Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 32

No.

572 July 13, 2006


�������

Vertical Integration and the Restructuring


of the U.S. Electricity Industry
by Robert J. Michaels

Executive Summary

Debates on restructuring the U.S. electricity tricity utility restructuring laws that may create
industry are often about the degree to which production inefficiencies that shrink the net
market relationships should replace transactions benefits of any move toward market provision of
that formerly took place within regulated, verti- power supplies.
cally integrated utilities. Markets for the pur- A review of the debate surrounding electric
chase of energy by vertically unintegrated distri- utility restructuring in California—the first state
bution utilities are clearly feasible, but vertical to embrace restructuring—reveals that legislators
deintegration of existing systems may eliminate and regulators regarded vertical integration pri-
some operational and reliability benefits that are marily as a tool that incumbent utilities could
important in light of the unique characteristics use to perpetuate their market power. They thus
of electricity. disregarded the benefits that might accrue from
Politicians and policy analysts have almost vertical integration and used the force of regula-
totally disregarded a large body of academic lit- tion to encourage the sale of generating plants to
erature regarding the efficiencies that are gained independent power producers. The idea was to
through vertical integration in the electricity sec- create a competitive market structure in the elec-
tor. At the same time, those parties have enthusi- tricity generation sector. Unfortunately, the costs
astically embraced other studies that purport to associated with this experiment in California
estimate the benefits of switching to a so-called and elsewhere have yet to be compared with ben-
restructured regime consisting of independent efits in any economically meaningful way.
generation and integrated transmission and dis- A proper comparison of the two suggests that
tribution. The result has been the passage of elec- restructuring is presently off course.

_____________________________________________________________________________________________________
Robert J. Michaels is a professor in the Department of Economics at California State University, Fullerton, and an
adjunct scholar at the Cato Institute.

PA Masthead.indd 1 2/9/06 2:08:34 PM


The case for Introduction: Vertical enhanced if that market were allowed to oper-
deintegration is Integration and Electricity ate. Transmission and distribution, however,
remain most efficiently organized as monopo-
problematic. The past 30 years have transformed the lies, and those activities should continue to be
Its advocates economic theory of the business firm.1 In- regulated.
stead of assuming that the scope of a firm’s In reality, the case for deintegration is
often argue from activities is fixed, economists now treat its problematic. Its advocates often argue from
inappropriate boundaries as matters of choice. The eco- inappropriate analogies with other industries
analogies with nomics of organization asks such questions or nations and disregard a large body of
as whether the firm should purchase its raw econometric research on the efficiencies of
other industries materials in markets or produce them in a vertically integrated utilities.4 If both integra-
or nations and facility that it owns and whether its product tion and competitive markets have desirable
disregard a should be sold by salaried employees or by economic properties, industry restructuring
independent retailers. A rational decision should focus on facilitating the most effi-
large body of about producing raw material or buying it cient mix of the two. Unfortunately, the value
econometric from a third party requires that the firm con- of integration between generation and trans-
sider alternative ways to hedge price uncer- mission has been conspicuously unexplored,
research on the tainty and ensure deliveries, its ability to and thus restructuring threatens to produce
efficiencies of coordinate production and use of the raw institutions that foreclose the realization of
vertically material in question, and its competence in important efficiencies.
managing the dissimilar activities of raw The economically efficient degree of dein-
integrated material and output production. tegration is not obvious. Vertical deintegra-
utilities. Almost since their origin, electric utilities tion could remedy discrimination against
have been vertically integrated, with genera- competitors by an integrated utility, but so
tion, transmission, and distribution com- could a policy that requires integrated utili-
bined in a single firm. The operational ration- ties that transmit their own power to honor
ale for vertical integration was largely related requests from others to use their lines on the
to the physics of electricity delivery. In order same terms. Note that the latter remedy does
for electricity to be transmitted from the gen- not change the organizational structure of
erator to the consumer, electricity supply and the company whereas the former does just
electricity demand must remain in precise that. Of course, there may not be a problem
balance at every instant over a wide area. That to remedy in the first place—favoring genera-
challenging task requires a central authority tors that one owns may be efficient.
to govern both the supply of and the demand Various gradations of deintegration have
for electricity along the power grid.2 been proposed. The least extreme form man-
There were also economic incentives for ver- dates a functional separation of generation,
tical integration. Low-cost production requires transmission, and distribution into different
the simultaneous optimization of both gener- administrative divisions within the firm. A step
ator dispatch and transmission capacity. Long- beyond that lies structural separation, which
run efficiency requires the coordination of creates subsidiaries that must deal at arm’s
investment decisions at all stages of the chain length and in a nondiscriminatory manner
from generators to low-voltage distribution with each other. A step beyond that lies the pre-
lines. ferred policy of the Federal Energy Regulatory
In the mid-1970s scholars first argued that Commission, which encourages an opera-
generation could be organized as a competi- tional separation of generation and transmis-
tive market.3 Superficially, the case for vertical sion services and a surrender of the control of
deintegration is clear: changes in technology the power grid to a nonprofit, public-private
have turned generation into a potentially com- independent system operator (ISO) or regional
petitive market, and efficiency would be transmission organization (RTO).5 The most

2
extreme deintegration breaks generation and tionship with B or lose any that were specific
transmission into separate corporations, as to the relationship with A.
occurred in the United Kingdom. Contracts will supersede markets, howev-
To better understand vertical integration er, when a nonstandardized product is par-
and electricity markets, this paper summarizes ticularly valuable, when durable and specific
the economics of vertical integration and its investments are necessary to realize that
application to electricity. I then confront the value, or when the allocation of risk the par-
record of economic and legal thought on ties prefer cannot be obtained in the market.
restructuring with the econometric evidence For instance, assume a buyer wants a fuel
concerning integration. That research almost supply with flexible deliveries, which requires
unanimously concludes that vertical integra- that the supplier construct a specialized stor-
tion is an efficient form of organization for age facility the cost of which is unrecoverable
electric utilities. Research on the role of com- if the buyer stops taking fuel from the firm
petitive markets in electricity has been less (there are no comparable buyers nearby). The
complete and often less rigorous. buyer gets value only if the facility is built,
and the seller builds it only if the buyer com-
mits to a long relationship. A contract
The Economics of Vertically between them may prohibit the buyer from
Economic activity
Integrated Utilities procuring fuel elsewhere and the supplier can be organized
from selling it to others when the buyer in three basic
Economic activity can be organized in expects delivery.
three basic ways: markets, contracts, or verti- Vertical integration is an efficient organi- ways: markets,
cal integration. The merits of each vary de- zational choice if (1) assets are highly specific contracts,
pending on the nature of the enterprise. to a given use or location, (2) assets are uti-
Markets are places or institutions where lized in activities that must be coordinated,
or vertical
buyers and sellers compare their valuations and (3) if the best uses of an asset depend on integration. The
of goods. Prices are discovered as informa- contingencies that are hard to predict.6 merits of each
tion about offers and other market condi- Whether governance of a relationship will be
tions becomes public. The cost of using a by integration, markets, or contracts depends vary depending
market instead of contracts or vertical inte- on the benefits and costs of each option, possi- on the nature of
gration will be lower the easier it is (1) to con- bly including the cost of changeover from one the enterprise.
tact potential counterparties, (2) to compare to another of the three. Markets may become
their offers, and (3) to perform the transac- more attractive if they offer better alternatives
tion, whose costs may include the determina- than the buyer could self-provide at the same
tion of product quality and buyer creditwor- cost or if the cost of using markets decreases
thiness. (Internet access, for instance, allows quick
Buyers and sellers are more likely to use worldwide shopping with lower risks of nonde-
markets to exchange relatively standardized livery). The benefits of contracting may likewise
goods in situations in which information rise (health insurance is more valuable to me,
about their characteristics and the character- for instance, if medicine is more advanced) if its
istics of counterparties is easy to obtain. The costs become lower (without standardized
cost of using markets is also affected by the automobile insurance, for instance, liability
cost associated with changing buyer-seller risks are so high that I choose not to drive).
relationships. Markets characterized by sub- Integration can become a more attractive orga-
stitutable products and uncommitted buyers nizational form (if the market for a raw materi-
and sellers work smoothly. For instance, a al input, for example, becomes more unstable
seller who stops dealing with buyer A and and the costs of writing contracts to manage
starts dealing with buyer B does not need to that instability are prohibitive). It can also
make any investments specific to the rela- become less attractive (for example, if growth of

3
an industry implies that external specialist sup- Several attributes of electrical service
pliers can make a component more cheaply make vertical integration an efficient organi-
than users can if they do the job themselves). zational choice.8

Electricity • Vertical Integration and the Hold-Up Problem.


Generation, transmission, and distribu- The dedicated nature of electricity assets
tion of electricity are highly interdependent. implies that generators need transmission
With minor exceptions, power cannot be to get their product to consumers and
stored and must be produced the instant it is that transmission assets need generators.
consumed. Failure of generation to meet Thus either side can “hold up” the other.9
demand will result in blackouts. The demand That is, once assets are in place and inde-
for electricity has both random elements and pendently owned, transmitters might
predictable hourly and seasonal characteris- refuse to pay anything above a generating
tics. Efficient response to both predictable plant’s marginal costs and generating
and unpredictable events requires centralized firms might accept such demands.
operation of generation and transmission.7 Generation requires transmission to reach
Electricity can be produced and delivered consumers, the power plant’s assets can-
economically only if highly specialized assets not be dedicated to other uses, and the
are in place. Distribution lines must physically plant itself cannot move to a more lucra-
reach users, and transmission lines must cover tive service territory. A solution to this pos-
the distance between distribution lines and sibility is vertical integration, which ends
generation. For reliability, some generators the fight between generation and trans-
must be close to consumers while for econom- mission over the division of the economic
ical production others may be more distant. surplus from their interaction.
Investment in generation and transmission is • Coordination of Investments in a Complex
a long and costly process, and, once in place, System. Vertical integration facilitates the
the equipment cannot be cheaply redeployed coordination of highly specific and inter-
to some other location or use. dependent investments in generation
Such characteristics suggest contract or and transmission. The two are substi-
vertical integration as the likely industrial tutes in the production of bulk power
organization for electricity. Contracts govern (since transmission allows access to a
some vertical relationships in electricity, for larger universe of power plants) and com-
example, between a utility and an indepen- plements in the delivery of electricity
dent power producer or between a transmis- from generators to consumers. Any new
sion-owning utility and a small municipal facility affects the economic value of all
utility that depends on the other’s lines for other facilities on the system, and an
deliveries. But even if a highly specific asset is organization that owns most such facili-
under contract, its owner may act oppor- ties may also be most likely to under-
tunistically (e.g., a generator may attempt to stand their interactions and invest opti-
overcharge the utility if it knows that refusal mally in them.
Its characteristics to cooperate will cause a blackout). The utili- • Risk Reduction and Risk Management. A ver-
suggest contract ty may, of course, sue the generator, but its tically integrated utility may have less risk
or vertical probability of success will depend on how a than one that operates under long-term
court interprets the details of a complex con- contracts with generators. The probabili-
integration as the tract. A contract will be more difficult to ty of a blackout will be lower with coordi-
likely industrial negotiate and enforce if there is uncertainty nated operation of a large system. Great-
about when the utility will require power er certainty may lower the company’s
organization for from the generator and how much it will cost of capital, potentially important in
electricity. require. such a capital-intensive industry.

4
Electricity’s Changing Environment Such facts imply that markets are more The facts imply
Do changes in the fundamental character- desirable today than in the past. They do not, that markets are
istics of electricity production warrant a recon- however, by themselves, imply that vertical
sideration of vertical integration as the default deintegration is warranted because they do more desirable
organizational design? To better understand not consider its costs. Deintegration’s net today than in the
vertical changes in the electricity sector, first value also depends on the benefits of integra-
consider the unchanging interface between tion that will be forgone. So, the policy ques-
past. They do
transmission and distribution, where restruc- tion is “What is the optimal degree of deinte- not, however, by
turing has had no substantial impact. Both are gration?” American restructuring, however, themselves, imply
highly specific assets, restricted as to location has not approached the problem this way
and transferable to nonelectrical uses only at despite the availability of some relevant that vertical
high cost. Competitive duplication of either is research findings. deintegration is
costly and sacrifices the scale economies and warranted
diminished line losses of larger conductors.
The process of transforming voltages across Restructuring and because they do
the transmission-distribution interface is little Economics not consider
changed, and second-by-second coordination
of flows across the grid remains necessary. Until the 1960s U.S. courts often ruled
its costs.
Vertical integration between transmission and that vertical mergers by large firms could
distribution may in fact have become more extend market power at one stage of produc-
valuable if the emergence of wholesale mar- tion into otherwise competitive stages.13 In
kets has increased uncertainty about fluctuat- the 1960s and 1970s economists came to the
ing flows across the interface.10 conclusion that the judicial view was general-
Vertical deintegration between generation ly incorrect.14 First, a monopolist in one stage
and transmission is more economically of a vertical chain (diamonds) does not need
defensible. FERC’s “open access” rules (see to merge with or acquire other competitive
below) require transmission owners to carry businesses in the chain (jewelry stores) to
the output of independent power producers capture all the monopoly gains possible. The
(IPPs) in a nondiscriminatory manner. IPPs more efficiently the diamonds are retailed,
now make up 45 percent of U.S. generation the higher the wholesale price the monopo-
capacity.11 Although the assets are highly spe- list can charge and the higher its profit.
cific and require coordination, other attrib- Second, if vertical mergers or restrictions can-
utes of electric energy may make markets not increase a seller’s market power, their
desirable. It is a homogeneous commodity, it probable purpose is to turn the firm into a
can be centrally traded, and bilateral con- better competitor by reducing the transac-
tracts are common between buyers and sell- tion costs between stages of production.
ers who choose not to use the central Regulatory evasion provides a potential
exchange. Market size is growing with exception to this benign view of vertical rela-
FERC’s RTO initiatives, and the technologies tionships. In 1973 the Supreme Court decid-
of long-distance transmission and wide-area ed Otter Tail Power v. U.S., holding that a verti-
system controls are improving. Finally, econ- cally integrated utility with market power in
omists and others have devised new market transmission had violated the antitrust laws
institutions to facilitate trade. Some short- by refusing municipal distribution utilities
term markets operate under “two-settle- the use of its lines to deliver inexpensive
ment” systems for day-ahead and real-time power they had purchased for themselves.15
transactions; ancillary services (load follow- Because the municipal utilities had no trans-
ing and reserve generation) can also be trad- mission alternatives, they had to take higher-
ed, and some grids use Locational Marginal cost service from Otter Tail. The Court con-
Pricing of transmission.12 cluded that the vertically integrated utility

5
company was attempting to monopolize dis- significantly reduce the cost of opera-
tribution in its area, when competition for tion at any stage of the industry.19
franchises was in fact possible. It further ruled
that the government could order Otter Tail to Some tried to prove their cases by analogy:
transmit power to the towns if necessary.
Guided by the Otter Tail ruling, scholars [I]n other industries, production has
began to make the case for the vertical deinte- not, for the most part, been integrated
gration of electricity. Over the 1970s and 1980s with distribution. There is today no
lawyers and economists produced several pro- compelling reason for such integration
posals for deintegration, some still cited in electric power either.20
today.16 They differ in numerous details, but all
begin by considering long-distance transmis- References such as these continue to guide
sion and local distribution as natural monopo- many policymakers. They do so despite the
lies. All of them want greater competition fact that, shortly after these studies were pub-
between corporate utilities and local govern- lished, economists began attempting to esti-
ments for franchises to distribute power. mate the benefits of vertical integration.
The reasons for encouraging franchise Almost uniformly, their findings would con-
There are at least competition are unclear. Distribution is a tradict the claims these studies made about
11 published standardized technology the costs of which, deintegration.
studies that in most areas, are under 15 percent of the
delivered cost of power, and few if any real Econometric Studies of Vertical Integration
investigate the savings would result if a small municipality There are at least 11 published studies that
relationship were to take over the operation of lines with- investigate the relationship between the vertical
in its boundaries.17 The authors of these integration of electricity generation, transmis-
between the studies also intended to facilitate the growth sion, and distribution and utilities’ costs.21
vertical integra- of energy markets by introducing competi- They cover the United States and Japan, both of
tion of electricity tion by nonutilities for contracts with dis- which are served by regulated, vertically inte-
tributors and shared participation in new grated corporate utilities with assigned territo-
generation, projects. At the time of their writings, howev- ries. Their data cover subsets of years between
transmission, and er, continuing technological progress in large 1970 and 1997, all taken from utilities’ annual
distribution and power plants and other factors actually made filings with regulatory agencies under stan-
generation an unpromising market.18 dardized reporting systems.22
utilities’ costs. The radical deintegrations that these The Appendix to this paper summarizes
The only study to authors proposed were based on a belief that their methods and findings.23 The only study
even relatively small market benefits were to find that vertical integration worsened
find that vertical worth pursuing since they could be obtained economic efficiency is the most questionable
integration by the simple (so the authors believed) step of on several grounds.24 Only one author finds
worsened breaking up corporate utilities. In particular, no statistically significant economic advan-
they unanimously asserted without proof that tages to integrated generation, transmission,
economic vertical deintegration would produce few if any and distribution.25 Because the authors uti-
efficiency is the efficiency losses: lize different samples and research tech-
niques, it is impossible to compare their
most question- The reduction of competition at the dis- numerical estimates of the savings from inte-
able on several tribution stage might be acceptable if gration, but with the exceptions mentioned
grounds. vertical integration made utilities more above they are all significantly positive.26
efficient. That, however, is not the case.
Utilities strive to integrate forward to Vertical Integration, Fuel Supplies, and
obtain a dependable supply of bulk Generator Performance
power. But vertical integration does not Research on electricity generation, trans-

6
mission, and distribution primarily concerns cost adjustment provision in rates, which
the effects of vertical integration on produc- might allow utilities to opportunistically over-
tion cost. Research on the integration of fuel state the costs of mining to obtain higher
supplies and the outsourcing of generator rates.33 Likewise, economist John Gonzales
engineering and construction, by contrast, is found that productivity is lower in utility-
about the transactions costs associated with owned coal mines than in independent ones.
vertical integration.27 For example, MIT econ- Some utility-owned mines, however, are
omist Paul Joskow has examined the factors unregulated, and their productivity is the
that may incline a coal-fired generator to enter same as that of independent mines.34 By con-
into long-term contracts for coal from mining trast, economist Joe Kerkvliet found that verti-
companies rather than to purchase coal from cally integrated mines were more technically
a third party.28 The more particular the needs efficient than unintegrated ones. With a given
of the power plant or the coal producer, the mix of inputs, Kerkvliet argued, an integrated
more likely—in theory—that coal production mine would produce more than an uninte-
and consumption will be integrated within grated one, other things being equal.35
the same firm. Greater specificity (in either the Generator performance provides a more
generator or the coal supply) should be more indirect but less conclusive test of the trans-
likely to entail integration between the mine action-cost model. Economists Paul Joskow
and the utility. His findings are generally con- and Richard Schmalensee examined the
sistent with this theory: operational heat rates and unit availability of
low-pressure “subcritical” and high-pressure
• Only a small amount of coal is traded in “supercritical” coal-fired units. Their regres-
spot markets, and trades are primarily sions included indicator variables for the
in the East, where there are more mines four utilities that were the largest owners of
and more generators than in the West.29 these plants, which performed their own
• Mine-mouth plants are more often design and engineering work; the other utili-
designed to burn a specific type of coal ties outsourced those functions. For both
than are non-mine-mouth plants, and types of generators, two of the four integrat-
more likely to be integrated with utility- ed owners enjoyed significantly better avail-
owned mines.30 ability and heat rates than average, while the
• Coal supply contracts are on average 12 other two companies were at the average.36
years longer for unintegrated mine-
mouth plants than for plants not locat- Vertical Integration and Reliability
ed there. Longer-term contracts tend to There are no publicly available studies that
exist for the generator’s full require- estimate the actual or potential impact of ver-
ments and they contain complex mar- tical deintegration on reliability. Noteworthy
ket-based price adjustment terms.31 outages are rare in the United States, and reli-
• Long-term contracts are more common ability analysts are justifiably more interested There are no
in the West, where a plant must burn in their proximate causes (equipment mal- publicly available
low-sulfur coal compatible with the function, trees touching lines, etc.) than in
details of a generator’s engineering, than their relationships to changes in industry
studies that
they are in the East, which has numerous structure. estimate the
interchangeable coal sources.32 Structural changes in the industry such as actual or
vertical deintegration, the formation of RTOs,
Regulation can change the costs and bene- the growth of existing wholesale markets, and potential impact
fits of the integration of mining and power direct access of final customers to nonutility of vertical
generation. Economist John Filer found that suppliers could affect system reliability. All of
the most important factor influencing the those changes make operations more complex
deintegration
decision to integrate is the presence of a fuel and possibly riskier, but there is no clear way on reliability.

7
The case for to apportion the causation of outages among NERC’s concerns about operating diffi-
deintegration and them. Concerns have also been expressed that culties may be justified, but its reports do not
more extensive restructuring will adversely discuss any actual outages or operating crises
restructuring has affect investment in transmission because cost that it believes were caused by vertical deinte-
implicitly been recovery may be at risk if unforeseen market gration or increased reliance on markets. The
changes leave a new line underutilized. These organization’s data, however, show increases
founded on a effects could worsen already-existing prob- of several hundred percent between 1998 and
belief that the lems that have been caused by 20 years of low 2004 in emergencies that required the use of
savings and transmission investment.37 extraordinary procedures for redispatch and
The North American Electric Reliability curtailment known as Transmission Loading
other benefits Council has for some time been concerned Relief.41
obtainable from about the effects of restructuring on reliabil- The increase in TLR probably has multiple
markets exceed ity.38 Its annual reliability assessments dis- causes. There has certainly been increased
cuss the consequences in general terms: stress on the transmission system due to low
those that are investment in new and upgraded facilities.
associated with The responsibility for coordinating oper- NERC also blames changes in the pattern of
ations between generating plants and grid use, as systems designed for predictable
vertical transmission systems traditionally has transfers between utility-owned generation
integration. been assigned to the utility transmission and captive loads have been required to
system operators and system planners. accommodate the less predictable flow pat-
Administrative separation [i.e., vertical terns that result from market transactions.42
deintegration of generation and trans- Some observers worry that a vertically inte-
mission] as well as the growing number grated utility can exercise market power if it
of [independent power producers] de- calls for TLR in a nonemergency situation.
mands a more standardized and formal That’s because TLR protocols on capacity
understanding of the bulk electric grid reservation and service curtailment can at
control and reliability criteria by all.39 times give priority to the transmission owner’s
own generation over transactions by competi-
NERC also sees inefficiencies resulting from tors that use the same lines. Attorney Diana
uncoordinated planning and investment Moss concludes that determining whether
decisions: emergencies or market power explain TLR
growth will require further research.43 If verti-
The close coordination of generation cally integrated utilities actually do invoke
and transmission planning is diminish- TLR for strategic reasons, however, it will
ing as vertically integrated utilities divest more likely be as a consequence of the particu-
their generation assets and most new lar TLR rules in effect than of vertical integra-
generation is being proposed and devel- tion itself.
oped by independent power producers. Moss’s work more generally addresses
Once new generation is announced the potential conflicts between competition and
necessary transmission additions to sup- reliability that may have been aggravated by
port it must still be designed, coordinat- deintegration and market growth. She recog-
ed with other generation and transmis- nizes, however, that inefficiency and threats
sion, and constructed. Since these activi- to reliability can also result from the absence
ties are no longer carried out within a of market forces. For example, if transmis-
single organization, more time will need sion is sold at regulated rates that recover
to be allowed to coordinate and perform average cost rather than priced in a market to
these tasks to properly integrate the new reflect its scarcity, there may be little invest-
generation to ensure reliability before it ment in new lines, and those that are actual-
can come into service.40 ly built may be inefficiently located.44 By con-

8
trast, NERC appears to believe that engineer- SEtrans had good reason to propose par-
ing standards should generally take prece- ticipant funding. Its area contained fuel sup-
dence over market outcomes: plies and generator sites that might produce
power for distant consumers, but those gen-
[Due to vertical deintegration] genera- erators would add little to system reliability.
tion additions cannot be planned in an Further, some people argue that mandatory
integrated fashion with transmission cost sharing might allow inefficient trans-
expansion, resulting in sub-optimal mission investments that would not be made
transmission expansion in some areas. if beneficiaries had to bear their full costs.
Generation is not locating close to One representative of a large utility in
demand centers, but rather is locating SEtrans saw the failures of past planning as
close to a fuel supply, adequate cooling further reason to institute participant fund-
water, and a transmission line inter- ing. In his view, the ability of grid planners to
connection.45 make efficient long-run choices is doubtful.
Seeing that today’s industry faces unprece-
The interrelationship between investments dented uncertainty about load growth, mar-
in generation and transmission leads NERC ket development, new technologies, and fuel
to favor planning by utilities over reliance on prices, he said, “We cannot optimally plan
The North
markets. Beyond this statement, however, the transmission grid any longer, and we American Electric
NERC provides no discussion about which should not try and pretend that we can.”48 Reliability
decisions it thinks are best made in markets. That statement is well-founded. A centrally
In electricity, the choice between planning and planned RTO must choose which lines to Council has for
markets is a matter of degree: vertical integra- build or upgrade from numerous alterna- some time been
tion and centralized planning yield reductions tives, each of which might be consistent with
in operating costs, but markets may at times reliability. Participant funding leaves those
concerned about
provide other sources of cost reduction bene- decisions to the market, where pressure to the effects of
fits that outweigh the losses from less com- make efficient choices may be greater. Lines restructuring on
prehensive planning. that create benefits for the entire region
An alternative perspective that empha- might still best remain under the ownership reliability.
sizes the benefits of independent transmis- of vertically integrated utilities.
sion, however, has recently surfaced at FERC, Harvard economist William Hogan, how-
which is considering several proposals to ever, has raised concerns about a participant
allow “participant funding” of additions to funding scheme. He observed that a “free-
RTO grids by generators and others.46 One of rider” problem might well arise if some lines
the most important proposals was a 2002 were funded by new participants while others
application to form SEtrans, an RTO in the were funded by all users as a group. That’s
Southeast, which envisioned participant because an entity that would normally pro-
funding as one of two types of transmission pose a participant-funded line may prefer to
investment.47 The SEtrans applicants argued wait until its absence begins to affect reliabil-
that lines linking new generators to the grid ity, at which time the RTO might authorize
should generally be funded by the new par- collective funding.49 Thus far, the search for a
ticipants in the system because the benefits clear distinction between lines that should be
accrued primarily to those parties. Some participant funded and those needed for reli-
other lines (often planned by the RTO) ability has produced no operational criteria
would bring more general benefits in the for making that distinction.50
forms of increased reliability and improved
access to markets. Their costs would be pro- Summary
rated (“rolled in”) according to agreed-upon The movement to restructure electricity
formulas. began with generalities about the desirability

9
of markets coupled with claims that vertical December 1995. The California legislature
integration in utilities was either unimpor- enacted that order into law in September 1996
tant or that its effects could easily be dupli- and established the California Power Exchange
cated in markets. The econometric evidence, (PX)—the market in which wholesale power
however, makes clear that there are substan- was to be traded—and the Independent System
tial economic advantages associated with ver- Operators to facilitate the new regulatory
tical integration. regime. The newly created electricity market
The case for deintegration and restructur- opened for business on April 1, 1998.53
ing has implicitly been founded on a belief Perhaps the most frequently expressed
that the savings and other benefits obtain- opinion on vertical integration before the
able from markets exceed those that are asso- CPUC was that it was undesirable in a regu-
ciated with vertical integration. It is quite lated world. In a deregulated system, vertical
possible that utilities invest or operate ineffi- integration was thought to facilitate the exer-
ciently. Rate of return regulation may induce cise of market power by utilities. Testifying
them to overcapitalize or to extend them- for municipal utilities, economics professor
selves excessively into unregulated business- William Shepherd either rejected or was
es. As regulated monopolies, they may feel unaware of the research discussed in the pre-
less pressure to cut costs than do firms in vious section of this paper. He claimed that,
competitive markets. in order to achieve economies of scale and
If rate of return regulation is retained dur- scope, “[t]here may need to be separation of
ing the process of vertical deintegration, the core functions into distinct entities.”54
however, deintegration by itself is unlikely to Shepherd provided no evidence, however,
produce more efficient operation or invest- that integrated utilities failed to exhibit
ment. Performance-based or price cap regula- economies of scale and scope. Others pro-
tions are less drastic alternatives to deinte- posed radical restructurings along the same
gration and have shown some success in lines, not necessarily restricted to California.
If markets for practice. Moreover, the latter reforms are eas- They included energy law professor Richard
ily reversible—deintegration is much more Pierce, who failed to mention any possible
generation are difficult to reverse. costs of deintegration in a scheme to separate
superior to If markets for generation are superior to generation from transmission and transmis-
vertically vertically integrated operations, can their ben- sion from distribution.55 The trade press was
efits be obtained by policies that also maintain full of similar arguments.56
integrated the benefits of integration? Such questions The two founders of independent power
operations, can have gone largely unasked as the U.S. industry producer AES attempted to make the quanti-
their benefits be restructures. tative case for vertical deintegration by citing
the postprivatization drop in UK generation
obtained by costs, but they failed to identify the key factor
policies that also Deintegration in California in that drop: lower fuel prices.57 They also
described but failed to cite an “analysis [that]
maintain the The campaign for vertical deintegration suggests divestiture of generation will lower
benefits of went into high gear on April 20, 1994, when overall costs per kWh by 15 percent” and an
integration? the California Public Utilities Commission unpublished consultants’ report that the sav-
instituted a rulemaking on electricity.51 Its rad- ing would be from 20 to 40 percent.58 Perhaps
Such questions ical proposal to allow consumers “direct the most surprising views were those of econ-
have gone largely access” to suppliers of their choice generated omist Irwin Stelzer, the retired founder of a
volumes of testimony from interest groups, consulting firm whose clients include many
unasked as the most of which is no longer available on the integrated utilities. He asserted that competi-
U.S. industry Internet.52 The CPUC held hearings in 1994 tion was impossible as long as utilities were
restructures. and early 1995 and issued its initial order in vertically integrated and proposed that utili-

10
ties deintegrate as a precondition for stranded utility structure is “rooted in the past and Only two
cost recovery.59 None of those people even incompatible with emerging markets.”65 The analyses by
brought up the possibility that integration decision cited no testimony or other evidence
could also be beneficial. regarding the benefits of vertical integration or economists prior
A few experts were a bit less hostile to verti- the possible costs of a breakup. to the opening
cal integration. Two economists from the Uni- The utilities accepted the decision primari-
versity of California Energy Institute wrote: ly because it would guarantee revenue to
of California’s
recover the costs associated with the construc- markets brought
If the vertically integrated utilities tion of power plants that had yet to be recov- up any of the
remain largely intact . . . their coordi- ered through the rate base (so-called stranded
nation abilities could enhance reliabili- costs) and allow the utilities to maintain some econometric
ty and reduce transaction costs. competitive advantages even after direct access studies of
However, the utilities would also have a began.66 The 1996 legislation authorizing the integration.
correspondingly large capacity for the PX, ISO, rate freeze, and stranded cost recov-
exercise of [horizontal] market power. ery imposed the same divestiture require-
If the utilities are dismantled along the ments, again with no discussion of the costs
lines of the UK model, then new mech- and benefits of integration.67
anisms for coordination would have to California then applied to FERC for
be developed.60 approval of its market-based PX and ISO-
managed transmission system. Testimony
MIT engineering professor Marja Ilic and before FERC’s market-based rate proceedings
her associates described the requirements for emphasized the ability of vertically integrated
operating methods and software that had yet utilities to leverage market power from trans-
to be developed if an ISO in a vertically dein- mission to generation and distribution. The
tegrated system was to operate a well-func- standards for market-based rates require an
tioning set of wholesale and direct access applicant to delineate geographic markets for
markets for both energy and ancillary ser- short-term energy and capacity, and possibly
vices.61 And only two analyses by economists other commodities. The applicant must then
prior to the opening of California’s markets show that it (in this case, California’s three
brought up any of the econometric studies of large corporate utilities as a group) controls a
integration discussed above.62 Both of them small enough part of the market and that its
provided cautionary discussions on the value power over price is minimal. The utilities,
of integration, and one noted that prior to however, were unable to meet FERC’s stan-
deintegration its advocates should show that dards. Intervenors (protesting parties) com-
“cost savings exceed foregone economies.”63 pounded the problem with testimony claim-
After more than a year of hearings and nego- ing that the utilities’ horizontal dominance of
tiations, the CPUC issued its initial decision in generation left them ideally suited to use their
December 1995. The wholesale power market transmission to exercise vertical market power,
and retail access aspects of that decision would and that even independent operation of the
be altered before markets opened, but its gener- transmission system (the ISO) might not suf-
ation divestiture provisions would remain. fice to neutralize it, at least prior to actual
They required that the state’s two largest cor- divestiture of the generating plants. The utili-
porate utilities divest themselves of 50 percent ties responded by proposing additional mar-
of their fossil fuel generating capacity located in ket power mitigation measures, including an
California.64 A commission majority justified independent monitor and special contracts
this radical step by stating (without evidence) for the pricing of generation required to oper-
that “the vertically integrated electric utility is ate for reliability.68 The utilities were the only
not compatible with the institutions of a com- parties one would expect to defend vertical
petitive market for electric services” and that integration, and in more normal circum-

11
stances they might have done so. Here, howev- bankrupt and its utilities in disastrous shape.
er, stranded costs were their prime concern Only after their deintegration did econo-
and they would reluctantly accept vertical mists begin rethinking the relationship
deintegration as the price for recovering them. between vertical integration and market
Thus the record at FERC is essentially devoid power. This time their conclusions were quite
of any discussion of vertical integration different.
beyond conjectures about market power. New models showed that integration
In sum, prior to the opening of California’s could actually constrain rather than enhance
markets, most interested parties viewed verti- a generation owner’s market power. A gener-
cal integration as a tool for the exercise of mar- ator required to serve final demand has little
ket power by utilities. The utilities also enjoyed reason to cut the output of plants that it
horizontal market power as owners of most owns unless it can obtain power more cheap-
existing generation. Regulators and others ly from a market.74 Forward contracts that
believed that the combination of divestiture commit generators and users to fixed deliv-
and an ISO might suffice to mitigate both ery prices likewise diminish the incentive for
types of market power; particularly during the a generator to exercise market power with its
limited time California gave its utilities to uncommitted plants.75 Vertical deintegration
Prior to the recover most of their stranded costs.69 was not solely responsible for California’s
opening of The CPUC required the two largest utili- problems, but a consensus arose that it facil-
California’s ties to divest half of their in-state gas-fired itated the exercise of market power by owners
plants, but ultimately they chose to divest all of the divested plants in ways that would not
markets, most of them to six different independent power have happened if the utilities had remained
interested parties producers and marketers.70 By FERC’s stan- vertically integrated.76 As this was happening,
dards for horizontal market power, the area the utilities began their long journey back to
viewed vertical was now sufficiently competitive that the financial health and found themselves with
integration prices arising at the PX and ISO would not be an opportunity to vertically reintegrate.
as a tool for subject to further regulation.71 Between 1998 and 2003 a binge of mer-
The reforms initiated by the CPUC set the chant power-plant construction had left
the exercise of stage for the crisis that was to follow. During many nonutility generators either bankrupt
market power the two years of the operation of the new or in poor financial health. The markets they
by utilities. California market, prices hovered near mar- had expected to materialize as states restruc-
ginal cost. By the spring of 2000, however, they tured had largely failed to appear. Over those
had begun their rise to crisis levels. Numerous years, total U.S. generation increased from
factors contributed to the problem and are roughly 800 GW to 1,000 GW; 150 GW of
still the subject of litigation and academic that increase had been built by Independent
debate.72 One possible factor that simple mea- Power Producers.77
sures of seller concentration could not predict Over only 10 years, the ownership struc-
was market power exercised by the owners of ture of generation had changed dramatically.
divested generation. If generation is near its In the mid-1990s approximately 90 percent of
limits, transmission is scarce, and demand is generating capacity was owned by utilities.
highly inelastic, a single generator might move Today, new plants and divestitures have left
the market price with a small change in out- only 55 percent of the national total under
put, and others would have reason to bid cost-based regulation. Approximately 60 per-
above their marginal costs as well.73 cent of the remainder is owned by unregulat-
ed affiliates of utilities. Overoptimism from
Vertical Integration after the California all parties allowed IPPs (usually under project
Collapse finance) to be funded largely by debt. By 2004,
Three years after California’s markets 90 GW of them had been turned back to
began operating, its Power Exchange was lenders, 23 GW had been bought by private

12
investors, and 10 GW had been purchased or ments occurring in those generators that were
repurchased by regulated utilities.78 Those divested to utility affiliates.82
changes may be evidence that vertical integra- It may be possible to perform studies com-
tion is returning to the industry. paring utilities before and after they became
As the finances of the IPP sector deterio- members of RTOs. The only available related
rate, the distressed assets have often been study is by economists Magali Delmas and
priced so attractively that purchase by utili- Yesim Tokat, who found that deregulation of
ties or their affiliates is clearly efficient. retail access has a generally negative effect on
According to some observers, however, these utilities’ productive efficiency.83 Consistent
purchases raise antitrust concerns because with the predictions of organization theory,
they needlessly reconcentrate suppliers in they found that vertically integrated utilities
regional energy markets.79 that supply the full requirements of their retail
Vertical integration is also being pursued customers experience smaller efficiency losses
more directly. Two of California’s three large from the opening of retail markets, and so do
utilities are building new generation and the those that purchase their entire power sup-
third is applying to the CPUC for permission plies on wholesale markets. Utilities that must
to do the same. Under new state laws, mix market purchases with internal produc-
California intends to reregulate and reverti- tion suffer efficiency losses greater than those
calize utilities in hopes of avoiding a repeti- at the extremes.
tion of the 2000–01 crisis.80 Utilities must California’s performance has brought a
now file short-term and long-term resource general agreement on the value of requiring
plans with state regulators, who approve transitional contracts between utilities and
individual investments, set reserve require- the owners of divested generation.84 A transi-
ments, and impose “renewable” resource tion from integration to unbundling gives rise
quotas on them. California utilities are also to new price risks for both generators and
attempting to slow the growth of distributed retailers because generators sell at the whole-
generation (very small facilities on end-user sale price while retail rates are usually fixed. In
sites). They claim that restriction of its scope an integrated utility, these cancel out, but a
is necessary for reliability, while others claim deintegrated system will probably require con-
that the utilities are trying to eliminate com- tracts to allocate the obligations and risks.85
petitors.81 Such contracts may be difficult to formulate
because independent plants can obtain capital
Lessons Learned about Vertical more cheaply if their contracts contain com-
Integration mitments for both prices and outputs, while There has been
There has been little pressure for reintegra- utilities prefer discretion about their econom- little pressure for
tion by either utilities or the public in those ic dispatchability under changing fuel prices
states where deintegration has been accompa- and system conditions. Utility CEO John reintegration by
nied by relatively successful market outcomes Rowe and his coauthors believe that a major either utilities
(e.g., Texas, Massachusetts, and New York). difference between California and Rowe’s util-
These market outcomes may reflect no more ities in Philadelphia and Chicago was that reg-
or the public in
than temporarily advantageous supply and ulators in his states allowed divestitures to be those states
demand situations, as California’s did during determined by the utilities themselves, and where deintegra-
its first two years. In particular, there are no they also allowed contracts and hedging.86
available research findings about the effects of Rowe also discusses the value of a properly tion has been
either deintegration or RTO membership on planned transition. In Pennsylvania, the time accompanied
the operating efficiency of utilities. One recent paths of stranded cost recovery were deter- by relatively
study has shown that fuel efficiency has mined in settlements with individual utilities
increased for both divested generators and and surcharges to their rates were set in successful market
utility-owned units, with the largest improve- advance. Only one of Pennsylvania’s utilities outcomes.

13
Some chose to divest.87 Instead of a discontinuous but contracts and uses the spot market to
retrospective institutional break like California’s, the provide for any excess load or to dispose of
regional transmission organization known as excess contracted power.91 California’s utili-
studies have the PJM (so called because it is an intercon- ties are in transition toward an intermediate
asked why nected system incorporating utility service in mix between the two, but one that will be
Pennsylvania, New Jersey, and Maryland, heavily weighted in favor of utility-owned
restructuring although it also manages utility service in assets and longer-term contracts. Utilities
attracted so much parts of Delaware, Illinois, Indiana, Kentucky, will have a continuing interest in well-func-
support, given its Michigan, North Carolina, Ohio, Tennessee, tioning bulk power markets, although the
Virginia, West Virginia, and the District of degree of interest may depend on whether
goal of moving a Columbia) imposed wholesale markets on a existing customers can also depart and use
vital industry into “tight” centrally dispatched regional power those markets.
largely unknown pool that had operating and settlement mech-
anisms in place. As a further safeguard, gener- Summary
territory. ators were required to submit only cost-based Some retrospective studies have asked why
bids during the first year after PJM’s markets restructuring attracted so much support,
opened. New York, however, offers a potential given its goal of moving a vital industry into
counterexample to Pennsylvania. Its regula- largely unknown territory. A slower opening
tors increased utilities’ uncertainty by requir- of markets to direct access by large customers
ing divestitures prior to formulating any would certainly have been feasible. As the dif-
stranded cost policy. They did, however, allow ficulties of administering the limited market
(but not require) contracts between utilities were resolved, transactions could have been
and owners of the divested plants.88 Most of opened to smaller customers. The market’s
those contracts will expire in the near future. scope would have been market determined
Partial vertical integration may be a sound rather than regulator imposed.92 A few econo-
strategy for utilities that expect to serve sub- mists even question whether markets should
stantial amounts of load that have chosen not have been opened at all. Richard Rosen has
to leave regulated service.89 In the future, many attempted to make a qualitative showing that
utilities will have some customers who obtain the cost of creating and using markets in a
their own power supplies and others who are deintegrated system is probably not worth the
either “captives” legally prohibited from using economies of integration that were sacri-
the market or who choose not to do so. ficed.93 Rosen believes that many industry
Economist Jamie Read observes that their analysts were blinded to the costs of massive
“provider of last resort” functions are no restructuring by a long-standing and some-
longer expected to be transitional, and verti- times justifiable dissatisfaction with the per-
cally deintegrated utilities must design effi- formance of regulation.94 Other economists
cient procurement plans for their core cus- argue that restructuring has been a success in
tomers.90 Utilities that have sold their power most states and nations that have carried it
plants and lost their safe monopolies will have out. Lynne Kiesling believes that deintegration
lower-quality credit, which will affect their itself can and should be market driven:
decisions to build generation or buy energy.
Read sees reverticalization by asset ownership The encouragement of restructuring of
at one extreme, providing the hedge that only utilities created substantial flexibility
physical assets can provide but also inviting in Pennsylvania’s electricity market.
regulatory scrutiny about prudence. That Divestiture is likely to occur to some
scrutiny will be more likely if the load served extent as a part of restructuring, when
by these assets chooses to depart. utilities refine their “core competen-
An alternative to reintegration is a portfo- cies.” Allowing retention of at least
lio model in which the utility holds nothing some generation capacity enables com-

14
panies and consumers to reap the ben- years demand would not catch up with the
efits of vertical integration where they state’s largely unchanged generation capaci-
exist.95 ty. At the peak of the crisis, the state govern-
ment signed long-term contracts for nearly
The California restructuring process could all of the power that its insolvent unities
have been a forum for reasoned discussion on could not generate from resources that they
the future of vertically integrated utilities. The still owned. A few weeks after the signing,
old view held that integration was an obstacle supply and demand conditions changed and
to competition and the coming of energy mar- energy prices fell below those in the con-
kets would allow regulators to specialize in tracts, but by then California’s utilities were
what they allegedly did well—controlling nat- in effect reintegrated.
ural monopolies. The market could be left to Over three years, California regulators were
do what regulators probably did poorly— given two lessons on the hazards of thought-
applying competitive pressure to produce and less decisions about integration: a quick
invest efficiently. divestiture aggravated the effects of depen-
The newer view holds that the continued dence on highly volatile energy markets, and a
existence of vertical integration is evidence of panic-driven reintegration through state con-
its efficiency. The fact that generation was tracts brought very high but stable prices.
The regulatory
technologically separable from other aspects Those lessons about integration went either restructuring
of power delivery did not imply that separa- unlearned or misinterpreted, and new laws undertaken in
tion was economically desirable. continue to expand the scope of state activity
Economists had a great deal to say about in utility planning. the electricity
the efficient design of energy markets during sector has been
the restructuring, but the design of utility orga-
nizations has been primarily a political ques- Transmission Operations in more ambitious
tion. In California the utilities’ prime interests a Restructured Industry than the
lay in recovering stranded costs and position- regulatory
ing themselves for post-transition competi- The regulatory restructuring undertaken
tion. After they made the bargains that in the electricity sector has been more ambi- restructurings
brought the PX, ISO, and divestiture, there tious than the regulatory restructurings undertaken in
were no parties interested in undoing the polit- undertaken in other industrial sectors. That’s other industrial
ical compromise by attempting to make the because, in the case of electricity, both market
case that some degree of continuing vertical institutions and governance institutions have sectors.
integration might in reality be efficient. been subject to politically induced change.96
During the 2000–01 crisis, energy prices The previous section described the changes
in the California spot markets tracked short- in industrial organization in California. This
term energy prices at other locations in the section describes changes in the transmission
West quite closely. The major difference was system’s governance institutions. Robust
that California’s utilities had a far greater wholesale markets require that buyers and
exposure to this market than utilities that sellers have access to a wide region, but access
remained integrated, and the CPUC did not had historically been obstructed by both utili-
allow them to use other risk management ties and regulators. Utilities preferred monop-
tools. Utilities elsewhere in the West would olies in their service territories and external
appear in the short-term markets as either transactions only with other utilities, and
buyers or sellers depending on the day’s oper- prior to 1992 FERC had no powers to order
ating conditions, but California’s utilities them to transmit for eligible third parties.
would always be massive buyers. Regulated transmission rates also stood in
The state’s disastrous transition was a the way. When two transmission-owning utili-
failed gamble by utilities that for the next five ties traded power, a fictitious “contract path”

15
between them would determine the allocation December 1995 decision on restructuring.100
of transmission charges. In reality, the power Virtually all interested parties, including
flowed everywhere in the region, but as long as competitive producers and traders, agreed
transactions were few and excess transmission with its plans for an ISO. They believed that
capacity was common, they could neglect the if the utilities continued to operate transmis-
consequences of power flows along the grid. sion they would schedule the flow of electric-
Regulators set transmission charges on an ity on the grid in order to advantage them-
average cost basis, and principles of nondis- selves against competitors. The ISO, on the
crimination treated utilities on the contract other hand, would take no market positions
path symmetrically. If utility A sent power to and have no interests in load or generation. A
utility C on a contract path that went through separate institution, the Power Exchange,
B, C would be expected to pay both A’s and B’s would administer the energy markets, and
filed transmission charges. From a regional bilateral transactions outside the PX were
standpoint, this was only a slight alteration in possible for all parties other than the utilities.
power flows, but under contract path ratemak- The ISO would integrate PX and bilateral
ing the cost of transmission over multiple sys- transactions and administer a zonal pricing
tems was a barrier to the growth of markets. system for transmission. The decision took
In late 1995 FERC began to study open no position on whether it should be a regu-
access transmission policy. FERC embodied its lated corporation, a nonprofit, or a govern-
findings in Order 888 of 1996.97 It expressed mental operation.101
the commission’s preference for ISOs that met After having helped to create the design of
certain standards of independence but did not the PX and ISO, in mid-1996 California’s
compel their formation. FERC would consider utilities applied to FERC for market-based
proposals for both nonprofit and for-profit rates and argued that those markets were suf-
ISOs, but stated that the latter could not be ficiently competitive that their prices would
closely affiliated with generation. FERC then satisfy its “just and reasonable” legal stan-
held technical conferences at which corporate dard. The PX and ISO would both be non-
utilities envisioned ISOs as regulated corpora- profit institutions, governed by boards of
tions while public entities preferred that they interest group representatives.102
take the form of nonprofit entities. Economists on all sides had much to say
Economists were quick to weigh in. MIT about California’s market designs and trans-
economist Paul Joskow envisioned a nonprof- mission pricing, but none questioned the insti-
it joint venture whose board of directors tutional structures being proposed.103 Only
would contain representatives of utilities, one economist, Dennis Carlton of the
Economists nonutility generators, regulators, and “others University of Chicago, testified as to the gover-
representing the public interest.”98 The appro- nance rules and independence of ISOs. The
on all sides had priate functions of an ISO were also debated, Sacramento Municipal Utility District retained
much to say with Harvard’s William Hogan favoring loca- Carlton to argue that transmission-owning
about California’s tional marginal pricing of transmission and utilities would dominate the ISO (their per-
full integration with a PX. Some attendees, sonnel were in some cases the only ones knowl-
market designs however, were concerned that they were plan- edgeable enough to operate it) and that they
and transmission ning the details of an institution that had would use that knowledge to advantage their
pricing, but none never before existed, and that once such an own generation. Acting as planners at the ISO,
institution was in place it could not adjust to the utilities would not want to build transmis-
questioned the changes in technology and markets.99 sion that would decrease the value of their gen-
institutional erators, many of which were “must-run” units
Transmission in California whose operation was at times required for reli-
structures being At the same time that FERC was formu- ability. Carlton also questioned the voting rule
proposed. lating Order 888, the CPUC released its that required a two-thirds majority, since it

16
would allow utilities to form coalitions with most of its results. Approximately 85 percent Two years after
allies to veto proposals beneficial to a majority of the alleged benefits came from its assump- the formation
of the board.104 Municipal utilities including tions about the increased efficiency of new
Sacramento’s also protested that in the “col- generation. Some of the remainder was due to of ISOs in
laborative” process to form the ISO and PX, assumptions that reserve margins could California and
the only parties allowed to vote were the three decline from 15 to 13 percent and that trans-
corporate utilities.105 mission transfer capability would increase by 5
the Northeast,
Shortly after the ISO began operation, the percent per year at no cost.110 only one other
president of the CPUC told a trade journal One of the most important flaws in this ISO had opened,
that the CPUC actually believed that trans- and most later studies was the lack of any
mission divestiture and the formation of a description of the trading institutions that in Texas.
single transmission-only corporation would were being assumed and how those trading
have been a superior alternative to ISOs. institutions might affect the calculation. The
“Political reality,” however, stood in the way benefit estimate in the FERC study, for
because a divestiture would have been legally instance, was the solution of a linear pro-
difficult and would have required three to gramming problem, derived from a model of
five years and extensive financing.106 This least-cost dispatch rather than a model of the
episode further points up the difficulty of operating practices that might occur in actu-
designing rational economic institutions in a al markets. Moreover, the study’s authors
political setting. At the time, there were no determined that the cost of forming RTOs
prospective transmission-only firms in exis- would be between $1 billion and $5.75 bil-
tence to offer expert testimony favoring such lion.111 If 85 percent of their projected bene-
a structure.107 Ten years later, a few transmis- fits are in fact due to improved generator effi-
sion-only companies exist, but they operate ciency, this implies that RTOs may not be
under ISOs whose governance is heavily worth forming. In practice, those costs have
influenced by the remaining integrated utili- proven quite high and have been increasing
ties.108 over time. Between 2000 and 2003, the opera-
tion and maintenance costs of RTOs and
Cost/Benefit Studies and Order 2000 ISOs in California rose by approximately 35
Two years after the formation of ISOs in percent; in New York they rose by 100 percent;
California and the Northeast, only one other and in the PJM they rose by 250 percent. The
ISO had opened, in Texas. FERC’s interest in corresponding figures per megawatt-hour of
regional coordination remained strong, but electricity were 23 percent, 73 percent, and
its legal ability to compel membership in 181 percent. All of those ISOs had initiated
RTOs is still in doubt. their basic market operations before or dur-
On December 17, 1999, the commission ing 2000.112 Their setup costs ranged from
issued Order 2000, which offered additional $250 million to $500 million.113
inducements to join RTOs. Still faced with A substantial number of other studies have
resistance, FERC next proposed a set of used methods similar to FERC’s. In 1996 a
regional RTOs, and in 2001 it commissioned a group of pro-market organizations examined
cost/benefit study of ISOs and the markets a least-cost dispatch model for wholesale
that would result. The study estimated that power markets and estimated a saving of up to
the RTO markets would create benefits in the 40 percent.114 The U.S. Energy Information
form of lowered production costs with a pres- Administration estimated savings of 8 to 15
ent value of $40.9 billion between 2002 and percent from competitive markets, again on
2021, approximately a 2 percent annual saving the basis of dispatch algorithms.115 A number
over their base case.109 Critics quickly deter- of others exist, most of little individual inter-
mined that the model’s assumptions about est.116 Their complex modeling techniques
technology, as opposed to markets, drove and large data requirements make it extreme-

17
ly difficult to pinpoint the reasons for their transmission firms is based on several appli-
differing results.117 cations of principal/agent theory and the
Even if we accept the calculations as accu- economic theory of voting.
rate, many of their treatments of economic Economists and political scientists have
efficiency are theoretically questionable. extensively analyzed rules for collective
Often they identify increased efficiency with choice.121 Their work has shown the innate
decreased customer bills, but some (possibly imperfections of nearly all voting systems in
much) of that decrease must be netted aggregating individual preferences and the
against the loss of wealth by generators, general impossibility of controlling strategic
whose incomes will be lower. The only study voting. That work, however, has also shown
that adequately accounts for the transfer is that some decisionmaking mechanisms are
economist Ellen Wolfe’s work on the pro- superior to others in important ways, such as
posed RTO West. She estimates a 2004 the ability of the person who sets the agenda
reduction in marginal costs of $1.3 billion, to influence results by choosing a sequence
from which lowered generation revenues of of votes.
$900 million must be subtracted. The report The quality of the decisions that an ISO’s
is also noteworthy because unlike others it governing board makes will be critical to the
The quality of the analyzes the situation with and without a success of the markets it operates, but no
decisions that an specific institutional innovation—the RTO’s experts on voting or committee structures
ISO’s governing proposed locational pricing system for trans- provided input during proceedings on ISO
mission.118 designs. The literature, however, suggests
board makes will that the constellation of interest groups on
be critical to Profits, Voting, and Monitors an ISO board may render it relatively vulner-
FERC Orders 888 and 2000 state that able to manipulation by strategic voting.122
the success of FERC will consider applications by both “Nonprofit” ISOs may show no profit in
the markets it nonprofit and profit-seeking ISOs or RTOs. their books, but the votes of their governors
operates, but no The original ISO proposals (made at a FERC affect the wealth of the interests they repre-
technical conference) by economists William sent. Some of California’s difficulties in
experts on voting Hogan and Paul Joskow envisioned a non- 2000–01 stemmed from the growing inabili-
or committee profit organization with representative gov- ty of its ISO’s governors to reach decisions,
structures provid- ernment. They said little about the difficul- which ultimately led FERC to order a recon-
ties in governance such an organization stitution of the board, which has since been
ed input during might actually encounter (and which ruled an impermissible extension of the com-
proceedings on California’s ISO did see during the 2000–01 mission’s authority.123
crisis). Neither they nor FERC gave notice- Economists with an understanding of
ISO designs. able weight to economists’ findings of more corporate organization and collective choice
efficient operations by profit-seeking firms could have usefully contributed to the RTO
in other industries that contained a mix of debate in a third area. Order 2000 requires
them and nonprofit organizations (e.g., hos- that all RTO applicants include a description
pitals).119 On the other side, supporters of of their proposed market monitoring institu-
nonprofit organizations largely disregard the tions (MMIs). These institutions use market
efficiency findings and conclude that an data to detect activities believed to be exercis-
investor-owned transmission company with es of market power, have further powers of
even minimal interests in generation will act investigation, and are also charged with
monopolistically. This author’s work is the pointing out any flaws they might find in
only work to examine the nonprofit contro- market design. Existing MMIs have pro-
versy in the light of recent developments in duced numerous reports and testimonies of
organizational and financial economics.120 varying quality, a discussion of which is
My case for the efficiency of investor-owned beyond the scope of this paper.

18
MMIs are both political and economic design of ISOs and RTOs. That new learning
institutions. They were not suggested by has convinced much of the economics profes-
FERC or by consumer groups. Instead, they sion that the design of institutions is as
were originally proposed by the California important as the design of markets them-
utilities as amendments to their PX and ISO selves, and that economics offers insights that
applications after FERC ruled them ineligible could not have been obtained from any other
for market-based rates. In some cases MMIs discipline. It might have been quite useful at
are staffed by RTO employees and in others the outset for economists to simply remind
by appointed committees of external experts. FERC and others that rational persons in
Their functions are at least in part political. nonprofit organizations will seek to advan-
Economists often disagree over whether tage themselves just as they would in for-prof-
certain behavior is anti-competitive, but all it ones. Instead, much of U.S. electricity is
MMI reports on record have been unani- now governed by organizations for which
mous.124 California’s MMIs reported some there are no precedents in any industrial con-
seller scheduling practices as anti-competi- text as important as electricity. Where those
tive attempts to raise price by submitting organizations have been stressed, as in
bids that did not reflect their true demands. California, they have failed to produce coher-
They made no similar reports about attempts ent policy.
by utilities, however, to submit false sched-
ules whose effect would be to lower prices.125
In another vein, arbitrage between the day- Conclusion
ahead and real-time markets known as virtu-
al bidding (simultaneous buy and sell orders The analysis of vertical integration became
in the two markets) is a generally desirable an integral part of economic theory only quite
and efficient practice. PJM’s monitors were recently. As this happened, economists came Much of U.S.
not under pressure from utilities to keep to understand that vertical integration often
prices artificially low, and they encouraged had desirable effects on economic efficiency electricity is now
virtual bidding. California’s monitors were because it reduced the costs of coordinating governed by
under such pressure, understood that virtual economic activities relative to the alternatives
trading would interfere with attempts to of markets or contracts. Vertical integration
organizations for
manipulate prices downward, and made the became a common organizational form in which there are
practice illegal. Economists have yet to per- electricity because of technological require- no precedents in
form an impartial study of the costs and ben- ments that supply equal demand at all times
efits of alternative methods of monitoring everywhere on a network. In addition, the any industrial
the competitive behavior of markets. Had industry’s specialized plants were less vulner- context as
they done so, market monitoring might be able to opportunistic conduct if they were
less politicized than it is today. owned by the same organization rather than
important as
under contract. electricity.
Summary The old economic view saw vertical inte- Where those
Economists have provided significant gration as a tool that a monopolist could use
input on the details of RTO market design, to extract profit from competitive activities. organizations
and their contributions have undoubtedly Modern theorists discredited that argument have been
improved market performance.126 Whether by in unregulated situations, but it might still stressed, as in
accident or intent, their contributions to the apply to regulated ones. In the 1970s and
design of RTOs and their governance were 1980s lawyers and economists created a liter- California, they
minimal. Over the past 40 years there have ature that made the case for vertical deinte- have failed to
been significant advances in the analysis of gration of utilities by simply assuming that
organizations, transaction costs, and collec- integration served no useful function. If true,
produce coherent
tive choice that were directly applicable to the the separation of generation from transmis- policy.

19
Politics saw to it sion could bring the benefits of competition the economic incentives of the institution’s
that the most at no cost in efficiency. Econometric research managers and clients.
proved that this was not so. Studies in the Some economic experts displayed the
important thing 1980s and 1990s almost invariably conclud- same naiveté as noneconomists in their
for the market to ed that vertical integration produced effi- expectation that nonprofit organizations
ciencies that would be lost in a breakup. would operate benignly and efficiently. There
decide would be These economies of integration applied to was never a real debate over whether RTOs
off limits—what both the generation-transmission interface should be for-profit or nonprofit, in large
the market itself and to the ownership of generators and fuel part because the nonprofit ISO was a politi-
supplies. cally expedient compromise rather than a
would actually This scholarship was almost totally for- thoughtfully planned institution. As econo-
look like. gotten as California and other states began to mists would have predicted, ISOs governed
restructure their power industries in the mid- by representatives of interest groups have at
1990s. A few economists argued that there times had difficulty reaching coherent deci-
were both costs and benefits to vertical inte- sions and have instituted highly imperfect
gration and a rule of reason was needed. and politicized monitoring procedures.
Many others simply chose to assert that inte- If economists and others had better
gration was worse than useless. If not con- understood the significance of vertical inte-
strained, transmission monopolists integrat- gration in the industry, restructuring would
ed into power production could destroy the have produced better policies and better
benefits of competitive generation. The ISO institutions. Contracts and vertical integra-
came into being as a midway point between tion are substitutes, but California left its
full integration and full deintegration. utilities to divest their plants and rely on
In California ISOs were supplemented by short-term markets without any hedging
divestiture. Generators that would often set possibilities. Markets have virtues, but the
market prices at the PX and ISO were sold off question of whether or not to rely on them is
without contracts that would have given the really a question about the costs and benefits
utilities security of supply and prices. Two of vertical integration. Economists have a
years after California’s markets began opera- great deal of useful knowledge in this area,
tion, the growing imbalance of supply and but they have played at best a peripheral role
demand combined with a constellation of in the design of the institutions that will
other forces to bring about a pricing crisis. In determine the industry’s future.
its aftermath, utilities and regulators are Ultimately, the question of how best to
investigating the possibilities for reverticaliz- organize the electricity industry is a question
ing utilities, possibly with a separation of that should be answered through trial and
core and noncore customers. error by market actors, rather than be decid-
The ISO and RTO were envisioned as ed by politics. Unfortunately, while longer-
institutions that could operate and price term power contract markets arose almost
regional power flows efficiently. They were spontaneously during the 1970s and 1980s,
also charged with administering markets for short-term electricity markets that balance
portions of that power. A series of question- hourly supply and demand require some
able quantitative studies estimated that large planning and design prior to the start of
benefits would be forthcoming, but the stud- operations, which renders some governmen-
ies were calculations of optimum dispatch tal role unavoidable. Decades of scholarship
rather than projections of the behavior of on vertical integration were largely ignored in
markets. Numerous interested parties were the restructuring and market design process,
concerned about discrimination by transmis- and both producers and consumers will pay
sion owners, but the ISO concept was formu- for that neglect for some time to come. As
lated without an adequate appreciation of states and regions reorganized their institu-

20
tions, almost every interested party went on saw to it that the most important thing for
record as favoring one or another type of the market to decide would be off limits—
market, and regulators often heard that they what the market itself would actually look
should “let the market decide.” But politics like.

Appendix: Summary of Vertical Integration Studies


Author Sample and
(date) Data Year Method Findings Comments

Henderson 160 U.S. utilities, Marginal cost of steam, hydro, and Estimate of model that Only addresses effect
(1985)127 most vertically purchased power is used as energy excludes produced power of generation costs on
integrated, 1970 transfer price in estimate of trans- yields, downwardly biased transmission/
log cost function that includes labor, estimate of scale distribution
capital, and energy; tests coefficients economies; concludes and not reverse
for separability costs are not separable
due to vertical economies
Roberts 65 U.S. electric- Estimates translog cost function for Coefficient restrictions implied Article primarily about
(1986)128 only utilities, no distribution to examine effects of by separability of distribution effects of territorial size
holding company territory size and density, tests for and generation/transmission and customer density
units, 1978 separability of distribution from costs are rejected (author on distribution cost;
generation and transmission notes this in passing since does not contain infor-
study was intended to esti- mation for numerical
mate effects of service area estimate of integration
density) effect
Eftekhari 61 U.S. non- Estimates multioutput translog cost Finds very few economies of Variables said to measure
(1989)129 nuclear utilities, function with labor, capital, fuel scale but substantial output include number
1986 inputs diseconomies of joint pro- of ultimate customers,
duction; concludes that fraction of generated
smaller, vertically deintegrated power they buy, and
utilities would be more efficient statistically unreliable
measure of interchange
Kaserman & 74 U.S. electric- Estimates quadratic multiproduct cost Finds 12 % cost savings from Estimates of scope
Mayo only utilities, function that allows tests of vertical integration for average- economies require use
(1991)130 vertically economies of scope between sized utilities; extremely small of a sample containing
integrated, 1981 generation and transmission/ utilities are the only ones not to distribution-only
distribution benefit from it. utilities
Gilsdorf 72 U.S. vertically Estimates translog cost function for Performs Evans-Heckman Author notes that failure
(1995)131 integrated utilities, generation and transmission/ subadditivity test for those to pass subadditivity test
1985 distribution [combined], with fuel, utilities whose location on need not support a
capital, and labor costs, also customer estimated function has normal divestiture policy, since
density, capacity utilization, and percent economic properties [20 were there may be economies
of sales to ultimate customers excluded]; fails to reject null of scope between stages
hypothesis of additivity for any without subadditivity
utilities; also finds stage-specific
economies of scale

Continued on next page

21
Summary of Vertical Integration Studies (Continued)

Author Sample and


(date) Data Year Method Findings Comments

Lee (1995)132 70 U.S. “electric Estimates translog production functions Tests for complete separability of Also estimates efficiency
utility firms,” for generation, transmission, generation, transmission, and losses from various
1990 distribution; also estimates final output distribution, and for separability forms of deintegration
as function of all variables of generation and distribution between 4.1 and 18.6
alone; all null hypotheses of no percent
separability rejected
Hayashi 50 U.S. electric Estimates translog cost functions for Rejects null hypothesis of cost Estimates economies of
et al. utilities, annual generation and transmission/ separability; also finds that both vertical integration for
(1997)133 data 1983–1987 distribution, and for total large and small firms operate in firms ranging from 9.2
range of scale economies in percent to 24.2 percent
generation
Thompson 83–85 U.S. “all Estimates translog cost function with Rejects separability of either Finds that in later years
(1997)134 major investor- input prices and number of distribution or power supply the difference between
owned utilities” customers, territory size, and sales from remaining utility services unrestricted and restrict-
1977, 1982, 1987, at different voltages over entire time period ed estimates is smaller
1992 but remains significant
Goto & 9 Japanese vertically Estimates shadow cost and input Finds that generation enters Method also allows
Nemoto integrated electric demands from Symmetric Generalized transmission/distribution cost estimation of allocative
(1999)135 utilities, annual McFadden (SGM) function, inputs function positively in distortions in input mix;
data 1980–1997 include purchased power; tests for unintegrated case; concludes finds that average per-
effect of generation capital on trans- that unintegrated costs are centage that costs could
mission/distribution costs and esti- higher because of overinvest- be reduced over sample
mates allocative distortions ment in generation relative to period ranges from
integrated firms 0.13 % to 2.97 % for
individual utilities
Kwoka 147 U.S. corporate Estimates quadratic cost function in Negative interaction term Concludes that most
(2002)136 utilities, some generation and distribution to test between generation and utilities have chosen to
unintegrated, 1989 for economies of scope distribution cost is evidence operate where they can
of complementarity; comparison best realize these
with standalone costs indicates economies, with
that only very small utilities generation close to but
show diseconomies of vertical less than distribution
integration output
Nemoto 9 vertically Estimates SGM for variable and fixed Compares variable costs for Authors note questions
& Goto integrated Japanese costs on assumption that capital is integrated and standalone pro- about their additive
(2004)137 utilities, annual data incompletely adjusted to optimum duction of stages; finds average allocation of capital
1980–1999 economies of integration over between stages, state
period for individual companies need to verify that
range from 4.5 % to 13.9 % observed cost structures
are sufficient for natural
monopoly

22
Natural Monopolies—In General and with Respect
to CATV,” Bell Journal of Economics and Management
Notes Science 7, no. 1 (1976): 73–104.
1. The traditional topics of efficient input choice,
profitable output choice, and optimal competitive 10. In the United States, the lines on the two sides
strategy are now subsumed in a more general theory of the interface between a large transmission-
of economic organizations. A contemporary text- owning utility and a small municipal distribution
book that follows this approach is James A. Brickley, utility are separately owned. Power deliveries are
Clifford Smith Jr., and Jerold Zimmerman, Manage- usually under an all-requirements contract. If the
rial Economics and Organizational Architecture, 3d ed. municipal system owns generation elsewhere, the
(New York: McGraw-Hill Irwin, 2002). transmission operator integrates its output into
the regional system and accounts for it in the
2. Demand is managed centrally and automati- price of deliveries to the city. The contracts gov-
cally by relays that cut off (black out) customers erning this relationship limit the options of both
in defined geographic areas when imbalances parties with effects similar to those of vertical
between supply and demand occur that cannot be integration.
remedied from backup generation.
11. U.S. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
3. See, e.g., Leonard W. Weiss, “Antitrust in the (FERC), “Minutes of Technical Conference on
Electric Power Industry,” in Promoting Competition in Public Utilities’ Acquisition and Disposition of
Regulated Markets, ed. Almarin Phillips (Washington: Merchant Generating Assets,” Docket No. PL04-
Brookings Institution, 1975), pp. 138–73. 9-000, June 10, 2004, p. 5, available in eLibrary at
www.ferc.gov.
4. Regarding other nations, deintegration is some-
times posited as an explanation for the fall in power 12. LMP is a computer algorithm that assigns
costs after the formation of the United Kingdom’s prices to locations on the grid that correspond to
markets; see, for instance, Roger Sant and Roger differences in the marginal cost of producing
Naill, “Let’s Make Electricity Generation More power at those locations. If at point A the cost is 5
Competitive,” Electricity Journal 7 (October 1994): cents per kilowatt-hour and at B it is 11 cents,
49–72. Shortly after the UK market was organized, then the implied value of additional transmission
real fuel prices decreased by 20 percent (coal) and 45 capacity between them is 6 cents. If production
percent (gas) while labor productivity doubled. capacity were available and transmission were
Increases in productivity are more likely a conse- unconstrained, then B would get all of its power
quence of privatization than of deintegration. from the cheaper plant at A and save 6 cents on
David Newbery, “Privatisation and Liberalisation of every kWh delivered. The 6-cent difference in
Network Utilities, European Economic Review 41 their LMPs is the value per kWh of increasing the
(1997): 374. capacity of that link. There are financial instru-
ments known as firm transmission rights (FTR)
5. RTOs have superseded ISOs in FERC’s termi- or congestion revenue rights (CRR) that allow
nology. Although their legal definitions differ, the their holders to hedge against unpredictable
text uses them interchangeably. changes in LMP as system conditions change.

6. Oliver Williamson, “The Vertical Integration of 13. The key case is Brown Shoe Co. v. U.S., 310 U.S.
Production: Market Failure Considerations,” 294 (1962). There the Supreme Court held that a
American Economic Review 61 (May 1971): 112–23; shoe manufacturer’s attempt to purchase a chain
and Brickley, Smith, and Zimmerman, p. 531. of retail stores was an attempt to use its market
power in manufacturing to monopolize retailing.
7. Small on-site “distributed generation,” howev-
er, can be scheduled by its users under certain 14. Richard Posner, Antitrust Law: An Economic
conditions. Perspective (Chicago: University of Chicago Press,
1976), pp. 147–211.
8. John Landon, “Theories of Vertical Integration
and Their Application to the Electric Utility 15. 410 U.S. 366. It appears that the Court disre-
Industry,” Antitrust Bulletin 28 (Spring 1983): 101–30. garded numerous facts that might have led it to a
For application of transaction-cost economics to the different decision. See Andrew Kleit and Robert
restructuring of other energy industries (and also Michaels, “Antitrust, Regulation, and Rent-
electricity), see Samuel Van Vactor, Flipping the Switch: Seeking: The Past and Future of Otter Tail,” Antitrust
The Transformation of Energy Markets (Ph.D. Bulletin 39 (Fall 1994): 689–725.
Dissertation, University of Cambridge, 2004).
16. Edward Berlin, Charles Cicchetti, and William
9. Oliver E. Williamson, “Franchise Bidding for Gillen, “Restructuring the Electric Power Industry,”

23
in Electric Power Reform: The Alternatives for Michigan, ers are the operating units of holding companies
ed. William H. Shaker and Wilbert Steffy (Ann that control several utilities. There are a few unin-
Arbor: University of Michigan, Institute of Science tegrated utilities that generate only for wholesale
and Technology, 1976), pp. 231–35; Matthew sales or distribute only purchased power. Several
Cohen, “Efficiency and Competition in the Electric- of the researchers exclude the unintegrated sys-
Power Industry,” Yale Law Journal 88 (1979): tems from their data sets. Some of the samples
1511–49; Philip Fanara Jr., James Suelflow, and treat a holding company as a single observation,
Roman Draba, “Energy and Competition: The Saga while others include each of their operating com-
of Electric Power,” Antitrust Bulletin 25 (Spring panies. This paper does not discuss some other
1980): 125–42; John Landon and David Huettner, forms of integration examined by economists.
“Restructuring the Electric Utility Industry: A They include cost comparisons between utilities
Modest Proposal,” in Electric Power Reform: the that sell only electricity and those that sell elec-
Alternatives for Michigan, pp. 217–30; James Meeks, tricity and gas. See John Mayo, “Multiproduct
“Concentration in the Electric Power Industry: The Monopoly, Regulation and Firm Costs,” Southern
Impact of Antitrust Policy,” Columbia Law Review Economic Journal 51 (July 1984): 208–18; and
72, no. 1 (1972): 64–130; Richard Pierce, “A Raymond Hartman, “The Efficiency Effects of
Proposal to Deregulate the Market for Bulk Power,” Electric Utility Mergers: Lessons from Statistical
Virginia Law Review 72 (October 1986): 1183–1235; Cost Analysis,” Energy Law Journal 17, no. 2
and Weiss. (1996): 425–57. This paper also does not discuss
estimates of economies of scope due to serving
17. There are, however, opportunities for cities to several types of customer. See Douglas Gegax and
take advantage of certain legal provisions. Kenneth Nowotny, “Competition and the Electric
Municipal debt in the United States is largely tax- Utility Industry: An Evaluation,” Yale Journal on
exempt, and municipal utilities have priority over Regulation 10 (Winter 1993): 63–87.
corporate utilities in the allocation of inexpensive
power from federal dams. The latter fact motivat- 22. This is the case in the United States. The
ed the requests for transmission service from authors of the Japanese studies do not comment
Otter Tail. Municipal utilities do not pay taxes, on the consistency or accuracy of their data,
but most of them contribute fractions of their which may mean that they, too, have few such
gross revenue (usually 10 percent or less) to city problems.
budgets and provide local government with free
power. Partisans and opponents of public power 23. One remaining study is not directly compara-
differ over whether these contributions are larger ble to those on the Appendix. Economist Faye
or smaller than the taxes that a corporate utility Steiner uses 1986–96 annual data from 19 OECD
would pay. countries to examine the effects of restructurings.
She attempts to explain variation in capacity uti-
18. Economies of scale in coal-fired plants were lization, deviations of actual from optimal
near their highest point, nuclear facilities were (assumed 15 percent) reserve margins, prices to
still feasible, hydroelectric sites were becoming industrial users, and the ratio of industrial to res-
scarce, and natural gas was in shortage because of idential prices, using random effects regressions
price controls. The technologies and laws that that include measures of restructuring and priva-
allowed independent power production to thrive tization. Vertical deintegration is associated with
were not operative at the time of most of these significantly higher rates of generator capacity
writings. utilization and smaller deviations of actual from
ideal reserves, as is her measure of privatization.
19. Cohen, p. 1524. His footnoted references are She finds that prices to industrial users are not
to Meeks, who also provided no useful sources; significantly associated with vertical deintegra-
Weiss, who acknowledged that studies were need- tion, but the ratio of industrial to residential price
ed; and prepared testimony by an economist, who is significantly lower in nations that have unbun-
still testifies today on behalf of municipal utilities dled generation and transmission or that have a
at FERC. power pool. Results like these are almost surely
sensitive to regression specification, particularly
20. Meeks, p. 82. His evidence was to note the exis- with international data. Her only published
tence of power contracts between utilities and results, however, are summaries of single regres-
between utilities and the federal government. sions for each of the four performance measures.
Faye Steiner, “Regulation, Industry Structure and
21. In the United States, a utility’s vertical inte- Performance in the Electricity Supply Industry,”
gration can be quantified as its degree of self-suf- OECD Economics Department Working Papers
ficiency in generation. Some companies own gen- no. 238, April 2000.
eration in excess of their own loads, others are
purchasing some power at all times, and still oth- 24. That study, by economist Hossein Eftekhari,

24
defines some variables in unorthodox ways. His integrated since their formation, instead of being
measure of interconnection activities includes the created by mergers of generation and distribution
algebraic sum of interchanges into and out of a util- operators.
ity’s territory, which could be zero for a large trader.
One of his output variables is sales to ultimate cus- 27. In addition to the works discussed below, one
tomers as a fraction of total sales, rather than an study details the range of data on utility operations
amount. In any case, his estimated cost function required to optimize and evaluate a demand-man-
carries the implication that utilities should always agement program and makes clear that a vertically
either specialize completely in retail sales or in sales integrated utility minimizes difficulties in obtaining
of power to other systems, rather than any mix of and analyzing those data. See Ren Orans, Chi-
the two. Hossein Eftekhari, “Vertical Integration Keung Woo, and Brian Horii, “Case Study: Target-
and Power Generation in the United States,” Journal ing Demand-Side Management for Electricity
of Economics 15, no. 1 (1989): 25–31. Transmission and Distribution Benefits,” Manage-
rial and Decision Economics 15 (1994): 169–75.
25. The author found that there was no cost com-
plementarity to be found in vertical integration. 28. Paul Joskow, “Vertical Integration and Long-
“Cost complementarity” means that the marginal Term Contracts: The Case of Coal-Burning Electric
cost of producing one good decreases when output Generating Plants,” Journal of Law, Economics, and
of the other is increased. Keith Gilsdorf’s findings Organization 1 (Spring 1985): 33–80.
of no cost complementarity are still potentially
consistent with economies of scope and economies 29. Ibid., p. 51; and Paul Joskow, “Contract
of vertical integration, and his estimates show Duration and Relationship-Specific Investments:
unexploited returns to scale in generation, trans- Evidence from Coal Markets,” American Economic
mission, and distribution. Keith Gilsdorf, “Vertical Review 77 (March 1987): 172. Most generators in
Integration Efficiencies and Electric Utilities: A the eastern United States operate with pollution
Cost Complementarity Perspective,” Quarterly control technologies that allow them to burn coal
Review of Economics and Finance 34 (Fall 1994): with a range of sulfur content. Those in the West
261–82; and Keith Gilsdorf, “Testing for Subaddi- are more often engineered to use low-sulfur coal
tivity of Vertically Integrated Electric Utilities,” from a particular mine.
Southern Economic Journal 62 (July 1995): 126–39.
30. Joskow “Vertical Integration and Long-Term
26. All of the studies use variants of two basic Contracts,” p. 65.
strategies to estimate vertical economies. The first
is to estimate a cost function (usually translog, 31. Ibid., p. 54.
otherwise quadratic) on the assumption that the
output of each stage (generation, transmission, 32. Keith Crocker and Scott Masten, “Regulation
and distribution) is from a multiproduct firm. and Administered Contracts Revisited: Lessons of
The sizes and signs of the coefficients of their Transaction-Cost Economics for Public Utility
interaction terms then provide evidence on Regulation,” Journal of Regulatory Economics,
economies of vertical integration. Some formula- January 1996, pp. 5–39, citing Joskow, “Contract
tions allow tests for economies of scope (i.e., Duration and Relationship-Specific Investments.”
whether the sum of costs of standalone firms pro-
ducing each of the stages exceeds the cost of final 33. John Filer, “Impact of Regulation on Vertical
output in an integrated firm) and invariably find Integration in the Electric Industry,” Review of
them. The second strategy estimates cost or pro- Industrial Organization 1 (Fall 1984): 219.
duction functions for each stage and then tests
for vertical separability by examining whether 34. John Gonzales, “Efficiency Aspects of Electric
output of an earlier stage significantly lowers the Utility Coal Operations,” Energy Economics 4
costs of a later one. If it does, vertical effects are (April 1982): 131. He also finds that productivity
present and the production process is not separa- is lower when a regulated mine operates under a
ble. It is possible but not likely that these results cost-plus contract with the buyer. He cautions
are tainted by selectivity bias. Perhaps integrated readers that his findings do not by themselves
utilities have been formed by merger or are toler- make a case for deintegration, since he has not
ated by regulators because of higher efficiency, as studied the possible benefits of integrated mines.
suggested in Michael Pollitt, Ownership and
Performance in Electric Utilities (Oxford: Oxford 35. Joe Kerkvliet, “Efficiency and Vertical Integration:
University Press, 1995), p. 33. The implication is The Case of Mine-Mouth Electric Generating
that these estimates should include unobserved Plants,” Journal of Industrial Economics 39 (September
characteristics of individual firms that lead some 1991): 467–82.
of them to vertically integrate and others not to.
Most if not all U.S. utilities have been vertically 36. Paul Joskow and Richard Schmalensee, “The

25
Performance of Coal-Burning Electric Generating Standardization of Generator Interconnection
Units in the United States: 1960–1980,” Journal of Procedures and Agreements, 106 FERC & 61,220,
Applied Econometrics 2 (April 1987): 85–109. 2004.

37. Eric Hirst, U.S. Transmission Capacity: Present 47. Cleco Power LLC et al., Order Granting
Status and Future Prospects, Report prepared for Petition for Declaratory Order, Docket No. EL02-
Edison Electric Institute, Washington, 2004, 101-000, October 10, 2002. SEtrans withdrew its
http://www.ehirst.com/PDF/TransmissionCapacit application in 2003 because of conflicting
yFinal.pdf; and North American Electric Reliability demands of state regulators and FERC.
Council (NERC), Reliability Assessment, 1998, p. 7,
http://www.nerc.com/~filez/rasreports.html. By 48. Bruce Edelston, director of policy and plan-
most measures, a construction boom in the 1960s ning, Southern Company, quoted in Bruce
and 1970s allowed the industry to enter the 1980s Radford, “The Laws of Physics,” Public Utilities
with significant unused transmission capacity. By Fortnightly, April 4, 2003, pp. 22–23.
the early 1990s most of that capacity was in use,
thanks to the growth in industry size and the 49. William Hogan, “Transmission Market Design,”
growth of wholesale markets that began in the Presentation graphics, April 4, 2003, http://ksg
1980s. There was, however, no increase in new home.harvard.edu/~whogan/trans_mkt_design_0
investments during the 1990s. Since 2003 trans- 40403.pdf.
mission investment has increased in most parts of
the country. 50. A recent unpublished paper proposes use of a
demand-revealing mechanism to circumvent free-
38. NERC is the coordinating agency for 10 rider problems. Robert Michaels, “The Economics of
regional electric reliability councils that cover Participant-Funded Electrical Transmission,” Paper
most of the continent. Members of those councils presented at Rutgers University 14th Annual
include corporate utilities, independent power Advanced Workshop on Regulation, San Diego, June
producers, governmental utilities, and coopera- 2004, http://www.business.fullerton.edu/econom
tives. NERC, Reliability Assessment, 1997, p. 3, http: ics/rmichaels/workingPapers/040920%20pf.pdf.
//www.nerc.com/~filez/rasreports.html.
51. California Public Utilities Commission
39. NERC, Reliability Assessment, 1998, p. 38. (CPUC), “Order Instituting Rulemaking on the
Commission’s Proposed Policies Governing Re-
40. Ibid., p. 7. structuring California’s Electric Services Industry
and Reforming Regulation,” R.94-04-031, April
41. The current TLR procedures have been in place 20, 1994 (unavailable on Internet). This document
since 1997. There are five different levels of emer- came to be known as the “Blue Book,” from the
gency. The figures in the text refer to the three most color of its cover.
serious ones, whose growth rates have all been
high. A graph and source data are available at 52. In 2002 the CPUC decided to remove all of
ftp://www.nerc.com/pub/sys/all_updl/oc/scs/logs these testimonies and the Blue Book itself from
/trends.htm. its website for reasons that it has not made pub-
lic. They are still accessible, however, at the com-
42. NERC, Reliability Assessment, 2001, p. 25, mission’s offices.
http://www.nerc.com/~filez/rasreports.html.
53. FERC ratified the California experiment by
43. Diana Moss, “Competition or Reliability in approving market-based rates in California
Electricity? What the Coming Policy Shift Means through 1997 and beyond. FERC had to act to
for Restructuring,” Electricity Journal 17 (March enable the California experiment to go forward
2004): 25. A small number of transmission-own- because the agency has the statutory obligation to
ing utilities have been responsible for a large per- regulate “just and reasonable” rates in wholesale
centage of TLR incidents. This, however, can transactions. Prior to the coming of markets, this
reflect either the weakness of their grids or their required comparisons of proposed prices and pro-
abundant opportunities to exercise market duction costs. In the 1980s FERC began allowing
power. rates to be set by market prices in areas where sup-
pliers were unconcentrated enough (according to
44. Ibid., p. 17. criteria set by the commission) that competitive
conditions would neutralize any market power one
45. NERC, Reliability Assessment, 2001, p. 25. of them might try to exert. In the months after the
California filings, FERC began to process applica-
46. Participant funding is also embodied in recent- tions to form exchanges in other parts of the coun-
ly issued rules for generator interconnections. See try, particularly the Northeast.

26
54. William Shepherd, “Reviving Regulation and tion studies are also mentioned in a report by the
Antitrust,” Electricity Journal 7 (June 1994): 23. He Consumer Federation of America, a political advoca-
did not cite any of the research discussed above cy group usually sympathetic to regulation.
but warned that existing utilities would claim Consumer Federation of America, All Pain, No Gain:
that vertical separation “will cause large ineffi- Restructuring and Deregulation in the Interstate Electricity
ciencies, even when those claims are false.” Market, 2002, http://www.consumerfed.org/allpain.
pdf.
55. Richard Pierce, “The Advantages of De-inte-
grating the Electricity Industry,” Electricity Journal 63. Hill, p. 53. I have encountered no subsequent
7 (November 1994): 16–21. His earlier writings citations to this article.
(Pierce, “A Proposal to Deregulate”) did describe
the possible benefits of vertical integration but 64. CPUC, Decision D.95-12-063, December 20,
asserted without evidence that deintegration 1995, p. 98, http://www.cpuc.ca.gov/static/indus
would be worth this cost. try/electric/electric+markets/historical+informa
tion. The units in question were gas-fired genera-
56. For instance, environmental economists tors and under normal conditions would set price
David Moskovitz and Douglas Foy proposed to in the new markets. Ultimately these two utilities
solve the stranded cost problem with a deintegra- chose to sell all of their in-state gas-fired capacity
tion that included a sale of transmission at pre- to independent power producers.
mium prices to pay off the stranded costs. David
Moskovitz and Douglas Foy, “Looking for Peace 65. CPUC, Decision D.95-12-063, pp. 10, 90.
in the Middle of a Nervous Breakdown,” Electricity
Journal 7 (November 1994): 22–33. Blank, Gilliam, 66. One economist from a utility, however, com-
and Wellinghoff likewise suggested vertical dein- mented, “The record in the CPUC case provided no
tegration of corporate utilities and the founding evidence of a market power problem that needs to
of a nonprofit transmission company in order to be resolved through divestiture.” “CPUC Power
pay the utilities’ stranded costs and obtain tax Exchange Tops List of Latest State Restructuring
advantages. Eric Blank, Rick Gilliam, and John Plans,” Inside FERC, December 25, 1995, p. 1. A
Wellinghoff, “Breaking Up Is Not So Hard to Do: Southern California Edison vice-president wrote
A Disaggregation Proposal,” Electricity Journal 9 that requiring the divestiture of generation
(May 1996): 46–55. “reduces competition” because it removes a com-
petitor from the market. (It also adds new competi-
57. See Weiss. tors who buy the units.) Vikram Budhraja, “Policy
Choices on the Road to a Competitive Electricity
58. Sant and Naill, p. 51. The probable source of the Market,” Electricity Journal 9 (May 1996): 60.
15 percent figure is Naill and Dudley, whose item-
ization of savings yields a range of estimates between 67. Currently in California Public Utilities Code.
5 and 15 percent. Roger Naill and William Dudley, The law is still commonly known as Assembly Bill
“IPP Leveraged Financing: Unfair Advantage,” Public (AB) 1890.
Utilities Fortnightly, January 15, 1992, pp. 15–20.
68. FERC, Order Conditionally Authorizing
59. Irwin Stelzer, “Vertically Integrated Utilities: Limited Operation of an Independent System
The Regulators’ Poisoned Chalice,” Electricity Operator and Power Exchange, Docket Nos. EC96-
Journal 10 (April 1997): 20–29. 19-001 (Oct. 30, 1997); and “California’s Three
Major IOUs Submit Market Power Mitigation
60. Carl Blumstein and James Bushnell, “A Guide Strategies,” Foster Electric Report, April 16, 1997, p. 8
to the Blue Book: Issues in California’s Electric
Industry Restructuring and Reform,” Electricity 69. The law allowed utilities to recover their
Journal 7 (September 1994): 19. At the time of stranded costs in the difference between frozen
their writing, the concept of an ISO had not yet retail rates and market-determined wholesale
been developed. energy costs prior to 2002. Most market power
studies submitted to FERC were concerned with
61. Marja Ilic et al., “A Framework for Operations monopolistically high prices, but the law’s provi-
in the Competitive Open Access Environment,” sions made utilities more interested in low mar-
Electricity Journal 9 (April 1996): 61–69. Problems ket prices. Some intervenors did express concerns
like those she describes complicated operations in about monopsony (market power of a buyer) and
the early years of the ISO and PX. predatory pricing. The law also required utilities
to apply any premia between the sales prices and
62. Gegax and Nowotny; and Lawrence Hill, “Is book values of divested plants to stranded costs.
Policy Leading Analysis in Electricity Restructuring?”
Electricity Journal 10 (July 1997): 50–61. The integra- 70. The third-largest utility, San Diego Gas &

27
Electric, also divested its gas-fired plants as a con- Working Paper, University of California Energy
dition imposed on its later merger with Southern Institute, April 2006, http://www.ucei.berkeley.
California Gas to form Sempra Energy. edu/PDF/EPE_017.pdf. For dissenting views, see
Scott Harvey, William Hogan, and Todd Schatzki,
71. FERC utilizes critical values of the “A Hazard Rate Analysis of Mirant’s Generating
Herfindahl-Hirschman Index of supplier concen- Plant Outages in California,” LECG LLC, Cam-
tration, a standard tool of antitrust analysis equal bridge, MA, January 2, 2004, http://ksghome.har
to the sum of squares of the market shares of all vard.edu/~whogan/Harvey_Hogan_Schatzki_Tou
competitors. In some models of oligopoly it pre- louse_010204.pdf; and Tim Brennan, “Question-
dicts that increased concentration will lead to ing the Conventional Wisdom,” Regulation 24, no. 3
higher prices, but in others it does not. See Robert (Fall 2001): 63–69.
Michaels, “Market Power in Electric Utility
Mergers: Access, Energy, and the Guidelines,” 77. FERC, “Minutes of Technical Conference,” p. 5.
Energy Law Journal 17, no. 2 (1996): 401–24.
78. Figures are from testimony by Jone-Lin Wang
72. For an overview of the crisis, see Jerry Taylor of Cambridge Energy Research Associates at a
and Peter Van Doren, “The California Electricity FERC technical conference. FERC, “Minutes of
Crisis: What’s Going On, Who’s to Blame, and Technical Conference,” pp. 5–7.
What to Do?” Cato Institute Policy Analysis no.
406, July 3, 2001. 79. See testimonies of Peter Esposito and Diana
Moss (antitrust concerns) and Christine Tezak
73. Timothy P. Duane, “Regulation’s Rationale: (few antitrust concerns) in FERC, “Minutes of
Learning from the California Energy Crisis,” Yale Technical Conference.”
Journal on Regulation 19 (Summer 2002): 508. The
CPUC documents he cites are no longer available 80. “California’s Electric Utilities File 20-Year
on the Internet. Plans with CPUC,” Foster Electric Report, April 23,
2003, p. 10.
74. Frank Wolak, “Measuring Unilateral Market
Power in Wholesale Electricity Markets: The 81. Richard Stavros, “Last Big Battle for State
California Electricity Market 1998–2000,” American Regulators? California Again Is the Proving
Economic Review 93 (May 2003a): 425–31; and Frank Ground,” Public Utilities Fortnightly, October 15, 1999,
Wolak, “Diagnosing the California Electricity p. 34.
Crisis,” Electricity Journal 16 (August 2003b): 11–37.
82. James Bushnell and Catherine Wolfram, “Owner-
75. Frank Wolak, “An Empirical Analysis of the ship Change, Incentives and Plant Efficiency,” Center
Impact of Hedge Contracts on Bidding Behavior in for Study of Energy Markets Working Paper 140,
a Competitive Electricity Market,” International March 2005.
Economic Journal 14 (Summer 2000): 1–39; and
James Bushnell and Celeste Saravia, “An Empirical 83. Magali Delmas and Yesim Tokat, “Deregulation
Assessment of the Competitiveness of the New Process, Governance Structures and Efficiency: The
England Electricity Market,” University of California U.S. Electric Utility Sector,” University of California
Energy Institute Working Paper CSEM-WP101, Energy Institute, Energy Policy and Economics 004,
2002, http://www.ucei.berkeley.edu/PDF/csemw March 2003.
p101.pdf. This argument contains an unstated
assumption that makes it empirically questionable. 84. Erin Mansur, “Vertical Integration in Restruc-
It assumes that forward contracts are for some rea- tured Electricity Markets: Measuring Market
son usually priced below the spot prices that will Efficiency and Firm Conduct,” Yale School of
actually prevail in the future. Management, Working Paper Series ES, no. 32,
2003, p. 36. He also notes: “These results do not
76. See Paul Joskow and Edward Kahn, “A imply that divesting powerplants was a poor deci-
Quantitative Analysis of Pricing Behavior in sion. However, it does caution regulators that, if they
California’s Wholesale Electricity Market during do require divestiture, then they also enable firms to
Summer 2000,” Energy Journal 23, no. 4 (2002): sign contracts that will limit incentives to distort the
1–35; Severin Borenstein, James Bushnell, and market.”
Frank Wolak, “Measuring Market Inefficiencies in
California’s Restructured Wholesale Electricity 85. Newbery, p. 6. The British contracts ran for
Market,” American Economic Review 92, no. 5 three years. He also makes the interesting point
(December 2002): 1376–1405; and Ramteen that although many electricity industries have
Sioshansi and Shmuel Oren, “How Good Are been restructured successfully, they all started
Supply Function Equilibrium Models? An Empiri- with substantial spare capacity (p. 10). California
cal Analysis of the ERCOT Balancing Market,” began with enough excess capacity that for its

28
first two years many generators could not cover that have not yet been realized. For example, he
their full costs at market prices. A rare constella- questions whether the choice of new generation
tion of events destroyed that excess more quickly investments should be in the hands of parties who
than the state’s utilities expected it would. do not bear the risks of excessive reliance on natur-
al gas.
86. John Rowe, Janet Szczypinski, and Peter
Thornton, “Competition without Chaos,” AEI- 94. Ibid., p. 112.
Brookings Joint Center for Regulatory Studies
Working Paper no. 01-07, June 2001, http://ssrn. 95. Kiesling, p. 23.
com/abstract=286415. Rowe’s Chicago utility
divested its fossil and nuclear plants, while the 96. Robert Michaels, “The Governance of
Philadelphia company divested only nuclear. Transmission Operators,” Energy Law Journal 20,
Along these lines, Green and Newbery supported no. 2 (1999): 233–62.
deintegration for large British suppliers but not for
small utilities in Scotland. Richard Green and 97. FERC, Order No. 888, FERC Statutes and
David M. Newbery, “Competition in the Electricity Regulations & 31,036, 1996.
Industry in England and Wales,” Oxford Review of
Economic Policy 13, no. 1 (1997): 27–46. As in 98. “FERC Wrestles with Implementation of
California, retail rates in Pennsylvania were capped. Independent System Operators,” Electric Utility
Week, January 29, 1996, p. 7. State regulators would
87. That utility, GPU, encountered financial prob- not appear on boards, but many other interests
lems when wholesale rates rose and customers in would. The trade press (a transcript of the confer-
its area began abandoning direct access to return to ence is unavailable) does not discuss the reasoning
its capped retail rates. State regulators refused to behind Joskow’s choice of a nonprofit.
grant the company relief, saying that GPU should
live with the consequences of divestiture and 99. “Most Industry Participants Voice Strong
refusal to hedge. “To Avoid California Experience, Support for ISOs,” Foster Electric Report, February
GPU Wants to Collect over Rate Caps,” Electric 7, 1996, p. 12.
Utility Week, January 22, 2001, p. 16.
100. CPUC, Decision D.95-12-063, December 20,
88. “New York Rebuts Idea of Bad Summer,” 1995, http://www.cpuc.ca.gov/static/industry/elec
Power Markets Week, January 29, 2001, p. 16. tric/electric+markets/historical+information/d95
12063/index.htm.
89. Lynne Kiesling, “Getting Electricity Deregu-
lation Right: How Other States and Nations Have 101. Ibid., p. 60.
Avoided California’s Mistakes,” Reason Public
Policy Institute Study no. 281, May, 2001, p. 23, 102. “California’s Three Major IOUs Submit
http://www.rppi.org/ps281.pdf. Market Power Mitigation Strategies,” Foster
Electric Report, April 16, 1997, p. 8. Above the PX
90. Jamie Read, “Re-Verticalizing Electricity,” and ISO would be a newly created Electricity
Presentation graphics to Harvard Electricity Oversight Board, whose jurisdictional conflicts
Policy Group, June 4, 2004, http://www.ksg.har with FERC were generally resolved in the latter’s
vard.edu/hepg/Papers/Read.Reverticalizing.Elect favor and which ceased to have many meaningful
ricity.060404.pdf. functions as the market crisis grew.

91. Read also suggests that a utility could auction 103. Della Valle gives a fuller discussion of the
the right to serve its residual load to an indepen- legal and financial issues in divestiture, as well as
dent organization. a taxonomy of the forms it might take. Anna
Della Valle, “Separating Transmission from
92. Experts initially viewed the breakup of Generation: What’s Required and Why,” Electricity
American Telephone and Telegraph as valuable to Journal 10 (March 1997): 83–90.
only a handful of large businesses with extensive
telecommunications requirements. Within two 104. Dennis W. Carlton, Prepared statement on
years, new service providers were selling to indi- behalf of the Sacramento Municipal Utility
vidual residences. District, FERC Dockets ER96-1663-000 et al.,
filed September 13, 1996. See also “FERC: Calif.
93. Richard Rosen, “Can Electric Utility Restruc- Must Run vs. Market Power,” Electricity Daily,
turing Meet the Challenges It Has Created?” Tellus September 13, 1996; and “Most California Utility-
Institute, Boston, 2000, p. 32, http://www.tellus. Owned Thermal Plants Deemed ‘Must-Run’ by
org/energy/publications/restructchallenge.pdf. He ISO Board,” Electric Utility Week, July 21, 1997, p.
also notes some potentially harmful externalities 11. Must-run units would be a continuing prob-

29
lem for the ISO, even after the utilities agreed on expenses in connection with expansion of mem-
contracts to set the price of their power. In 1997 bership that should not be included in operating
the ISO governing board classified 14,500 MW costs.
(one-third of the state’s power supply) as must-
run, a figure which has since fallen. 113. Vito Stagliano, “The Life and Death of
Regional Transmission Organizations,” Electricity
105. “Various Parties Protest the California IOU’s Journal 14 (December 2001): 23.
ISO and Power Exchange Proposals,” Foster
Electric Report, June 26, 1996, p. 1. 114. Michael Maloney, Robert McCormick, and
Raymond Sauer, “Consumer Choice, Consumer
106. “California PUC’s Conlon Urges Transmis- Value: An Analysis of Retail Competition in
sion Sales, Not ISOs, as Market Power Cure,” America’s Electric Industry,” Citizens for a Sound
Electric Utility Week, July 28, 1997, p. 10. Note that Economy Foundation, 1997, http://www.cse.org.
California’s political reality became FERC’s pre-
ferred institutional form. FERC, however, probably 115. U.S. Energy Information Administration,
does not have the power to order divestitures. Electricity Prices in a Competitive Environment: Marginal
Cost Pricing of Generation Services and Financial Status of
107. Enron Capital and Trade Resources, a mar- Electric Utilities, A Preliminary Analysis through 2015,
keter, sponsored testimony at the CPUC by DOE/EIA-0614, 1997, p. ix, http://tonto.eia.doe.
Richard Tabors proposing a transmission-only gov/FTPROOT/electricity/0614.pdf. The report
entity. The research underlying that testimony estimated that prices could fall by as much as 24
appears in Chitru Fernando et al., “Unbundling the percent under conditions of “intense competition”
U.S. Electric Power Industry: A Blueprint for with sellers aggressively cutting prices.
Change,” Risk Management and Decision Proc-
esses Center Working Paper 95-03-05, Wharton 116. One recent study has shown largely negative
School, University of Pennsylvania, 1995, http:// consequences of an RTO. It was prepared by ICF
www.tca-us.com/Publications/RUEI.pdf. Consulting for the three corporate utilities that
would be operating under the proposed Grid-
108. They include American Transmission Florida operator. See Cost-Benefit Study of the
Company in the Midwest, http://www.atcllc.com, Proposed GridFlorida RTO, December 12, 2005, http:
and Trans-Elect, which operates regional systems //www.icfconsulting.com/Markets/Energy/doc_fil
in Michigan and Canada and is prime contractor es/gridflorida-rto-report.pdf.
for the expansion of Path 15 between northern and
southern California, http://www.trans-elect.com. 117. John Clapp and Margaret McGrath, “Compar-
ing Apples and Oranges: RTO Cost-Benefit Studies
109. ICF Consulting, Economic Assessment of RTO Are Difficult to Reconcile,” Public Utilities Fortnightly,
Policy, Report to FERC, February 26, 2002, p. 7, September 15, 2002, pp. 32–37.
http://www.ferc.gov/industries/electric/indus-
act/rto/cost/02-26-02-report.pdf. The assumed 118. Ellen Wolfe, “RTO West Benefit/Cost Study,
discount rate was 6.97 percent. Several other sce- Final Report Presented to RTO West Filing Utilities,”
narios were posited, all of which provided annual Tabors Caramanis & Associates, 2002, p. vii. This
benefits ranging from 0 to 3 percent. report is also the only one of its kind that estimates
the spillover benefits to other regions that will result
110. Thomas Lenard, “FERC’s Flawed Assessment from the changeover in RTO West’s territory.
of the Benefits and Costs of Regional Transmis-
sion Organizations,” Electricity Journal 15 (May 119. A summary of research on for-profit and non-
2002): 74–78. profit institutions appears in Henry Hansmann,
The Ownership of Enterprise (Cambridge, MA:
111. ICF Consulting, p. 79. Harvard University Press, 1996). In one of many
similar articles, lawyers Angle and Cannon assert in
112. Margot Lutzenheiser, “Comparative Analysis their text that for-profit institutions will watch
of ISO/RTO Costs,” Presentation graphics from costs more closely and be more innovative than
American Public Power Association National nonprofits. The only authorities they cite are two
Conference, June 21, 2004, pp. 3–4, available from FERC commissioners, neither of whom was an
author at www.ppcpdx.org. The total percentages economist. Stephen Angle and George Cannon Jr.,
were calculated from figures on a graph. Data are “Independent Transmission Companies: The For-
given for the per mWh costs, but these also Profit Alternative in Competitive Electric Markets,”
include maintenance while the others are only Energy Law Journal 19, no. 2 (1998): 229–79.
“operating costs.” In unpublished correspon-
dence, PJM has argued that Lutzenhiser’s figures 120. Michaels, “The Governance of Transmission
are too high since they include extraordinary Operators.”

30
121. James Buchanan and Gordon Tullock, The Power Generation in the United States,” Journal of
Calculus of Consent (Ann Arbor: University of Economics 15, no. 1 (1989): 25–31.
Michigan Press, 1965); William Riker, The Theory of
Political Coalitions (New Haven, CT: Yale University 130. David Kaserman and John Mayo, “The
Press, 1962); and Donald Saari, The Geometry of Measurement of Vertical Economies and the
Voting (New York and Berlin: Springer-Verlag, Efficient Structure of the Electric Utility Industry,”
1994). Journal of Industrial Economics 39 (September 1991):
483–502.
122. Michaels, “The Governance of Transmission
Operators.” 131. Keith Gilsdorf, “Testing for Subadditivity of
Vertically Integrated Electric Utilities,” Southern
123. California Independent System Operator v. FERC, Economic Journal 62 (July 1995): 126–39.
372 F.3d 395 (2004)
132. Byung-Joo Lee, “Separability Test for the
124. Robert Michaels, “Watching the Watchers: Can Electricity Supply Industry,” Journal of Applied
RTO Market Monitors Really Be Independent?” Econometrics 10 (January–March 1995): 49–60.
Public Utilities Fortnightly, July 15, 2003, pp. 35–38.
133. Paul Hayashi et al., “Vertical Economies: The
125. In one of their reports the California PX’s Case of the U.S. Electric Industry, 1983–87,” Southern
monitors went so far as to explain how utilities Economic Journal 63 (January 1997): 710–25.
could modify their bidding strategies to improve
their chances of success in lowering market prices. 134. Herbert Thompson Jr., “Cost Efficiency in
Power Procurement and Delivery Service in the
126. For a summary, see Robert Wilson, Electric Utility Industry,” Land Economics 73, no. 3
“Architecture of Power Markets,” Econometrica 70 (1997): 287–301.
(July 2002): 1299–1340.
135. Mika Goto and Jiro Nemoto, "Analysis of
127. Stephen Henderson, “Cost Estimation for Cost Structure by Multi-Product Symmetric
Vertically Integrated Firms: The Case of Electricity,” Generalized McFadden Cost Function: Economies
in Analyzing the Impact of Regulatory Change in Public of Vertical Integration of Japanese Electric Power
Utilities, ed. Michael Crew (Lexington, MA: Lexington Companies," (in Japanese) Denryoku Keizai Kenkyu
Books, 1985), pp. 75–94. This table was originally (Electricity Economic Studies) 42 (1999): 1–13.
published in Robert J. Michaels, “Vertical Integra-
tion: The Economics that Electricity Forgot,” 136. John Kwoka, “Vertical Economies in Electric
Electricity Journal 17 (December 2004): 16–17. Power: Evidence on Integration and Its Altern-
atives,” International Journal of Industrial Organization
128. Mark Roberts, “Economies of Density and 20 (2002): 653–71.
Size in the Production and Delivery of Electric
Power,” Land Economics 62 (November 1986): 137. Jiro Nemoto and Mika Goto, “Technological
378–86. Externalities and Economies of Vertical Integration
in the Electric Utility Industry,” International Journal
129. Hossein Eftekhari, “Vertical Integration and of Industrial Organization 22 (2004): 676–81.

31
OTHER STUDIES IN THE POLICY ANALYSIS SERIES

571. Reappraising Nuclear Security Strategy by Rensselaer Lee (June 14, 2006)

570. The Federal Marriage Amendment: Unnecessary, Anti-Federalist, and


Anti-Democratic by Dale Carpenter (June 1, 2006)

569. Health Savings Accounts: Do the Critics Have a Point? by Michael F.


Cannon (May 30, 2006)

568. A Seismic Shift: How Canada’s Supreme Court Sparked a Patients’


Rights Revolution by Jacques Chaoulli (May 8, 2006)

567. Amateur-to-Amateur: The Rise of a New Creative Culture by F. Gregory


Lastowka and Dan Hunter (April 26, 2006)

566. Two Normal Countries: Rethinking the U.S.-Japan Strategic


Relationship by Christopher Preble (April 18, 2006)

565. Individual Mandates for Health Insurance: Slippery Slope to National


Health Care by Michael Tanner (April 5, 2006)

564. Circumventing Competition: The Perverse Consequences of the Digital


Millennium Copyright Act by Timothy B. Lee (March 21, 2006)

563. Against the New Paternalism: Internalities and the Economics of Self-
Control by Glen Whitman (February 22, 2006)

PA Masthead.indd 2 2/9/06 2:08:35 PM

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi