Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 18

Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481 www.elsevier.

com/locate/jom

Toward a model of strategic outsourcing


Tim R. Holcomb *, Michael A. Hitt 1
Texas A&M University, Mays Business School, Department of Management, College Station, TX 77843-4221, United States Available online 16 June 2006

Abstract Acknowledging efciency motives, rms have increasingly turned to outsourcing in an effort to capture cost savings. Transaction cost theory (TCT) has been the dominant means of explaining outsourcing as an economizing approach whereby cost efciencies are achieved by assigning transactions to different governance mechanisms. Recent research has used the resourcebased view (RBV) to examine the role of specialized capabilities as a potential source of value creation in relationships between rms. Although research in supply chain management has expanded substantially, only limited applications of TCT and the RBVare available, especially in the eld of operations management. We extend both perspectives to explain conditions leading to strategic outsourcing. # 2006 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Keywords: Strategic outsourcing; Operations strategy; Resource-based view; Transaction cost theory; Resource management; Value creation; Operations management; Supply chain management; Capabilities; Vertical disintegration; Intermediate markets

1. Introduction Understanding how rms establish rm scope has interested management scholars for some time, and a body of research has explored the boundary conditions rms consider when choosing to source activity from the marketplace (e.g. Fine and Whitney, 1999; Gilley and Rasheed, 2000; Quinn, 1999). In particular, this research highlights the complex choices rms make when deciding whether to internalize or outsource production. On the one hand, internalization requires rms to commit resources to a course of action, which may limit strategic exibility and be difcult to reverse

* Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 979 845 4852; fax: +1 979 845 9641. E-mail addresses: tholcomb@mays.tamu.edu (T.R. Holcomb), mhitt@mays.tamu.edu (M.A. Hitt). 1 Tel.: +1 979 458 3393; fax: +1 979 845 9641. 0272-6963/$ see front matter # 2006 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.jom.2006.05.003

(Leiblein et al., 2002). On the other hand, internalization may be required by rms to more effectively carry out production. The complexity of these boundary decisions has intensied in recent years stimulated by increased competitive pressures, the rapidity of technological change, and the dispersion of knowledge across different organizations and geographic markets (Hoetker, 2005; Teece, 1992). Accordingly, a variety of outsourcing arrangements has emerged. We rely on both transaction-based and resource-based logics to explain the emergence of one such arrangement strategic outsourcing in which rms rely on intermediate markets to provide specialized capabilities that supplement existing capabilities used in production. What determines rm scope? A well-developed approach for boundary decisions associated with rm scope is transaction cost theory (TCT). According to this perspective, rms integrate production to minimize costs from opportunism and bounded rationality of

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1321061

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481

465

rms and their suppliers, the uncertainty and frequency of market exchange, and asset specicity that arises from supplier-rm or rm-customer relationships (Coase, 1937; Williamson, 1985). This theory holds that certain types of governance mechanisms manage exchanges with particular characteristics more efciently than others; cost economizing therefore reects a rms efforts to minimize costs arising from the governance of market exchanges.2 Accordingly, the decision to outsource often rests on economizing motives related to the t between rms governance choices and specic attributes about an economic exchange (Grover and Malhotra, 2003; Silverman et al., 1997). Recently, however, scholars have presented resource-based perspectives of integration that augment transaction-based views and sharpen the focus on rms relative advantages (Combs and Ketchen, 1999; Leiblein and Miller, 2003; Poppo and Zenger, 1998). This growing body of work, which is based on the original work of Penrose (1959) and uses Barneys (1991) more recent translation of the resource-based view (RBV) of the rm, emphasizes the importance of resources in guiding rm activity and the management of a rms portfolio of capabilities as central to competitive advantage.3 More specically, this research contends that the reasons for internalization extend beyond the cost of transacting through the market to the conditions that enable rms to establish, maintain, and use capabilities more efciently than markets can do (Conner, 1991; Ghoshal and Moran, 1996; Teece et al., 1997).

2 There are multiple sources and aspects of transaction costs. Coase (1937), for example, emphasized the frictional costs, such as those costs that arise from negotiating, drafting, and monitoring contracts. Williamson (1975, 1985) expanded this perspective by focusing attention on the costs of transactional hazards (e.g. difculties) and governance mechanisms to limit such hazards. Whereas Williamson focuses on the tendency of transaction difculties to emerge as a function of the exchange, Coases frictional costs are a feature of economic conditions that occur independent of deliberate calculation or motives (see also Jacobides and Winter, 2005). 3 Resources, broadly dened, have often been used in the literature in a generic sense to include capabilities (e.g. Barney, 1991). Other scholars have claimed that capabilities represent how rms manage resources (e.g. Dutta et al., 2005; Helfat and Peteraf, 2003) or that capabilities represent a unique combination of resources that enable rms to pursue specic actions that create value (Sirmon et al. in press). For purposes of this paper, we use resources to represent tangible or intangible assets owned or controlled by rms (Barney, 1991; Grant, 1996) and capabilities to represent organizational routines that allow rms to effectively integrate and use resources to implement their strategies (Lavie, 2006; Winter, 2003).

The resulting convergence between these two theories has stimulated a number of empirical studies, which has created a more effective understanding of what drives strategic outsourcing. For example, in recent years, transaction cost scholars have accepted that transaction-based and resource-based perspectives deal with partly overlapping phenomena, often in complementary ways and that capability endowments matter to boundary decisions (Williamson, 1999, p. 1098). Combs and Ketchen (1999) found evidence that rms often place resource-based concerns ahead of exchange economies when deciding on potential interrm cooperation. Complementary to this view, Madhok (2002) pursued the question of how rms should organize production given certain resourcebased conditions (e.g. pre-existing strengths and weaknesses). He suggested that boundary decisions depend not only on the conditions surrounding the transaction, but also on capability attributes, and the governance context that it creates. Thus, substantial empirical support exists for the proposition that capability considerations trade-off with economizing constraints in the decision to outsource (e.g. Hoetker, 2005; Jacobides and Winter, 2005; Poppo and Zenger, 1998). Our work contributes to this stream by extending earlier conceptualizations of outsourcing based on economizing conditions, such as asset specicity, small numbers bargaining, and technological uncertainty, to include factors that inuence the selection and integration of capabilities from intermediate markets (Argyres and Liebeskind, 1999; Jacobides and Winter, 2005). In particular, we consider the complementarity of capabilities, strategic relatedness, relational capability-building mechanisms, and cooperative experience as four important conditions that establish a resource-based context for strategic outsourcing. According to this perspective, in the decision regarding the strategic outsourcing of production, rms evaluate internally accessed capabilities and those capabilities available externally from intermediate markets, and consider how they might best be integrated to produce the greatest value. Therefore, this work goes beyond the question of governance mechanisms to enrich our understanding of capability selection and use, providing a more meaningful understanding of strategic outsourcing. Whereas transaction-based perspectives typically conne outsourcing to more specialized, repetitive activities such as manufacturing, logistics, and facilities management, resource-based theory provides a context to explain strategic outsourcing arrangements for more visible and

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1321061

466

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481

potentially sensitive functions such as research and development (R&D), engineering design, and customer support. This trend is evident in the personal computer (PC) and communications equipment sectors, where growing demand for new product offerings has driven the market for third-party R&D and design. As a result, the volume of outsourced R&D, design, and manufacturing services in these two sectors is expected to grow almost two-fold between 2004 and 2009, from $179 billion to $345.5 billion (Carbone, 2005). Despite the dramatic increase in strategic outsourcing in recent years, few systematic studies of strategic outsourcing have been completed (Gilley and Rasheed, 2000). In fact, this topic has received only limited exposure in the elds of healthcare management (e.g. Billi et al., 2004; Roberts, 2001), economics (e.g. Chen et al., 2004a; Shy and Stenbacka, 2003), and strategic management (e.g. Fine and Whitney, 1999; Quinn, 1999; Quinn and Hilmer, 1994). Accordingly, this work represents an early attempt to frame and provide a theoretical understanding to the strategic outsourcing concept in operations and supply chain management research using both transaction-based and resource-based logics. This work follows Grover and Malhotras (2003) call for more research by operations management scholars that integrate strategic management and organizational theory into the study of interrm relationships. In particular, our work contributes to the stream of research synthesizing TCT and the RBV by integrating them to extend earlier conceptualizations of outsourcing. We also make three important contributions to the outsourcing literature. First, we offer a more concise denition of strategic outsourcing that extends transaction-based logics and considers value created when rms more effectively leverage the specialized capabilities these relationships provide. Second, we explain how developing a capabilities view better informs the discourse about the outsourcing choices that rms make. Prior work has established a relationship between outsourcing and cost economies from the selection of more efcient governance mechanisms (e.g. Cachon and Harker, 2002; Walker and Weber, 1984). However, to date, there has been little understanding provided of the role that internal and external capabilities play in strategic outsourcing decisions. Herein, we shift the focus on value creation from different exchange conditions to value chain structures and to the process by which rms produce goods and services. Thus, we provide managers with a richer framework to understand the trade-offs between internalization, past relationships

and experience, and capabilities that guide their decision to internalize or outsource. Third, we highlight the expanded role that boundaries serve in the formation of strategic outsourcing relationships. Establishing rm boundaries requires understanding more than how internally- and externally-sourced production activities affect performance (Araujo et al., 2003). It also requires a better understanding of the bridging function that boundaries perform in linking rms production activity with intermediate markets (McEvily and Zaheer, 1999). Accordingly, we argue that a more complete understanding of the organization of economic activity requires a greater sensitivity to the interdependence of capabilities, production activity, and interrm relations that emerge from boundary decisions, as suggested by Coase (1988). Fig. 1 summarizes our model for strategic outsourcing. This model depicts conditions for value creation integrated with economizing arguments for strategic outsourcing. These theoretical arguments are examined in the following sections. We begin with a concise review of the literature and derive a more complete denition of strategic outsourcing. Next, transaction-based and resource-based arguments for outsourcing are reviewed. Building on these two perspectives, we present a model of strategic outsourcing that uses transaction- and capability-based factors to examine a rms decision to outsource. Finally, we discuss opportunities for future research. 2. Theoretical foundation Whereas transaction-based perspectives explain different governance mechanisms, resource-based theory considers the relative capabilities of focal rms and exchange partners as important in vertical integration decisions (e.g. Afuah, 2001; Argyres, 1996). According to this view, rms are largely heterogeneous in terms of their resources and capabilities (e.g. Barney, 1991; Wernerfelt, 1984), and thus often carry out the same activity with different production efciencies and costs. As a result, separate rms that display different ways of accomplishing the same task achieve different cost efciencies and performance outcomes. 2.1. Strategic outsourcing dened We dene strategic outsourcing as the organizing arrangement that emerges when rms rely on intermediate markets to provide specialized capabilities that supplement existing capabilities deployed along a

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481

467

Fig. 1. A theoretical model for strategic outsourcing.

rms value chain.4 Further, we suggest that strategic outsourcing creates value within rms supply chains beyond those achieved through cost economies. As explained later, intermediate markets that provide specialized capabilities emerge as different industry conditions intensify the partitioning of production. As a result of greater information standardization and simplied coordination, clear administrative demarcations emerge along a value chain (Jacobides, 2005). Partitioning of intermediate markets occurs as the coordination of production across a value chain is simplied and as information becomes standardized, making it easier to transfer activities across boundaries (Richardson, 1972). Accordingly, an orientation toward strategic outsourcing evolves, as specialized capabilities emerge, resulting in a greater dependence on intermediate markets for production (Fine and Whitney, 1999; Quinn, 1999). The decision to outsource existing production represents the simplest form of strategic outsourcing.

4 A value chain, as dened herein, consists of the set of value-adding activities within a supply chain that may be undertaken for a product to be made or a service to be rendered. The concept of the value chain was originally used to conceptualize the set of productive activities that occur within the boundaries of any given rm, such as research and development, engineering design, inbound/outbound logistics, marketing, etc. (see Porter, 1985). Our denition of the term is consistent with the general use (e.g. Porter, 1985) to mean a structured set of activities associated with a rms productive output, regardless of whether they take place within the boundaries of a single integrated rm or occur externally using intermediate markets. Focusing on distinct activities that rms perform provides an efcient way of examining how boundaries change and how specialized capabilities from intermediate markets can be leveraged to accommodate some or all of the activities within a value chain.

Gilley and Rasheed (2000) refer to this organizing form as substitution-based outsourcing. With substitution, rms discontinue internal production (e.g. the production of goods or services) and replace existing activities and/or factors of production (e.g. resources) with capabilities provided by intermediate markets. Accordingly, applying a capabilities perspective, we suggest that rm scope is partly determined by considering the performance differential between existing internal capabilities and those available in intermediate markets for substitution. By contrast, rms can also decide to outsource production a priori. Gilley and Rasheed refer to this form as abstention-based outsourcing, which occurs when rms acquire capabilities from intermediate markets, rather than incur the necessary investments to internalize production. Thus, rm scope is also determined by examining the differential between the costs of internally developing new capabilities against accessing these capabilities in intermediate markets (Argyres, 1996; Langlois and Robertson, 1995). Research indicates that economizing rms often consider the value of their capabilities in decisions about internalizing an activity or conducting it through intermediate markets (e.g. Argyres, 1996; Combs and Ketchen, 1999; Hoetker, 2005). Specically, in deciding whether or not to internalize, rms often compare their capabilities with those of other rmsas signaled by the price and quality terms that exchange partners are prepared to provide (Jacobides and Winter, 2005). However, due in part to ambiguity that emerges based on imperfections in the market, boundedly rational agents are often unable to foresee potential synergies from the integration of distinctive capability combinations.

468

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481

An important distinction introduced herein is how resource-based logics inuence the decision to strategically outsource more effective specialized capabilities along a value chain, beyond that which we know by examining different governance mechanisms. More effective capabilities can enable rms to increase inventory turns, shorten product development cycles, and reduce the time-to-market for new products (Clark and Fujimoto, 1992; Petersen et al., 2005). Stated differently, we contend that strategic outsourcing not only creates cost economies by shifting production activity from a focal rm to intermediate markets, but also creates economic value, especially when production involves the use of potentially more valuable specialized capabilities (Fine and Whitney, 1999; Mowery et al., 1996). Argyres (1996) was one of the rst to provide qualitative evidence on the role of capabilities in internalization decisions, observing that capabilities are a signicant driver of rm scope in the cable connector industry. When comparing transactionand rm-level inuences on rm scope, Leiblein and Miller (2003, p. 854) found that rm-level capabilities independently and signicantly inuence rms boundary decisions. Jacobides and Hitt (2005, p. 1222) examined how capability differences shape the make-versus-buy decision concluding that, productive capabilities can and do play a major role in the determination of vertical scope, and account for mixed governance modes. 2.2. Specialized capabilities and the emergence of intermediate markets A stream of research originally characterized as vertical disintegration (Stigler, 1951) helps explain strategic outsourcing by developing a capabilities view (e.g. Langlois and Robertson, 1995; Leiblein and Miller, 2003). According to this perspective, the emergence of new intermediate markets is driven largely by the desire of rms to pursue gains from the trade of specialized production. Richardson (1972) was one of the rst to suggest that boundaries were contingent on the different activities in which rms engage, the capabilities such activities require, and the selection and use of those capabilities along a value chain. Jacobides (2005) examined conditions leading to increased specialization. He explained the emergence of new intermediate markets on the basis of gains from intrarm specialization that condition a market, dividing previously integrated value chains among different sets of specialized rms and shifting the focus on value creation from the nal market for goods or services to

the value chain structure and the process by which the good or service is produced (2005, p. 490). In the automobile sector, for example, advances in engineering and production technologies have led manufacturers to decouple supply chain capabilities giving up parts of the value chain to newly formed specialists in intermediate markets (Fine and Whitney, 1999). Similar trends are evident in the PC and communications sectors, with the emergence of electronics manufacturing services (EMS) and original design manufacturing (ODM) rms, such as Flextronics, Hon Hai, Sanmina, and Compal Communications, and the corresponding growth of original equipment manufacturers in these sectorsthat only market, but do notdesign or manufacture their own equipment. In the banking sector, standardization and advances in information technology led to signicant specialization of production activities such as application development and data processing, which enabled non-nancial rms such as IBM, EDS, and Accenture to become key participants in the intermediate market for information services. Accordingly, given advances in technology and standardization, new intermediate markets emerge, decomposing the value chain, allowing rms to acquire valuable yet specialized capabilities cost-effectively via the market. As a result, rm boundaries shift as activities that were carried out internally are transferred to newly formed intermediate markets. We therefore argue that strategic outsourcing not only allows rms to reduce costs, but also to enhance their portfolio of capabilities, and value creation potential, especially whenrmsproduce unique combinationsusing capabilities provided by these markets. We suggest that three assumptions underlie resourcebased views about strategic outsourcing. First, selection determines gains available to rms from capabilities accessed in the intermediate markets and then intensies the effect of these capabilities on rm performance. Complementarity and relatedness creates uniquely valuable synergy, especially when specialized capabilities are effectively combined and when no other combination can replicate the resulting value chain activities (Harrison et al., 1991, 2001; Prahalad and Bettis, 1986; Richardson, 1972; Tsai, 2000). To the extent that intermediate markets have superior capabilities that complement a rms existing capabilities, selection processes will combine the specialized internal and external capabilities. By contrast, if a rm possesses superior capabilities that are already integrated, selection will accommodate internalization. Second, strategic outsourcing relationships form within a social context. Ties, both direct and indirect, with rms in intermediate markets create a network

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481

469

(Uzzi, 1997), and become an important source of information about the reliability and performance of current and future exchange partners (Granovetter, 1985). Such information helps a focal rm to learn about capabilities available in intermediate markets. Repeated ties improve trust in current and potential exchange partners and increase the likelihood of future cooperation (Gulati, 1995). Accordingly, cooperative experience forges close bonds over time and increases condence that exchange partners will pursue mutually compatible interests thereby reducing the probability of opportunism (Das and Teng, 1998), and facilitating the exchange of capabilities crucial for performance (Combs and Ketchen, 1999; Uzzi, 1996). Because strategic outsourcing involves coordinating the actions of two or more rms, cooperative experience is vital to its success. Third, rms enhance their ability to leverage specialized capabilities by developing and rening mechanisms that strengthen the synergies such capabilities provide. We refer to these mechanisms as relational capability-building mechanisms (Dyer and Singh, 1998; Makadok, 2001), which allow rms to enhance the potential value of specialized capabilities deployed along a value chain. When purposefully developed, relational capability-building mechanisms allow rms to accumulate, integrate, and leverage experience over time; they are derived from previous capability-building actions, the results of those actions, and the future actions rms pursue (Fiol and Lyles, 1985). From a transaction-based perspective, these mechanisms reduce coordination and integration costs and enable rms to exploit new opportunities in the market, especially when they develop the mechanisms to more effectively manage the portfolio of capabilities they acquire from intermediate markets. These mechanisms also create causal ambiguity, obscuring the use of capabilities deployed across a value chain and making it difcult for competitors to determine a priori the sources of value within rms supply chains. In sum, we contend that specialized capabilities accessed by strategic outsourcing may allow rms to achieve greater performance gains. In the following two subsections, we briey describe several economic incentives behind strategic outsourcing and contrast this organizing arrangement with two related concepts: strategic purchasing and strategic alliances. 2.3. Economic motives and incentives behind strategic outsourcing Although previous empirical studies of outsourcing have produced equivocal results, there is increasing

evidence that certain economic motives may prompt a rms decision to pursue this organizing form. We provide three possible economic motives behind strategic outsourcing. First, strategic outsourcing potentially reduces bureaucratic complexity. As rms grow, information asymmetries emerge (Hitt et al., 1996). Asymmetries produce information decits. Information decits add to the administrative demands of organizing transactions. Excessive bureaucratic costs associated with governance oversight reduce rm performance (DAveni and Ravenscraft, 1994; Rothaermel, Hitt and Jobe, in press). In turn, these demands distract managerial attention from important sources of innovation and growth and add to the costs of internalization (DAveni and Ravenscraft, 1994). As transaction volumes increase, mobility and exit barriers form reducing strategic exibility and often trapping rms in obsolescent technologies (Harrigan, 1985). Thus, strategic outsourcing helps rms align competing priorities, focus management attention on growth and innovation opportunities, and target resources to those tasks rms do best. Second, strategic outsourcing improves production economies, especially when rms fail to achieve sufcient production scale to overcome cost disadvantages (Teece, 1980). Because decisions about price and production are made before actual demand is observed, as transaction volumes vary, rms may nd it difcult to make optimal use of available capacity or may ration production when existing production scale limits activity (Green, 1986). Strategic outsourcing allows rms to avoid or reduce rationing and meet production requirements by relying on intermediate markets as demand varies over time; it also provides a mechanism for rms to reduce uncertainty, transfer risk, and share scale economies with specialized rms from these markets. As a result, overhead is reduced, production costs decline, and investments in certain facilities and equipment are eliminated, which in turn reduces rms break-even points. Based on the considerations noted above, nancial advantages evolve in three ways. First, rms pursuing strategic outsourcing through substitution (Gilley and Rasheed, 2000) benet from nancial capital (cash) exchanged for internal factors of production (e.g. facilities, equipment, management and production personnel, etc.) when assets are transferred or sold to rms in intermediate markets. The nature and size of this nancial capital-factor exchange often has substantial effects on the total value of strategic outsourcing deals. Second, with strategic outsourcing, rms can reduce or eliminate longer-term capital outlays to fund future investments related to the

470

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481

outsourced production. This allows rms to partly shift specic internal costs, including xed charges, such as amortization and depreciation costs, to intermediate markets. Finally, strategic outsourcing can buffer rms by providing access to resources (Miner et al., 1990). Thus, rms reduce their exposure as capacity and costs are more directly linked to actual production output (e.g. the number of units produced). This allows rms to transfer the risk of changes in production as well as responsibility for future capital outlays to intermediate markets. Third, increases in bureaucratic complexity increase the coordination costs associated with different factors of production, especially when specialization reduces the degrees of freedom (Rothaermel et al., in press). Diminishing returns result when the loss of strategic exibility and the increase in administrative costs outweigh the benets of integration (Jones and Hill, 1988). Accordingly, when increased specialization simplies coordination across a value chain (Jacobides, 2005), or when internal production is more efcient through intermediate markets, rms are more likely to integrate and use specialized capabilities. 2.4. Strategic outsourcing and related concepts We draw a distinction between strategic outsourcing and strategic purchasing. Strategic purchasing refers to the ongoing process of soliciting, negotiating, and contracting for the delivery of goods and services from suppliers (Chen et al., 2004b; Murray and Kotabe, 1999). Key activities include procurement, supplier and contract management, and other related supply chain management actions (Salvador et al., 2002) that involve arms-length transactions with suppliers (Chen and Paulraj, 2004). Firms regularly purchase products or services from suppliers on a frequent or recurring basisfrom the procurement of production inputs to the purchase of supplies for ofce and administrative use (Walker and Weber, 1987). Accordingly, these decisions tend to be more routine and rarely involve the transfer of resources (Chen et al., 2004a). By contrast, strategic outsourcing is less common, and may involve the transfer or sale of resources to rms in intermediate markets. Moreover, strategic outsourcing reects a primary relational view involving linkages with exchange partners that provide access to specialized capabilities. This relational view explains performance gains that arise when these capabilities are congured along the value chain to create value that cannot be realized through internalization (Das and Teng, 1998; Sirmon et al., in press). Equating strategic outsourcing

with the purchase of goods and services fails to capture full nature of this organizing form. We also differentiate strategic outsourcing from strategic alliances. Strategic alliances represent collaborative arrangements that rms establish to achieve common goals in which benets are ultimately shared by alliance partners (Inkpen, 2001). As such, in alliances, individual rm performance is a function of both the total value generated by the alliance and the share of this value each rm appropriates (Alvarez and Barney, 2001; Hamel, 1991). Alliances also allow partners to share risks and resources (Ireland et al., 2002), to gain access to new knowledge (Dyer and Singh, 1998), and to obtain access to new product markets (Hitt et al., 2000). By contrast, strategic outsourcing arrangements generally involve a focal rms decision to deploy specialized capabilities along its value chain thereby linking rm performance directly to the productive activities it controls. While alliances infer joint decision-making and shared residuals, strategic outsourcing primarily benets rms that originate the action (Insinga and Werle, 2000) by allowing them to appropriate directly the residual value such actions create. Accordingly, outsourcing decisions are not based on appropriation logic per se, rather on economic terms dened by a focal rm after considering the different cost/performance trade-offs. 3. Transaction-based arguments for strategic outsourcing Efciency assumptions in TCT drive the classical reasoning for strategic outsourcing. With this view, difculties that emerge from market-based exchanges generate transaction costs. Such costs include negotiation, contracting, monitoring, and enforcement costs, as well as costs incurred when resolving disputes. Based on this perspective, the performance implications of outsourcing and thus the decision criteria rms apply are based on the alignment of different governance structures with attributes of the exchange and the underlying contracting environment. For example, a rm that selects a simple governance structure lacking adequate safeguards and controls is exposed to moral hazard and hold-up risks when the contracting environment is complex or when it involves transaction-specic investments (Leiblein et al., 2002). By contrast, selecting an excessively complex governance structure for a simple contracting environment unnecessarily intensies bureaucratic complexity, which reduces decision-making speed, decreases strategic exibility, and increases overall costs (Williamson,

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481

471

1985). Accordingly, cost economies as a consequence of effective governance structures represent important criteria in the decision to strategically outsource. We briey describe three transaction-based considerations for strategic outsourcing: asset specicity, small numbers bargaining, and technological uncertainty. 3.1. Asset specicity Among the exchange conditions originally identied by Williamson (1975), asset specicity has been perhaps the most robust empirically. Specic assets, in contrast to general purpose assets, are considered an obstacle to market efciency, because they are costly to redeploy to alternative uses (Williamson, 1991). Thus, asset specicity is the principal factor giving rise to transaction costs. Williamson (1985) dened asset specicity as durable investments that are made in support of particular exchange transactions. Specic assets are investments made in specic, non-marketable resources and reect the degree to which an asset can be redeployed to alternative uses and by alternative users without sacricing productive value (Williamson, 1991, p. 281). Highly specic supply chain assets, for example, might include investments in facilities, equipment, personnel, and rm- or process-specic training associated with the production of goods or services that have little or no use outside the exchange relationship (Grover and Malhotra, 2003). With strategic outsourcing, one of the principal challenges in deciding whether to make a specic investment concerns the possibility that exchange partners might act opportunistically. Asset specicity creates a bilateral interdependency between the rms (Carney, 1998; Jones, 1983). As such, conditions of outsourcing often lead to one or more rms being locked in and increasingly vulnerable. Trading hazards created by the structure of the market exchange, in turn, produce transactions costs. Diseconomies related to weak incentives and monitoring costs emerge. Under these conditions, asset specicity exposes outsourcing rms to potential opportunism, when exchange partners advance their own self-interest. Contracting in such situations is difcult, expensive, and often counter-productive. Consequently, where resource investments by focal rms are idiosyncratic to an exchange relationship, interrm cooperation is likely to involve internalization. Thus, we propose that: Proposition 1a. Requirements for rm-specic investments by a focal rm in exchange-specic assets between the rm and specialized rms from intermedi-

ate markets negatively affect the likelihood a rm will pursue strategic outsourcing. Under certain conditions, however, asset specicity may serve as a catalyst for interrm cooperation. When rms involved in outsourcing relationships are required to invest collectively in the development of specic assets or new capabilities, such collaboration can form a reciprocal interdependency that increases the level of cooperation and reduces the incentive to engage in opportunism. These conditions reduce the costs of using capabilities from intermediate markets (Combs and Ketchen, 1999; Teece, 1992). Accordingly, in contexts that involve mutual investments in capabilities, collaboration may encourage mutual gain, even when such investments result in exchange-specic assets, and thus increase the likelihood a rm will pursue strategic outsourcing. Thus, we propose that: Proposition 1b. Requirements for collaborative investments in exchange-specic assets between a rm and specialized rms from intermediate markets positively affect the likelihood a rm will pursue strategic outsourcing. 3.2. Small numbers bargaining TCT scholars also argue that small numbers bargaining situations create market inefciencies that create higher switching costs and increase the likelihood of opportunistic behavior (e.g. Klein et al., 1978; Williamson, 1975). The possibility of opportunistic behavior arises when the number of specialized rms in intermediate markets is small, resulting in small numbers bargaining (Williamson, 1975). Moreover, the likelihood of opportunistic behavior is most severe when focal rms are required to make signicant exchange-based investments because such investments may be subject to hold-up by external partners (Klein et al., 1978). Small numbers bargaining affects the distribution of bargaining power in outsourcing relationships. Bargaining power is dened as the ability to inuence the outcomes of negotiated relations (Bacharach and Lawler, 1981; Schelling, 1956). Firms with more bargaining power can obtain more favorable outcomes. In this case, bargaining power is important because it can lead specialized rms to act opportunistically in order to gain an advantage in outsourcing relationships. Thus, small numbers bargaining reduces the likelihood rms will pursue outsourcing. Moreover, when the degree of competitiveness within intermediate markets is low (e.g. small number of specialized rms), specialized rms acting oppor-

472

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481

tunistically may be less willing to share costs caused by changes in production volume or design specications, thereby increasing transaction costs for a focal rm (Walker and Weber, 1987). By contrast, the higher the degree of competitiveness in an intermediate market, the more likely that partners will collaborate to share scale economies by leveraging adjustment costs across customers (Walker and Weber, 1984). Such economies dampen opportunistic bargaining, reduce potential transaction costs, and therefore provide a stronger incentive for rms to outsource. Accordingly, the greater the density of specialized rms, the lower a focal rms exposure to small numbers bargaining, and the more likely that strategic outsourcing will emerge. Thus, we propose that: Proposition 2. The number of specialized rms from intermediate markets is positively related to the likelihood a rm will pursue strategic outsourcing. 3.3. Technological uncertainty Technological uncertainty refers to unanticipated changes in circumstances surrounding technology, i.e., new generations of technology that render existing technology obsolete (Folta, 1998; Robertson and Gatignon, 1998). Broadly dened, technology represents theoretical and practical knowledge, skills, production and supply chain systems, and related artifacts that can be deployed along a rms value chain to develop goods and services (Burgelman et al., 1996). Changes in technology create new complexities for structuring value chain activities, especially when new knowledge is applied at a faster rate reducing the time between innovations (Song and Montoya-Weiss, 2001). In the presence of technological uncertainty, greater resource commitments produce more exposure to negative shocks. Thus, relative to arrangements that provide on-demand access to capabilities through intermediate markets, technological uncertainty may serve as a disincentive to internalize because it often requires greater resource commitments. These conditions may prompt rms to pursue strategic outsourcing to reduce their exposure to unforeseen contingencies and to improve nancial and operational stability and predictability. Schoonhoven (1981, pp. 355356) found that destandardization and decentralization of task execution had positive effects on rm performance under conditions of technological uncertainty. Harrigan (1985, 1986) argued that increases in technological uncertainty may lead rms to use less rm-specic resources. As

a consequence, internalization is likely to decrease in the long-run, because strategic outsourcing allows rms to partly transfer the risk of task variability to the intermediate markets. Specialized rms in these markets may be better able to achieve cost efciencies that are difcult for focal rms to achieve by balancing task requirements across multiple customers. As technological uncertainty increases, internal economies of specialization deteriorate in relation to the external economies of specialized rms (Teece, 1980). As such, strategic outsourcing not only can provide scale economies during periods of technological uncertainty, but may also act as a coping strategy helping to deal with risk. From this perspective, strategic outsourcing provides more predictable and orderly patterns of exchange within and between rms. However, at higher levels of technological uncertainty, larger information decits increase the likelihood for opportunism, making it costly to handle exchanges through intermediate markets. These asymmetries reduce the ability to foresee potential contingencies that may occur in the future making it costly to write, monitor, and enforce complete contracts (Grossman and Hart, 1986). As a result, parties to such exchanges are more likely to regularly renegotiate the terms of their relationship, which increases the likelihood of opportunism. At increasingly higher levels of uncertainty, greater information decits emerge, reducing cost economies and increasing the difculty of interrm collaboration. Reductions in cost economies lead to diminishing returns. At higher levels of technological uncertainty, rms nd it difcult to accurately predict a priori the combination of possible events and outcomes that are likely to emerge from production (March and Simon, 1958). Thus, beyond a certain level of technological uncertainty, we expect this relationship to be negative. Specically, we propose that: Proposition 3. Technological uncertainty will have a non-linear (inverse U-shaped) effect on the likelihood a rm will pursue strategic outsourcing, with the slope positive at low and moderate levels of technological uncertainty but negative at high levels of technological uncertainty. 3.4. Critique of transaction-based arguments for strategic outsourcing While providing a number of important insights regarding the most efcient means to govern a particular economic exchange (Grover and Malhotra, 2003), TCT generally involves a set of restrictive

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481

473

assumptions that ignore the potential inuence of a rms extant governance forms, its portfolio of exchange transactions, and other rm-specic capabilities on value created through value chain activities. Thus, in equilibrium, TCT implies that all rms facing a similar set of exchange conditions and transactional attributes will reach similar conclusions regarding which activities to internalize and which activities to outsource (Leiblein and Miller, 2003). However, this proposition is untenable. Comparisons of internalization decisions across rms in the same industry suggest that the internalization decisions often differ dramatically. For instance, while companies such as IBM and Nokia have remained historically integrated, other companies such as Dell, HP, Ericsson, and Motorola outsource a variety of production functions ranging from R&D and engineering design to manufacturing and logistics. Moreover, variance in performance within and between these two groups of rms suggests a more complex set of factors affect the decision to outsource. Thus, using economizing motives alone limits the quality of discourse about the decision to outsource. In the following section, we extend the conceptual orientation of strategic outsourcing to consider resource-based factors. 4. Resource-based arguments for strategic outsourcing Drawing on the RBV, we extend transaction-based perspectives of strategic outsourcing by focusing attention on the role of specialized capabilities obtained through intermediate markets. This approach, however, requires a renement in the traditional role of boundaries. In particular, while conventional approaches to boundary conditions emphasize boundaries as an economizing buffer to environmental contingencies (Araujo et al., 2003), boundaries also act as a bridge to intermediate markets through relationship ties formed by a focal rm. In other words, boundaries integrate as well as separate a rm from its environment. In this work, we dene bridging as the process by which rms establish linkages with intermediate markets, suggesting that new capabilities may be obtained through relationships established within and across a rms relationship network (e.g. Burt, 1992; Granovetter, 1973). Herein, our focus is on the specialized capabilities provided through these relationships. The ability to access new and potentially more valuable capabilities is a critical driver of strategic outsourcing because these actions can fundamentally

alter a rms capability endowments (Morrow et al., 2005), making it easier to pursue new opportunities in the market. We maintain that different conditions affect the value of capabilities sourced from intermediate markets. In particular, we briey describe four resourcebased considerations for strategic outsourcing: complementarity of capabilities, strategic relatedness, relational capability-building mechanisms, and cooperative experience. 4.1. Complementarity of capabilities Beginning with Penrose (1959), strategy scholars have proposed that rms enhance value chain performance when they align with exchange partners in order to access complementary capabilities (e.g. Harrison et al., 1991; Rothaermel, 2001; Teece, 1986). Applied to strategic outsourcing, this argument suggests that rms seek ties with specialized rms that possess capabilities benecial to and needed by a focal rm. Such capabilities may be required to replace existing capabilities deployed along a value chain (e.g. substitution-based outsourcing) or to fulll a specic need not currently available in a rm (e.g. abstentionbased outsourcing). Capability complementarity reects a situation in which specialized capabilities enhance the value creation potential of a focal rms own capability endowments. Complementary capabilities are different, yet mutually supportive (Luo, 2002a; Hitt et al., 2001). Richardson (1972) suggests that capabilities are complementary when they represent different phases of production and require in some way or another to be coordinated in order to create maximum value (Richardson, 1972, p. 889). Where complementarities exist, the integration of internal and external capabilities enhances the potential performance gains rms realize, especially when economies of scope in production increase their market power (Mahoney and Pandian, 1992). When complementary capabilities are idiosyncratic and indivisible, and thus not otherwise available in the factor markets (Barney, 1986), strategic outsourcing can provide access to them. When complementary capabilities are linked together, they are especially difcult for competitors to duplicate because imitation not only requires obtaining the capabilities from intermediate markets, but also duplicating their deployment along a value chain (Holcomb et al., 2006). Barney (1988) suggested that acquiring rms gain above normal returns from acquisitions only when private or uniquely valuable

474

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481

synergies can be realized. Private and uniquely valuable synergy is created when information about the combination is obscured from rivals and when no other combination of rms could produce the same value. Research suggests that rms participating in exchange relationships that involve complementary capabilities perform better than rms with relationships that are formed to achieve cost economies (Harrison et al., 2001; Holcomb et al., 2006). Chung et al. (2000) also found the likelihood of alliance formation was positively related to the complementarity of investment banks capabilities. Similarly, other research suggests that rms consider the potential for complementarity an important partner selection criterion (Hitt et al., 2000, 2004). Different but complementary resources can help a rm improve scale economies, enhance responsiveness and innovative potential, and increase quality. Furthermore, because complementary capabilities are generally relationship-specic (Dyer and Singh, 1998), the value created may be unavailable to rivals through alternative sources (e.g. private; Barney, 1988), which may create a sustainable competitive advantage. Thus, strategic outsourcing relationships are more important to value-creating activities when these relationships provide specialized capabilities that are complementary to those currently held by a rm, especially when the integration of those capabilities across a value chain create private and uniquely valuable synergy. From the resource-based perspective, rm scope then is determined by the limits in specialization and the need to maximize gains from the combination of complementary capabilities along a value chain. By applying this logic, we argue that strategic outsourcing is a likely alternative when benets from specialized capabilities accessed from intermediate markets are based on complementarity. A complementarity perspective for strategic outsourcing suggests that a rm will ally with partners in whom the greatest complementarity exists between the rms capability endowments and those held by partners in intermediate markets. Thus, we conclude that the complementarity of capability endowments between a rm and its exchange partners has a positive effect on the likelihood the rm will pursue strategic outsourcing. Specically, we propose that: Proposition 4. The extent of complementarity that exists between a rms existing capability endowment and capabilities available from intermediate markets positively affects the likelihood a rm will pursue strategic outsourcing.

4.2. Strategic relatedness Strategic relatedness characterizes the degree to which rms are strategically similar; it reects the extent to which rms produce similar goods and services, serve similar markets, utilize similar production and supply chain systems, or rely on similar technologies. Relatedness provides a rationale for capability-sharing between rms (Prahalad and Bettis, 1986; Rumelt, 1974; Tsai, 2000). We expand this view of relatedness to include goal congruence and the commonality of knowledge-sharing routines. A high degree of relatedness between a rm and its exchange partners implies that they share common goals and are able to transfer knowledge between them more effectively. Accordingly, strategic relatedness is an important factor in a rms decision to pursue strategic outsourcing. Goal congruence is the degree to which rms operational, strategic, and performance objectives overlap and/or reinforce one another. When rms goals are not congruent, performance considered satisfactory to a focal rm may not be satisfactory to exchange partners and vice versa. Likewise, behavior promoting the interests of a focal rm may not promote the interests of those partners (Luo, 2002b). The presence of congruent goals helps to resolve these potential concerns. Despite the importance of goal congruity for success in exchange relationships (Luo, 2002a), evidence suggests a lack of goal congruity in many such relationships. As prot-maximizing goals are aligned, strategic outsourcing not only reduces monitoring and enforcement costs associated with the arrangement but also increases synergies as well. When goals are aligned, specialized rms are more likely to share common interests with a focal rm and thus be more supportive of exploiting new opportunities, even if such opportunities require these rms make additional investments. These synergies enable rms with common goals to more quickly exploit competitive imperfections observed in the market (Mahoney and Pandian, 1992), and thus hold the potential to create value beyond cost savings alone. Goal congruency also reduces conict and encourages cooperative behavior (Parkhe, 1993). Thus, rms with exchange partners that share congruent goals nd it easier to collaborate thereby enhancing the value of these relationships. Moreover, congruent goals improve the quality of relationships with exchange partners, which reduce the probability of opportunism (Granovetter, 1985; Uzzi, 1996). With the threat of opportunism reduced, exchange partners may be more

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481

475

willing to make additional resources available. Finally, congruent goals can reduce the need for formal contractual arrangements (Dyer and Singh, 1998). These informal agreements in turn promote adaptability and reduce the need for formal governance mechanisms (Uzzi, 1997). Thus, costs are reduced to the extent that less monitoring and enforcement is required. By contrast, incongruent goals often lead to the development of sub-goals, which exchange partners may pursue at the expense of a focal rm (Williamson, 1975). Incongruent goals also impede cooperation, limit the exchange of resources between exchange partners (Luo, 2002a), and can lead to early termination of these relationships. Furthermore, in the presence of incongruent goals, the time and energy spent resolving disputes detract from developing and implementing innovative strategies and can prevent valuable strategies from emerging. Incongruent goals therefore make it difcult to leverage specialized capabilities accessed by rms through strategic outsourcing. Thus, we argue that goal congruency affects the likelihood a rm will pursue capabilities from intermediate markets through strategic outsourcing. Specically, we propose that: Proposition 5a. Goal congruency between a rm and specialized rms from intermediate markets positively affect the likelihood a rm will pursue strategic outsourcing. A high degree of strategic relatedness also results when focal rms and specialized rms share common or similar knowledge-sharing routines (Dyer and Singh, 1998). We dene knowledge-sharing routines as regular patterns of interactions that permit the transfer, assimilation, and integration of new knowledge (Grant, 1996). The advantage of such routines lies in the ability to economize effort, which reduces coordination costs and affords greater capacity for knowledge-sharing between rms. Common knowledge-sharing routines may emerge as new intermediate markets are formed by increasing specialization within an industry (Jacobides, 2005). For example, with the emergence of intermediate markets specializing in information services, rms have increasingly transferred in-house computing systems resourcesi.e., programming and data center operations personnel, computer hardware, and enterprise application software as well as software design and programming processes and methodologiesto rms in these markets (e.g. EDS, IBM, and Accenture) who integrate and use these resources. As a result of these transfers, focal rms commonly share routines with their partners, which facilitates knowledge-sharing.

Further, because rms within an industry often share common knowledge structures, the emergence of vertically specialized markets in an industry increases the likelihood they will share common knowledgesharing routines. Accordingly, the emergence of intermediate markets increases the diffusion of knowledge and thus increases the probability of strategic outsourcing in an industry. Various scholars have argued that interorganizational learning is also critical to competitive success, noting that rms partners are, in many cases, the most important sources of new knowledge (Powell et al., 1996; Von Hippel, 1988). Common knowledge-sharing routines between a rm and its exchange partners enable more efcient absorption and use of acquired knowledge (Cohen and Levinthal, 1990). Absorptive capacity includes relationship-specic capabilities, such as knowledge-sharing routines, that arise when rms develop mutually specialized ways of exploiting each others capabilities. Dyer and Singh (1998) dene partner-specic absorptive knowledge as a function of (1) the extent to which rms develop overlapping knowledge bases, and (2) the extent to which partners develop routines that maximize the benet of their interactions. In sum, we conclude that effective knowledge-sharing routines are crucial to the exploitation of intermediate markets and thus affect the likelihood rms will pursue strategic outsourcing. Thus, we propose that: Proposition 5b. Commonality of knowledge-sharing routines between a rm and specialized rms from intermediate markets positively affects the likelihood a rm will pursue strategic outsourcing. 4.3. Relational capability-building mechanisms Evidence suggests that rm performance is affected by its abilities to integrate, build, and recongure resources. This process is referred to as dynamic capabilities (Teece et al., 1997). According to Loasby (1998, p. 139), managing capabilities is itself a capability; that is, rms develop capabilities over time that help them develop and link productive capabilities across a value chain. In particular, dynamic capabilities have been used to explain why rms in the same industry perform differently. For example, Helfat and Peteraf (2003) suggest that dynamic capabilities are embedded within rms and consist as a set of specic and identiable strategic and organizational routines. We use the work on the dynamic capabilities (e.g. Teece et al., 1997; Helfat and Peteraf, 2003) to dene relational

476

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481

capability-building mechanisms as routines that allow rms to synthesize and leverage specialized capabilities (Dyer and Singh, 1998; Makadok, 2001). Our view of these mechanisms also complements recombinatory (e.g. Galunic and Rodan, 1998; Grant, 1996; Kogut and Zander, 1992) views of capabilities, which emphasize the manipulation of competences residing within the rm. Accordingly, these mechanisms improve a rms ability to accumulate, integrate, and leverage specialized capabilities across a value chain, and affect its ability to pursue new opportunities in the future. Relational capability-building mechanisms also act as a focal point for learning and leveraging experiences from past capability-building actions, the results of those actions, and the rms future actions (Fiol and Lyles, 1985). They represent a more systematic and routine implementation of dedicated processes that support production activity involving the use of specialized capabilities. For example, Kale et al. (2002) found that rms with a dedicated capability to manage interrm relationships generated substantially higher market value than rms without such capability. Stated differently, rms that systematically invest in developing the ability to manage interrm relationships consistently perform better than others that choose not to make such investments. Zollo and Singh (2004) found that dedicated processes in which rms accumulate and explicitly codify acquisition experience signicantly improved overall acquisition performance by counteracting the coordination problems that future contingencies create. Accordingly, we expect investments in development of relational capability-building mechanisms will reduce coordination and integration costs, and improve the synergistic benets available through strategic outsourcing. In sum, relational capability-building mechanisms not only enable rms to generate greater value (Mahoney and Pandian, 1992; Makadok, 2001), but also create additional ambiguity that allow rms to sustain certain advantages over time (Rumelt, 1984). Under these conditions, we expect relational capabilitybuilding mechanisms to directly affect the likelihood rms pursue strategic outsourcing. Accordingly, we propose that: Proposition 6. Relational capability-building mechanisms positively affect the likelihood a rm will pursue strategic outsourcing. 4.4. Cooperative experience Strategic outsourcing relationships are formed within a social context that inuences selection

decisions and the pattern of interrm linkages that emerge. We represent cooperative experience as repeated ties, direct and indirect, formed with specialized rms from intermediate markets. Repeated ties with these rms create a pattern of relationships in which focal rms can access information about the reliability and performance of current and future partners (Granovetter, 1985; Uzzi, 1997). These ties reduce information asymmetries, heighten awareness about specialized capabilities and rms from intermediate markets, and establish a basis for trust. In turn, trust enhances the potential benets of strategic outsourcing by reducing the risk of adverse selection and improving the level of collaboration once such relationships are established. Herein, we dene trust as a rms condence in the reliability of a specialized rm to fulll its obligations and act fairly when the possibility for opportunism is present. Zaheer et al. (1998) found that organizational trust formed by repeated market exchanges is an important driver of interrm relationships because it enhances overall performance, decreases the complexity and costs of negotiation processes, and reduces conict. Examining international joint ventures (IJVs), Luo (2002b) found that cooperation had a linear effect on IJV performance, especially at higher levels of contract term specicity and contingency adaptability, which represents the extent to which unanticipated contingencies are accounted for and the guidelines for handling such contingencies are specied in a contract. We suggest that a focal rms cooperative experience with specialized rms reduces information asymmetry and opportunistic behavior, and thus enhances the potential benets of strategic outsourcing. Accordingly, cooperative experience increases the likelihood that additional outsourcing arrangements will be pursued with these rms in the future. Whereas, according to the transaction-based view, interrm cooperation occurs only when the costs of governing production can be minimized, the resourcebased perspective suggests that rms share capabilities in order to stimulate growth (Combs and Ketchen, 1999). As such, cooperation represents the willingness of a partner rm to pursue mutually compatible interests . . . rather than act opportunistically (Das and Teng, 1998, p. 492). Because market exchanges are embedded in a social context, the governance of interrm exchanges involve more than contracts; they depend on the level of cooperation between the rm and its partners (Luo, 2002b). For such relationally-governed exchanges, the enforcement of obligations, promises, and expectations involves social processes that promote norms of

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481

477

adaptation and information exchange. The signicance of cooperative experience is reected in the paradox that results: rms are expected to pursue strategies and programs that best serve their interests; however, interrm relationships require simultaneous investment and restraint in order for each party to gain maximum value from the relationship (cf. Das and Teng, 1998). The pattern of cooperation that emerges when intermediate markets form around specialized capabilities (Jacobides, 2005; Richardson, 1972) encourages rms to engage in repeated exchanges, especially as these markets mature improving accessibility to specialized capabilities. Repeated ties with specialized rms improve trust and increase the likelihood of future cooperation (Gulati, 1995). This pattern of connections broadens the rms scope and also affects the nature of ongoing capability development processes (Araujo et al., 2003; Jacobides and Winter, 2005), i.e., the way in which a rm shapes or improves its value chain over time. Changes in capabilities then reshape intermediate markets, allowing additional rms to participate. These changes facilitate growth in the number of potential suppliers but also increase the complexity of the selection and coordination process. Cooperative experience provides knowledge that helps in selecting and coordinating specialized capabilities in which relationship ties serve as a valuable conduit for rich information. Previous cooperation, dened in terms of both the length and quality of the exchange relationship, fosters a climate of trust, openness and condence. Repeated interactions or cycles of exchange between parties strengthen their willingness to trust each other and to expand the boundaries the relationship (Rousseau et al., 1998). Over time, such relationships become integrated into the social context that develops between rms, which fosters knowledge-sharing, supports adaptability, and deters opportunism. In so doing, the synergy from exchange relationships is magnied. Specically, exchange relationships based on trust are more likely to exploit market opportunities requiring access to resources from exchange partners. Such relationships are more likely to result in collaborative efforts to exploit emerging opportunities in the market. We conclude that cooperative experience affects the likelihood rms will pursue strategic outsourcing. Thus, we propose that: Proposition 7. Cooperative experience between a rm and specialized rms from intermediate markets, dened by the length and the quality of previous relationships, positively affects the likelihood a focal rm will pursue strategic outsourcing.

5. Discussion and conclusion The dominant goal most often cited for strategic outsourcing is cost efciency. According to this perspective, rms internalize value chain activity to minimize costs from opportunism and bounded rationality, the uncertainty of frequent market exchanges, and specic assets that may arise from this organizing arrangement. This rationale, in part, holds that specic governance mechanisms used to manage certain exchanges are more efcient and reects the view of rm boundaries as the point at which resource owners relinquish control over access and use. Accordingly, transaction-based perspectives develop logic for strategic outsourcing on the basis of economizing motives linking governance choices to attributes of an exchange. The restrictive assumptions offered by TCT suggest that, in equilibrium, rms with similar exchange conditions will make the same decisions about strategic outsourcing. However, the arguments presented herein show this proposition to be incomplete. Strategic outsourcing enables rms to bridge boundaries and access capabilities from intermediate markets that are subsequently deployed along the value chain. According to the RBV, resource heterogeneity leads to otherwise similar rms displaying signicantly different ways of accomplishing the same set of value chain activities, emboldened by the use of different capabilities. We argued that by linking value chain activities with intermediate markets for the purpose of gaining access to valuable specialized capabilities, rms can accrue value beyond the cost economies available through more efcient governance mechanisms. Thus, we augmented transaction-based arguments with resource-based perspectives to sharpen the focus on conditions that might favor the use of specialized capabilities. The purpose of this work has been to extend our understanding of strategic outsourcing by integrating transaction-based and resource-based logics. First, we offered a more concise denition of strategic outsourcing and extended the focus on cost economies resulting from more efcient governance mechanisms to consider value that is created when rms more effectively leverage the specialized capabilities that outsourcing relationships provide. An important distinction introduced herein is how rms understanding of their capabilities and those of specialized rms affect their decision to strategically outsource. We also showed how the emergence of new intermediate markets (e.g. vertical disintegration; Jacobides, 2005;

478

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481

Richardson, 1972) provides a theoretical framework explaining the logic for a capabilities view of strategic outsourcing. In particular, we shift the focus on value creation from different exchange conditions to value chain structures and to the process by which rms produce goods and services. Accordingly, intermediate markets that maintain specialized capabilities emerge as conditions within an industry intensify the partitioning of production activity. As a result, boundaries shift to accommodate access to specialized capabilities that are then deployed along a rms value chain. Second, we extended the view of boundaries as providing a bridge between rms and intermediate markets (Araujo et al., 2003) to explain how value chain linkages are enabled through strategic outsourcing. On the one hand, boundaries provide a space for the development of valuable and difcult-to-imitate capabilities within the rmthe buffering function. On the other hand, boundaries provide a bridge to access specialized capabilities outside the control of the rm. While TCT generally establishes rm boundaries on the basis of anticipated efciencies, our extended model of strategic outsourcing accommodates a view of boundaries in which rms join with exchange partners to create synergies they cannot realize alone. This extended model of strategic outsourcing suggests several research questions worthy of further investigation. First, we still know very little about the process by which specialized capabilities are deployed and integrated along a value chain. For example, how do rms integrate specialized capabilities along the value chain? What performance measures best reect synergies created by the use of specialized capabilities across the value chain? Although exchange transactions through the market can often be economized, value derived from strategic outsourcing lies more in the combinative value of specialized capabilities available through intermediate markets. Thus, scholars should closely examine the underlying processes involved with integration and measurement of specialized capabilities along a value chain. Second, our understanding of the sources of value creation is limited. Do focal rms pursuing outsourcing benet more by selecting valuable capabilities from intermediate markets or by more effectively integrating these capabilities in difcult-to-imitate ways? Using our model of strategic outsourcing, for example, scholars can evaluate Makadoks (2001) assertions regarding synergies from the two main sources of rent generationresource-picking and capability-building within a strategic outsourcing context. According to this perspective, specialized capabilities affect rm

performance by enhancing the productivity of other capabilities that rms possess. Finally, as strategic outsourcing arrangements continue to expand in scope and complexity, scholars should more closely examine specic attributes of outsourcing deals, especially when such deals involve the divestment of assets by a focal rm as part of the exchange. In some cases, these arrangements involve the exchange of substantial nancial considerations for assets controlled by a focal rm. Where is value created (and lost) by focal rms and intermediate markets? How do nancial considerations affect focal rms decision to outsource? What are the implementation challenges? How do investors view these arrangements? Thus, research that provides a more comprehensive view of strategic outsourcing deals and anticipates aggregate economic considerations is needed. The value-creating potential of the rm is at the heart of the theory of the rm. Adopting a model of strategic outsourcing can help scholars and practitioners to understand the strategic, operational, and nancial motivations and incentives behind this organizing arrangement. If outsourcing is pursued strategically, rms can achieve above normal returns. Examining the different conditions in which value creation occurs can extend managements view of strategic outsourcing and provide a new paradigm for supply chain practitioners to demonstrate the practical benets of strategic outsourcing. Acknowledgements We thank David Ketchen, Tomas Hult, and the two anonymous reviewers for their helpful suggestions. We also beneted from valuable comments and suggestions by Sharon Alvarez, Lorraine Eden, and Michael Holmes on earlier drafts of this article. References
Afuah, A., 2001. Dynamic boundaries of the rm: are rms better off being vertically integrated in the face of a technological change? Academy of Management Journal 44 (6), 12111228. Alvarez, S.A., Barney, J.B., 2001. How entrepreneurial rms can benet from alliances with large partners. Academy of Management Executive 15 (1), 139148. Araujo, L., Dubois, A., Gadde, L.E., 2003. The multiple boundaries of the rm. Journal of Management Studies 40 (5), 12551277. Argyres, N., 1996. Evidence on the role of rm capabilities in vertical integration decisions. Strategic Management Journal 17 (2), 129 150. Argyres, N.S., Liebeskind, J.P., 1999. Contractual commitments, bargaining power, and governance inseparability: incorporating

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481 history into transaction cost theory. Academy of Management Review 24 (1), 4963. Bacharach, S.B., Lawler, E.J., 1981. Bargaining: Power, Tactics, and Outcomes. Jossey-Bass, San Francisco. Barney, J.B., 1986. Strategic factor markets: expectations, luck and business strategy. Management Science 32 (10), 12301241. Barney, J.B., 1988. Returns to bidding rms in mergers and acquisitions: reconsidering the relatedness hypothesis. Strategic Management Journal 9, 7178. Barney, J.B., 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management 17 (1), 99120. Billi, J.E., Pai, C.W., Spahlinger, D.A., 2004. Strategic outsourcing of clinical services: a model for volume-stressed academic medical centers. Health Care Management Review 29 (4), 291297. Burgelman, R.A., Maidique, M.A., Wheelwright, S.C., 1996. Strategic Management of Technology and Innovation, 2nd ed. Irwin, Burr Ridge, IL. Burt, R.S., 1992. Structural Holes: The Social Structure of Competition. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. Cachon, G.P., Harker, P.T., 2002. Competition and outsourcing with scale economies. Management Science 48 (10), 13141333. Carbone, J., 2005. EMS prots get squeezed. Purchasing 134, 2933. Carney, H., 1998. The competitiveness of networked production: the role of trust and asset specicity. Journal of Management Studies 35 (4), 457479. Chen, I.J., Paulraj, A., 2004. Towards a theory of supply chain management: the constructs and measurements. Journal of Operations Management 22 (2), 119150. Chen, I.J., Paulraj, A., Lado, A.A., 2004a. Strategic purchasing, supply management, and rm performance. Journal of Operations Management 22 (5), 505523. Chen, Y.M., Ishikawa, J., Yu, Z.H., 2004b. Trade liberalization and strategic outsourcing. Journal of International Economics 63 (2), 419436. Chung, S., Singh, H., Lee, K., 2000. Complementarity, status similarity and social capital as drivers of alliance formation. Strategic Management Journal 21 (1), 122. Clark, K.B., Fujimoto, T., 1992. Product Development Performance. Harvard Business School Press, Boston, MA. Coase, R.H., 1937. The nature of the rm. Economica 4 (16), 386405. Coase, R.H., 1988. The nature of the rm: inuence. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 4 (1), 3347. Cohen, W.M., Levinthal, D.A., 1990. Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly 35 (1), 128152. Combs, J.G., Ketchen, D.J., 1999. Explaining interrm cooperation and performance: toward a reconciliation of predictions from the resource-based view and organizational economics. Strategic Management Journal 20 (9), 867888. Conner, K.R., 1991. A historical comparison of resource-based theory and 5 schools of thought within industrial organization economics: do we have a new theory of the rm. Journal of Management 17 (1), 121154. DAveni, R.A., Ravenscraft, D.J., 1994. Economies of integration versus bureaucracy costs: does vertical integration improve performance. Academy of Management Journal 37 (5), 11671206. Das, T.K., Teng, B.S., 1998. Between trust and control: developing condence in partner cooperation in alliances. Academy of Management Review 23 (3), 491512. Dutta, S., Narasimhan, O., Rajiv, S., 2005. Conceptualizing and measuring capabilities: methodology and empirical application. Strategic Management Journal 26 (3), 277285.

479

Dyer, J.H., Singh, H., 1998. The relational view: cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage. Academy of Managemsent Review 23 (4), 660679. Fine, C.H., Whitney, D.E., 1999. Is the make-buy decision a core competence? In: Muffato, M., Pawar, K. (Eds.), Logistics in the Information Age, Servizi Graci Editoriali. Pandova, Italy, pp. 3163. Fiol, C.M., Lyles, M.A., 1985. Organizational learning. Academy of Management Review 10 (4), 803813. Folta, T.B., 1998. Governance and uncertainty: the trade-off between administrative control and commitment. Strategic Management Journal 19 (11), 10071028. Galunic, D.C., Rodan, S., 1998. Resource recombinations in the rm: knowledge structures and the potential for Schumpeterian innovation. Strategic Management Journal 19 (12), 11931201. Ghoshal, S., Moran, P., 1996. Bad for practice: a critique of the transaction cost theory. Academy of Management Review 21 (1), 1347. Gilley, K.M., Rasheed, A., 2000. Making more by doing less: an analysis of outsourcing and its effects on rm performance. Journal of Management 26 (4), 763790. Granovetter, M.S., 1973. Strength of weak ties. American Journal of Sociology 78 (6), 13601380. Granovetter, M.S., 1985. Economic action and social structure: the problem of embeddedness. American Journal of Sociology 91 (3), 481510. Grant, R.M., 1996. Toward a knowledge-based theory of the rm. Strategic Management Journal 17 (Winter Special Issue), 109 122. Green, J.R., 1986. Vertical integration and assurance of markets. In: Stiglitz, J.E., Mathewson, G.F. (Eds.), New Developments in the Analysis of Market Structure. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp. 177207. Grossman, S.J., Hart, O.D., 1986. The costs and benets of ownership: a theory of vertical and lateral integration. Journal of Political Economy 94 (4), 691719. Grover, V., Malhotra, M.K., 2003. Transaction cost framework in operations and supply chain management research: theory and measurement. Journal of Operations Management 21 (4), 457 473. Gulati, R., 1995. Social structure and alliance formation patterns: a longitudinal analysis. Administrative Science Quarterly 40 (4), 619652. Hamel, G., 1991. Competition for competence and inter-partner learning within international strategic alliances. Strategic Management Journal 12 (Special Issue), 83103. Harrigan, K.R., 1985. Vertical integration and corporate strategy. Academy of Management Journal 28 (2), 397425. Harrigan, K.R., 1986. Matching vertical integration strategies to competitive conditions. Strategic Management Journal 7 (6), 535555. Harrison, J.S., Hitt, M.A., Hoskisson, R.E., Ireland, R.D., 1991. Synergies and postacquisition performance: differences versus similarities in resource allocations. Journal of Management 17 (1), 173190. Harrison, J.S., Hitt, M.A., Hoskisson, R.E., Ireland, R.D., 2001. Resource complementarity in business combinations: extending the logic to organizational alliances. Journal of Management 27 (6), 679690. Helfat, C.E., Peteraf, M.A., 2003. The dynamic resource-based view: capability lifecycles. Strategic Management Journal 24 (10), 9971010.

480

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481 on technological performance. Strategic Management Journal 23 (9), 817833. Leiblein, M.J., Miller, D.J., 2003. An empirical examination of transaction- and rm-level inuences on the vertical boundaries of the rm. Strategic Management Journal 24, 839859. Loasby, B.J., 1998. The organisation of capabilities. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 35 (2), 139160. Luo, Y.D., 2002a. Contract, cooperation, and performance in international joint ventures. Strategic Management Journal 23 (10), 903919. Luo, Y.D., 2002b. Building trust in cross-cultural collaborations: toward a contingency perspective. Journal of Management 28 (5), 669694. Madhok, A., 2002. Reassessing the fundamentals and beyond: Ronald Coase, the transaction cost and resource-based theories of the rm and the institutional structure of production. Strategic Management Journal 23 (6), 535550. Mahoney, J.T., Pandian, J.R., 1992. The resource-based view within the conversation of strategic management. Strategic Management Journal 13 (5), 363380. Makadok, R., 2001. Toward a synthesis of the resource-based and dynamic-capability views of rent creation. Strategic Management Journal 22 (5), 387401. March, J.G., Simon, H.A., 1958. Organizations, 1st ed. Wiley, New York, NY. McEvily, B., Zaheer, A., 1999. Bridging ties: a source of rm heterogeneity in competitive capabilities. Strategic Management Journal 20 (12), 11331156. Miner, A.S., Amburgey, T.L., Stearns, T.M., 1990. Interorganizational linkages and population-dynamics: buffering and transformational shields. Administrative Science Quarterly 35 (4), 689713. Morrow, J.L., Sirmon, D.G., Hitt, M.A., Holcomb, T.R., 2005. Creating Value in the Face of Declining Performance: Designing Actions to Effect Organizational Recovery. Paper presented at the 2005. Strategic Management Society, Orlando, Florida. Mowery, D.C., Oxley, J.E., Silverman, B.S., 1996. Strategic alliances and interrm knowledge transfer. Strategic Management Journal 17, 7791. Murray, J.Y., Kotabe, M., 1999. Sourcing strategies of US service companies: a modied transaction-cost analysis. Strategic Management Journal 20 (9), 791809. Parkhe, A., 1993. Strategic alliance structuring: A game theoretic and transaction cost examination of interrm cooperation. Academy of Management Journal 36 (4), 794829. Penrose, E., 1959. The Theory and Growth of the Firm, 3rd ed. Oxford University Press Inc., New York, NY. Petersen, K.J., Handeld, R.B., Ragatz, G.L., 2005. Supplier integration into new product development: coordinating product, process and supply chain design. Journal of Operations Management 23 (3/4), 371388. Poppo, L., Zenger, T., 1998. Testing alternative theories of the rm: transaction cost, knowledge-based, and measurement explanations for make-or-buy decisions in information services. Strategic Management Journal 19 (9), 853877. Porter, M.E., 1985. Competitive Advantage: Creating and Sustaining Superior Performance, 1st ed. The Free Press, New York, NY. Powell, W.W., Koput, K.W., Smith-Doerr, L., 1996. Interorganizational collaboration and the locus of innovation: networks of learning in biotechnology. Administrative Science Quarterly 41 (1), 116145.

Hitt, M.A., Hoskisson, R.E., Johnson, R.A., Moesel, D.D., 1996. The market for corporate control and rm innovation. Academy of Management Journal 39 (5), 10841119. Hitt, M.A., Dacin, M.T., Levitas, E., Arregle, J.-L., Borza, A., 2000. Partner selection in emerging and developed market contexts: resource-based and organizational learning perspectives. Academy of Management Journal 43 (3), 449467. Hitt, M.A., Harrison, J.S., Ireland, R.D., 2001. Mergers and Acquisitions: Creating Value for Stakeholders. Oxford University Press, New York. Hitt, M.A., Ahlstrom, D., Dacin, M.T., Levitas, E., Svobodina, L., 2004. The institutional effects on strategic alliance partner selection in transition economies: China versus Russia. Organization Science 15 (2), 173185. Hoetker, G., 2005. How much you know versus how well I know you: selecting a supplier for a technically innovative component. Strategic Management Journal 26 (1), 7596. Holcomb, T.R., Holmes, R.M., Hitt, M.A., 2006. Diversication to achieve scale and scope: the strategic implications of resource management for value creation. In: Baum, J.A.C., Dobrev, S. (Eds.), Advances in Strategic Management: Ecology and Strategy, vol. 23. JAI-Elsevier Science, Oxford, UK. Inkpen, A.C., 2001. Strategic alliances. In: Hitt, M.A., Freeman, R.E., Harrison, J.S. (Eds.), The Blackwell Handbook of Strategic Management. Blackwell Publishers Inc., Malden, MA, pp. 409 432. Insinga, R.C., Werle, M.J., 2000. Linking outsourcing to business strategy. Academy of Management Executive 14 (4), 5870. Ireland, R.D., Hitt, M.A., Vaidyanath, D., 2002. Alliance management as a source of competitive advantage. Journal of Management 28 (3), 413446. Jacobides, M.G., 2005. Industry change through vertical disintegration: how and why markets emerged in mortgage banking. Academy of Management Journal 48 (3), 465498. Jacobides, M.G., Hitt, L.M., 2005. Losing sight of the forest for the trees? Productive capabilities and gains from trade as drivers of vertical scope. Strategic Management Journal 26 (13), 12091227. Jacobides, M.G., Winter, S.G., 2005. The co-evolution of capabilities and transaction costs: explaining the institutional structure of production. Strategic Management Journal 26 (5), 395413. Jones, G.R., 1983. Transaction costs, property rights, and organizational culture: an exchange perspective. Administrative Science Quarterly 28 (3), 454467. Jones, G.R., Hill, C.W.L., 1988. Transaction cost analysis of strategystructure choice. Strategic Management Journal 9, 159172. Kale, P., Dyer, J.H., Singh, H., 2002. Alliance capability, stock market response, and long-term alliance success: the role of the alliance function. Strategic Management Journal 23 (8), 747767. Klein, B., Crawford, R.G., Alchian, A.A., 1978. Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process. Journal of Law and Economics 21 (2), 297326. Kogut, B., Zander, U., 1992. Knowledge of the rm, combinative capabilities, and the replication of technology. Organization Science 3 (3), 383397. Langlois, R.N., Robertson, P.L., 1995. Firms, Markets, and Economic Change: A Dynamic Theory of Business Institutions. Routledge, London, UK. Lavie, D., 2006. Capability reconguration: an analysis of incumbent responses to technological change. Academy of Management Review 31 (1), 153174. Leiblein, M.J., Reuer, J.J., Dalsace, F., 2002. Do make or buy decisions matter? The inuence of organizational governance

T.R. Holcomb, M.A. Hitt / Journal of Operations Management 25 (2007) 464481 Prahalad, C.K., Bettis, R.A., 1986. The dominant logic: a new linkage between diversity and performance. Strategic Management Journal 7 (6), 485501. Quinn, J.B., Hilmer, F.G., 1994. Strategic outsourcing. Sloan Management Review 35 (4), 4355. Quinn, J.B., 1999. Strategic outsourcing: leveraging knowledge capabilities. Sloan Management Review 40 (4), 921. Richardson, G.B., 1972. Organisation of industry. Economic Journal 82 (327), 883896. Roberts, V., 2001. Managing strategic outsourcing in the healthcare industry. Journal of Healthcare Management 46 (4), 239249. Robertson, T.S., Gatignon, H., 1998. Technology development mode: a transaction cost conceptualization. Strategic Management Journal 19 (6), 515531. Rothaermel, F.T., 2001. Incumbents advantage through exploiting complementary assets via interrm cooperation. Strategic Management Journal 22 (6/7), 687699. Rothaermel, F.T., Hitt, M.A., Jobe, L.A., in press. Balancing vertical integration and strategic outsourcing: effects on product portfolio, product success, and rm performance. Strategic Management Journal. Rousseau, D.M., Sitkin, S.B., Burt, R.S., Camerer, C., 1998. Not so different after all: a cross-discipline view of trust. Academy of Management Review 23 (3), 393404. Rumelt, R.P., 1974. Strategy, Structure and Economic Performance. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. Rumelt, R.P., 1984. Towards a strategic theory of the rm. In: Lamb, R.B. (Ed.), Competitive Strategic Management. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ, pp. 556570. Salvador, F., Forza, C., Rungtusanatham, M., 2002. Modularity, product variety, production volume, and component sourcing: theorizing beyond generic prescriptions. Journal of Operations Management 20 (5), 549575. Schelling, T., 1956. An essay on bargaining. American Economic Review 46 (3), 281306. Schoonhoven, C.B., 1981. Problems with contingency theory: testing assumptions hidden within the language of contingency theory. Administrative Science Quarterly 26 (3), 349377. Shy, O., Stenbacka, R., 2003. Strategic outsourcing. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 50 (2), 203224. Silverman, B.S., Nickerson, J.A., Freeman, J., 1997. Protability, transactional alignment, and organizational mortality in the U.S. trucking industry. Strategic Management Journal 18, 3152. Sirmon, D.G., Hitt, M.A., Ireland, R. D., in press. Managing rm resources in dynamic environments to create value: looking inside the black box. Academy of Management Review. Song, M., Montoya-Weiss, M.M., 2001. The effect of perceived technological uncertainty on Japanese new product development. Academy of Management Journal 44 (1), 6180.

481

Stigler, G.J., 1951. The division of labor is limited by the extent of the market. Journal of Political Economy 59 (3), 185193. Teece, D.J., 1980. Economies of scope and the scope of the enterprise. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 1 (3), 223247. Teece, D.J., 1986. Proting from technological innovation: implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy 15 (6), 285305. Teece, D.J., 1992. Competition, cooperation, and innovation: organizational arrangements for regimes of rapid technological progress. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 18 (1), 125. Teece, D.J., Pisano, G., Shuen, A., 1997. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal 18 (7), 509 533. Tsai, W.P., 2000. Social capital, strategic relatedness and the formation of intraorganizational linkages. Strategic Management Journal 21 (9), 925939. Uzzi, B., 1996. The sources and consequences of embeddedness for the economic performance of organizations: the network effect. American Sociological Review 61 (4), 674698. Uzzi, B., 1997. Social structure and competition in interrm networks: the paradox of embeddedness. Administrative Science Quarterly 42 (1), 3567. Von Hippel, E., 1988. Sources of Innovation. Oxford University Press, New York, NY. Walker, G., Weber, D., 1984. A transaction cost approach to make-orbuy decisions. Administrative Science Quarterly 29 (3), 373391. Walker, G., Weber, D., 1987. Supplier competition, uncertainty, and make-or-buy decisions. Academy of Management Journal 30 (3), 589596. Wernerfelt, B., 1984. A resource-based view of the rm. Strategic Management Journal 5, 171180. Williamson, O.E., 1975. Markets and Hierarchies. Free Press, New York, NY. Williamson, O.E., 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. Free Press, New York, NY. Williamson, O.E., 1991. Comparative economic organization: the analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quarterly 36 (2), 269296. Williamson, O.E., 1999. Strategy research: governance and competence perspectives. Strategic Management Journal 20 (12), 1087 1108. Winter, S.G., 2003. Understanding dynamic capabilities. Strategic Management Journal 24 (10), 991995. Zaheer, A., McEvily, B., Perrone, V., 1998. Does trust matter? Exploring the effects of interorganizational and interpersonal trust on performance. Organization Science 9 (2), 141159. Zollo, M., Singh, H., 2004. Deliberate learning in corporate acquisitions: post-acquisition strategies and integration capability in U.S. bank mergers. Strategic Management Journal 25 (13), 12331256.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi