Policy Analysis should be construed as necessarily reflecting the views
of the Cato Institute or as an attempt to aid or hinder the passage of any bill before congress. Contact the
Cato Institute for reprint permission. Additional copies of Policy Analysis are $6.00 each ($3.00 each for five
or more). To order, or for a complete listing of available studies, write the Cato Institute, 1000 Massachusetts
Ave., N.W., Washington, D.C. 20001, call toll free 1-800-767-1241 (noon - 9 p.m. eastern time), fax (202) 842-
3490, or visit our website at www.cato.org.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi