Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 16

No.

498 November 13, 2003

Public and Private Rule Making in


Securities Markets
by Paul G. Mahoney

Executive Summary

Recent corporate scandals have ignited debate for listings will make exchanges reluctant to
over appropriate rules for accounting and corpo- enforce their rules. A third is that disclosure rules
rate governance. The debate has largely ignored have external effects that an exchange cannot
an important preliminary question: who should internalize. Finally, it is argued that exchanges
set standards of corporate governance and disclo- may lack sufficiently varied enforcement tools to
sure for publicly traded companies? This paper ensure compliance with their rules. Under cur-
argues that stock exchanges have substantial rent practice, the primary threat exchanges can
advantages, in comparison with government hold over listed companies is delisting, which
bodies, as the primary regulators of corporate may be too large a penalty for some violations
governance, disclosure, and accounting. Those and too slight for others.
advantages stem from superior incentives. Stock Only the last of those is a significant obstacle,
exchanges gain from investors’ willingness to and even that can be resolved contractually to
trade and accordingly have an incentive to pro- some extent. Listing agreements could call for
vide any cost-effective rules that will increase fines and other penalties for violation of rules.
investor welfare. Nevertheless, government agencies have a clear
There are several standard arguments against advantage in investigating and punishing wrong-
increasing the role of exchanges in setting disclo- doing. A natural solution, then, would be to main-
sure and governance rules. One is that exchanges tain the Securities and Exchange Commission as
have market power, which dulls their incentive to an enforcement agency but cede much of its rule-
set optimal rules. Another is that competition making authority to the exchanges.

_____________________________________________________________________________________________________
Paul G. Mahoney is Brokaw Professor of Corporate Law and Albert C. BeVier Research Professor at the University
of Virginia School of Law.

CATO PROJECT ON CORPORATE GOVERNANCE, AUDIT, AND TAX REFORM


The case for
allowing Introduction Incentives Matter
exchanges to Debates over appropriate standards for The U.S. securities laws incorporate a lim-
determine corporate governance and accounting, once ited degree of self-regulation. Securities
the province of specialist journals and confer- exchanges and the National Association of
standards of ences, have become front-page affairs in the Securities Dealers, which operates the
corporate wake of recent corporate scandals. Politicians, National Association of Securities Dealers
governance and regulators, journalists, corporate executives, Automated Quotation System, are “self-regu-
institutional investors, and academics have all latory organizations” with authority to adopt
disclosure rests weighed in on a variety of once-esoteric issues: and enforce rules for their members and list-
on incentives, not Should incentive stock options be treated as ed companies, to the extent those rules do not
expertise. an ordinary business expense? Should pub- conflict with the federal securities laws. The
licly traded companies be required to separate exchanges and the NASD also have discipli-
the posts of chairman and chief executive offi- nary authority over their members. Both
cer? Should companies be required to change functions, however, are subject to the supervi-
accounting firms periodically? sion and ultimate control of the SEC.
Each of those questions is important and The standard argument for self-regulation
deserves attention. But relatively little atten- is that the securities industry has more exper-
tion has been paid to an issue that is arguably tise in the problems and potential solutions
much more important, because it will affect associated with securities trading than does a
each of the others: who should set standards government agency. The argument is not ter-
for corporate governance and disclosure for ribly persuasive. All of the information and
publicly traded companies? expertise in the world will be wasted unless the
This paper attempts to analyze that ques- regulator has an incentive to make rules that
tion. The potential standard setters include benefit investors. A regulator with appropriate
government bodies such as Congress, state leg- incentives, on the other hand, could easily hire
islatures, the Securities and Exchange people with the relevant experience.
Commission or other regulatory bodies, and The case for allowing exchanges to deter-
private entities such as stock exchanges or mine standards of corporate governance and
industry groups. Stock exchanges have sub- disclosure, then, rests on incentives, not exper-
stantial advantages, in comparison with gov- tise. Exchanges and their members profit from
ernment bodies, as the primary regulators of investors’ trades. The traditional nonprofit
corporate governance, disclosure, and account- exchange is owned by its members, who typi-
ing standards. This is an argument, not for the cally are brokers. Higher trading volumes on
status quo, in which stock exchanges are statu- the exchange generate greater profits for bro-
torily appointed as “self-regulatory organiza- kers. A for-profit exchange can be owned by
tions” under the firm control of the SEC, but dispersed investors, many of whom may not be
rather for a more substantial privatization of brokers. Such exchanges earn profits from fees
the regulatory function. paid by listed companies and brokers and by
Perhaps many observers will find this pre- selling market data. More transactions mean
scription entirely backwards, even danger- more fees and more data that the exchange can
ous. Conventional wisdom about the various sell. Anything, then, that increases the public’s
accounting and governance crises of recent eagerness to trade in listed securities is good for
months holds that they demonstrate the exchanges, whether nonprofit or for-profit,
need for “tougher” regulation and a firmer mutual or publicly owned.
governmental hand on the wheel. But that Political actors, by contrast, are motivated
badly misconceives the dynamics of the regu- to seek approval in the form of votes and
latory process. campaign contributions. Their interests span

2
a much wider set of public policy issues than Those two phenomena combine to create
those related to securities markets. Most bad regulation because they are so easily
important for present purposes, it is clear exploited by rent-seeking businesses. The
from centuries of observation that securities lure of stability is the only positive induce-
markets become salient political topics only ment that the would-be monopolist or cartel
in the immediate aftermath of broad and can offer to consumers. In ordinary times,
sharp declines in securities prices. As legal consumers and political actors are more like-
historian Stuart Banner has noted, every ly to recognize that they are being offered a
important regulatory statute in England and terrible deal. The absence of competition
the United States from the very start of orga- does indeed promote stability, in the sense
nized securities markets in the late 17th cen- that consumers are spared the difficult task
tury was enacted after a market crash.1 of comparison shopping and are not faced
The differences between the incentives fac- with the tough choice between lower prices
ing stock exchanges and those facing politi- and established reputation. The cost, howev-
cians, then, are quite stark. Exchanges have an er, is exorbitant. Consumers pay a high price
ongoing financial incentive to increase trading for the monopolist’s goods or services. A real-
volumes. Elected officials, by contrast, have an ly creative monopolist may even discover a
incentive to avoid blame for market crashes and way to price discriminate and appropriate
Exchanges and
to respond to crashes in ways that will mollify most of the consumer surplus. brokers gain
their constituents. Political actors may respond The history of regulatory efforts in the U.S. when trading
directly through legislation or indirectly by securities markets bears this out. The earliest
putting pressure on regulatory agencies. widespread attempt to regulate securities volumes are high
Political incentives are unlikely to pro- offerings was the so-called blue-sky laws of the and lose when
mote optimal market regulation. First and early 20th century. Those statutes, enacted by
foremost, the incentives facing political individual states, often required advance per-
volumes are low.
actors are considerably more one-sided than mission by a state official to market securities By contrast, the
those facing market actors. Exchanges and in that state. One obvious and notable feature political harm
brokers gain when trading volumes are high of those statutes is that they placed greater
and lose when volumes are low. By contrast, hurdles in the way of high-risk, high-return that elected offi-
the political harm that elected officials suffer securities. Often, companies without a long cials suffer when
when a market decline occurs on their watch operating history, or those whose balance a market decline
is typically much greater than the credit they sheets contained a large amount of intangible
receive when markets are healthy. When mar- assets, were singled out for harsher treatment. occurs is typically
kets are rising, the public typically judges its As legal scholars Jonathan Macey and Geoff much greater
political leaders on some other set of issues— Miller hypothesized, and I have confirmed
education, prescription drug benefits, and so empirically, those statutes were shaped by the
than the credit
on. The stock market is politically important lobbying efforts of banks that feared competi- they receive when
only when it is in sharp decline. tion for depositors’ funds from securities markets are
That tendency reinforces a ubiquitous, salesmen.2 From the outset, then, securities
and exceptionally unhealthy, political reac- regulation was plagued by the problem of sell- healthy.
tion to market crises. When markets decline, ers of low-risk investments trying to use the
faith in and enthusiasm for the chaotic regulatory system to put barriers in the way of
nature of capitalism—Joseph Schumpeter’s sellers of high-risk investments.
“creative destruction”—decline as well and The same phenomenon shaped the federal
are replaced by a desire for stability. Thus, at securities laws of the 1930s.3 Some segments
the same time that the likelihood of signifi- of the securities industry warmly welcomed
cant regulatory changes is at its highest, the federal regulation and benefited substantially
public’s tolerance for risk is at its lowest. That from it. The “bulge bracket” (i.e., the most
is a toxic combination. elite) investment banks of the late 1920s—led

3
by J.P. Morgan & Co. and including a few make sure that today’s problems won’t recur.
other select firms such as Kuhn, Loeb & Co. Accepting such a deal is foolish. By their very
and Dillon, Read & Co.—specialized in rela- nature, extreme events are usually followed
tively low-risk securities such as blue-chip by more normal times—that is, there’s regres-
bonds and railroad stocks. They also sold sion to the mean. Whatever problems have
through a slow, painstaking process involving occurred, therefore, may be temporary. But
multiple syndicates. During the 1920s, howev- the barriers to competition and innovation
er, the securities market changed substantial- that they prompt live on well after the mem-
ly. Investors in pursuit of higher returns began ory of the problems which they were intend-
to include riskier securities in their portfolios. ed to address has faded.
Newer, more aggressive investment banks
such as the National City Company began to
sell securities rapidly through nationwide Why Not the Exchanges?
sales networks linked by telegraph, rather than
through the traditional syndication methods, Counterarguments against the exchanges
and to offer volume discounts. as regulators typically fall into four categories.
As a result, when Congress decided to reg-
ulate public offerings through the Securities • Monopoly. Because trading in a particu-
Act of 1933, the established investment banks lar security is a natural monopoly (or, as
lobbied eagerly for a statute that would slow it is sometimes now expressed, a “net-
down the offering process. The Securities Act work good”), the necessary competitive
did just that. Moreover, the investment pressures are absent.
bankers’ trade group helped to shape a sepa- • Competition. When push comes to shove,
rate innovation, the Maloney Act of 1938, the NYSE would never enforce its rules
which created the National Association of against a listed company, because that
Securities Dealers. The Maloney Act was accu- company would threaten to move to
rately described as a mini–National Recovery Nasdaq, or vice versa. Competition
If the entire Act for the securities industry. Like the NRA, it between exchanges for listings will lead
granted the regulated industry the right to to toothless enforcement.
market for a ban some forms of price competition. A long- • Externalities. Good disclosure and corpo-
specific stock can standing goal of the NASD’s predecessor, the rate governance rules do not merely
migrate at a Investment Bankers Association of America, benefit the marginal investor who hap-
was to make underwriting a “one-price busi- pens to trade in a particular stock at a
reasonable cost ness” by ending all volume discounts. This, particular point in time. They have
from one the IBAA said, was its primary objective in spillover benefits to third parties,
drafting a code of fair practice under the including other investors, competitors,
exchange to NRA.4 After the Supreme Court held the NRA and suppliers. An exchange and its
another, then the unconstitutional, Congress revived the fair members cannot capture all those bene-
incumbent practice code by enacting the Maloney Act, fits because they do not contract with
which explicitly permitted the NASD to out- those third parties. Accordingly, the
exchange cannot law volume discounts. exchange will put less than the socially
extract a Investors, therefore, should not feel reas- optimal amount of effort into design-
monopoly rent sured by reports that Sen. Paul Sarbanes (D- ing and enforcing the rules.
MD) modeled the recently enacted Sarbanes- • Ineffective tools. Because exchanges control
even if it controls Oxley Act on the Maloney Act.5 Instead, that access to the trading mechanism, they
100 percent of analogy should remind us that Congress is have an array of graduated sanctions
constantly tempted by the siren song of available against member firms. A bro-
trading in the industry groups who promise that, if given a kerage firm might be fined a small
stock. free hand to stifle competition, they will amount for a minor violation, suspended

4
for a few days for a slightly greater one, Such monopolists provide low-quality prod- The New York
and expelled for an egregious fraud. The ucts because they can charge only a low-qual- Stock Exchange
same is not true, however, when it comes ity price. Absent price regulation, however,
to disciplining listed companies. Were an the monopolist has ample incentive to and Nasdaq
exchange to suspend trading in a listed improve the product. unquestionably
company’s stock, it would harm invest- The more sophisticated version of the
ors and exchange members as much or argument notes that an exchange is not a uni-
act as if the
more than the listed firm. The primary tary actor but an amalgamation of members market for any
threat the exchange has against a listed offering different services and subject to dif- given stock is
firm is delisting. That, unfortunately, is ferent demand and marginal cost functions.6
too great a sanction for lesser violations Exchange members are heterogeneous; they contestable.
and perhaps too small a sanction for are brokers, arbitrageurs, market makers, spe- Each devotes
extreme violations. The absence of grad- cialists, and others. An exchange’s rules, there- considerable
uated punishments means that the fore, do not simply determine the amount of
exchange’s rules will be violated with the members’ profits; they also determine the effort to arguing
impunity. distribution of those profits. Each group has that its trading
a strong interest in shaping the rules for its
Let us examine these arguments one at a own benefit. The resulting competition
platform is
time. among groups for rents will distort the rule- superior.
making process, potentially generating rules
Monopoly that are less beneficial to investors than those
The monopoly argument comes in two that would be adopted by a unitary actor.
varieties. The less sophisticated version sim- That is a variant of the monopoly argu-
ply holds that a monopolist will provide a ment because it turns on the exchange hav-
shoddy product, and therefore an exchange ing market power—that is, being able to
that has a monopoly over trading in a partic- charge a price in excess of marginal cost for
ular asset will provide shoddy rules of corpo- its services. Absent market power, there are
rate governance and disclosure. This is an old no rents to distribute and therefore no fights
argument with an old answer—even monopo- over their distribution.
lists are subject to the demand curve. They The question of exchange market power is,
can sell their product for more money than a unfortunately, unresolved. It is clear that
competitive firm can, but not for more than traders desire liquidity, which means that a
the product’s value to the marginal con- market is not viable unless it captures
sumer. A rational monopolist will therefore “enough” of the trading in a particular stock
adopt any improvements to the product that to ensure liquidity. The more debatable ques-
cost less than their value to the marginal con- tion is whether “enough” is 100 percent of the
sumer. We would therefore expect a monopo- demand for that stock (in which case trading
list exchange to offer the same “product” in a particular security is a pure natural
(that is, the same corporate governance and monopoly) or something less (in which case
disclosure rules) as a competitive exchange there could be two, or perhaps more, markets
but to charge a higher price. for a given stock). A second issue is whether,
The persistence of the notion that supposing the market for a stock is a natural
monopolists offer a lower-quality product is monopoly, that monopoly is contestable. If
likely a consequence of the fact that our expe- the entire market for a specific stock can
riences with monopolists usually involve migrate at a reasonable cost from one
heavily regulated firms that may not be per- exchange to another, then the incumbent
mitted to raise prices sufficiently to justify exchange cannot extract a monopoly rent even
improvements in service (utilities are a good if it controls 100 percent of trading in the
example, as was AT&T before deregulation). stock. Distributional fights are therefore elim-

5
inated. These are empirical questions on the basis of usage rather than ownership.12 As
which the evidence is not conclusive.7 noted above, the exchange’s members care not
Whatever the merits of the competing the- merely about the size of the rents but also
oretical and empirical arguments, they are about their distribution. They may choose a
being overtaken by events. The New York set of rules that is not optimal from the
Stock Exchange and Nasdaq unquestionably investors’ perspective, and therefore reduce
act as if the market for any given stock is con- the size of the rents, in order to achieve a pre-
testable. Each devotes considerable effort to ferred distribution. For-profit exchanges, how-
arguing that its trading platform is superior. ever, are concerned, not about the distribution
There is persistent migration from the of rents, but about the maximization of prof-
Nasdaq to the NYSE, but in the past few its (and thereby the maximization of investor
years there have also been moves in the other welfare). Nonprofit status allows the ex-
direction.8 Equally important, it is not change’s leadership to focus less on the size of
inevitable that large firms will end up at the the pie and more on how the pie is sliced. This
NYSE. As of the beginning of September opens up the possibility that inefficient rules
2003, 74 of the companies in the Standard & will survive because they achieve the desired
Poors 500 were traded on Nasdaq.9 distribution.
Nonprofit Equally important is the growth of electron- Once an exchange faces substantial com-
status allows the ic trading networks. Initially, these networks petition, however, it can no longer afford the
exchange’s leader- focused on Nasdaq securities because of the luxury of designing rules to create the desired
NYSE’s Rule 390, which restricted off-exchange distribution of rents among its members,
ship to focus less trading of listed stocks by member firms. Rule because there are no longer any rents to dis-
on the size of the 390 was repealed in 2000, however, clearing the tribute. At that point, the exchange is better
way for electronic networks to trade NYSE-list- off dropping its nonprofit status and creat-
pie and more on ed stocks.10 Since the repeal, Instinet, the largest ing—and charging for—optimal rules.
how the pie is electronic network, has accounted for approxi- This analysis sheds light on a fallacy that
sliced. This opens mately 3 percent of quarterly trading volume in has become widespread. Recently, commenta-
NYSE-listed stocks.11 tors and regulators have expressed great con-
up the possibility One measure of the competitive pressure cern that when exchanges convert to for-profit
that inefficient that exchanges feel from electronic networks status, they will abandon investor protection in
rules will survive is the growing movement toward demutual- favor of profits.13 This conventional wisdom is
ization and for-profit status. Exchanges have exactly backwards. The move to for-profit sta-
because they traditionally been organized as mutuals—that tus will increase an exchange’s incentives to
achieve the is, they are owned by their member brokers. adopt optimal investor protections precisely
They have also been nonprofit entities. The because such protections lead to greater prof-
desired principal constraint on a nonprofit entity is its. A for-profit exchange may charge the full
distribution. that it may not make distributions in the marginal cost for its services. It will therefore
nature of dividends. Thus a nonprofit ex- benefit directly from any improvements in
change cannot charge profit-maximizing those services that cost less than what investors
transaction fees and distribute the resulting are willing to pay. The argument against for-
surplus to its members on the basis of their profit status is, therefore, simply a variant of
percentage ownership. Instead, it charges the argument against competition, to which
reduced fees, with the effect that the benefits we now turn.
of exchange membership are captured only to
the extent the member actually consumes the Competition
exchange’s services. Imagine that exchanges have become the
When an exchange has market power and principal source and enforcers of disclosure
its members are heterogeneous, members rules. Now imagine that a large, prominent
might prefer to distribute economic rents on company is accused of violating those rules.

6
Will the exchange vigorously investigate the reflect information. For prices to adjust to an
allegation and apply the agreed-upon penal- exchange’s poor enforcement record, it
ty? Or will it sweep the matter under the rug requires only that a sophisticated few uncov-
so as not to offend a powerful constituent? A er the truth. Those investors respond by trad-
common assumption is that the company ing, which means that prices will reflect the
need only threaten to move to a competing information they have uncovered. The bulk
exchange. The incumbent exchange, unwill- of investors need not have particularly good
ing to risk the loss of a high-profile listed information—they can free ride on the infor-
company, will then back down. mation produced by others.
University of Chicago Law School profes- The other common departure from opti-
sor Daniel R. Fischel and Wharton School mality comes about through externalities, or
economist Sanford J. Grossman have studied circumstances in which third parties who are
that issue at length, but it is worth discussing not participants in the market gain or lose
it here briefly.14 The analysis in the last para- because of transactions in that market.
graph concludes that competition is bad (Externalities are discussed in the next section.)
because companies can play exchanges off Finally, one might declare that we should
against one another. It ignores, however, the look up from economic theory and view the
fact that investors are not innocent bystanders world around us. Participants in markets are
but active participants who can also vote with not automatons but people with human
their feet. If investors care about good disclo- emotions and frailties. Will investors really
sure, then they will penalize exchanges that do know or care enough to desert an exchange
not enforce their disclosure rules. Competi- that doesn’t punish violations of disclosure
tion for companies is profitless unless it is rules? Perhaps not, but that is not an argu-
accompanied by successful competition for ment against exchange regulation relative to
investors. government regulation. Government bureaus
That is simply an application of the First are made up of people, too. Government
Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics, agencies have ample authority, resources, and
which holds that a competitive equilibrium is motivation to prevent frauds such as Enron
Pareto optimal. In other words, the allocation and WorldCom, yet they failed as much as
(in our case, of rules and enforcement) pro- investors, broker-dealers, and exchanges.
duced by a competitive process maximizes con- The point deserves elaboration. Many of
sumer welfare within the constraints of the the market shortcomings that culminated in
consumers’ willingness to pay. The corollary the Enron and other scandals are painfully
for our purposes is that the exchange’s gains clear in retrospect—but only in retrospect.
from keeping the miscreant company will be Before the scandals, it would not have been The move to
more than offset by losses caused by investors’ unreasonable to argue, for example, that for-profit status
reduced desire to trade. firms would be unlikely to go to great lengths
The First Fundamental Theorem of to create temporary mispricings of their will increase an
Welfare Economics, like any analytical result, stock because the move would backfire in the exchange’s incen-
requires some restrictive assumptions. When long run. However, this argument is not tives to adopt
those assumptions do not hold, we can show quite correct in a world in which corporate
that the outcome of the competitive process officers can make tens of millions of dollars optimal investor
will not be optimal. One common departure instantaneously through the exercise of protections
is imperfect information. If investors do not incentive stock options. In that situation, the
know that the exchange is failing to enforce benefits of a brief, one-time increase in price
precisely because
its rules, they will not react appropriately. may really outweigh the discounted value of such protections
Investors in securities markets, however, future compensation and reputation. That, lead to greater
have an especially valuable tool for overcom- in turn, suggests that options align manager-
ing informational deficits. Securities prices ial and investor incentives only imperfectly. profits.

7
The score stands For options to work properly, managers lem, or perhaps boards of directors conclud-
at Market 0, must face strong constraints from accoun- ed that the risk was outweighed by the sub-
tants and securities analysts who attempt to stantial tax benefits to the firm of using
Regulators 0. spot misleading disclosures. Put differently, options rather than cash compensation. A
That is not an when managers have great incentives to mis- 1993 tax law amendment disallowed as a
lead, accountants and analysts must also deductible business expense any executive
argument in favor have strong incentives to prevent deception. compensation exceeding $1 million unless it
of government Unfortunately, the incentives facing is “performance based.” Certainly, Congress
regulation. accountants and analysts have been moving failed to recognize that it was creating poten-
in precisely the opposite direction. One of the tially bad incentives.
striking trends in financial services over the The story differs only in the details when we
past few decades has been the service turn to conflicts of interest facing the account-
providers’ dreams of becoming “one-stop ing industry. Some commentators—in both
shops.” This led accounting firms to offer the private sector and the SEC—warned that
auditing, financial advisory, tax, and legal those conflicts were a substantial problem.15
services. It led Citigroup to bring commercial Investors, however, did not appear to view the
banking, investment banking, securities problem as serious until it was too late. After
analysis, mutual funds, and insurance under the recent scandals, investors changed their
one roof. Such combinations offer operating views about the problem, which prompted
efficiencies and customer convenience. But some accounting firms to divest their advisory
both the service providers and their cus- businesses and some investment banks to
tomers seem to have underestimated the make changes in their analysts’ practices.
associated costs that stem from ubiquitous Meanwhile, Congress and the SEC did not
conflicts of interest. Those conflicts dulled act to address the problem in advance, in part
the accountants’ and analysts’ incentives to because of the strong resistance to the pro-
keep managers honest. posed reforms by accounting firms and
That, in broad outline, is the case for more investment banks. Only after the scandals
regulation. But there is one enormous hole in did the political salience of accounting and
the analysis. Regulators did no better than analyst conflicts of interest reach a level that
investors at appreciating and taking steps to permitted legislative change. To sum up,
prevent problems before the consequences then, prior to the recent scandals, investors
became obvious. Let us begin with incentive did not act aggressively because they did not
options. The sources to which a sensible reg- appreciate the magnitude of the problem,
ulator might turn for guidance—academic and regulators did not act aggressively
opinion, the financial press, and so on—did because it was not politically expedient. At
not identify the problem with sufficient clar- the end of the episode, the score stands at
ity and forcefulness to make a difference. Market 0, Regulators 0. That is not an argu-
Prior to the recent scandals, it was widely ment in favor of government regulation.
accepted among academic lawyers and econ- The government’s after-the-fact response
omists that incentive options closely aligned may seem more vigorous because it is more
the interests of managers and investors. Only highly visible. With considerable fanfare,
in hindsight does it appear that options may Congress has prohibited accounting firms
have an undesired side effect because they from providing certain nonaudit services to
increase in value as the volatility of the stock audit clients and instructed the SEC to make
increases. Thus, options enable managers to rules to improve the independence of securi-
profit from volatility and not only from ties analysts. The market’s solutions, however,
increases in value. That, in turn, can provide are considerably harder to spot. Markets send
a huge payoff from a temporary mispricing. their commands through prices. Having
Perhaps the market failed to notice the prob- learned the hard way that excessive option-

8
based compensation, or the combination of governance rules turns on the idea that the
audit and consulting services, can create bad exchange can profit from providing such
incentives, investors will react. But investors rules by capturing larger trading volumes
do not call press conferences or hold hear- and perhaps charging higher fees. High-qual-
ings—they simply revalue assets. We won’t ity disclosure and governance rules increase
know the results until time has passed and investor wealth by increasing the accuracy of
researchers have had an opportunity to look prices and reducing the ability of corporate
carefully at the clues that prices provide. promoters and managers to misappropriate
We should also keep in mind that political corporate assets.17
actors and regulators seeking more regulatory Not all of these benefits, however, accrue
authority have every incentive to overstate the to the marginal investor—the party whose
contribution of failures of accounting and willingness to pay for improved disclosure
corporate governance to the stock market’s and governance is critical to the analysis.
decline. Although the conflict-of-interest Accurate prices and faithful corporate man-
problems outlined above undoubtedly con- agement also help competing firms, suppli-
tributed to Enron’s collapse, it seems plausible ers, and employees. The exchange does not
that the proximate cause of that collapse was a sell its services to all of those other benefited
failed business model.16 Managers who tried parties, so it cannot charge them for the ben-
Political actors
to hide debt through off-balance-sheet enti- efits the exchange confers. Similarly, some of and regulators
ties, and analysts who credulously or deceit- the benefited parties are inframarginal have every
fully predicted continued rapid growth, may traders who would have traded under either
have made the collapse more violent. The low- or high-quality rules. The exchange also incentive to
absence of conflict-of-interest problems, how- does not capture a share of the benefits overstate the
ever, probably would not have prevented it. received by those inframarginal traders.
Moreover, we cannot easily determine how Because it bears all of the costs and captures
contribution of
much of the price declines that followed the only part of the benefits of writing and failures of
revelations of accounting frauds were a conse- enforcing high-quality rules, the exchange accounting and
quence of investors’ revaluation of the earning will underprovide them. Externalities create a
power of the assets and how much reflected wedge between private and social optimality. corporate gover-
investors’ fears of lawsuits and regulatory Of course, all economic activities generate nance to the
overreaction. Thus, if it turns out that some externalities. When the manufacturer stock market’s
investors viewed the conflict-of-interest prob- of my favorite breakfast cereal invests in
lems as relatively minor, that is not proof that improving the taste, I am in a better mood decline.
the investors were foolish. after eating breakfast, to the benefit of my
It is obvious that investors, like all humans, family and colleagues. The manufacturer
fall short of the perfect cognition and calcula- can’t force those third parties to pay for the
tion required for optimal outcomes. This is a benefit thus conveyed, and it will therefore
large part of the standard argument for regu- invest too little, from a social perspective, in
lation. But it is a deeply flawed argument. We improving the taste of the cereal. But we
cannot expect either markets or regulators to readily recognize such external effects as triv-
achieve perfection. The critical question is ial—as occupying one end of a spectrum. A
whether private or public actors will do better factory dumping toxic wastes into a river
at setting rules. That question just takes us upstream from a town that uses the river for
back to the beginning—to incentives, which drinking water and recreation is at the other
favor the exchange. end of the spectrum.
A substantial majority of academics and
Externalities policymakers would agree that the external
The argument that exchanges have strong effects in the breakfast cereal case are too small
incentives to provide optimal disclosure and to justify government intervention, whereas

9
those in the second case are too large to justify usually needs some in-house legal and
confidence that the invisible hand of the mar- accounting staff to prepare disclosure docu-
ket will solve the problem. Empirical hunches ments and monitor compliance with gover-
about the size of externalities tend to drive nance rules. Those costs are a barrier to new
attitudes toward regulation in many settings. entry. It is, accordingly, unlikely that maxi-
Advocates of regulation believe that externali- mizing the amount of required disclosure is a
ties are often very large and the perverse incen- good way to maximize competition among
tives created by the government’s intervention publicly traded firms. The dominant exter-
are typically small, while advocates of private nality argument in the academic literature,
solutions believe the opposite. For the purpos- then, is not very convincing.
es of this paper, it is not necessary to settle that
debate here; it suffices to ask whether the Poor Enforcement Tools
externalities present in securities markets are The strongest reason to be concerned
closer to the breakfast cereal or toxic waste end about an exchange’s ability to write and
of the spectrum. enforce disclosure and governance rules is
The claim most frequently advanced in the that it lacks good enforcement tools. The
academic literature is that disclosure rules exchange’s principal threat is to delist a com-
affect competitors of the disclosing compa- pany that violates its rules. That is an exces-
ny.18 In particular, disclosures enable competi- sive sanction for minor violations and
tors and potential competitors to learn about accordingly not credible. It is an insufficient
the disclosing firm’s costs and revenues. sanction for egregious violations, particular-
Companies would therefore prefer to disclose ly those prompted by “last period” concerns.
less than the socially optimal amount in order Assume, for example, that a company finds
to hide information from competitors. itself in severe financial distress, but that fact is
At bottom, the concern must be that, not yet publicly known. The company’s offi-
absent disclosure, there will be too little cers face the decision of whether to make com-
entry. Public policy doesn’t (or shouldn’t) plete and accurate disclosures or to conceal
care about the purely distributive question of the company’s true position. They may believe
whether Company A or Company B gets a that concealment could enable them to raise
profitable business opportunity. Instead, we new capital and weather the crisis. By contrast,
care that neither A nor B has the opportuni- full and prompt disclosure will quickly lead to
ty to make more than the competitive level of bankruptcy. To make the hypothetical as com-
profit. If it is easy to identify industries or pelling as possible, let us assume that mere
products in which above-average profits are concealment would not constitute actionable
The strongest available, entry into those businesses will fraud, so the exchange’s sanctions are the only
whittle the profit down to the competitive relevant ones.
reason to be level. If the externality problem is large, then, In that situation, the company has nothing
concerned about it is because companies can hide their prof- to lose from concealment if the only sanction
an exchange’s itability and thereby earn excessive profits is delisting. If the company discloses, it will
quietly without fear of new entry. become bankrupt. If it conceals and the
ability to write The net effect of disclosure and gover- exchange discovers the deception, the compa-
and enforce nance rules on entry, however, is likely nega- ny will be delisted. Assuming that the stigma
disclosure and tive. Compliance with these rules is costly. of delisting in those circumstances destroys
Some of the costs vary with the size of the the market for the company’s securities, the
governance rules company. An outside accounting firm worst that can happen is bankruptcy. There is
is that it lacks charges more for a more complex audit, and no marginal deterrence of concealment.
a larger company usually requires more in- An exchange faces a similarly troubling
good enforce- house compliance staff. But some costs are problem if it tries to withhold its primary
ment tools. fixed—even a very small publicly traded firm benefit—listing and its attendant liquidity—

10
in response to less serious violations. The closed more than those listed on less presti- The exchange’s
exchange could merely suspend listing for a gious exchanges. Clearly, the exchanges did principal threat
brief period rather than terminate it, but not achieve perfection, but by the standards of
most of the cost of the lost liquidity would be their day they did quite well. is to delist a
imposed on investors rather than the corpo- A more important issue for a contempo- company that
rate wrongdoers. rary exchange might be investigation rather
There is no technical barrier, however, to an than sanctioning. In order to impose punish-
violates its rules.
exchange developing a more targeted and var- ments that actually deter, an exchange must That is an exces-
ied set of sanctions. The listing contract be able to determine when a company has sive sanction for
between a company and the exchange is just broken the rules. Government investigators
that—a contract. Like any other contract, it have powerful tools, such as subpoena and minor violations
may include detailed remedy provisions in the search-and-seizure powers, that an exchange and accordingly
event of breach. For example, the listing agree- lacks. Faced with a recalcitrant company, it is not credible.
ment could provide a schedule of fines for much more effective to break down the door
delays and shortcomings in disclosure docu- than to threaten a lawsuit or delisting.
ments. The listed company could be required Once again, the problem can be solved to a
to post a deposit from which the exchange significant extent by contract. The listing
could deduct those fines. As lawyers often say, agreement can ensure the exchange’s employ-
a contract is a “private law” between the par- ees unrestricted access to a listed company’s
ties and can detail their rights and obligations personnel and records, with a provision for
as the parties think appropriate. significant fines if the listed company chooses
It is only natural to ask why exchanges do not to cooperate. Exchanges already typically
not write such detailed contracts. If contract- require that member organizations (such as
ing could solve the enforcement problem, we brokerage firms) permit examination of their
would expect to see exchanges write enforce- books and records by exchange personnel.19
ment procedures into their listing agreements. Were exchanges, rather than the SEC, the pri-
That is unrealistic, however, under the current mary regulators of listed company disclosure,
regulatory regime. The exchanges have rela- they might decide to put a similar provision
tively little authority over listed companies into their listing agreements. Despite those
compared to the SEC. An exchange’s principal contractual solutions, it would be naïve to
enforcement responsibility is with respect to argue that exchanges would have as effective a
its member broker-dealers. We therefore learn set of investigation and enforcement tools as
very little about what is feasible and desirable the SEC possesses today. It is undeniable that
from observing exchange behavior in a world a government agency backed by the state’s
where the SEC writes and enforces disclosure monopoly of force has an edge in investigating
rules for publicly traded companies. and punishing wrongdoing. Perhaps the most
Of course, exchanges didn’t write detailed effective arrangement, then, would be a mix-
enforcement procedures into their listing con- ture of private rule making and government
tracts during the pre-SEC era either. Perhaps enforcement.
this shows that exchanges were unwilling to
spend the resources necessary to ensure that
their disclosure and governance standards Ancient History: The 1920s
were followed. But drawing that conclusion
may simply be succumbing to the nirvana fal- We need not limit ourselves to a purely the-
lacy—i.e., letting the best get in the way of the oretical discussion because there are actual
good. In the pre-SEC era, the level of disclo- examples of securities exchanges acting as the
sure by listed companies was better than that principal regulators of disclosure, accounting,
of over-the-counter firms. Similarly, compa- and governance standards for publicly traded
nies listed on more prestigious exchanges dis- firms. Prior to the enactment of the federal

11
securities laws, stock exchanges played that stantively defective—they were not. They man-
role in the United States. State “blue-sky” laws dated, in rough outline, the principal types of
regulated public offerings, but they were based financial information that forms the back-
on a regulatory theory entirely different from bone of mandated disclosures today. The SEC
that underlying disclosure laws. Disclosure based its early disclosure forms on the NYSE’s
rules seek to make information available to listing standards, reinforcing the notion that
the market so that investors can judge the those standards were reasonably comprehen-
merits of securities offered for sale. Blue-sky sive. Obviously, views about the appropriate
laws, by contrast, were based on the paternal- level of disclosure have evolved since the
istic notion that state officials should decide 1930s, but it is not a controversial proposi-
which securities were “safe” enough to be tion that the NYSE’s stated listing standards
offered for sale. Accordingly, those laws did were adequate for their time.
not aim to make information available to the The debate is over whether those standards
investing public, which was assumed to be were actually enforced and respected. The
incapable of evaluating information. accepted wisdom is that the federal securities
Public offerings were also subject to disclo- laws were adopted precisely because exchange
sure rules that had been developed by courts regulation was ineffective. Listed companies,
There is no under the rubric of the fiduciary duties of cor- critics argue, flouted the NYSE’s standards
technical barrier porate directors, officers, and promoters.20 without consequences. Unfortunately, lawyers
to an exchange Generally speaking, those who sold securities to and policymakers have uncritically accepted
the public had a duty to disclose conflicting the claims of the New Deal proponents of fed-
developing a interests, such as the fact that the sellers stood eral regulation. When scholars have ventured
more targeted to gain from the sale of property to the corpo- beyond the polemics and looked at the evi-
ration or the fact that the sellers would earn a dence directly, a different picture has emerged.
and varied set of commission were the offering successful. Those Contemporary observers were impressed
sanctions. disclosure requirements were focused, however, with the extent of disclosures made by
on conflicts of interest, not on making infor- exchange-listed companies. Columbia Univer-
mation about corporate performance available sity corporate law professor Adolph Berle, who
to the investing public. Stock exchange listing helped shape much of the banking and securi-
standards were the most important means of ties legislation of the New Deal, noted in his
achieving the latter objective. 1932 classic study, The Modern Corporation and
The New York Stock Exchange first adopt- Private Property, that a substantial amount of
ed listing standards in 1856.21 Listed compa- financial information was available to
nies were required to make specified financial investors.23 We can easily verify the accuracy of
information available to the exchange and its Berle’s assessment by picking up a bound vol-
members. By the late 1920s, the mandated ume of Moody’s or Standard & Poor’s invest-
information for newly listed companies ment manuals from the 1920s. Those volumes
included audited annual balance sheets and contain income statements and balance sheets
income statements, and listed companies were for thousands of companies. A quick perusal is
strongly encouraged to provide quarterly sufficient to verify that companies traded on an
financial reports.22 The existence and effective- exchange provided more comprehensive and
ness of stock exchange listing standards in the detailed financial statements than companies
pre-SEC era are obviously relevant to the cur- traded over the counter.
rent debate. The theoretical arguments for More recently, economist George J.
and against exchange regulation of corporate Benston has extensively studied pre-SEC dis-
governance and disclosure must be evaluated closure practices. He discovered a very high
in light of the historical evidence. rate of compliance with the NYSE’s listing
There is little debate over whether the requirements.24 I have separately examined
NYSE’s pre-SEC listing standards were sub- the claim that poor disclosure enabled large

12
traders to manipulate stock prices and found pensation committees composed entire-
that the evidence did not support the claim.25 ly of independent directors, while the
Stuart Banner, although principally con- Nasdaq proposals permit decisions by an
cerned with enforcement actions against bro- independent committee or a majority of
kers, describes the NYSE’s enforcement independent directors. Both the NYSE
efforts in the late 1800s.26 His description is and Nasdaq rules tighten the definition
sharply at odds with the notion that the of “independence” for audit committee
NYSE was unable or unwilling to police its members as required by the Sarbanes-
members (and, by extension, its listed compa- Oxley Act.
nies). The evidence available to us suggests 4. Shareholders must approve adoption
that in the pre-SEC era, listed companies sub- of stock option plans (Nasdaq) or equi-
stantially complied with the NYSE’s listing ty-based compensation plans generally
standards and the resulting disclosures were (NYSE), subject to exceptions.
sufficient to permit investors to make 5. Listed companies must adopt codes of
informed investment decisions. conduct covering legal and ethical
responsibilities.

Modern History: The NYSE proposals also contain a new


The Aftermath of Enron enforcement tool. The exchange may send a
public reprimand letter to a listed company
Both the NYSE and the Nasdaq have pro- that violates a listing standard. The commen-
posed changes to their listing standards, sub- tary to the proposed new rule observes the
ject to the SEC’s approval, in light of the gov- problems noted above—delisting or suspen-
ernance and accounting scandals. It is, of sion hurts investors as much as it does the
course, difficult to determine precisely how company’s management. Adverse publicity is
the exchanges would have altered their listing an alternative sanction that, although less
standards if left to their own devices. The severe, also has fewer third-party effects.
Sarbanes-Oxley Act, which was making its way Those changes, together with the Sarbanes-
through Congress as the exchanges’ proposals Oxley Act, create an interesting experiment
were being formulated, mandates some of the regarding the difference between exchange
The evidence
rule changes ultimately proposed. The SEC regulation and SEC regulation. Two groups of suggests that in
also took considerable interest in the listed companies have protested quickly and the pre-SEC era,
exchanges’ deliberations. Nevertheless, within vociferously against portions of the new list-
the narrow scope of the discretion left to the ing standards. One consists of foreign compa- listed companies
exchanges, the proposed changes provide nies. In general, the NYSE has exempted for- substantially
insight into the exchanges’ views of good cor- eign listed companies from its requirement of
porate governance. an independent audit committee. European
complied with
The revised listing standards include the companies with two-tier board structures the NYSE’s
following provisions:27 (particularly those, like German companies, listing standards
with mandatory union participation) find it
1. Listed companies must have a majority difficult to set up committees of genuinely and the resulting
of independent directors. independent directors. The Sarbanes-Oxley disclosures were
2. Independent directors must meet peri- Act, however, directs the SEC to make inde- sufficient to
odically in executive session without pendent audit committees mandatory. A
management. group of German companies has accordingly permit investors
3. Listed companies must increase the role requested that the SEC exempt them from the to make inform-
of independent directors in nomination audit committee requirement.
and compensation decisions. The NYSE A second concerned group consists of
ed investment
proposals require nominating and com- small businesses. They are worried, among decisions.

13
Rule making by other things, about the cost of recruiting a suf- who believes that more regulation is always
actors whose ficient number of independent directors to better will find such a proposal manifestly
have a majority-independent board. This list- unwise, because exchanges might choose not
wealth is at stake ing requirement, however, is not mandated by to replicate some parts of the current regula-
and who face Sarbanes-Oxley, so the NYSE and the Nasdaq tory structure. But competition will provide
will have to decide whether to build in excep- the necessary incentive for exchanges to
competitive tions to the rule for smaller firms. Thus the select rules that they believe will appeal to
pressure to get SEC on one hand, and the NYSE and the investors, given their costs.
the rules right Nasdaq on the other, must directly confront a For what it is worth, I suspect that the
cost/benefit question regarding new listing immediate result of such a change would not
will be better than standards. Are the costs to investors of deter- be dramatic, just as the immediate results of
rule making by ring some foreign companies, or small busi- federal regulation in the 1930s were not dra-
government nesses, from listing greater or less than the matic. The infant SEC borrowed liberally
costs of failing to hold a steady line on the new from the NYSE’s listing standards to write its
actors. listing standards? The theoretical discussion initial disclosure forms. Similarly, exchanges
above suggests that the exchanges will be more would surely borrow liberally from existing
likely to arrive at the correct answer because precedents—including not only SEC forms
they have a direct financial incentive to do so. but market-tested alternatives such as typical
Watching the SEC, the NYSE, and the Nasdaq Eurodollar disclosure documents. Unlike
as they try to determine how strictly to apply existing law, however, those standards would
the new listing standards may shed new light have to survive the market’s fitness test on an
on the comparative efficacy of exchange and ongoing basis.
agency regulation.

Conclusion
The Best of Both Worlds?
Conventional wisdom has it that recent
Imagine that the Securities Act of 1933 and corporate governance and accounting scan-
the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 were dals demonstrate the need for more govern-
amended to remove all substantive provisions ment and less private regulation of securities
regarding disclosure, accounting standards, markets. The case rests on the fact that the
proxy regulation, and takeover regulation and securities industry developed practices (such
to divest the SEC of its rule-making authority as the close integration of investment bank-
over such matters. However, the statutes ing and securities analysis, or auditing and
retained their anti-fraud provisions and consulting) that were in retrospect not opti-
authorized the SEC to investigate and impose mal, and investors arguably failed to react
civil sanctions against listed companies (and with sufficient alarm. Conveniently ignored
their officers, directors, and affiliates) that vio- is the fact that regulators failed as well.
late any disclosure or corporate governance Regulation by hindsight may be emotion-
rules promulgated by the exchange or other ally soothing, but it is not be the best way to
market on which they are traded. prevent yet unknown problems. In a dynam-
The resulting system would combine the ic setting like the securities markets, self-
advantages of the exchanges’ superior incen- interest is the most powerful tool available
tives to adopt optimal rules and the govern- for adjusting rapidly to changing conditions.
ment’s unique enforcement tools. We could That suggests that rule making by actors
expect competing exchanges to adopt disclo- whose wealth is at stake and who face com-
sure, accounting, and governance standards petitive pressure to get the rules right will be
that are closer to optimal than those adopted better than rule making by government
by Congress and the SEC. Of course, anyone actors.

14
8. The first voluntary move to Nasdaq of a compa-
ny that met the NYSE’s continued listing stan-
Notes dards was in 2000. See “Nasdaq Concludes Record
1. See Stuart Banner, Anglo-American Securities Share and Dollar Volume; Year Composite Index
Regulation: Cultural and Political Roots, 1690–1860 Finishes Lower,” M2 Presswire, January 23, 2001.
(New York: Cambridge University Press, 1998).
9. Standard & Poor’s website, www.spglobal.com/
2. See Geoffrey P. Miller and Jonathan Macey, indexmain500_data.html, visited October 15, 2003.
“Origins of the Blue Sky Laws,” Texas Law Review 70
(1991): 347; and Paul G. Mahoney, “The Origins of 10. See Exchange Act Release No. 42758, 65 Fed.
the Blue Sky Laws: A Test of Competing Reg. 30175 (May 10, 2000).
Hypotheses,” Journal of Law and Economics 46, no. 1
(April 2003): 229–51. 11. Instinet website, www.instinet.com/trade_data
/trade_data_quarter.shtml, visited October 15,
3. This section follows Paul G. Mahoney, “The 2003.
Political Economy of the Securities Act of 1933,”
Journal of Legal Studies 30, no. 1 (2001): 1–31. 12. See Pirrong, “The Theory of Financial Exchange
Organizations.”
4. See “Meeting of Board of Governors of Invest-
ment Bankers Association of America to Be Held 13. See, e.g., International Organization of Securities
Feb 10–11 to Consider Fair Practice Rules for Commissions, Discussion Paper on Stock Exchange
Investment Banking Code,” Commercial and Demutualization, December 2000; Norman S.
Financial Chronicle 138 (February 3, 1934): 782. Poser, “The Stock Exchanges of the United States
and Europe: Automation, Globalization, and
5. See “New Rules on Accountants, but Also Consolidation,” University of Pennsylvania Journal of
Questions,” New York Times, July 26, 2002, p. C1. International Economic Law 22, no. 3 (2001): 497–540
Title I of Sarbanes-Oxley creates a Public Company (“regulators see a conflict between the duty of the
Accounting Oversight Board that regulates audit- managers of a publicly owned stock exchange to
ing firms and their activities. The compliance and maximize profits for the benefit of its shareholders
financial costs imposed by this new body will cre- and their regulatory obligation to protect
ate barriers to entry for smaller firms, thus consol- investors”). A good overview of the arguments
idating the position of the Big Four accounting regarding the compatibility of for-profit status and
firms, which now have significant market power to self-regulation appears in Roberta S. Karmel,
raise the rates for their audit services. “Turning Seats into Shares: Causes and Impli-
cations of Demutualization of Stock and Futures
6. Craig Pirrong has provided the most rigorous Exchanges,” Hastings Law Journal 53, no. 2 (2002):
form of the argument. See Craig Pirrong, “A 367–430.
Theory of Financial Exchange Organization,”
Journal of Law and Economics 43, no. 2 (2000): 14. See Daniel R. Fischel and Sanford J. Grossman,
437–72; and Craig Pirrong, “The Self-Regulation “Consumer Protection in Futures and Securities
of Commodity Exchanges: The Case of Market Markets,” Journal of Futures Markets 4 (1984): 273.
Manipulation,” Journal of Law and Economics 38,
no. 1 (1995): 141–206. 15. See, e.g., Tamar Frankel, “Accountants’ Inde-
pendence: The Recent Dilemma,” Columbia Business
7. For evidence of exchange market power, see Law Review 2000, no. 2 (2000): 261–74; and
Craig Pirrong, “The Organization of Financial “Auditory Discomfort: Auditors under Fire,” The
Exchange Markets: Theory and Evidence,” Journal Economist, January 13, 2000 (discussing SEC con-
of Financial Markets 2, no. 4 (1999): 329–57. By con- cerns about accountants’ nonaudit services),
trast, other commentators look at the structure of www.economist.com/research/articlesBySubject/P
financial exchanges and see considerable competi- rinterFriendly.cfm?Story_ID=274092&subjectID=
tion, both among trading platforms and between 1290116.
exchanges and their members, for the provision of
order execution services. See, e.g., Marshall E. 16. See Christopher L. Culp and William A.
Blume, “The Structure of U.S. Equity Markets,” in Niskanen, eds., Corporate Aftershock: The Public Policy
Brookings-Wharton Papers on Financial Services, ed. Lessons from the Collapse of Enron and Other Major
Robert E. Litan and Richard Herring (Washington: Corporations (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 2003).
Brookings Institution Press, 2002), pp. 35–60; and
Benn Steil, “Changes in the Ownership and 17. Although debates over securities regulation typ-
Governance of Securities Exchanges: Causes and ically focus on the first of these harms, I have
Consequences,” in Brookings-Wharton Papers on argued that the second—the fact that poor disclo-
Financial Services, pp. 61–91. sure helps corporate promoters and managers to

15
misappropriate assets without being detected—is reprint, New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publish-
the greater harm, and the one to which securities ers, 1991).
disclosure norms were originally addressed. See
Paul G. Mahoney, “Mandatory Disclosure as a 24. See George J. Benston, Corporate Financial
Solution to Agency Problems,” University of Chicago Disclosure in the UK and the USA (New York:
Law Review 62 (1995): 1047. Lexington Books, 1976); George J. Benston, “An
Appraisal of the Costs and Benefits of
18. See Merritt B. Fox, “Securities Disclosure in a Government-Required Disclosure: SEC and FTC
Globalizing Market: Who Should Regulate Requirements,” Law and Contemporary Problems 41
Whom?” Michigan Law Review 95, no. 8 (1997): (Summer 1977): 30; and George J. Benston,
2498–2629; and Frank H. Easterbrook and Daniel “Required Disclosure and the Stock Market: An
R. Fischel, “Mandatory Disclosure and the Evaluation of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934,”
Protection of Investors,” Virginia Law Review 70, American Economic Review 63 (1973): 132.
no. 3 (1984): 669–715.
25. See Paul G. Mahoney, “The Stock Pools and
19. See, e.g., NYSE Rule 304(h)(4). the Securities Exchange Act,” Journal of Financial
Economics 51 (1999): 343–69.
20. See Easterbrook and Fischel.
26. See Banner, “The Origins of the New York
21. See Stuart J. Banner, “The Origin of the New Stock Exchange.”
York Stock Exchange, 1791–1860,” Journal of Legal
Studies 27, no. 1 (1998): 113–40. 27. See “Report of the New York Stock Exchange
Corporate Accountability and Listing Standards
22. The discussion herein draws from Paul G. Committee,” June 6, 2002, www.nyse.com/pdfs/
Mahoney, “The Exchange as Regulator,” Virginia corp_govreport.pdf. A summary of Nasdaq’s most
Law Review 83 (1997): 1453. recent (as of September 10, 2003) corporate gover-
nance proposals can be found at www.nasdaq.com
23. Adolf A. Berle and Gardiner C. Means, The /about/Corp_Gov_Summary.pdf.
Modern Corporation and Private Property (1932;

Published by the Cato Institute, Policy Analysis is a regular series evaluating government policies and offer-
ing proposals for reform. Nothing in Policy Analysis should be construed as necessarily reflecting the views
of the Cato Institute or as an attempt to aid or hinder the passage of any bill before congress. Contact the
Cato Institute for reprint permission. Additional copies of Policy Analysis are $6.00 each ($3.00 each for five
or more). To order, or for a complete listing of available studies, write the Cato Institute, 1000
Massachusetts Ave., N.W., Washington, D.C. 20001, call toll free 1-800-767-1241 (noon - 9 p.m. eastern
time), fax (202) 842-3490, or visit our website at www.cato.org.

16

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi