Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 44

December 11, 2002 No.

21

Reforming the Antidumping Agreement


A Road Map for WTO Negotiations
by Brink Lindsey and Dan Ikenson

Executive Summary
In the current Doha Round of World pant abuses that allow trade-restrictive
Trade Organization talks, negotiations are antidumping remedies to punish normal,
now under way on the arcane, highly tech- healthy, import competition. Such abuses
nical, and intensely controversial subject of run afoul of what supporters of antidump-
antidumping rules. On the agenda are pos- ing claim is the purpose of the laws: name-
sible changes to the WTO Antidumping ly, to ensure a “level playing field” by target-
Agreement, which sets the standards that ing “unfair” trade practices that reflect
govern national antidumping laws. underlying market distortions. Accordingly,
In the United States, current antidump- changes to antidumping rules are needed to
ing rules enjoy strong political support. bring national laws into conformity with
Defenders of the status quo allege that the basic principles, concepts, and objectives
changes to the Antidumping Agreement will of the Antidumping Agreement.
“weaken” the U.S. law and thereby expose This paper sets forth a detailed road map
American industries to unfair, “dumped” for the WTO antidumping negotiations. We
competition. In response to such concerns start by fleshing out the basic concepts, prin-
and at the United States’ insistence, the ciples, and objectives of the Antidumping
Doha declaration that launched the new Agreement—as elucidated by the justifica-
antidumping talks insists on “preserving the tions for antidumping laws offered by the
basic concepts, principles and effectiveness of U.S. government and prominent supporters
[the Antidumping Agreement] and [its] of the U.S. law. Working from that founda-
instruments and objectives.” tion, we then outline 21 reform proposals
Fears of weakening the U.S. law are mis- designed to improve antidumping laws’ aim
placed. The object of WTO negotiations is and limit the collateral damage inflicted on
not to weaken national antidumping laws business practices that have nothing to do
but to improve them—by curtailing ram- with “unfair trade.”

Brink Lindsey is director of the Cato Institute’s Center for Trade Policy Studies. Dan Ikenson is
a trade policy analyst with the center.
The WTO of our trading partners, many of whom main-
antidumping negoti- Introduction tain serious unfair trade practices, continue to
seek to weaken these laws,” the letter stated. 4
ations face strong In November 2001, representatives of 142 The TPA legislation almost included an amend-
political opposition countries convened in Doha, Qatar, and launched ment that would have provided for the denial of spe-
a new round of global trade negotiations. cial “fast-track” voting procedures (i.e., an up-or-
in the United States. Included on the agenda of this Doha Round of down vote by Congress without amendments and
World Trade Organization talks is the arcane, within specified time periods) to those parts of any
highly technical, and intensely controversial sub- trade agreement that made changes to antidumping
ject of antidumping rules. Specifically, talks will rules. This so-called Dayton-Craig amendment
focus on possible changes to the existing WTO passed in the original Senate TPA bill but was even-
Antidumping Agreement, which governs what tually dropped in conference committee.
WTO member states can and cannot do to pro- Mindful of domestic political pressures,
tect domestic industries from “dumped” or both the Clinton and Bush administrations
“unfairly priced” import competition.1 strongly opposed inclusion of antidumping on
The WTO antidumping negotiations face the negotiating agenda for the new round. The
strong political opposition in the United Clinton administration refused to budge on
States. According to that opposition, any the issue, and the resulting impasse between
change in the WTO Antidumping Agreement the U.S. government and other WTO mem-
threatens to “weaken” the U.S. antidumping bers was one of the major contributors to the
law and so expose American industries to failure to launch a new round at the Seattle
unfair foreign competition. Such concerns are ministerial conference in 1999.5 The Bush
reflected in the “trade promotion authority” administration sought to continue its predeces-
(TPA) legislation passed by Congress in sor’s position but ultimately bowed to over-
August 2002. Language in the bill instructs the whelming international pressure and agreed at
president, in any trade negotiations, to Doha to put antidumping rules on the table.
Although the U.S. government made that
preserve the ability of the United States important concession, it still sought to limit the
to enforce rigorously its trade laws, scope of WTO negotiations. Specifically, at
including the antidumping, countervail- U.S. insistence, the provision in the Doha min-
ing duty, and safeguard laws, and avoid isterial declaration that authorizes antidump-
agreements which lessen the effective- ing talks reads in relevant part:
ness of domestic and international disci-
plines on unfair trade, especially dump- In light of experience and of the increas-
ing and subsidies, in order to ensure that ing application of these instruments by
United States workers, agricultural pro- Members, we agree to negotiations
ducers, and firms can compete fully on aimed at clarifying and improving disci-
fair terms and enjoy the benefits of reci- plines under the [Antidumping
procal trade concessions.2 Agreement], while preserving the basic con-
cepts, principles and effectiveness of [the
Nearly identical language was incorporated Agreement] and [its] instruments and
into a resolution passed by the House of objectives. . . . In the initial phase of the
Representatives on November 7, 2001, on the negotiations, participants will indicate the
eve of the Doha ministerial conference. That provisions, including disciplines on trade
resolution passed by a vote of 410 to 4.3 And 62 distorting practices, that they seek to clarify
senators signed a letter to the president in May and improve in the subsequent phase.6
2001 warning him not to agree to any trade
deals that would weaken the antidumping or The commitment to preserve the “basic
other trade remedy laws. “Unfortunately, some concepts, principles and effectiveness” of the

2
agreement and its “instruments and objectives” tious for creative thinking about how negotia-
was inserted after an effort by the United tions should proceed. In this paper we attempt
States to limit the scope of permissible changes to outline a road map for WTO antidumping
to antidumping rules. The inclusion of “disci- negotiations in the Doha Round. We begin
plines on trade distorting practices” on the with the language of the ministerial declaration
negotiating agenda may open the door to and then proceed to identify the basic con-
changes that expand national governments’ cepts, principles, and objectives of the
authority to apply antidumping remedies. Antidumping Agreement—as delineated, not
The resistance to changes in the WTO by critics of antidumping practice, but by the
Antidumping Agreement is based on a funda- U.S. government and policy experts who sup-
mental misunderstanding of what antidump- port the use of antidumping remedies. We then
ing laws actually do in practice. Those laws are examine how antidumping laws actually work
defended as necessary bulwarks against unfair in practice and compare that reality with the
trade practices. But antidumping laws—in the purposes those laws are supposed to serve.
United States and dozens of other countries— That examination defines the basic work
have little to do with targeting unfair trade program of current and future WTO antidump-
under any plausible definition of that term. ing negotiations: to reduce the gap between con-
Stiff antidumping duties are routinely imposed temporary antidumping practice and the
The resistance to
against products of foreign firms that are agreed-upon concepts, principles, and objectives changes in the
engaged in perfectly normal and unexception- of the Antidumping Agreement. We then elab- WTO
able commercial practices. At the root of the orate upon that basic mission with detailed
problem are serious flaws in the current rules analysis of the specific changes that are needed Antidumping
for conducting antidumping investigations. in the Antidumping Agreement. Agreement is based
Because of those flaws, there is at present very
little connection between the stated objectives
on a fundamental
of antidumping policy and the actual effects of Identifying Antidumping’s misunderstanding
antidumping actions.
Objectives of what antidump-
Accordingly, the fear that changes in WTO
antidumping rules will expose American WTO antidumping negotiations should ing laws actually do
industries to unfair competition is entirely mis- begin at the beginning by attempting to define in practice.
placed. Significant changes in those rules are the basic concepts, principles, and objectives of
needed, not to “weaken” national laws, but to the Antidumping Agreement. No such
improve them by closing the yawning gap attempt has been made in any previous WTO
between what they are supposed to do and or General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
what they actually do. negotiations. That is an oversight whose cor-
The newly launched Doha Round of WTO rection is long overdue.
talks offers the chance to close that gap. The oversight may be explained by the fact
Although the U.S. government attempted to that antidumping has been around much
limit the scope of negotiations with restrictive longer than the multilateral trading system.
language in the Doha ministerial declaration, a Antidumping laws originated in the early years
proper reading of that language makes clear that of the 20th century; the U.S. law, for example,
far-reaching changes in antidumping rules are dates back to 1921, 7 and laws in Canada,
not precluded. Indeed, that language—with its Australia, New Zealand, Great Britain, and
emphasis on the basic concepts, principles, and France go back even further. These laws thus
objectives of the Antidumping Agreement— predate even the original 1947 GATT treaty,
provides an excellent point of departure for pro- Article VI of which provides basic authority for
ductive negotiations. national governments to apply antidumping
WTO antidumping negotiations remain in remedies. Subsequent negotiations to elaborate
their preliminary stages, so the timing is propi- multilateral standards for the use of antidump-

3
ing remedies—the Kennedy Round talks that tion. As negotiations proceed, many countries can
produced an Antidumping Code in 1967, the be expected to push antidumping reform as one of
Tokyo Round talks that revised that code in their top priorities. Accordingly, the course of the
1979, and the Uruguay Round talks that pro- antidumping negotiations is likely to have impor-
duced the current 1994 WTO Antidumping tant implications for the overall outcome of the
Agreement—simply assumed the background round. Even if the U.S. government persists in
fact of national antidumping laws without resisting major antidumping reforms, it has a com-
making any effort to establish a consensus on pelling interest in avoiding a rancorous deadlock
why such laws are needed or what purposes that jeopardizes its own negotiating priorities.
they are meant to serve. Unless some common ground is first estab-
With so much water under the bridge, why lished, negotiators with opposing interests will
focus now on what might be considered simply talk past each other. Antidumping
abstract or theoretical issues? The most obvious negotiations are simultaneously highly techni-
reason lies in the language of the ministerial cal and intensely controversial: the details are
declaration that launched the Doha Round. comprehensible only to experienced specialists,
That declaration authorizes negotiations to and the general subject matter is one on which
amend the existing Antidumping Agreement views are sharply conflicting and strongly held.
“while preserving the basic concepts, principles That combination is a recipe for impasse and
and effectiveness of [the Agreement] and [its] acrimony, not productive results.
instruments and objectives.” To ensure that A preliminary focus on defining the basic
negotiations do not exceed the scope of this concepts, principles, and objectives of the
limiting language, it is necessary for parties to Antidumping Agreement could help avoid a
determine in the first instance what the basic deadlock that might wreck the whole round. In
concepts, principles, and objectives actually are. many other contentious sectors—for example,
Furthermore, antidumping negotiations agriculture and services—parties have made
promise to play a critical role in determining progress by agreeing on basic principles with a
the overall success of the Doha Round. In prior commitment to gradual (if unspecified) imple-
rounds, antidumping was at best a second-tier mentation of those principles in the future.
issue. The United States and what is now the Such an approach might be the only way for
European Union accounted for the over- the U.S. government to reconcile its present
whelming majority of antidumping cases, and opposition to significant changes in the
they were united in opposing anything but Antidumping Agreement with its overriding
marginal changes in their laws. Although many interest in a successful round. If the United
A preliminary focus other countries may have had an interest in States were to accept a clear definition of the
restricting antidumping abuses, none with any basic concepts, principles, and objectives of the
on defining the bargaining power made that interest a top pri- Antidumping Agreement, other countries
basic concepts, ority. Consequently, the United States and the might be satisfied with fairly modest changes
principles, and European Union were able to contain to it in the current round. The U.S. government
antidumping reform initiatives within narrow could then remove the antidumping issue as an
objectives of the limits without any real sacrifice of their own obstacle to its own major negotiating objectives
Antidumping major negotiating objectives. and ultimately bring home an agreement that
This time, the situation is different. With the keeps controversial changes to U.S. law within
Agreement could proliferation of antidumping laws in recent years, tolerable limits.
help avoid a the threat that antidumping abuses pose to the Meanwhile, supporters of antidumping
deadlock that world trading system has become an issue of reform have a strong interest in initial discus-
intense and widespread concern. There was over- sions on basic concepts, principles, and objec-
might wreck the whelming support for the inclusion of antidump- tives. Such discussions, if conducted properly,
whole round. ing on the agenda of the Doha Round; indeed, the could significantly strengthen the reformers’
United States was completely isolated in opposi- bargaining position. Specifically, they could

4
enable reformers to claim the rhetorical high antidumping would at last find themselves on Negotiations aimed
ground of support for “fairness” and a “level the negotiating defensive. at fleshing out the
playing field.” The effects of changing the terms of debate
At present, defenders of antidumping stake would be felt within the WTO negotiations basic concepts,
their case on the grounds of “fairness” and a themselves, and also in U.S. domestic politics. principles, and
“level playing field.” Any efforts to change cur- Within the WTO, antidumping reformers
rent practice, they claim, are really just plots to would be better able to recruit allies and isolate
objectives of the
“weaken” existing laws and create “loopholes” for their opponents. Their position would be both Antidumping
unfair traders. Defenders of antidumping thus more attractive and easier to understand, and Agreement could
define the debate as a conflict between a level their ability to persuade fence sitters to join their
playing field on the one hand and unfair traders cause would be correspondingly enhanced. allow antidumping
on the other. Those terms, needless to say, Antidumping reformers were able to force the reformers to call
strongly favor maintenance of the status quo. United States to accept antidumping negotia- their opponents’
Defenders of antidumping have been able to tions in Doha only because they succeeded in
create and hold this rhetorical advantage isolating the United States diplomatically. If bluff.
because they have never been required to define they hope to achieve significant reforms in the
“fairness” and “level playing field” or explain how present negotiations, they will once again have
current antidumping rules advance those to rally world opinion to their side. This time
admirable-sounding goals. They simply assert the task will be considerably more difficult.
the connection between current antidumping Building a consensus on what antidumping is
rules and fairness and rely on the complexities of supposed to do (and on the fact that it isn’t
the law’s methodologies to shield their assertion doing its job properly) would aid the needed
from scrutiny. For decades that strategy has been diplomatic effort immensely.
tremendously successful. Meanwhile, in the United States, a debate
Negotiations aimed at fleshing out the basic that highlighted the contrast between
concepts, principles, and objectives of the antidumping’s objectives and its current prac-
Antidumping Agreement could allow antidump- tice could drive a wedge between hard-core
ing reformers to call their opponents’ bluff. If the supporters of the status quo and more casual
much-invoked level playing field were actually supporters. The hard core is concerned primar-
defined—if the specific circumstances that sup- ily with the interests of import-competing
posedly give rise to unfair trade were spelled out industries (notably the steel industry) that use
and the criteria for distinguishing those circum- the law regularly. To those supporters, results
stances from normal conditions of competition are all that count: anything that makes it easier
were clearly delineated—then antidumping for domestic industries to win protection
reformers could argue with considerable force makes the law better, and anything that makes
that the imposition of antidumping duties in any protection harder to achieve is a step backward.
other circumstances amounts to simple protec- That standard, of course, has nothing to do
tionism. Antidumping reformers could turn their with any notions of fair trade; it is a protec-
opponents’ traditional rhetorical advantage tionist standard, pure and simple.
against them and claim with justice that they, not On the other hand, many U.S. supporters of
defenders of the status quo, are the ones truly the antidumping law are not so blatantly results
concerned with fairness. oriented. Rather, they are attracted to the idea
They could, in other words, redefine the of a level playing field and believe that
terms of the debate. Instead of a choice antidumping remedies work to secure that
between the level playing field and unfair noble-sounding objective. If those casual sup-
traders—with defenders of antidumping on porters could be made aware of the disconnect
the side of the angels—the debate would now between the law’s appealing rhetoric and how
offer a choice between a level playing field and the law really works, they might be more
old-fashioned protectionism. Supporters of amenable to changes in antidumping rules—or

5
at least less hostile to such changes. WTO The Bush administration’s position paper
negotiations that focused initially on adopts what has become the standard refrain of
antidumping’s basic concepts, principles, and U.S. antidumping supporters: that antidumping
objectives would illuminate that disconnect, measures are needed to offset artificial competitive
thereby helping to reduce casual supporters’ advantages created by market-distorting government
attachment to the antidumping status quo. policies. According to the document, “Effective
That change in the U.S. political climate could trade remedy instruments are important to
lead in turn to a more accommodating U.S. respond to and discourage trade-distorting govern-
position at the negotiating table. ment policies and the market imperfections that
result.”10 Specifically, the U.S. government argues,
government policies can create “artificial” competi-
Defining the tive advantages that may be distinguished from the
“real” competitive advantages that arise in normal
“Level Playing Field” market competition:
What are the basic concepts, principles, and
objectives of the Antidumping Agreement? The Ideally, companies and nations would
agreement itself is silent on those matters. It compete in the international market-
The Antidumping establishes standards for how antidumping inves- place on the basis of real comparative
Agreement estab- tigations are to be conducted and remedies advantages such as natural resource
lishes standards for imposed, but it says nothing about why dumping endowments, labor skills and abun-
is a problem in the first place. The agreement, in dance, availability of capital, and tech-
how antidumping other words, defines the “solution,” but not the nological innovation. Faced with the
investigations are to problem that it supposedly solves. We therefore true relative prices of these production
must look outside the agreement for guidance. factors, companies and nations would
be conducted and We propose to look for that guidance in the gravitate towards producing and
remedies imposed, statements of the U.S. government and promi- exporting those products in which they
but it says nothing nent supporters of the U.S. antidumping law. have a relative cost advantage and buy-
There are many sound reasons why this approach ing/importing those products in which
about why dumping makes sense. The United States is the world’s they do not have this advantage. . . .
is a problem in the leading antidumping user.8 In the international However, government attempts to
first place. arena, the U.S. government has been the leading create artificial advantages distort
defender of the need for “strong” antidumping market signals indicating where the
remedies. In the current WTO negotiations, the most profitable business opportunities
United States is expected to be the most formi- are found. Such distortions can lead to
dable opponent of any changes to the chronic oversupply by inefficient pro-
Antidumping Agreement that might “weaken” ducers on the one hand, and the clo-
national laws. Accordingly, if it can be shown that sure of otherwise efficient and com-
existing antidumping rules do a bad job of petitive facilities on the other. . . . In
addressing the problem of dumping as U.S. short, market-distorting practices
antidumping supporters define that problem, the reduce worldwide economic efficiency,
strongest possible case for changing the rules will thereby diminishing the gains to all
have been made. Members from international special-
The U.S. government recently issued a posi- ization and exchange based on com-
tion paper on the “Basic Concepts and parative advantage. 11
Principles of the Trade Remedy Rules” in the
Doha Round antidumping negotiations. 9 This This formulation of the problem that gives
paper provides an excellent starting point for rise to antidumping laws differs somewhat from
understanding the problem that antidumping the others discussed below in that it focuses on
laws supposedly solve. efficiency rather than fairness. The Bush admin-

6
istration has focused on the losses to worldwide As will be seen in the discussion that fol-
economic efficiency caused by market-distorting lows, the association between dumping and
practices; the usual focus, however, is on the “sanctuary markets” figures prominently in the
unfairness to national industries that must face justifications for antidumping laws offered by
foreign rivals with artificial (i.e., government pol- supporters of the U.S. law.
icy–caused) competitive advantages. There is no The Bush administration’s interpretation of
necessary conflict between the differing the basic concepts, principles, and objectives of
emphases, however.12 And in either case, the bot- the Antidumping Agreement shows consider-
tom line is the same: antidumping measures are able continuity with the line taken by the
needed to neutralize artificial competitive advan- Clinton administration in another document
tages and restore the so-called level playing field. that attempted to justify the use of antidump-
The Bush administration’s paper goes on to ing measures. That earlier document goes into
identify dumping as particular pricing practices greater depth than the Bush administration’s
that reflect the underlying existence of govern- position paper and also accords more closely
ment policy-caused market distortions. with the formulations of antidumping policy
Specifically, the paper states that dumping takes made by other prominent supporters of the
the form of either “international price discrimina- U.S. law. Accordingly, the Clinton administra-
tion” or “export pricing at levels below the cost of tion’s paper merits detailed analysis.
production plus a reasonable amount for selling, The document in question is a 1998 sub-
general and administrative expenses and profit.”13 mission by the U.S. government to the WTO
That definition tracks the one normally supplied Working Group on the Interaction of Trade
by U.S. supporters of antidumping, although the and Competition Policy. 15 Some members of
second half of the Bush administration’s defini- that working group had asserted that
tion is more expansive than the usual formulation. antidumping laws should be judged by the
Typically, as discussed below, dumping is defined standards of competition policy—in other
as either international price discrimination or words, on the basis of whether they promote
sales below the cost of production. consumer welfare by targeting anti-competi-
The pricing practices that constitute dumping, tive conduct. In the submission in question, the
however that term is precisely defined, are prob- Clinton administration argued vociferously
lematic because they supposedly are the conse- against that approach:
quence of market-distorting government policies.
The Bush administration’s paper offers little detail Stated simply, the antidumping rules
here, but the one example it gives is typical of those and competition laws have different
provided by U.S. antidumping supporters: objectives and are founded on differ- The association
ent principles, and they seek to reme-
A government’s industrial policies dy different problems. If the
between dumping
or key aspects of the economic system antidumping rules were eliminated in and “sanctuary
supported by government inaction can favor of competition laws or modified markets” figures
enable injurious dumping to take to be consistent with competition pol-
place. . . . For instance, these policies icy principles, the problems which the prominently in the
may allow producers to earn high antidumping rules seek to remedy justifications for
profits in a home “sanctuary market,” would go unaddressed.16
which may in turn allow them to sell
antidumping laws
abroad at an artificially low price. Such In making its case, the submission expounds offered by support-
practices can result in injury in the at considerable length on antidumping rules’ ers of the U.S. law.
importing country since domestic underlying objectives and principles—to define
firms may not be able to match the the problems that antidumping rules seek to
artificially low prices from producers address. Accordingly, the Clinton administra-
in the sanctuary market.14 tion’s paper offers illuminating insights into

7
According to what the basic concepts, principles, and objec- benefit even when they maintain current
antidumping sup- tives of the Antidumping Agreement might be. home market prices. . . . Absent interven-
The Clinton administration’s paper defines tion by their own government, competing
porters, dumping is dumping as “a situation where an exporter sells producers in export markets are at a dis-
generally the result its product abroad at lower prices than it does advantage and often suffer injury, such as
at home or at prices that are below cost, which lost market share, because they cannot
of government causes ‘material injury’ to producers of the match the low pricing from producers in
policies in the product in the importing country.”17 It then the home market.19
dumping exporter’s asserts that the need for antidumping rules
arises from “imperfections in the multilateral The 1998 paper goes on to address how dif-
home market. trading system.” Specifically, dumping is gen- ferences in national economic systems can
erally the result of government policies in the result in dumping. For example, in countries in
dumping exporter’s home market: which social pressures or policies inhibit layoffs
during downturns, labor costs are more fixed
Although some dumping may be due to than variable. In such settings, producers may
business advantages and market segmen- choose to sell below full costs instead of laying
tation which have arisen in response to off unneeded workers. In other words, they will
commercial forces, more typically it is a “export [their] unemployment to the other
government’s industrial policies or key country’s industry.”20 In another scenario, pro-
aspects of the national economic system ducers rely more heavily on debt in countries
which a government has created, promot- with poorly developed equity markets. They
ed or tolerated that enables injurious may find it necessary to sell below cost to ser-
dumping to take place.18 vice their debt obligations, whereas producers
with lower debt-equity ratios might cut back
The 1998 U.S. submission identifies the production during slumps. The paper also
following industrial policies as possibly giving identifies other situations—the presence of
rise to dumping: high tariffs or nontariff barri- large, conglomerate business groupings with
ers that exclude foreign competition, regula- noncommercial access to financing; cut-throat
tions that restrict domestic competition, the pricing encouraged by a policy of adopting
absence of adequate competition laws to coun- “market stabilization” cartels on the basis of
teract private anti-competitive conduct, price precartel production levels; state planning
controls that set artificially high prices for the regimes with quantitative export targets—in
exported product or artificially low prices for which differences in national economic struc-
inputs for the exported product, and govern- tures can lead to dumping.
ment subsidies that give foreign producers an In sum, the Clinton administration’s paper
artificial cost advantage or that result in excess traces the roots of dumping to anti-market
capacity. “Although these policies take on many policies and institutions. The resulting sup-
different forms,” the paper states, “they provide pression or distortion of market competition
similar artificial advantages to the benefitting yields either abnormally high prices in the
producers.” The paper then elaborates: home market or abnormally low prices in
export markets—or both. Those artificial pric-
Specifically, these policies enable the ben- ing patterns are the problem supposedly
efitting producers to charge higher than addressed by antidumping rules. According to
competitive prices in their home mar- the 1998 U.S. paper:
ket—what can be thought of as a “sanc-
tuary market”—and, as a result, to realize [T]he antidumping rules simply seek
increased profits. If the government’s to remove unfairness and create a
policies have the effect of lowering the “level playing field” for producers and
producers’ unit costs, the producers may workers. It therefore may be more

8
appropriate to view the antidumping characteristics vary widely, but may
rules as a judgment by the importing include the existence of some form of
country that it will not accept low- government support, the ability to
priced or below-cost imports—even if cross-subsidize losses in one product
its immediate overall economic wel- area with profits earned in other areas,
fare would be enhanced—to the or simply enormous resources which
extent that acceptance means forcing make it possible to sell at a loss for a
its producers and workers to compete long period of time. 22
against, and be injured by, foreign pro-
ducers receiving unfair advantages Terence Stewart, another prominent attor-
from government policies or actions ney who represents domestic industries in U.S.
which lead to significant differences in antidumping investigations, takes a similar
economic systems.21 line. The antidumping law, he argues, is
“designed to offset any artificial advantage that
Other prominent supporters of the U.S. flows from closed foreign markets, cross-subsi-
antidumping law concur in the overall analysis dization by multiproduct producers, govern-
put forward by the Bush and Clinton adminis- ment largesse, or other factors having nothing
trations. Alan Wolff, counsel to the U.S. steel to do with comparative advantage.”23
Other prominent
industry and a leading lobbyist for the Greg Mastel is probably the most promi- supporters of the
antidumping status quo, also identifies two nent supporter of the U.S. antidumping law in U.S. antidumping
types of dumping, “price-to-price dumping” the public policy community. A former analyst
and “below-cost dumping.” In a 1995 speech with the Economic Strategy Institute and the law concur in the
before the Steel Manufacturers Association, he New America Foundation, he is the author of overall analysis put
answered the question, “What gives rise to Antidumping Laws and the U.S. Economy, a
dumping?” as follows: stout defense of current rules. 24 At present he
forward by the
serves as chief trade counsel for the U.S. Senate Bush and Clinton
Price-to-price dumping. Price-to- Committee on Finance; as a key staffer on the administrations.
price dumping can occur because the Senate committee with primary jurisdiction
dumping industry enjoys some degree over trade policy, he plays an important role in
of market power in its domestic mar- the ongoing debate over antidumping reform.
ket which enables it to maintain a Mastel’s views on the need for antidumping
higher price in the home market than rules align closely with those expressed in the two
in export markets. This may arise out U.S. government papers as well as those of Wolff
of protection of the home market from and Stewart. He identifies government interven-
import competition . . . ; the relative tionism—whether targeted subsidies or the per-
absence of internal competition vasive controls of nonmarket economies—as a
because of the existence of a monopo- major cause of dumping. In particular, he pays
listic, oligopolistic or cartelized market special attention to the interrelation between
structure; or some combination of dumping and sanctuary markets:
these factors. Absent such elements,
the domestic price and the world price A secure closed home market or sanc-
will equalize. tuary market encourages companies to
Below-cost dumping. Below-cost make aggressive production and expan-
dumping can occur because the indus- sion decisions because they can be cer-
try which is dumping possesses a tain of selling a percentage of their pro-
structural characteristic which enables duction at home at good prices. . . .
it to export its products below the cost From a sanctuary market, it is also pos-
of production for a sustained period sible to dump in the markets of foreign
without going out of business. Such competitors to depress the profit mar-

9
gins of those competitors and reduce tions caused by the anti-market policies of for-
their funds available for investment in eign governments. Interventionist policies, it is
R&D and marketing. argued, can confer an “artificial” or “unfair”
Companies from countries with open competitive advantage on foreign producers,
markets do not enjoy this luxury. . . . Over allowing them to charge lower prices in export
time, this puts companies in open-market markets than at home or to charge below their
countries, such as the United States, at a cost of production. Antidumping remedies off-
serious disadvantage in competition with set that artificial advantage and thereby restore
companies with sanctuary home markets.25 a “level playing field.”
This approach to defining the problem of
According to Mastel, a closed home market dumping offers a justification for antidumping
allows a dumping strategy to work by main- rules that can be distinguished from simple pro-
taining a price differential between the home tectionism. Many forms of government inter-
and export markets: ventionism do indeed distort markets and give
particular firms an artificial competitive advan-
If a company engages in dumping and tage. Although it remains highly debatable
its home market is open, the price differ- whether trade barriers are the proper response to
ential will induce the company’s com- such market distortions, at least it can be main-
petitors or other resellers to reexport tained plausibly that government policy–caused
dumped products to the dumper’s home market distortions are a legitimate problem in
market. These reexports would quickly international trade. The case for trade barriers
pull the home market price down to the narrowly targeted at artificially advantaged firms
dumped price and erase home market is clearly distinguishable from the case for
profits. Thus, a closed or restricted home across-the-board protectionism.
market is also a virtual precondition to a Some of the analyses cited above, however,
successful dumping strategy.26 suggest that dumping can also be the result of
purely private conduct. Thus, Wolff suggests that
Mastel argues that sanctuary markets can be creat- price-discrimination dumping can occur because
ed either by government-imposed trade barriers or of oligopolistic market power and that below-cost
by government acquiescence in the “private-sector dumping can be due to cross-subsidization by a
protectionism” of anti-competitive collusion. multiproduct firm. Stewart also cites cross-subsi-
The justification of antidumping rules dization as a possible cause of dumping.
advanced in these analyses differs sharply from This attempted extension of the definition of
The justification of the popular view that antidumping is a remedy dumping’s causes cannot survive careful scrutiny.
for “predatory” private anti-competitive con- Many manufacturing industries are characterized
antidumping rules duct. The Clinton administration’s WTO sub- by oligopolistic competition, and virtually all
differs sharply from mission states flatly that “antidumping rules are manufacturing enterprises are multiproduct
the popular view not intended as a remedy for the predatory firms. Yet within the United States, there is no
practices of firms or as a remedy for any other regulation of price premiums earned by oligopo-
that antidumping is private anti-competitive practices typically listic firms. For instance, it is not considered legal-
a remedy for condemned by competition laws.”27 Mastel ly actionable that a company with a strong brand
takes a similar view. “There are only a handful name can use the strength of its brand to com-
“predatory” private of cases in recent history,” he writes, “in which mand a higher price. Likewise, there is no gener-
anti-competitive it reasonably can be argued that such a system- al regulation of cross-subsidies by multiproduct
conduct. atic predatory strategy was being followed.”28 firms. For example, a firm that makes razors and
Instead, the U.S. government, through two blades may sell the former at or even below cost
administrations, and leading supporters of the in order to maximize revenue from the latter. If
U.S. antidumping law argue that the law is domestic firms are completely free to engage in
needed primarily to offset the effects of distor- such practices, one cannot argue plausibly that

10
foreign producers who do exactly the same thing sales below cost often indicate the presence of There is a serious
are engaging in unfair trade.29 Any resort to vigorous competition rather than any kind of mismatch between
antidumping remedies in such situations is indis- market distortion. Accordingly, if antidumping
tinguishable from garden-variety protectionism. rules are to target the effects of market distor- what antidumping
tions without collateral damage to normal com- rules actually do
petition, they must have some mechanism for
Missing the Target? weeding out the “false positives.” Current
and what their sup-
antidumping rules, however, lack any such porters say they are
Now that we have some sense of the problem mechanism. As a result, antidumping rules fre- supposed to do.
antidumping rules are supposed to solve, we can quently punish foreign producers for business
turn to judging how well those rules actually practices having nothing to do with unfair trade.
work. Are antidumping remedies reliably target- Finally, antidumping remedies are supposed
ing artificial competitive advantages that result to be limited to offsetting artificial competitive
from market-distorting government policies? advantages caused by market distortions. In
Or are they frequently missing their target? other words, they are supposed to produce a
Unfortunately, there is a serious mismatch “level playing field,” not slant the field in favor of
between what antidumping rules actually do and the domestic industry. To that end, antidumping
what their supporters say they are supposed to do. duties may be imposed only when dumping is
Antidumping rules are supposed to impose trade found to cause or threaten injury to the domes-
barriers only as a response to market distortions, tic industry. Because of flaws in current rules,
but as currently written and enforced they do a however, remedies may be applied even when
terrible job of distinguishing between market dis- alleged dumping from a particular import source
tortions and normal, healthy competition. is not harming or even threatening to harm the
Consequently, antidumping remedies frequently domestic industry. Furthermore, antidumping
punish foreign competitors for unexceptionable remedies are frequently far in excess of what
business practices routinely engaged in by domes- would be needed to remedy any harm and thus
tic industries. In other words, there is a huge gap exceed the levels arguably needed to secure a
between the basic concepts, principles, and objec- “level playing field.”
tives of the Antidumping Agreement and current The flaws in current antidumping rules are
antidumping practice. examined in great detail in two other Cato
First of all, antidumping rules are supposed Institute papers. First, we coauthored another
to identify instances of price discrimination or Cato Trade Policy Analysis published earlier this
below-cost sales. In fact, however, the method- year titled “Antidumping 101: The Devilish
ologies used in antidumping investigations can Details of ‘Unfair Trade’ Law.”30 In that paper
easily find dumping even when export prices we provide a detailed analysis of the procedures
are above cost and the same as or higher than and methodologies used in U.S. antidumping
prices in the home market. Consequently, the investigations, illustrating the many subtle and
margins of dumping calculated in investiga- not-so-subtle ways in which the law is biased
tions are often largely or totally artifacts of against normal, healthy, foreign competition.
flawed methodologies rather than evidence of Second, in a 1999 Cato Trade Policy Analysis
the targeted pricing practices. titled “The U.S. Antidumping Law: Rhetoric
Second, antidumping rules supposedly target versus Reality,” Brink Lindsey presents a gener-
price discrimination and below-cost sales on the al overview of how dumping is calculated and
ground that they are the consequences of under- shows that current calculation methodologies
lying market-distorting government policies. bear little relation to finding unfair trade.31
But the truth is that companies can charge dif- Rather than repeat at length the analyses and
ferent prices in different markets for perfectly findings of those papers here, we simply incor-
valid commercial reasons having nothing to do porate them by reference. Here we take the con-
with government interventionism. Likewise, clusion of those papers—that the U.S.

11
antidumping law and, by extension, antidump- Department of Commerce for calculating dump-
ing laws around the world, are woefully deficient ing margins. Those calculations offer telling illus-
in distinguishing between normal, healthy com- trations of exactly how methodological distor-
petition and government-caused market distor- tions in current antidumping rules can act to gen-
tions—and examine its implications for the erate dumping margins out of thin air.
WTO antidumping negotiations. But reliance on U.S. examples should not be
The fundamental problem with antidump- taken as a suggestion that U.S. antidumping rules
ing rules today is their failure to limit the appli- are especially flawed or that the U.S. law ought to
cation of antidumping remedies to instances of be the prime target of WTO negotiations. On
unfair trade under any plausible definition of the contrary, the methodological flaws that
that term. That failure defines the gap between plague the U.S. antidumping law are the norm
the basic concepts, principles, and objectives of around the world, and changes in the WTO
the Antidumping Agreement and current Antidumping Agreement are needed to restrain
antidumping practice. Closing that gap by abuses across the board. As we documented in an
altering the provisions of the Antidumping earlier paper, U.S. exports are now a leading target
Agreement ought to be the goal of WTO of antidumping actions abroad—and a leading
negotiations—in the present Doha Round and victim of antidumping abuses.32 Accordingly, it
The fundamental in future rounds if need be. should be remembered that the U.S. government
problem with has an “offensive” as well as a “defensive” posture
antidumping rules in antidumping negotiations.33
Reforming the
today is their failure Require Evidence of Market Distortions
Antidumping Agreement
to limit the applica- Critics of the antidumping status quo have
Below we offer a number of specific proposals a long laundry list of complaints, but surely the
tion of antidump- for reforming the Antidumping Agreement—not fundamental problem with current antidump-
ing remedies to to “weaken” national antidumping laws, but to ing practice is the failure to require any direct
instances of unfair improve them. For each proposal, we identify some evidence of underlying market distortions.
element of current antidumping practice that con- The supposed justification for targeting
trade under any flicts with the basic concepts, principles, and objec- antidumping remedies at price discrimination
plausible definition tives of the Antidumping Agreement. We explain and below-cost sales is that those pricing prac-
of that term. why the element in question is in need of reform tices reflect the existence of underlying, mar-
and then discuss how the proposed reform or ket-distorting government policies. And,
reforms would help to reduce the gap between indeed, unusually high home-market prices
antidumping theory and antidumping practice. can indicate a closed sanctuary market, and
In explaining why reforms are necessary, we sustained red ink can be a sign of subsidies or
frequently illustrate our analysis with examples of “soft budget constraints.” But there is a host of
methodological distortions in current U.S. other possible explanations for international
antidumping practice. We do this, not because price differences, most of which have nothing
the U.S. law is uniquely abusive, but simply to do with unfair trade under any plausible def-
because data on U.S. antidumping cases are much inition of that term. Likewise with below-cost
more accessible to us than equivalent data from sales: losses can be found in healthy, competi-
other countries. In particular, for purposes of this tive markets as well as in distorted markets. 34
study, we were able to gain access to the full evi- Unfortunately, current antidumping practice
dentiary record of 18 recent U.S. dumping deter- includes no mechanism for weeding out “false pos-
minations. Accordingly, we were able to calculate itives”—for distinguishing between those instances
precisely how dumping margins would be affect- of targeted pricing practices that actually reflect
ed if various methodological distortions were underlying market distortions and those that have a
removed—using the companies’ actual case data perfectly innocent explanation. Under present rules,
and the actual computer programs of the U.S. sales at less than normal value are simply assumed

12
to be unfair—an assumption that is often com- authorities, before they initiate an
pletely unsupportable. Consequently, antidumping investigation, to find that the domes-
remedies are frequently imposed on exporters for tic industry has provided credible evi-
engaging in normal commercial conduct that has dence of underlying market distor-
nothing at all to do with unfair trade or an unlevel tions. Furthermore, Article 2 of the
playing field. Antidumping Agreement should be
Antidumping remedies will routinely deviate amended to provide that authorities
from the basic concepts, principles, and objec- may find dumping only if they deter-
tives of the Antidumping Agreement so long as mine, on the basis of credible evidence
this fundamental flaw remains uncorrected. provided by the domestic industry,
There are many possible approaches to address- that the price discrimination or
ing this problem, but we suggest the following below-cost sales found during the
reforms. First, domestic industries should be investigation reflect the existence of
required to present evidence of underlying mar- underlying market distortions as
ket distortions in their antidumping petitions: alleged in the petition.

Reform Proposal 1: Article 5.2 of the It should be noted that the reform proposal
Antidumping Agreement should be above does not confer any new investigatory
amended to require domestic industries powers on national antidumping authorities. Any
to provide credible evidence of underly- open-ended mandate to investigate “hidden”
ing market distortions in the antidump- trade barriers, anti-competitive conduct, or other
ing petition. If price-discrimination market distortions could easily lead to abusive
dumping is alleged, the evidence must “fishing expeditions.” Responding to antidump-
indicate the existence of (1) tariffs sig- ing questionnaires is already far too burdensome;
nificantly higher than those in the requiring respondents, under the threatened use
export market under investigation, (2) of “facts available,”35 to satisfy antidumping
nontariff barriers significantly higher authorities’ potentially limitless curiosity about
than those in the export market under conditions in the home market would make a bad
investigation, (3) government restric- situation immeasurably worse. Accordingly, in
tions on competition in the home mar- the above proposal, findings by antidumping
ket, or (4) government acquiescence in authorities of underlying market distortions are to
private anti-competitive conduct. If be based on evidence provided by the domestic
sales-below-cost dumping is alleged, industry in its petition and subsequent submis-
the evidence must relate to the existence sions—not on any independent fact-finding by Antidumping
of (1) subsidies that allow persistent the authorities themselves.
losses to continue or (2) other govern- Procedural fairness dictates that respondents
remedies are
ment policies that create a “soft budget in antidumping investigations should be able to frequently imposed
constraint” that allows persistent losses rebut the evidence of market distortions provid- on exporters for
to continue. ed by the domestic industry. In particular, they
should be allowed to provide affirmative defens- engaging in normal
In addition, national antidumping authori- es to refute any causal connection between any commercial conduct
ties should be required to make a finding of market distortions in the home market and the
underlying market distortions before initiating pricing practices under investigation:
that has nothing at
an investigation as well as in their final deter- all to do with unfair
mination of sales at less than normal value: Reform Proposal 3: Article 6 of the trade or an unlevel
Antidumping Agreement should be
Reform Proposal 2: Article 5.3 of the revised to give respondents the right playing field.
Antidumping Agreement should be to present evidence that the pricing
revised to require antidumping practices under investigation are due

13
The use of the “cost to factors other than market distor- tial element of the overall reform program.
test” is probably the tions in the home market. In investi-
gations of price-discrimination Eliminate the Cost Test
single most egregious dumping, respondents would have the Current antidumping rules fail to achieve
methodological dis- right to show, for example, that (1) their supposed objectives on two basic levels.
high home-market prices are due to First, as discussed above, they make no attempt
tortion in contempo- normal commercial factors (for exam- to connect the targeted pricing practices of
rary antidumping ple, strong brand-name recognition); price discrimination and sales below cost to
practice. (2) notwithstanding the existence of underlying market distortions. Second, they do
high prices, the respondent does not a poor job of identifying actual instances of
enjoy unusually high home-market price discrimination and below-cost export
profits on sales of the subject mer- sales. Because of methodological distortions in
chandise (and thus does not enjoy any the rules that define dumping, findings of sales
artificial competitive advantage); or at less than normal value all too frequently have
(3) the respondent’s home market is little or nothing to do with the presence of
too small for high profits in that mar- price discrimination or below-cost export sales.
ket to confer an artificial competitive The use of the “cost test” is probably the
advantage in the export market under single most egregious methodological distor-
investigation. In investigations of tion in contemporary antidumping practice.36
sales-below-cost dumping, respon- Like many other distortions, it skews compar-
dents would have the right to show, isons of home-market and export prices and
for example, that below-cost sales thereby artificially inflates dumping margins.
were made (1) to maximize the contri- What is especially noteworthy about the cost
bution to fixed costs; (2) to maximize test, though, is that it operates to inflate dump-
overall revenue of joint products, ing margins under specific conditions that are
products that share overhead, or com- the complete opposite of those that supposed-
plementary goods; (3) to maximize ly give rise to unfair trade.
long-term revenue by exploiting The existence and extent of dumping are at
learning-curve effects or by building present determined by a comparison of export
long-term market position; or (4) oth- prices to “normal value,” which is typically
erwise as part of a conscious strategy based on prices in the foreign producer’s home
to maximize long-term profits. market. If adjusted export prices are lower than
National antidumping authorities normal value, dumping is said to exist; the dif-
must take this evidence into account ference between normal value and net export
when determining whether the pric- prices, divided by net export prices, is the
ing practices under investigation dumping margin or dumping rate.
actually reflect (rather than merely Under the cost test, home-market sales found
coincide with) the existence of under- to be below the cost of production are excluded
lying market distortions. from the calculation of normal value. In other
words, all export prices are compared to those of
The reform proposals above, if adopted, only the highest (that is, above-cost) home-market
would mark a significant departure from tradi- sales. This asymmetric comparison skews the cal-
tional antidumping policy. But the fact is that culation in favor of finding dumping.
traditional policy has been sharply at odds with In the U.S. antidumping cases we have
the basic concepts, principles, and objectives examined, the effect on dumping margins was
that it supposedly serves. If the enormous gap dramatic. As Table 137 indicates, each of the 17
between antidumping rhetoric and antidump- cases against market-economy countries had
ing reality is to be closed, proposals along the margins that were inflated by the cost test
lines of those suggested above will be an essen- (investigations of countries judged to be non-

14
market economies use a different method for antidumping cases over a three-year period
calculating dumping in which the cost test is found that only 4 of 37 determinations in
irrelevant). In two cases, the calculated dump- which home-market sales were available as a
ing margin would have been zero had the cost basis for normal value employed a pure com-
test not been administered. Most of the parison of home-market and U.S. prices. In 33
remaining 15 would have had margins at least of 37 determinations, or 89 percent of the time,
50 percent lower than the rate ultimately cal- the Commerce Department excluded some or
culated. On average, the 17 cases would have all home-market sales through use of the cost
had margins 59.69 percent lower. 38 test. The average dumping margin when the
What possible purpose could be served by cost test was used was 16.14 percent; by com-
excluding below-cost home-market sales from parison, in the four determinations when the
normal value? Remember that the theory cost test wasn’t employed, the average dumping
behind price-discrimination dumping is that margin was only 4.00 percent. 39
the foreign producer is enjoying an artificial Because the cost test is explicitly authorized
advantage because of a sanctuary market at in the current agreement, and because it is such
home. According to the theory, trade barriers a regular feature of contemporary antidumping
or other restrictions on competition cause investigations, resistance to reform in this area
prices (and profits) in the home market to be will be fierce. And there is only one reform that
The existence of
artificially high, thus allowing the foreign pro- is adequate: outright elimination of the cost test. below-cost sales in
ducer to unfairly cross-subsidize cheap export The pretext for excluding below-cost sales the home market is
sales. Consequently, price differences between from normal value is that such sales are not “in
the export market and the home market are the ordinary course of trade.” While it might actually affirmative
supposedly probative of unfair trade because make sense to exclude certain aberrant sales— evidence of the
they might indicate the existence of a closed sales of obsolete inventory or of damaged
sanctuary market in the foreign producer’s goods—there is no serious case that unprofitable
absence of a sanc-
home market. Whether those price differences sales are outside the ordinary course of trade. In tuary market.
exist, though, cannot be fairly determined if all normal, healthy, competitive markets, there is
the lowest home-market prices are excluded nothing extraordinary at all about red ink—
from the comparison. especially on a product-specific rather than a
Moreover, the existence of below-cost sales company-wide basis. It is absolutely routine for
in the home market is actually affirmative evi- companies to fail to cover full costs of produc-
dence of the absence of a sanctuary market. A tion on particular products at particular times.
sanctuary market, after all, is supposed to be an Selling below full cost is often the rational, prof-
island of artificially high prices and profits. If it-maximizing strategy. As long as variable costs
home-market sales at a loss are found in signif- of production are covered by the selling price,
icant quantities, isn’t that a fairly compelling any contribution that price makes to covering
indication that there is no sanctuary market? fixed costs is more than would be received if the
But because of the cost test, it is precisely under product did not sell at all, which is often the
those conditions that dumping margins are alternative if the price is incrementally higher.
boosted significantly higher than they other- Accordingly, the Antidumping Agreement
wise would be. should be revised to prohibit use of the cost test:
This absurd methodology clearly flies in the
face of the basic concepts, principles, and Reform Proposal 4: Article 2.2.1 of
objectives of the Antidumping Agreement. Yet the Antidumping Agreement should
it is nonetheless specifically authorized under be rewritten to make clear that exclu-
Article 2.2.1 of the current agreement. Under sion of home-market sales from the
this authority, the cost test has become a cen- calculation of normal value is permit-
tral feature of antidumping investigations. A ted only in the case of specified aber-
survey by one of this study’s coauthors of U.S. rational sales. In particular, sales must

15
16
not be categorized as outside the ordi- comparable comparison-market products, or
nary course of trade simply because above-cost comparison-market products? Those
they are made at less than the full cost criteria are completely irrelevant and therefore
of production. should not be preconditions for comparing export
prices to constructed value.
Until this reform is made, antidumping practice Accordingly, the Antidumping Agreement
will bear little relation to its stated justification of should be amended to revise the criteria for use
remedying market distortions. of constructed value:

Revise Criteria for Use of “Constructed Value”; Reform Proposal 5: Article 2 of the
Eliminate Profit Component Antidumping Agreement should be
Supporters of antidumping generally con- revised to provide for two alternative
tend that dumping takes two basic forms: bases of normal value: price-to-price
price-discrimination dumping and below-cost comparisons of export and home-
dumping. For the former, the cost test dis- market sales (unmodified by any cost
cussed above and many other methodological test in the home market) and cost of
distortions discussed below ensure that actual production (known in the United
price discrimination is rarely targeted in States as constructed value). Which
antidumping investigations, since comparisons basis is used will depend on the form
of prices are often badly skewed. Meanwhile, of dumping alleged by the petitioner.
the inclusion of profit in the calculation of In its petition the domestic industry
“constructed value” means that below-cost will allege either price-discrimination
export sales are never directly targeted. dumping or below-cost dumping,
The closest that current antidumping rules with appropriate corroborating evi-
come to examining whether export sales are dence. If a price-discrimination case is
below cost is when constructed value is used as initiated, normal value will be based
the basis of normal value. Constructed value is the on home-market prices; if a below-
U.S. term for an artificial price that is determined cost case is initiated, normal value will
by calculating the unit cost of production for a be based on cost of production.
given product and then adding some amount for
profit. Constructed value is used only when (1) Furthermore, if the goal is to determine
virtually all the foreign producer’s sales of the sub- whether export sales are below cost, then
ject merchandise are to the export market under export prices should be compared to actual unit
investigation (that is, no “viable” home market or costs of production—not cost plus profit. An If the goal is to
third-country export markets exist); (2) there is a ex-factory export price that is lower than the
viable comparison market for the merchandise, cost of production plus profit indicates only
determine whether
but no models sufficiently similar to those sold in that the export price is below a certain level of export sales are
the export market are sold there; or (3) all sales of profitability. Yet supporters of antidumping below cost, then
similar comparison-market models have been generally define dumping, not as “insufficient-
excluded by the cost test. ly profitable” sales, but as below-cost sales. The export prices should
Accordingly, antidumping rules are egregious- remedy should target the problem. be compared to
ly misdesigned for the purpose of detecting It should be noted that the Bush adminis-
below-cost export sales. First of all, export sales tration’s recent position paper on trade remedy
actual unit costs of
are compared to constructed value only under rules does define dumping more broadly to production—not
exceptional circumstances that bear no relation- include “export pricing at levels below the cost cost plus profit.
ship whatsoever to the likelihood that export sales of production plus a reasonable amount for
may be below cost. If the problem to be addressed selling, general and administrative expenses
is below-cost export sales, what does it matter and profit”40—a formulation that tracks the
whether there are viable comparison markets, or definition of constructed value under U.S. law.

17
The present inclu- In support of this more expansive definition, it investigation of preserved mushrooms from India,
sion of profit in can be argued that a “normal” profit is part of a the Commerce Department calculated a dumping
company’s cost of capital. In other words, a margin of 7.94 percent for Dieng/Surya Jaya; if
constructed value company earning a subnormal return is selling profit had not been included, the margin would
serves to inflate below its full economic costs, if above its full have fallen to 4.88 percent—39 percent lower. In
accounting costs. Nevertheless, the Bush the 1997 U.S. investigation of cut-to-length steel
dumping margins administration’s definition goes beyond the plate from China, Liaoning’s dumping margin was
inappropriately. prevailing characterization of dumping—and found to be 17.33 percent; it would have been only
is unwarranted in doing so, since any claim that 5.43 percent—69 percent lower—if profit had not
low profitability is evidence of market distor- been added to constructed value.42
tions is much weaker than is the case with The Antidumping Agreement should
respect to outright losses. Determining exactly therefore be amended as follows:
what constitutes a normal rate of profit for a
given company in a given industry at a given Reform Proposal 6: Article 2.2 of the
time is significantly more difficult than deter- Antidumping Agreement should be
mining whether or not that company is losing revised to exclude profit from the calcu-
money. Moreover, low profits are generally sus- lation of cost of production (known in
tainable over much longer periods than are the United States as constructed value).
outright losses. Persistent failure to earn com-
petitive returns can undermine a company’s If negotiators are unable to make this reform,
ability to make necessary investments and an alternative, “second best” proposal is to revise the
thereby may lead eventually to outright losses; way profit is calculated. Under current practice,
it may also threaten the employment security profit is usually calculated on the basis of above-cost
of the company’s management. Unlike sus- comparison-market sales only. Clearly, if an estimat-
tained losses, though, low profitability in and of ed amount for profit must be included in con-
itself does not imperil a company’s solvency structed value, then limiting consideration to only
and future as a going concern. Accordingly, the profitable sales distorts the actual profitability
even chronically low profits are much less sug- picture, artificially inflating profits—and therefore
gestive of “artificial” market conditions caused normal value, and therefore dumping margins.
by government policies than is genuine red ink. Current practice can result in absurdly high
The present inclusion of profit in constructed amounts for profit. For example, in the 1997 U.S.
value serves to inflate dumping margins inappro- investigation of melamine institutional dinnerware
priately.41 In 5 of the 18 actual U.S. dumping from Taiwan, Chen Hao Taiwan was given a prof-
determinations that we examined, constructed it rate of 25.77 percent; in the parallel investigation
value was used for at least some product compar- of dinnerware from Indonesia, PT Multi Raya was
isons. In 4 of those 5, the profit element influ- given a profit rate of 22.61 percent. The average
enced the outcome. Had profit not been added to profit rate for the U.S. plastic products industry, by
constructed value, the average calculated dump- contrast, was only 5.23 percent.43 The methodolo-
ing margin would have been 11.02 percent lower gy of using only above-cost sales for calculation of
(Table 1). In particular, the margin reduction profit routinely yields such absurd results.
would have been 22.80 percent in an investiga- Accordingly, if constructed-value profit is
tion involving concrete reinforcing bars from retained, its calculation should be reformed:
Moldova, 18.25 percent in an investigation of sta-
tic random access memories (SRAMs) from Reform Proposal 7: If profit is not
Taiwan, and 13.91 percent in an investigation excluded altogether from the calculation
concerning dynamic random access memories of cost of production, it should be based
(DRAMs) from Taiwan. on actual representative profit rates for
Those findings agree with earlier findings the subject merchandise. Specifically,
made by one of the coauthors. In the 1998 U.S. profit rates should be based on average

18
industry-wide profit rates derived from barriers are shielding it from competition. On
public sources. In any event, profit should the contrary, it had to overcome any barriers
never be calculated on the basis of the that were present in that third-country market
foreign producer’s (or anyone else’s) to be selling there at all. Meanwhile, prices
above-cost sales only. charged in a third country indicate nothing
about whether a firm’s home market is closed.
While any inclusion of profit in constructed Since a comparison of export-market and
value is inconsistent with the basic concepts, third-country prices cannot possibly identify any
principles, and objectives of the Antidumping of the practices supposedly targeted by
Agreement, the reform outlined above would at antidumping policy, it follows that third-country
least curtail some of the most egregious abuses prices are an inappropriate basis for normal value.
created by this methodological distortion. Accordingly, the Antidumping Agreement needs
to be revised along the following lines:
Eliminate Use of Third-Country Sales in
Calculating Normal Value Reform Proposal 8: Article 2.2 of the
Article 2.2 of the present Antidumping Antidumping Agreement should be
Agreement provides for the use of third-country amended to provide that, in the
sales as the basis of normal value under specified absence of sufficient home-market
The practice of
circumstances—in particular, when the foreign sales, there is no basis for an allegation “zeroing” is one of
producer under investigation does not sell the of price-discrimination dumping. the most notorious
subject merchandise in its home market or sells
in insufficient volumes there to “permit a proper After this reform, the petitioning domestic distortions in cur-
comparison.” Although expressly allowed under industries would still be able to allege below- rent antidumping
current antidumping rules, a comparison of cost dumping in those cases where there are
third-country prices to export prices has no insufficient home-market sales. But it would
methodology.
rational relation to the basic concepts, principles, no longer be possible to allege price-discrimi-
and objectives of the Antidumping Agreement. nation or sanctuary-market dumping when the
Dumping, once again, is supposed to con- alleged sanctuary market doesn’t even exist.
sist of either international price discrimination
that reveals the existence of a sanctuary market Prohibit “Zeroing”
or below-cost sales that reveal some underly- The practice of “zeroing” is one of the most
ing, market-distorting government policies. A notorious distortions in current antidumping
comparison of export and third-country prices methodology.44 It occurs in the final dumping
is incapable of identifying either phenomenon. determination, when the foreign producer’s
First, and most obviously, a comparison of export prices (whether individual transactions or
prices in the export market under investigation model-specific averages) are compared to nor-
to prices in other export markets says nothing mal value (usually average prices of comparable
about whether the investigated sales are below home-market merchandise). When normal
cost. Second, while differences between value is higher than the export price, the differ-
export-market prices and third-country prices ence is treated as the dumping amount for that
can possibly show international price discrimi- sale. When, however, the export price is higher,
nation, they cannot reveal a sanctuary market. the dumping amount is treated as equal to zero.
Any foreign producer under investigation is an All dumping amounts are then added and divid-
“outsider” as far as all third-country markets are ed by the aggregate export sales amount to yield
concerned; it is hindered, not helped, by any the company’s overall dumping margin.
government barriers that block access to its Zeroing thus eliminates “negative dumping
export sales. If for some reason the company is margins” from the dumping calculation. In so
earning higher prices in that third country, the doing, it can create dumping margins out of
reason clearly is not that government-imposed thin air. Consider the results of the 18 U.S.

19
dumping determinations that we were able to tion and systematically ignores differences in the
examine. All of the 17 determinations involv- other direction has no methodological validity
ing market economies had margins inflated by whatsoever. Eliminating zeroing would help to
zeroing. In 5 of the cases, the overall dumping ensure that the price differences targeted by
margin would have been negative. On average, antidumping remedies actually exist in reality and
the margin results of the 17 cases would have are not just artifacts of skewed methodologies.
been 86.41 percent lower if zeroing had not To close the door on zeroing completely, it
been employed (see Table 1). would be helpful to supplement the reform
The practice of zeroing has been found to proposal above as follows:
violate the current Antidumping Agreement.
In a case brought by India against the Reform Proposal 10: Article 2.4.2 of
European Union involving bed linen, the the Antidumping Agreement should
WTO Appellate Body ruled in March 2001 be amended to require that, in both
that the EU’s practice was WTO-inconsis- original investigations and administra-
tent.45 The European Union has since changed tive reviews, dumping margins must be
its practice as a consequence of the Appellate calculated on the basis of comparing
Body’s ruling, but it still has not abandoned average export prices to average nor-
zeroing completely. 46 mal values or else transaction-specific
The practice of zeroing continues unabated export prices to transaction-specific
in other jurisdictions, most notably the United normal values. Comparisons of indi-
States. The U.S. Department of Commerce vidual export prices to average normal
has thus far refused to alter its practice, dis- values are never allowed.
missing the EU–Bed Linen case on the ground
that the United States was not a party. Given Under the current Antidumping Agreement,
the EU’s continued (if limited) use of zeroing, Article 2.4.2 provides that “in the investigation
the United States’ complete intransigence, and phase” dumping margins shall “normally” be
the need generally to provide certainty for established on the basis of comparing average
worldwide antidumping practice, a revision of prices to average prices or transaction-specific
the Antidumping Agreement to expressly pro- prices to transaction-specific prices. It does,
hibit zeroing is called for: however, allow comparisons of individual export
prices to average normal values “if the authori-
Reform Proposal 9: Article 2 of the ties find a pattern of export prices which differ
Antidumping Agreement should be significantly among different purchasers, regions
Eliminating zeroing revised to clarify that the practice of or time periods.” The ostensible purpose of this
zeroing is prohibited. Specifically, exception is to address instances of so-called tar-
would help to when calculating dumping margins, geted dumping, in which unfairly low prices to
ensure that the negative dumping amounts (i.e., specific customers or regions or at specific times
price differences instances in which export prices are are masked by higher prices otherwise.
higher than normal value) should be The current wording of Article 2.4.2 creates
targeted by treated as such and given their full possible openings for the continued use of zero-
antidumping reme- weight in the calculation of the foreign ing notwithstanding the Appellate Body’s opin-
producer’s overall dumping margin. ion in the EU–Bed Linen case. As explained
dies actually exist above (see endnote 46), the Appellate Body
in reality and are Especially in light of the Appellate Body’s deci- concluded that zeroing is WTO-inconsistent
not just artifacts sion in the EU–Bed Linen case, this reform would because it prevents true average-to-average
be in full accord with the basic concepts, principles, comparisons as called for by Article 2.4.2. This
of skewed and objectives of the Antidumping Agreement. reasoning leaves open the possibility that zero-
methodologies. Any measurement of international price differ- ing may be permissible when dumping is calcu-
ences that recognizes differences in only one direc- lated another way. Indeed, since the agreement

20
explicitly allows individual-to-average compar- expenses. If, however, adjustments are made At present a glaring
isons under certain circumstances, and since asymmetrically—that is, subtractions are made asymmetry exists in
those comparisons would yield exactly the same from the export price but not from the home-
results as average-to-average comparisons unlessmarket price—dumping margins can be gener- the treatment of
zeroing is employed for the former, there is a ated out of thin air. indirect selling
plausible argument that zeroing is implicitly At present a glaring asymmetry exists in the expenses in “con-
permitted under current WTO rules whenever treatment of indirect selling expenses in “con-
individual-to-average comparisons are allowed. structed export price” situations. Under U.S. law, structed export
Thus, zeroing may be consistent with indirect selling expenses are expenses that do not price” situations.
Article 2.4.2 as currently worded in targeted vary directly with the volume of sales—sales staff
dumping cases. That is the EU’s position at salaries, sales department overhead, and the like.
present. 47 In addition, the United States claims
In export price situations—that is, when the for-
that Article 2.4.2’s reference to “the investiga-
eign producer sells directly to an unrelated pur-
tion phase” implies that average-to-average chaser in the export market—no adjustment is
comparisons are the rule only in investigations,made to export or home-market prices for such
and that individual-to-average comparisons are indirect selling expenses. But in “constructed
allowed generally in administrative reviews. export price” situations—when the foreign pro-
Accordingly, the U.S. Department of ducer sells to unrelated customers through a relat-
Commerce currently uses average-to-average ed reseller in the export market—certain indirect
comparisons in investigations and individual- expenses are deducted. Specifically, all indirect
to-average comparisons in reviews—with selling expenses incurred with specific respect to
zeroing used in both methodologies.48 Thus, the export market are deducted from the export
even if the United States eventually loses a price, but the adjustment to home-market price
WTO challenge along the lines of the EU–Bed for home-market-related indirect selling expens-
Linen case, it could continue to argue that es is capped at the amount of the export-market
zeroing remains permissible, not only in target-indirect selling expenses. All home-market-relat-
ed dumping situations during original investi- ed indirect selling expenses in excess of the cap are
gations, but also in all administrative reviews.49
simply disregarded.
A clear rule against individual-to-average There is no possible justification for this
comparisons under any circumstances is neces- asymmetry. The policy of deducting export-
sary to eliminate all uncertainty and ensure that
market indirect expenses is apparently based on
zeroing is completely abolished. As to concerns the assumption that resales by the reseller in the
about targeted dumping, allowing the imposi- export market are on a different level of trade—
tion of customer-specific antidumping duty and therefore that those resale prices include
rates would be preferable to the exaggeration ofadditional expenses—than are direct sales by the
overall duty rates that zeroing causes. foreign producer in the home market. That
assumption, though, is completely arbitrary. It
Eliminate Asymmetric Treatment of Indirect may be that the reseller’s customers are large
Selling Expenses national distributors, while the foreign producer
Dumping calculations are not based on a sells directly to small local wholesalers—in
comparison of actual sales prices in the com- which case the home-market price actually has
parison and export markets. Rather, antidump- more of the distribution chain built into it than
ing authorities perform numerous adjustments does the export price. Why then should the
to actual sales prices and then compare the adjustment for home-market indirect selling
adjusted “net” prices. The adjustments are expenses be limited to the amount of similar
designed to produce “apples-to-apples” com- expenses incurred in the export market?
parisons by taking into account differences in This asymmetry—known as the “CEP off-
transportation costs, physical characteristics, set cap”—skews dumping calculations in the
credit terms, warranty terms, and other selling direction of higher dumping margins. 50 If

21
export-market indirect expenses are greater with constructed export price situa-
than equivalent home-market expenses, then tions) should prohibit the automatic
both are fully taken into account; if, however, deduction of indirect selling expenses
the home-market expenses are greater, they are from either the constructed export
capped. The result in that case is an artificially price or the comparison-market price.
inflated normal value—and an artificially In situations where the related reseller’s
inflated dumping margin. sales in the export market are deemed
As shown in Table 1, 10 of the 18 actual U.S. to take place on a different level of
cases we examined would have had lower trade from sales in the home market,
dumping margins if the asymmetry of the CEP differences in indirect selling expenses
offset cap had been eliminated. For example, in might serve as one possible basis for
2 reviews involving tapered roller bearings from quantifying the appropriate level-of-
Japan (one review involved “large” bearings; the trade adjustment.
other involved “small” bearings), if no indirect
selling expenses had been deducted on either This reform would eliminate the asymmetry of
side, the dumping margin in the large bearings the CEP offset cap by eliminating indirect-
case would have been 25.55 percent lower, and selling-expense deductions altogether in nor-
It makes no sense its rate in the small bearings case could have mal cases. As a result, price comparisons would
to adjust prices been 15.84 percent lower. For the 10 determina- be fairer and more realistic—and the chances
automatically for tions involving CEP transactions, the average of penalizing firms for normal commercial
effect of eliminating the deduction of indirect conduct simply because of flawed methodolo-
indirect selling selling expenses was to reduce the dumping gies would be correspondingly reduced.
expenses. margin by 9.06 percent.
It makes no sense to adjust prices automat- Revise the Arm’s-Length Test
ically for indirect selling expenses. There is no The Antidumping Agreement is currently
reasonable basis for assuming such overhead silent about the treatment of comparison-market
costs are built directly into the selling price. sales to affiliated parties.51 As a result, national
Stripping them out of the price, instead of cre- antidumping authorities have a great deal of lati-
ating fairer price comparisons, produces price tude in addressing this issue—with correspond-
comparisons even more removed from the ing potential to skew margins significantly.
actual market reality of real sales prices. This The practice in the United States has been to
artificiality is exacerbated by the asymmetry of give special scrutiny to comparison-market sales
always deducting all export-market indirect made to customers that are judged to have an
selling expenses while only partially deducting affiliation with the foreign producer.52 Pursuant
equivalent home-market expenses. The proper to what is known as the “arm’s-length test,” the
approach would be to end the automatic U.S. Department of Commerce includes affili-
deduction of any indirect selling expenses from ated sales in the calculation of normal value only
either the constructed export price or the if they meet certain standards.
home-market price. The purpose of the test is to determine
At present the Antidumping Agreement is whether sales to affiliated customers in the com-
silent on the specific issue of the CEP offset parison market have been made at prices and on
cap (although Article 2.4 does require a “fair terms comparable to those granted to unaffiliated
comparison” between export price and normal customers. The test involves comparisons of the
value). Accordingly, supplemental language is average net selling prices per product for each
necessary to make clear that this arbitrary and affiliated customer to the average net prices per
asymmetric distortion is prohibited: product to all unaffiliated customers. Ratios are
calculated for each unique combination of affili-
Reform Proposal 11: Article 2.3 of the ated customer and product—provided that the
Antidumping Agreement (which deals product was also sold to at least one unaffiliated

22
customer—where the affiliated net price is the ticular market, industry, or time—and it should
numerator and the average unaffiliated net price be applied symmetrically.
is the denominator. From these individual ratios As evidenced in Table 1, the arm’s-length
for each affiliate, a weighted-average ratio is cal- test can severely inflate dumping margins.
culated. If that ratio is equal to or greater than Eliminating the test from the dumping calcu-
99.5 percent, then all sales to the affiliate are lation affected the results in 8 of the 13 cases in
accepted as having been made at arm’s length. which the test was used (affiliated sales were
Otherwise, all sales to that affiliate are excluded not an issue in 5 of the 18 cases), with an over-
from the calculations of average comparison- all average reduction in the dumping margin of
market prices.53 The apparent theory behind this 6.95 percent. In each of the 8 cases affected, the
practice is that affiliated customers may receive margin decreased. In an investigation of hot-
more favorable sales terms than do unaffiliated rolled steel from Japan, the company’s dump-
customers, and thus the test is designed to find ing margin decreased by 15.97 percent.55 The
and eliminate sales to affiliated customers that margin decreased by 52.60 percent for a com-
have paid lower prices on average. pany in a review concerning stainless steel
The current U.S. arm’s-length test is seri- sheet and strip from Japan.
ously flawed.54 First of all, it is asymmetrical, Some reform of the U.S. test is necessary even
since it ignores the equally likely possibility under the current Antidumping Agreement. In
that prices to affiliates might be higher than the Japanese Hot-Rolled Steel case, the WTO
those to unaffiliated customers. If the affiliates Appellate Body ruled that the U.S. test’s asym-
are seeking to maximize their combined wel- metry is inconsistent with WTO rules. 56 In
fare (which is the implicit premise of the arm’s- response to the WTO’s ruling, the U.S.
length test), it might be optimal to show high- Department of Commerce is now proposing to
er revenues for the seller (to attract investors, change the test. Under the new approach, all sales
improve the stock value, etc.) and higher costs under a 98 percent threshold and above a 102
for the buyer (to avoid tax liabilities, etc.). Yet, percent threshold would be eliminated.57 The
only when sales to affiliates are lower than sales proposed new “band” approach eliminates the
to unaffiliated customers are they excluded. arm’s-length test’s asymmetry, but the fixed 98
The current test’s asymmetry has the effect of percent and 102 percent thresholds, like the cur-
raising average prices in the comparison mar- rent 99.5 percent threshold, are simply arbitrary.
ket, and hence raising dumping margins. However the United States ultimately
Not only is the asymmetric application of responds to the WTO’s ruling, there is a need to
the test inappropriate, but because it ignores revise the Antidumping Agreement and clarify
the reality that prices vary within and between the standards for dealing with sales to affiliated If an arm’s-length
industries and over time, the 99.5 percent parties. Since evidence of price manipulation is
threshold is simply arbitrary. While in some nearly impossible to ascertain by comparing aver-
test is to be used at
industries or in some years, there may be very age prices, and since the presumption that manip- all, the relevant
little price variation, prices may vary widely in ulation is evidenced by slightly lower prices to threshold should
other situations. What this suggests is that the affiliates is patently unfair, the Antidumping
threshold for deviations from the average price Agreement should be revised to instruct national reflect the range of
should be more liberal when wider price varia- authorities to simply eliminate all abnormally prices offered in
tion is normal. A constant benchmark makes high-priced and low-priced sales in the compari-
no sense in light of this inherent variability. son market to affiliated parties from the calcula-
that particular mar-
And why should ratios below that level be con- tion of normal value. And rather than allow ket, industry, or
strued as evidence that prices were manipulat- “abnormally” to be defined subjectively by each time—and it
ed to lower normal value anyway? Could there national authority, valid statistical methods
not be other reasons? If an arm’s-length test is should be required. For example, average (mean) should be applied
to be used at all, the relevant threshold should prices might be calculated along with the stan- symmetrically.
reflect the range of prices offered in that par- dard deviations, which reflect the variance of each

23
individual price from that average. Those sales at always give rise to high dumping margins. 58
prices exceeding the average plus two (or three) Ideally, such sales would be compared to equiva-
standard deviations and at below the average lent sales in the home market. Such comparisons
minus two (or three) standard deviations should are usually precluded, however, by the operation
be dropped. Such an approach would reduce the of the cost test. Although secondary merchandise
skewing impact of aberrational comparison-mar- must be sold at lower prices than the prime mer-
ket sales on the overall picture of that market. chandise it was intended to be, it costs the same
Thus, the Antidumping Agreement should to produce as prime merchandise. As a result, off-
be revised along the following lines: quality merchandise is almost always sold at
prices below the cost of production. With all
Reform Proposal 12: Article 2 of the home-market sales of off-quality goods eliminat-
Antidumping Agreement should be ed by the cost test, export sales of secondary mer-
revised to require that the exclusion of chandise must be compared to much higher
comparison-market sales to affiliated priced home-market sales of prime merchandise.
parties be administered in a symmet- Antidumping rules do provide for price
rical manner to both higher and lower adjustments for physical differences in products.
non-arm’s-length sales terms. When export sales are compared to home-mar-
Under current Furthermore, Article 2 should require ket sales of nonidentical merchandise, a “differ-
antidumping rules, a statistically sound methodology for ence-in-merchandise,” or DIFMER, adjust-
sales of secondary determining whether or not sales ment is made to compensate for physical differ-
prices are at arm’s length. ences and thereby, presumably, ensure an
merchandise in “apples-to-apples” comparison. Unfortunately,
the export market Special Consideration for “Off-Quality” or however, DIFMER adjustments are typically
“Secondary” Merchandise calculated as the difference in the variable costs
almost always give The Antidumping Agreement is currently of the models being compared. While there are
rise to high dumping silent on the treatment of “off-quality” or “sec- real and important physical differences between
margins. ondary” merchandise. This silence needs to be prime and off-quality merchandise, there are no
remedied, since export sales of off-quality mer- cost differences, and therefore no basis for a
chandise now tend to generate large dumping DIFMER adjustment. Accordingly, when off-
margins—not because of any unfair trade, but quality export sales are compared to prime
simply as a result of methodological flaws in home-market sales, typically there is no adjust-
dumping calculations. ment of the large price difference between them,
Production processes do not always yield and the end result is a large dumping margin on
exactly what was intended. If the output fails to those sales.
meet desired specifications or tolerances, it is Much of the problem with secondary mer-
considered off-quality or secondary merchan- chandise would disappear if the cost test were
dise. Especially in industries where product eliminated. Export sales of off-quality goods
specifications reflect inflexible safety standards could be compared to equivalent home-market
or engineering requirements, off-quality output sales—provided such sales existed in the home
often cannot be sold for its intended purpose. market. But if the cost test is retained, some-
Nevertheless, secondary merchandise may have thing needs to be done about this specific
some value to a customer, as an input for a less- problem. And even if the cost test is eliminat-
er product or as scrap material, for example. In ed, the problem still arises whenever there are
these cases the producer is better off selling the export sales of secondary merchandise but no
secondary merchandise rather than simply corresponding home-market sales.
scrapping it, but it usually must sell the off-qual- Accordingly, even if the cost test is elimi-
ity products at a substantial discount. nated, but especially if it isn’t, the Antidumping
Under current antidumping rules, sales of sec- Agreement needs to be modified along the fol-
ondary merchandise in the export market almost lowing lines:

24
Reform Proposal 13: Article 2 of the market distortions. If imports are not materially
Antidumping Agreement needs to affecting the competing domestic industry, then
include a special provision dealing with clearly there is no artificial competitive advan-
sales of secondary merchandise in the tage to be offset—and thus no cause for
export market. This provision should antidumping remedies.
require national antidumping authori- Unfortunately, implementation of the injury
ties either to (1) disregard sales of off- requirement is seriously flawed under current
quality merchandise in their dumping antidumping rules. The chief problem is the
calculations or (2) compare export sales absence of clear standards for judging whether
of off-quality merchandise to corre- there is a causal link between dumped imports
sponding comparison-market sales and injury to a domestic industry. Under U.S.
without regard to whether the compar- law, the usual approach of the International
ison-market sales are below the full Trade Commission has been to engage in a so-
cost of production. If export sales of called bifurcated analysis: first, determining
off-quality merchandise are included whether a domestic industry is injured; and, sec-
in the dumping calculation, but there ond, determining whether subject imports con-
are no corresponding home-market stitute “a cause” of that injury. With this
sales, comparisons of the export sales approach, assuming the domestic industry is
to comparison-market sales of prime doing poorly and that import volumes are up (or
merchandise should receive a special at least substantial, even if flat or falling) and
DIFMER adjustment that reflects the prices are down (or at least consistently lower
average price difference between prime than the domestic industry’s prices), it is always
and secondary subject merchandise. possible for the commission to find that imports
have made at least some contribution to the
Under current rules, export sales of off- domestic industry’s condition—and thus to
quality merchandise are virtually certain to make an affirmative determination.
generate dumping margins—simply because of This approach has absolutely no analytical
quirks in dumping-calculation methodologies. rigor. Any coincidence of significant or rising
As a result, companies are being punished for imports and poor industry performance can
normal commercial practices that have nothing serve as the basis for imposing antidumping
to do with unfair trade under any plausible def- remedies. There are no standards for distin-
inition of that term. Fidelity to the basic con- guishing between mere coincidence and actual
The analysis of cau-
cepts, principles, and objectives of the causation; accordingly, the commission has vir-
Antidumping Agreement requires that this tually unchecked discretion to confuse the for- sation is a “black
abuse be eliminated. mer with the latter. The analysis of causation is box”—there is no
a “black box”—there is no way of predicting
Tighten Standards on Causation of Injury when the commission will find injury, or even of way of predicting
In keeping with traditional practice, the cur- being sure that commissioners don’t secretly when the commis-
rent Antidumping Agreement requires more resort to extrastatutory criteria in making their sion will find injury,
than simply a finding of dumping before determinations. That said, U.S. practice is a
antidumping remedies may be imposed. In model of transparency and high analytical stan- or even of being
addition, it requires a finding that dumped dards compared to what goes on in many other sure that commis-
imports are causing “material injury” (or threat antidumping jurisdictions.
of material injury) to a domestic industry. This At a bare minimum, WTO rules should be
sioners don’t secret-
injury requirement is in keeping with the basic amended to require, as a necessary but not suf- ly resort to
concepts, principles, and objectives of the ficient condition for finding injury, the exis- extrastatutory crite-
Antidumping Agreement—namely, that trade- tence of a clearly established correlation
restricting remedies be used to offset artificial between increased imports and declining ria in making their
competitive advantages caused by underlying domestic industry performance. Accordingly, determinations.

25
It is necessary to we propose a change in the Antidumping Current WTO rules do make some effort
push beyond mere Agreement along the following lines: along these lines. Specifically, under the “non-
attribution requirement” of Article 3.5,
correlation and Reform Proposal 14: Article 3.5 of the antidumping authorities are required to “exam-
require the estab- Antidumping Agreement should be ine any known factors other than dumped
lishment of a causal revised to provide that no affirmative imports which at the same time are injuring the
injury determination shall be made in domestic industry, and the injuries caused by
link between the absence of a substantial correlation these other factors must not be attributed to the
imports and injury. between increased imports during the dumped imports.” In a Japanese challenge to the
period of investigation and declining U.S. antidumping investigation of hot-rolled
operating profits for the domestic steel, the WTO Appellate Body made clear
industry during the corresponding that, under this provision, antidumping author-
period. The required increase in ities are not allowed to lump imports with other
imports may take the form of either an factors and determine that, collectively, all the
absolute increase in import volume or a factors are causing injury. Rather, authorities
relative increase (i.e., an increase in must disentangle imports from other factors and
market share). In codifying this judge their injurious effects separately:
requirement, the Antidumping
Agreement should make clear that the We recognize, therefore, that it may
mere presence of such a correlation, not be easy, as a practical matter, to
standing alone, does not necessitate an separate and distinguish the injurious
affirmative determination. effects of different causal factors.
However, although this process may
If imports have not increased (whether in not be easy, this is precisely what is
absolute or market-share terms) during the peri- envisaged by the non-attribution lan-
od of investigation, there is no analytically tenable guage. If the injurious effects of the
basis for concluding that any woes suffered by the dumped imports and the other known
domestic industry during that period are due to factors remain lumped together and
imports rather than some other factor. Although indistinguishable, there is simply no
there are many indicators of industry perfor- means of knowing whether injury
mance besides operating profits (including sales ascribed to dumped imports was, in
volumes, average prices, investment, and employ- reality, caused by other factors. Article
ment), operating profits go to the heart of an 3.5, therefore, requires investigating
industry’s well-being. Profit levels reflect both authorities to undertake the process of
volumes and prices, and they have a direct impact assessing appropriately, and separating
on investment and employment. A bright-line and distinguishing, the injurious
requirement of a substantial (i.e., statistically sig- effects of dumped imports from those
nificant) correlation between increased imports of other known causal factors. 60
and declining operating profits is therefore emi-
nently sensible on the merits and has the added The Appellate Body’s interpretation of the
advantage of establishing some minimal analyti- nonattribution requirement, though, threatens
cal transparency in the injury process.59 to lead antidumping investigations into
But appropriate standards for guiding injury intractable factual and analytical difficulties. In
determinations cannot stop here. It is not two opinions dealing with causation of injury
enough to show that imports could have been in the context of the Agreement on Safeguards,
responsible for the domestic industry’s deterio- the Appellate Body ruled that, once an admin-
rating condition. It is necessary to push beyond istering authority isolates the injurious effects
mere correlation and require the establishment of imports from those of other causal factors,
of a causal link between imports and injury. the authority need not find that increased

26
imports alone are causing or threatening will simply fill the place formerly occupied by
injury. 61 Rather, the authority need find only a subject imports. If subject imports and domestic
“genuine and substantial relationship of cause production are not good substitutes (for exam-
and effect” between imports and injury that ple, if there are quality differences or other forms
may be the result of many causes. 62 of product differentiation), then the injurious
How this murky formulation should be effect of subject imports on the prices of domes-
applied in practice is unclear. What the tically produced merchandise will be attenuated.
Appellate Body’s standard appears to involve is And if other products are good substitutes for
some weighing of different causal factors— the subject merchandise, the effect of antidump-
that is, assigning relative importance to all the ing remedies will again be limited, because
various causal factors and then determining domestic producers will be constrained from
whether imports alone contribute “enough” to increasing prices because of competition from
the combined injurious effect. In many cases, substitute goods.
however, such a task would be so analytically Here then is an analytically sound approach
daunting as to be impracticable. to determining causation of injury. It is straight-
There is an easier and better way. We suggest forward and administrable: making reasonable
that the approach rejected by the Appellate estimates of substitutability is far easier than
Body in the context of the Safeguards assessing individually several different causal
The proper
Agreement be made an explicit requirement in factors and assigning to each some level of cul- approach is some-
the Antidumping Agreement: pability for an industry’s condition. This thing along the
approach opens up the black box of current
Reform Proposal 15: Article 5.3 of the injury analysis and makes clear exactly what lines of the so-
Antidumping Agreement should be conditions of competition need to be assessed. called unitary cau-
revised to require that antidumping A unitary-style approach to causation is not
authorities must find that dumped mechanical: it requires judgment calls and inter-
sation analysis,
imports, considered alone, are causing pretation of evidence. Accordingly, it does not which was used in
material injury or threat thereof. eliminate controversy or conflicting interpreta- the past by some
tions. Nevertheless, it at least specifies the factors
How is this requirement to be administered that bear on causation and makes them transpar- members of the
when there are multiple causal factors involved? ent. Revising the Antidumping Agreement to U.S. International
The proper approach is something along the lines require such an approach would be a dramatic Trade
of the so-called unitary causation analysis, which step toward making the injury requirement oper-
was used in the past by some members of the U.S. ational in an a consistent, administrable, and Commission.
International Trade Commission. Specifically, intellectually credible manner.
antidumping authorities should use basic tools of
quantitative economic analysis to determine Change Standards for “Negligibility”
whether the domestic industry is materially worse Under the current Antidumping Agreement,
off because of dumped imports—or, in other national antidumping authorities are authorized
words, whether application of the proposed to “cumulate” imports from multiple countries
antidumping measures would make the domestic for purposes of making an injury determination.
industry materially better off. In other words, authorities can group together
To make this determination, the administer- the imports from some or all countries under
ing authority would need to estimate the substi- investigation and determine whether the com-
tutability of subject and nonsubject imports, bined effect of those imports is to cause or
subject imports and domestic production, and threaten injury. Consequently, imports from a
domestic production and other goods. If non- particular country are frequently subject to
subject imports substitute easily for subject antidumping duties even though those imports,
imports, then the effect of antidumping reme- considered alone, were never found to have
dies will be limited, since nonsubject imports caused any harm.

27
There are understandable reasons for allow- investigation. In the investigation of hot-rolled
ing cumulation to some degree. Without it, arti- steel from Argentina, China, India, Indonesia,
ficial competitive advantages caused by market Kazakhstan, Netherlands, Romania, South
distortions might go completely unremedied Africa, Taiwan, Thailand, and Ukraine, five coun-
simply because no one import source, on its tries were considered and rejected for negligibili-
own, is considered injurious. On the other hand, ty exclusions because they exceeded the collective
dumping is a company- and country-specific threshold: Argentina, 1.74 percent of imports;
phenomenon: the artificial competitive advan- Kazakhstan, 2.78 percent; South Africa, 2.26 per-
tages targeted by antidumping policy supposed- cent; Thailand, 2.40 percent; and Ukraine, 2.65
ly accrue to particular companies and arise out of percent. Although each of those countries fell
government policies in those companies’ partic- below the normal negligibility threshold of 3 per-
ular home markets. Accordingly, if particular cent, collectively they accounted for 11.80 percent
companies or even whole countries are such of imports—and thus their products did not
minor players in an export market that they have qualify collectively as negligible imports.
no significant impact on competitive conditions In this particular case, however, all imports
in that market, then they cannot be said to enjoy from all sources accounted for only 26.4 percent
any real competitive advantage vis-à-vis the of the total U.S. merchant market for hot-rolled
domestic industry—and therefore cannot be steel and only 11.15 percent of total U.S. domes-
proper targets of antidumping remedies. tic consumption of hot-rolled steel. Accordingly,
Current antidumping rules balance these the import sources in question had the following
competing considerations by prohibiting the market shares: Argentina, 0.46 percent of the
cumulation of “negligible” imports—imports merchant market (0.19 percent of total domes-
from countries whose combined market share tic consumption); Kazakhstan, 0.74 percent
falls below a designated threshold. Specifically, (0.31 percent); South Africa, 0.60 percent (0.25
under Article 5.8 of the present Antidumping percent); Thailand, 0.63 percent (0.27 percent);
Agreement, imports from a particular country and Ukraine, 0.70 percent (0.30 percent). Those
are considered negligible if they amount to less countries thus had a combined market share of
than 3 percent of total imports of the product only 3.13 percent—or 1.32 percent, depending
under investigation—unless all the countries on how market share is measured for this partic-
under investigation that individually fall under ular industry. 63 This level of combined import
the 3 percent threshold together account for penetration cannot seriously be considered evi-
more than 7 percent of total imports. dence of an unfair competitive advantage—yet
While the general approach of allowing under current antidumping rules such imports
While the general cumulation except for negligible imports seems can be swept into the maw of a multicountry
basically sound, the current threshold for antidumping duty order.
approach of allow- determining negligibility is indefensible. Furthermore, judging negligibility on the
ing cumulation Specifically, determining negligibility on the basis of import share makes the standard a vari-
except for negligible basis of percentage of total imports makes no able one—indeed, one that varies in perverse
methodological sense. What matters is ways. The higher the total level of import pene-
imports seems basi- whether the arguably negligible imports are tration, the greater the market share an import
cally sound, the cur- capable of contributing meaningfully to the source can gain and still be considered negligi-
injury being suffered by the domestic indus- ble—despite the fact that overall high import
rent threshold for try—that is, whether they can be said to enjoy penetration presumably means that the domes-
determining negligi- any real competitive advantage relative to the tic industry is more vulnerable. Meanwhile, the
bility is indefensible. domestic industry. The proper criterion for lower the overall import penetration, the small-
judging this question is, not share of total er the volume of imports that exceeds the negli-
imports, but share of the overall export market. gibility cutoff—even though the domestic
Consider the difference between the two cri- industry is presumably less affected by foreign
teria in the context of a recent U.S. antidumping competition under such circumstances.

28
Accordingly, Article 5.8 of the Antidumping initiation of an antidumping investigation raises The mere act of
Agreement should be revised along the following the prospect of significant extra costs in the form launching an
lines: of duty liabilities—a prospect that many
importers, quite understandably, are anxious to antidumping inves-
Reform Proposal 16: Article 5.8 of the avoid. Consequently, the mere act of launching an tigation tends to
Antidumping Agreement should be antidumping investigation tends to depress
revised to change the threshold for neg- imports from investigated countries. And since
depress imports
ligibility from 3 percent of total import investigations last for approximately one year, sig- from investigated
volume (and 7 percent collectively) to 2 nificant damage can be done to a foreign produc- countries.
percent of domestic consumption (and 5 er even if it is ultimately cleared of all charges.64
percent collectively). Under current rules, it is too easy to launch
antidumping cases. Here in the United States,
This proposal would preserve the negligi- innocent companies are frequently harassed by
bility rule’s tradeoff between cumulation and ill-founded charges and unnecessary investiga-
exemption of small import sources. However, tions. Consider, for example, the fact that about
by redefining the criterion for judging negligi- 35 percent of U.S. cases result in findings of no
bility, it would decrease the likelihood that injury or no dumping. In other words, even
imports that by reason of small volume cannot assuming that all affirmative dumping and
materially injure a domestic industry get injury findings are justified, more than one-
unfairly tangled in protracted antidumping third of all U.S. investigations result in year-
proceedings. It would also discourage the long disruptions in fairly traded imports’ access
increasingly popular but abusive “shotgun to the U.S. market.
approach” to filing antidumping petitions, in Furthermore, it is instructive to compare
which domestic industries pile up allegations dumping margins alleged in U.S. antidumping
against many small exporting countries, many petitions with the dumping margins actually
of which are of no competitive concern what- found by the U.S. Department of Commerce.
soever, just for the purpose of pushing past the Although the Commerce Department’s calcula-
collective negligibility threshold of 7 percent. tions are rife with methodological distortions
that inflate dumping margins, they generally
Raise Initiation Standards result in dumping margins substantially lower
We have already proposed a major change than those alleged in the petition. For example,
in the process of initiating antidumping inves- in original investigations during 2001 in which
tigations—namely, that credible evidence of adverse facts available were not used, Commerce
underlying market distortions be made a found an average dumping margin of 38.18 per-
requirement for initiation (see Reform cent. By contrast, the average dumping margin
Proposals 1 and 2). Even if such fundamental alleged in the petitions in those cases was 100.80
reform of the definition of dumping is not percent—more than twice as high.65 It is clear,
undertaken, there are less far-reaching but still then, that the evidentiary quality of dumping
valuable improvements that can be made in the allegations in U.S. petitions is extremely low—
initiation process. Here again, the guiding yet it nonetheless passes muster with the
principle of reform should be to improve Commerce Department.
antidumping’s aim and limit disruption of nor- Hair-trigger initiation of antidumping cases is
mal commercial conduct. by no means an exclusively American problem. For
Lax initiation standards can be the cause of example, a WTO dispute settlement action
significant disruptions. This is so because mere brought by Mexico against Guatemala addressed
allegations of dumping can wreak havoc with the issue of lax initiation standards. At the center of
trade patterns. Under U.S. law, for example, the dispute was Guatemala’s decision to initiate an
importers are responsible for paying antidumping antidumping investigation of grey portland cement
duties. Thus, from an importer’s perspective, the from Mexico on the basis of laughably flimsy evi-

29
dence. The only evidence of dumping provided in Reform Proposal 17: Articles 5.2 and 5.3
the petition was two sets of invoices: two Mexican of the Antidumping Agreement should
invoices for one bag of cement each and two be revised to specify concrete evidentiary
invoices for Guatemalan imports from Mexico of standards for initiation. With respect to
thousands of bags each. Given the glaring differ- evidence of dumping, the petitioner
ences in sales volumes and levels of trade of the two must supply documentation on a compa-
sets of invoices, it should have been obvious that ny-specific basis of representative prices
this documentation provided no evidence of of the subject merchandise sold by the
dumping. Nevertheless, Guatemalan authorities foreign producer in the export market
initiated the case. Meanwhile, the two import and either (a) representative prices of
invoices also served as the only evidence in support comparable products sold by the foreign
of the petitioner’s allegation of threatened injury. producer in its home market or (b) credi-
In this particular case, the WTO found that ble estimates of the foreign producer’s
Guatemala’s initiation of an investigation cost of production. The petitioner must
under these circumstances was improper.66 We supply such company-specific evidence
have no way of knowing, however, how fre- with respect to at least four foreign pro-
quently antidumping authorities around the ducers or, alternatively, foreign producers
The current world are initiating investigations in a similar- accounting for a significant portion (for
Antidumping ly slipshod manner but are never held to example, at least 40 percent) of subject
Agreement provides account before the WTO. imports. With respect to evidence of
The problem is that the current Antidumping injury and causation, the petitioner must
no standards at all to Agreement provides no standards at all to con- supply documentation of trends in (a)
constrain the initia- strain the initiation of bogus cases. Article 5.2 of subject import volumes (including mar-
the agreement requires antidumping petitions to ket share); (b) prices in the export market;
tion of bogus cases. provide evidence of dumping, injury, and a and (c) the domestic industry’s sales vol-
causal link between the two; the agreement also umes (including market share), prof-
says that a “simple assertion, unsubstantiated by itability, and employment.
relevant evidence, cannot be considered suffi-
cient.” Even this nebulous language was enough For purposes of the above proposal, “representative”
to allow the WTO, after the fact, to rule price data means prices of major products that are
Guatemala’s egregious actions in the cement representative of price levels throughout the period
case out of bounds, but it does nothing to restrict of investigation. “Credible estimates” of production
abuses before they happen. Clear rules are need- costs should, to the extent possible, be based on the
ed to limit authorities’ discretion or create incen- foreign producer’s own data or at least data relating
tives for responsible behavior. to the foreign industry under investigation.
Reform Proposals 1 and 2, which would The requirements proposed above would
require credible evidence of underlying market not stop the filing of antidumping petitions for
distortions before any investigation is initiated, harassment purposes. However, they would at
would go a long way toward restricting baseless least bring some minimal discipline to the ini-
investigations. Those proposals, though, aim to tiation process and thereby afford some addi-
go beyond mere initiation standards to tional protection against the harassment of
rethinking the basic question of how dumping healthy import competition. Such an improve-
is defined. Even if such reforms are not adopt- ment in antidumping policy would be in keep-
ed in the short term, greater specification of the ing with the basic concepts, principles, and
evidentiary requirements for dumping as tradi- objectives of the Antidumping Agreement.
tionally defined would help to limit abuses in
the initiation process. We therefore suggest Mandate “Lesser-Duty Rule”
changes to the Antidumping Agreement along Article 9.1 of the current Antidumping
the following lines: Agreement states that it is “desirable” that

30
antidumping duties “be less than the [dumping] 49.8 percent, but the final duty rate was only 18.9
margin if such lesser duty would be adequate to percent—or 62 percent lower—because of the
remove the injury to the domestic industry.” This lesser-duty rule.67
express preference for the so-called lesser-duty Because the language in Article 9.1 is not
rule is in keeping with the basic concepts, princi- mandatory, WTO members are under no oblig-
ples, and objectives of the Antidumping ation at present to adopt a lesser-duty rule. The
Agreement. After all, the avowed purpose of U.S. law, for instance, does not have such a rule.
antidumping remedies is to restore a “level play- Among jurisdictions that do have some kind of
ing field”—in other words, to neutralize artificial lesser-duty rule, there is no consistency and little
competitive advantages created by market-dis- transparency in the manner in which it is applied.
torting government policies. If a particular duty As a result, antidumping duties in excess of those
rate is deemed sufficient to eliminate injury to the that can be justified by the basic concepts, princi-
domestic industry, there is no justification for ples, and objectives of the Antidumping
imposing a higher rate; a higher rate exceeds the Agreement are being imposed routinely.
mandate of creating a level playing field and slants To cure this glaring defect in current antidump-
the field in favor of the domestic industry. ing practice, we recommend a change in the
A number of WTO members—including the Antidumping Agreement along the following lines:
European Union—follow the approach recom-
mended in Article 9.1 and apply a lesser-duty rule Reform Proposal 18: Article 9.1 of the
in their antidumping investigations. The basic Antidumping Agreement should be
approach is to calculate “noninjurious prices”— revised to require that antidumping
prices for export sales that would not depress or duties be less than the dumping mar-
suppress the prices charged by the domestic gin if the lesser duty is sufficient to
industry. The difference between the export price remove the injury to the domestic
and the noninjurious price is referred to as the industry. Specifically, antidumping
“injury margin.” If the injury margin is greater authorities should be required to cal-
than the dumping margin, then the antidumping culate noninjurious prices for export
duty rate is equal to the dumping margin; if, how- sales, which would be at levels that do
ever, the injury margin is lower than the dumping not depress or suppress the prices
margin, the lesser duty applies and is set at the charged by the domestic industry. If
level of the injury margin. the difference between the noninjuri-
The lesser-duty rule can result in significant ous prices and the export prices
reductions in the antidumping duty rates that (known as the injury margin) is less
would otherwise apply. Consider the following than the dumping margin, the If a particular duty
examples of definitive duties imposed by the antidumping duty should be set at the
European Union during 2000. In the investigation lesser rate equal to the injury margin.
rate is deemed suf-
of seamless pipes and tubes from Croatia and ficient to eliminate
Ukraine, the authorities found final dumping mar- Raise de Minimis to 5 Percent in Investigations injury to the
gins of 40.8 percent and 123.7 percent, respective- and Reviews
ly; application of the lesser-duty rule, though, The calculation of dumping margins is domestic industry,
brought the actual duty rates down to 23.0 percent plagued with methodological difficulties. Most there is no justifica-
for Croatia and 38.5 percent for Ukraine—reduc- obviously, there are the distortions that tend to
tions of 44 percent and 69 percent, respectively. In skew the analysis in favor of finding dumping:
tion for imposing a
the investigation of hot-rolled steel from China, the failure to require evidence of underlying higher rate.
the final dumping margin came to 55.5 percent, market distortions, the cost test, the inclusion of
but because of the lesser-duty rule the actual duty profit in constructed value, the asymmetric
rate was only 8.1 percent—an 85 percent reduc- treatment of related-party sales, the asymmetric
tion. And in the investigation of black colorform- treatment of indirect selling expenses, the use of
ers (i.e., dyes) from Japan, the dumping margin was zeroing in dumping calculations, and so forth.

31
Even if obvious dis- Even if all those obvious distortions were elim- work. Especially vexing is the allocation of shared
tortions were elimi- inated, though, the measurement of dumping costs. Consider, for example, coproducts or joint
margins would still be highly inexact. In the typical products—two or more different goods that are
nated, the measure- investigation, antidumping authorities compare produced simultaneously in the same manufac-
ment of dumping home-market and export prices of physically dif- turing process. Examples include different cuts of
margins would still ferent goods, in different kinds of packaging, sold meat from the same animal, different ores
at different times, in different and fluctuating cur- extracted in the same mining operation, and dif-
be highly inexact. rencies, to different customers at different levels of ferent chemicals produced by the same reaction.
trade, in different quantities, with different freight For such products, some allocation of shared
and other movement costs, different credit terms, manufacturing costs is necessary for cost-
and other differences in directly associated selling accounting purposes. But how costs are allocated
expenses (for example, commissions, warranties, may well determine whether a given coproduct
royalties, and advertising). Is it really surprising that shows a profit or a loss. If costs are allocated
the prices compared are not identical? Wouldn’t it equally to high-value and low-value products (for
be surprising if they were? example, pig’s feet and pork chops), the low-value
Admittedly, antidumping authorities try to products will always show a huge loss. On the
adjust for some of those differences, but the other hand, if costs are allocated on the basis of
adjustments are necessarily crude and impre- the relative sales value of the coproducts, all
cise. For example, when the U.S. Department coproducts will show the same profitability—an
of Commerce compares physically different equally arbitrary outcome.
merchandise, it adjusts for differences in mate- The fact is that the accounting treatment is
rials, direct labor, and variable overhead costs. and should be irrelevant to proper business
While this makes a certain amount of sense, in decisions. Managers should decide what mix of
a real-world context it goes without saying that coproducts to target, not on the basis of arbi-
actual price differences may be more or less trary unit costs, but on the basis of maximizing
than the differences in variable manufacturing total net revenue. If a low-value product can
costs. As we pointed out in relation to second- fetch a price that covers the marginal costs of
quality merchandise, sometimes huge differ- further processing after “splitoff” from other
ences in commercial value can exist without joint products, the decision to engage in that
any measurable differences in manufacturing further processing and sell that low-value
costs. Similarly, the Commerce Department product is profit-maximizing regardless of how
adjusts for differences in warranty terms on the costs are allocated among all the joint products.
basis of differences in repair parts and labor Joint products are manufactured from the
costs. While this approach is logical enough, it same raw materials, but there are many other
is still extremely unlikely that the actual real- ways for products to share costs. Sharing of
world price differences between products with factory overhead costs (for example, the costs
different warranties are precisely equal to the of electricity, fuel, maintenance, plant and
differences in warranty costs. equipment depreciation, engineering support,
And in many cases, antidumping authorities research and development, selling, and general
make no adjustment at all. Thus, prices of goods and administrative expenses) is the norm in
sold in the export market may be compared to multiproduct firms. Indeed, economists explain
prices of goods sold many months earlier or later the very existence of multiproduct firms in
in the home market, without any adjustment for terms of cost sharing. The ubiquitousness of
market fluctuations. And although unit prices such cost sharing shows that unit costs must
typically decline with larger order quantities, the always be taken with several grains of salt. A
U.S. Department of Commerce rarely adjusts particular product that is never profitable when
for quantity discounts. viewed in isolation may nonetheless contribute
Calculations of unit costs of production are to fixed costs that would be incurred anyway on
similarly rife with more-or-less arbitrary guess- other, profitable products. Paradoxically, then, a

32
perennially money-losing product can help to Mandate a Public-Interest Test
maximize firmwide profits. A number of WTO members—including
In view of all these methodological chal- the EU, Canada, Thailand, and Malaysia—have
lenges, a healthy dose of humility is in order incorporated a “public-interest test” into their
regarding the accuracy of any dumping calcula- antidumping regulations. The basic idea behind
tions. Appropriately, such humility informs the such public-interest provisions is to make the
current Antidumping Agreement’s concept of imposition of antidumping measures permissive
de minimis dumping margins. Dumping mar- rather than mandatory. Specifically, a public-
gins below a certain threshold are deemed to be interest provision allows authorities to refuse to
de minimis and are treated as equal to zero. impose duties, even when dumping and injury
Given the tension between the trade-restrictive have been found, on the ground that antidump-
effects of antidumping measures and the overall ing measures in a particular case would be con-
orientation of the WTO agreement toward trary to the broader public interest.
market opening, a conservative policy of resolv- A public-interest test, if properly devised and
ing doubts against the imposition of duties is implemented, can help to reconcile a country’s
entirely fitting. antidumping policy with its larger national
The de minimis rule badly needs strength- interests. After all, even staunch defenders of
ening, however. Under Article 5.8 of the cur- antidumping remedies must recognize that the
A healthy dose of
rent agreement, the threshold is set at 2 per- resort to such remedies carries costs. Even if a humility is in order
cent. And because of awkward draftsmanship, domestic industry is being harmed by allegedly regarding the accu-
this provision is claimed by the United States dumped imports, other domestic interests—
to apply only to investigations—and not to namely downstream import-using industries racy of any dump-
subsequent administrative reviews that recalcu- and consumers—are benefited by them. Indeed, ing calculations.
late dumping margins after an antidumping the fact that the imports are entering the coun-
duty order goes into effect. Under U.S. law, the try in sufficient quantities to injure domestic
de minimis threshold in such reviews continues producers shows that many domestic interests
to be a mere 0.5 percent. prefer those imports to products made at home.
The threshold needs to be raised and applied Accordingly, antidumping investigations involve
equally to original investigations and reviews: more than a dispute between a domestic indus-
try and its foreign rivals; they also involve a con-
Reform Proposal 19: Article 5.8 of the flict of interest between that domestic industry
Antidumping Agreement should be and other domestic industries.
revised to provide that any margin of An antidumping law with no public-interest
dumping of less than 5 percent should provision fails to take account of these conflicting
be treated as de minimis. The same interests. If the requisite showings of dumping
definition of de minimis should apply and injury are made, trade-restrictive remedies
in both original investigations and follow automatically—regardless of the conse-
administrative reviews. quences for the rest of the country. That is hardly
a recipe for rational policymaking: if major affect-
In view of the irreducible imprecision of dumping ed interests are systematically ignored in the deci-
calculations, the de minimis threshold should be sionmaking process, it’s hardly likely that the
raised even if all of the reform proposals in this resulting policy will reflect an optimal accommo-
paper for addressing methodological distortions dation of all competing interests.
are ultimately adopted. If, however, any of the Furthermore, given the tension between the
existing distortions are left intact, the case for rais- trade-restrictive effects of antidumping measures
ing the de minimis threshold becomes that much and the market-opening thrust of the WTO
stronger. A relatively high de minimis threshold agreements as a whole, due restraint in the appli-
would act as a kind of final check on unremedied cation of antidumping measures is in keeping
methodological abuses. with the basic concepts, principles, and objectives

33
of the Antidumping Agreement. In that regard, Note that we suggest the use of some kind
Article 9.1 of the current agreement states, “It is of “disproportionate impact” standard for pur-
desirable that the imposition [of duties] be per- poses of applying the public-interest test. The
missive in the territory of all Members.” existence of a disproportionate impact could be
The present agreement, however, does not measured in a number of different ways. For
require any kind of public-interest test, much less example, the estimated welfare gain for the
specify standards for how it should be applied. petitioning industry could be compared to the
Consequently, many WTO members—includ- estimated welfare loss for specific downstream
ing the United States—have no public-interest industries, or for consumers. If the loss is some
provision at all. Meanwhile, there is little consis- designated multiple of the gain, the impact
tency or transparency in the public-interest provi- would be deemed disproportionate and duties
sions that do exist; by and large they are stan- would not be imposed. Alternatively, the esti-
dardless “black boxes” that occasionally block the mated number of jobs saved in the petitioning
imposition of duties for no clearly defined reason. industry could be compared to the estimated
In some countries, such as Canada, the public- number of jobs lost in downstream import-
interest provision merges with a lesser-duty rule, using industries. If the ratio of downstream
so that a public-interest determination must be jobs lost to petitioning industry jobs saved
made before the lesser-duty rule is invoked. crosses some designated threshold, duties
Antidumping policy around the world would would not be imposed on the ground of dis-
be greatly improved by mandating the inclusion of proportionate impact. Or authorities could cal-
a public-interest test and then specifying standards culate the deadweight loss to the economy per
for how it should be applied. On the latter point, job saved in the petitioning industry and com-
the critical challenge is to find some set of criteria pare that to average wages in the industry. If
that give the public-interest test real teeth without the economic cost is some designated multiple
causing it to swallow up all of antidumping policy. of the average wage, disproportionate impact
Thus, if the public interest is defined as “whatever’s would be found and no duties would be
good for domestic import-competing industries,” imposed.
then a public-interest provision will have no effect Any of these cost/benefit comparisons
at all. On the other hand, if the public interest is could be made with the use of fairly basic tech-
defined as pure economic efficiency, then the test niques of quantitative economic analysis.
would work to block the imposition of duties in Relatively easy to administer, such a public-
virtually all cases. interest test would have real teeth while still
Accordingly, we suggest that the Antidumping giving wide scope for the use of antidumping
Antidumping poli- Agreement be amended along the following lines: measures. Exactly how sharp the teeth or wide
the scope can be settled by choosing a higher or
cy around the world Reform Proposal 20: Article 9.1 of the lower threshold for “disproportionate”: the
would be greatly Antidumping Agreement should be higher the designated multiple of harms to
improved by man- revised to require the application of a benefits is set, the more modest the effect of
public-interest test before antidumping the public-interest test.
dating the inclusion measures are imposed. For purposes of
of a public-interest this test, antidumping measures would Make Termination of Antidumping Duty
be deemed contrary to the public interest Orders Automatic
test and then speci- if the harm inflicted by those measures on Before the WTO Antidumping Agreement,
fying standards for downstream import-using interests is some jurisdictions—in particular, the United
how it should be deemed disproportionate to the benefit States—lacked any regularly scheduled “sunset”
conferred on the petitioning domestic process for terminating antidumping duty
applied. industry. “Disproportionate,” for these orders. As a result, the average lifetime of U.S.
purposes, should be defined explicitly in orders exceeded a decade, and some continued
reference to specified benchmarks. for more than 30 years.

34
Such a state of affairs was glaringly inconsis- Reform Proposal 21: Article 11.3 of It is difficult
tent with any theory of antidumping policy as a the Antidumping Agreement should enough to control
response to market distortions. If antidumping be amended to provide for automatic
measures are to be justified on the ground that termination of antidumping duty antidumping
they offset artificial competitive advantages orders after five years. Domestic authorities’ abuse
caused by market distortions, it follows that industries would be able to file new of discretion when
those measures should be discontinued as soon petitions immediately upon expira-
as the distortions are eliminated or the advan- tion, but they would be required to their investigations
tages disappear. But if imports can be subject to show evidence of actual injury or are tied to a clear
antidumping remedies year after year despite the threat of injury by reason of dumped
fact that they are no longer injuring a domestic imports just as in any normal case. For evidentiary record;
industry, then antidumping has ceased to have petitions filed within one year of the it is next to impos-
anything to do with a level playing field and expiration of a prior order, special pro- sible when the
crossed over to simple protectionism. cedures would be required to expedite
To address this issue, the current WTO relief for petitioners. Specifically, the authorities are
Antidumping Agreement provides for a so- administering authorities would be allowed to gaze
called sunset review process. Specifically, Article required to make a preliminary find-
11.3 of the agreement mandates the automatic ing as to injury within 45 days of the
into a crystal ball.
termination of antidumping duty orders after initiation of the new investigation. If
five years unless a special review initiated before that preliminary determination is
expiration determines that termination of the affirmative, preliminary antidumping
order “would be likely to lead to the continua- measures would go into effect at the
tion or recurrence of dumping and injury.” rates that applied at the expiration of
Unfortunately, Article 11.3 has proved less the old order.
than successful in phasing out old orders. In
the United States, for example, there were 354 This proposal strikes a reasonable compromise
sunset reviews initiated between July 1998 and between two competing interests: on the one hand,
August 2002, of which 265 were contested by ensuring that antidumping measures are not main-
petitioners. The outcomes in 2 of those 265 tained even after the conditions that justified them
contested cases were still pending. The no longer exist, and, on the other hand, continuing
Department of Commerce made affirmative to provide a remedy when those conditions happen
sunset determinations to continue the order in to persist. Under the suggested reform, automatic
all but 4 of the 263 decided cases, while the termination ensures that all orders will come to an
ITC voted affirmative 72 percent of the time.68 end; at the same time, though, special provisions
The sunset review process is fundamentally for follow-up investigations ensure reasonable con-
flawed. At the root of the problem is the fact that tinuity of relief if conditions warrant. As to the pre-
the review is prospective and counterfactual in its liminary injury finding proposed, we envision
focus and thus inherently speculative. It seeks to something along the lines of the U.S. ITC’s pre-
determine whether dumping and injury will hap- liminary injury investigation. An affirmative find-
pen in the future if an order is lifted. It is difficult ing in this preliminary phase would trigger the
enough to control antidumping authorities’ abuse imposition of preliminary measures at the old rates
of discretion when their investigations are tied to even before any new finding on dumping margins.
a clear evidentiary record; it is next to impossible Subsequent preliminary and final determinations
when the authorities are allowed to gaze into a on dumping in the follow-up investigation would
crystal ball. replace the old rates with new ones.
Accordingly, to ensure that antidumping mea- Other than the special provisions for ensur-
sures do not continue after the artificial competitive ing continuity of relief, follow-up investigations
advantages that are their supposed target have been would be just like original investigations in every
neutralized, we suggest the following reform: respect: the same evidentiary requirements for

35
initiation, the same standards for determining earlier study, between 1995 and 2000 five of eight
dumping and injury. The all-too-often bogus Indian dumping determinations against U.S.
guessing games of the sunset process would be products were based on facts available—and the
replaced by full-blown dumping and injury average dumping margin in those five cases was
analysis in accordance with the normal provi- 83 percent. Three of four South African dumping
sions—and the basic concepts, principles, and determinations against U.S. products over the
objectives—of the Antidumping Agreement. same period were based on facts available, with an
average dumping margin of 89 percent.70
Unfortunately, no clear-cut solution to
Other Issues abuses of facts available is apparent. Since
antidumping authorities do not have subpoena
The 21 reform proposals discussed do not target power, they have to rely on the voluntary coop-
all of the flaws in current antidumping practice. eration of investigated companies. If those
Indeed, some of the most glaring flaws are not companies refuse to participate, the authorities
addressed—at least not directly. In crafting our pro- cannot simply give up; otherwise, stonewalling
posals, we chose to focus on problems that are (1) seri- would be a perfect defense. And authorities
ous and (2) susceptible to reform by changes in the must be able to throw out incomplete data;
Unfortunately, no WTO Antidumping Agreement. Unfortunately, otherwise, respondent firms could submit frag-
clear-cut solution to some of the worst abuses of antidumping laws cannot mentary data that appear to exonerate them
abuses of facts avail- be remedied effectively by adding one particular pro- and the authorities would again be stymied.
vision or another to WTO rules. Accordingly, there seems to be no alternative
able is apparent. The use of “facts available” in calculating to allowing authorities the discretion to disre-
dumping margins is one of the most important gard respondents’ price and cost data. Given that
issues that we did not address. Normally, fact, authorities must also have the discretion to
antidumping authorities calculate a foreign pro- choose the facts available that will substitute for
ducer’s dumping margin on the basis of compa- respondents’ data in the dumping calculations.
ny-specific price and cost data submitted during And where there is discretion, there is the ever-
the course of the investigation. If, however, the present possibility of abuse of discretion.
foreign producer declines to participate in the We do not see how WTO rules could define
investigation, or if the authorities determine that with any clarity either (1) the circumstances
the information submitted is either incomplete under which resort to facts available is justified
or inaccurate, the authorities may use facts avail- or (2) the standards for selecting facts available
able to calculate the company’s dumping mar- for use in dumping calculations. The propriety
gin. Those facts available frequently include the or impropriety of antidumping authorities’ con-
alleged dumping margins featured in the duct on either front will inevitably turn on case-
domestic industry’s antidumping petition. specific factual circumstances that cannot be
The use of facts available typically results in specified in advance. The best that can be done
extremely high dumping margins. In an earlier is to lay out broad, general standards for when
paper by one of the coauthors of this study, an and how facts available should be used.
examination of 141 U.S. dumping determina- The current Antidumping Agreement
tions over a three-year period found that the already establishes such standards. Article 6.8
average dumping margin calculated on the states that facts available can be used only when
basis of facts available was a whopping 95.58 a respondent “refuses access to, or otherwise
percent—compared to 27.22 percent when the does not provide, necessary information within a
foreign producer’s data were used. In that peri- reasonable period or significantly impedes the
od, the Commerce Department used facts investigation.” Annex II, paragraph 5 of the
available just over 25 percent of the time.69 agreement further states that respondents’ infor-
U.S. exporters are frequent victims of facts mation should not be disregarded “even though
available determinations. As we discussed in an the information provided may not be provided

36
in all respects, . . . provided the interested party in the first place. Because of the glaring flaws in
has acted to the best of his ability.” Also, para- existing antidumping rules, investigations are
graph 7 of Annex II provides guidance regard- routinely instituted without any evidence of
ing sources of facts available to be used by unfair trade under any plausible definition of
antidumping authorities. that term. The harm caused by those unjustifi-
It is possible that the existing language could able investigations can then be exacerbated by
be tightened up and improved. Even if that is abuses of administrative discretion or outright
done, however, little will have changed. misconduct. If the number of unjustifiable
Authorities will still have broad discretion to investigations can be reduced, the number of
disregard respondents’ data, and even wider dis- investigations plagued by facts available or non-
cretion about what to use in their stead. If transparency can likewise be expected to fall.
antidumping authorities are intent on abusing The reform proposals set forth in this paper
the law and achieving a protectionist outcome, thus constitute an indirect and partial solution to
they will still have wide latitude to do so. On other problems that resist straight-on efforts at
occasion, victimized countries might challenge reform. All of our reform proposals take the form
the use of facts available through WTO dispute of specific rules—as opposed to broad, discre-
settlement and win a reversal. But by and large, tionary standards. Such clear-cut rules provide
the facts available loophole cannot be closed. authorities with little discretion about how to
Another serious problem with current implement them and thus are hard to circumvent.
antidumping practice is the lack of transparency If the new rules proposed here are adopted and
and basic administrative fairness. With its com- incorporated into the WTO Antidumping
plexity and wide scope for discretion, the Agreement, dramatic improvements in antidump-
antidumping law creates enormous potential for ing practice would almost certainly ensue. With
abuse in poorer countries that lack well-estab- some coherence achieved between the basic con-
lished traditions of transparency and the rule of cepts, principles, and objectives of the
law. Failure to provide respondent companies Antidumping Agreement and the specific provi-
with the factual and legal bases for determina- sions of that agreement, there would be a signifi-
tions, to allow them a fair hearing, to take cant reduction in unjustifiable antidumping activi-
account of their claims of legal and factual errors ty—that is, in antidumping investigations and
in determinations, and to safeguard the privacy measures that have no rational relation to offsetting
of their confidential business data are all proce- artificial competitive advantages created by mar-
dural irregularities that are in clear violation of ket-distorting government policies. As a result,
current WTO rules, yet they are alleged to be there would be fewer opportunities for authorities
distressingly common in many countries. to misuse facts available or run roughshod over the The only effective
Consequently, substantive flaws in antidumping requirements of procedural fairness.
rules are all too often compounded by egregious
way to reduce the
procedural unfairness. abuses of facts
Abuses caused by nontransparency or out- Conclusion available and non-
right corruption are difficult to remedy
through changes in WTO rules. Since current Antidumping reform faces formidable obsta- transparency is to
rules are being widely ignored, it is doubtful cles. Use of antidumping laws around the world reduce the number
that new rules will meet a better fate. Indeed, is widespread and growing; and wherever these
the very essence of nontransparency and cor- laws operate, the protectionist status quo enjoys
of unjustified
ruption is that government officials don’t fol- the support of entrenched bureaucracies and antidumping inves-
low the stated rules. import-competing corporate interests. In the tigations that are
The only effective way to reduce the abuses United States in particular, energetic and well-
of facts available and nontransparency is to organized protectionist lobbies have mobilized initiated and con-
reduce the number of unjustified antidumping nearly overwhelming political support for their ducted in the first
investigations that are initiated and conducted position on antidumping issues. As a result, for place.

37
Now is the time to many years the world’s most powerful country more or less the same position—namely, that
build a durable and leader of the multilateral trading system has the basic objective of the Antidumping
stood as the principal opponent of meaningful Agreement is to allow member states to offset
foundation for an changes in antidumping rules. artificial competitive advantages created by
ongoing project of Of all the obstacles hindering antidumping market-distorting government policies.
reform, however, none is greater than ignorance. A consensus along those lines would be of
reform. Now is the Failure to understand how antidumping laws enormous value in guiding negotiations about
time to change the actually operate in practice—and how they fail so specific provisions of the Antidumping
terms of the debate. spectacularly to do what their supporters say they Agreement. That consensus would provide a
are supposed to do—lies at the root of much of benchmark by which to evaluate contemporary
the resistance to antidumping reform. Many sup- antidumping practice—a benchmark in com-
porters of the antidumping status quo honestly parison to which much of contemporary prac-
believe that these laws in their present form are tice would be found sadly deficient. This critical
necessary to combat unfair trading practices and evaluation, in turn, would help to define the
thereby ensure a level playing field. If those sup- work program of negotiators—namely, to
porters fully understood the reality of contempo- reduce the yawning gap between antidumping’s
rary antidumping practice—if they understood accepted goals and its actual practice. We believe
how frequently trade-restrictive measures are that the specific reform proposals outlined in
inflicted on normal, healthy competition—their this study define, at least in broad outline, the
opposition to needed reforms would likely soften. work program that needs to be undertaken.
Of course, protectionist interests support This work program may prove too ambi-
the antidumping status quo so fervently pre- tious to be accomplished in a single round. But
cisely because of its flaws. Their goal is to at least the work can be started—and the
squelch foreign competition in whatever way groundwork for ongoing progress in future
they can, and the antidumping law in its cur- rounds can be laid. In the Uruguay Round
rent form has proved very handy indeed. And agreements on agriculture and services, for
because of ignorance about the law’s complex example, actual reductions of market barriers
workings, protectionist interests are able to were modest, but at least a consensus was built
cloak their special pleading in the high-mind- for the need to make further progress in the
ed rhetoric of fairness and concern for a level future. As a result, in the current Doha Round,
playing field. If they were forced to defend the there is no dispute about whether market barri-
status quo honestly, for the protectionist scam ers in agriculture and services should be
that it is, they would find it much harder to win reduced; the only question is how much.
adherents to their cause. By contrast, the Uruguay Round achieved
Accordingly, supporters of antidumping no consensus on the proper objectives of
reform need to make education and clarifica- antidumping policy. Negotiators succeeded in
tion their top priorities in WTO negotiations. hammering out the Antidumping Agreement,
Negotiations that focus exclusively on specific but all it really did was to codify existing U.S.
changes to the Antidumping Agreement are and EU practice with a few technical modifi-
doomed to achieve disappointing results. cations around the edges. Without any consen-
Instead, the first order of business ought to be sus on why the agreement exists or what pur-
clarifying what exactly are the basic concepts, pose it serves, when the time came to launch a
principles, and objectives of the Antidumping new round, supporters of reform had to strug-
Agreement. In this paper, we have sought to gle ferociously just to get antidumping on the
identify those basic concepts, principles, and negotiating agenda.
objectives by relying on the justifications for Antidumping reform shouldn’t have to start
antidumping measures offered by U.S. from scratch every time. Now is the time to build
antidumping supporters. We believe that a durable foundation for an ongoing project of
WTO negotiations would ultimately arrive at reform. Now is the time to change the terms of

38
the debate. If supporters of reform play their cards nomic efficiency may very well conflict with con-
cerns about fairness. Even if worldwide economic
right, the Doha Round will end the question of efficiency is harmed by trade-distorting practices,
whether antidumping abuses should be curtailed. it may still be in the national economic interest of
How much will be the only topic for negotiation in an importing country to allow “unfair” imports
future rounds. to enter freely and thereby reap the gains of their
artificially low prices. In such situations, trade-
restrictive antidumping remedies will sacrifice
national economic efficiency for the sake of fair-
Notes ness to domestic import-competing industries.
1. The agreement is available online at www.wto. 13. “Basic Concepts and Principles of the Trade
org/english/docs_e/legal_e/19-adp.pdf. Remedy Rules,” p. 3.
2. Trade Act of 2002, Public Law 107-210, sec. 14. Ibid., p. 4.
2102(b)(14)(A).
15. “Observations on the Distinctions between
3. House Con. Res. 262, 107th Cong., 1st sess., Competition Laws and Antidumping Rules,”
November 7, 2001. Interestingly, at the same time the Submission of the United States to the WTO
resolution also instructed the president to “ensure Working Group on the Interaction of Trade and
that United States exports are not subject to the abu- Competition Policy,” Meeting of July 27–28, 1998.
sive use of trade laws, including antidumping and Cited hereafter as U.S. WTO 1998 Submission.
countervailing duty laws, by other countries.”
16. U.S. 1998 WTO Submission, p. 1.
4. “62 Senators Call on President Not to Weaken
Trade Remedy Laws,” Inside U.S. Trade, May 11, 2001. 17. Ibid., p. 2.
5. See Gary Horlick, “The Speed Bump at Seattle,” 18. Ibid.
Journal of International Economic Law 3 (March 2000):
167. 19. Ibid., p. 9.

6. World Trade Organization, Ministerial Declaration, 20. Ibid., p. 14.


November 14, 2001, WT/MIN(01)/DEC/W/1, para.
28. Emphasis added. 21. Ibid., p. 4.

7. An earlier U.S. antidumping law with criminal 22. Alan Wolff, “Role of the Antidumping Laws,”
sanctions was enacted in 1916 (and is at this writ- Remarks before the Steel Manufacturers
ing still on the books despite a WTO ruling that Association, May 3, 1995, p. 2. Emphasis in original.
it is inconsistent with the Antidumping
23. Terence P. Stewart, “Administration of the
Agreement), but the current law that imposes
Antidumping Law: A Different Perspective,” in
antidumping duties traces back to 1921.
Down in the Dumps: Administration of the Unfair Trade
8. During 1995–2001, the United States initiated Laws, ed. Richard Boltuck and Robert E. Litan
255 antidumping investigations, more than any (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1991), p. 288.
other country. The second most frequent
24. Greg Mastel, Antidumping Laws and the U.S.
antidumping user over the same period was India,
Economy (Armonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, 1998).
with 248 initiations; the European Union fol-
lowed closely with 246 initiations. Argentina was 25. Ibid., pp. 42–43.
a distant fourth with 170 initiations. For statistics
on antidumping initiations worldwide during 26. Ibid., p. 43.
1995–2001, see www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/
adp_e/adp_stattab2_e.htm. 27. U.S. 1998 WTO Submission, p. 2.

9. “Basic Concepts and Principles of the Trade 28. Mastel, p. 40.


Remedy Rules,” Communication from the
United States to the WTO Negotiating Group on 29. This point is developed at greater length in
Rules, TN/RL/W/27, October 22, 2002. Brink Lindsey, “The U.S. Antidumping Law:
Rhetoric versus Reality,” Cato Institute Trade
10. Ibid., p. 3. Policy Analysis no. 7, August 16, 1999, pp. 16–17.

11. Ibid. 30. Brink Lindsey and Dan Ikenson, “Antidumping


101: The Devilish Details of ‘Unfair Trade’ Law,”
12. On the other hand, a focus on national eco- Cato Institute Trade Policy Analysis no. 20,

39
November 26 2002. 46. In the EU–Bed Linen case, the Appellate Body
found that zeroing is inconsistent with Article 2.4.2
31. Lindsey, “The U.S. Antidumping Law: of the Antidumping Agreement, which provides
Rhetoric versus Reality.” that dumping shall be determined on the basis of
comparing average normal values to average export
32. See Brink Lindsey and Dan Ikenson, “Coming prices except under special circumstances. Zeroing,
Home to Roost: Proliferating Antidumping Laws the Appellate Body concluded, departs inappropri-
and the Growing Threat to U.S. Exports,” Cato ately from a true average-to-average comparison and
Institute Trade Policy Analysis no. 14, July 30, 2001. thus runs afoul of WTO rules. Because of the
Appellate Body’s ruling, the EU has discontinued
33. U.S. Trade Representative Robert Zoellick has
zeroing in cases in which dumping margins are
noted this fact on numerous occasions. See, for
based on average-to-average comparisons.
example, “Statement of U.S. Trade Representative
However, Article 2.4.2 allows a departure from
Robert B. Zoellick before the Committee on Finance
average-to-average comparisons in cases where
of the U.S. Senate,” February 6, 2002, www.
“authorities find a pattern of export prices which
ustr.gov/speech-test/zoellick /zoellick_14.html.
differ significantly among different purchasers,
34. For a detailed discussion of alternative causes regions or time periods.” In those so-called targeted
of price differences and below-cost sales, see dumping situations, authorities may calculate
Lindsey, “Rhetoric versus Reality,” pp. 11–19. dumping by comparing individual export transac-
tions to average normal values. The EU’s present
35. Under certain circumstances, antidumping position is that, in cases where individual-to-average
authorities ignore data submitted by companies comparisons are used, zeroing is not inconsistent
under investigation and instead base their dump- with the Appellate Body’s ruling in EU–Bed Linen.
ing findings on “facts available”—which usually Accordingly, the EU will continue to perform zero-
means the allegations made by the domestic ing in those kinds of cases. See, e.g., “Proposal for a
industry in its petition. See the section on “Other Council Regulation Imposing a Definitive Anti-
Issues” below for a fuller discussion. Dumping Duty and Collecting Definitively the
Provisional Duty Imposed on Imports of
36. See Lindsey and Ikenson, “Antidumping 101,” Recordable Compact Disks Originating in Taiwan,”
pp. 13–16. Official Journal of the European Communities, 2002/C
227E/362, September 24, 2002, para. 32–33.
37. Note that this table appeared previously as Table 4
in Lindsey and Ikenson, “Antidumping 101.” 47. See discussion in note 46.
38. These findings are consistent with an examina- 48. The effect of zeroing is somewhat worse in indi-
tion of an earlier U.S. case by one of the coauthors. vidual-to-average comparisons, since when model-
In that case, the 1998 investigation of static random specific average prices in the home market and export
access memory chips from Taiwan, the Commerce market are compared to each other, at least negative
Department found a dumping margin of 7.56 per- dumping margins on particular sales of that model
cent. If no cost test had been used, the margin would will offset positive dumping margins on sales of that
have been only 2.74 percent—64 percent lower. See model. Even here, though, overall negative dumping
Lindsey, “Rhetoric versus Reality,” p. 9. margins for one model cannot offset overall positive
margins of other models because of zeroing.
39. These figures are derived from Lindsey,
“Rhetoric versus Reality,” Table 2, Appendix. 49. At present, the Appellate Body has not ruled on
whether zeroing is permissible in targeted dump-
40. “Basic Concepts and Principles of the Trade ing situations, or whether individual-to-average
Remedy Rules,” p. 3. comparisons are generally permissible in adminis-
trative reviews. It is possible that, if these issues are
41. See Lindsey and Ikenson, “Antidumping 101,” p. 16. ever litigated, the Appellate Body could decide to
42. Lindsey, “Rhetoric versus Reality,” p. 10. close these loopholes under current WTO rules.
Such an outcome, though, cannot be assumed.
43. Ibid., Table 4, p. 11.
50. See Lindsey and Ikenson, “Antidumping 101,”
44. See Lindsey and Ikenson, “Antidumping 101,” pp. 20–21.
pp. 21–22.
51. By contrast, Article 2.3 of the current
45. Appellate Body Report on European Antidumping Agreement provides that export-mar-
Communities—Anti-Dumping Duties on Imports of ket sales to affiliates may be disregarded, in which case
Cotton-Type Bed Linen from India, WT/DS141/ a “constructed export price” based on resales from the
AB/R, March 1, 2001. affiliates to unrelated purchasers may be used instead.

40
52. The appropriate standards for determining of Wheat Gluten from the European Communities,
whether companies should be regarded as affiliated WT/DS166/AB/R, December 22, 2000, para. 69.
parties raise a host of additional issues not covered
in this paper. 63. These figures were derived from U.S.
International Trade Commission, Hot-Rolled Steel
53. Under certain circumstances, after excluding affili- Products from Argentina, China, India, Indonesia,
ated sales, the Commerce Department will require the Kazakhstan, Netherlands, Romania, South Africa,
affiliated party to report its resales to unaffiliated cus- Taiwan, Thailand, and Ukraine, Investigation nos. 701-
tomers. Those resales will then be included in the cal- TA-404-408 (preliminary) and 731-TA-898-908 (pre-
culation of normal value. In this paper we do not make liminary), USITC Publication no. 3381, January
any proposal regarding the practice of including 2001; Hot Rolled Steel Products from Argentina and South
resales in the calculation of normal value. Africa, Inv. nos. 701-TA-404 (final) and 731-TA-898
and 905 (final), USITC Publication no. 3446, August
54. See Lindsey and Ikenson, “Antidumping 101,” 2001. Note that the difference between the mer-
pp. 12–13. chant market and total domestic consumption lies
in the fact that approximately 65 percent of hot-
55. This investigation gave rise to the dispute that rolled steel produced by the U.S. industry is “cap-
resulted in the WTO’s ruling that the U.S. arm’s- tively consumed” by U.S. steel producers in the man-
length test is WTO-inconsistent. See below for a ufacture of downstream products.
discussion of that ruling.
64. See Thomas J. Prusa, “On the Spread and
56. Report by the Appellate Body on United Impact of Antidumping,” National Bureau of
States–Anti-Dumping Measures on Certain Hot-Rolled Economic Research Working Paper 7404,
Steel Products from Japan, WT/DS184/AB/R, July October 1999, www.nber.org/papers/w7404.
24, 2001.
65. The average Commerce dumping margin was
57. See the Commerce Department’s request for calculated as the simple average of all the compa-
public comment, 67 Fed. Reg. 53339, August 15, ny-specific dumping margins from original inves-
2002. tigations during 2001 in which adverse facts avail-
able were not used. Since adverse facts available
58. See Lindsey and Ikenson, “Antidumping 101,”
are generally based on figures in the petition,
p. 20.
inclusion of these determinations would have cre-
59. Note that, under certain circumstances, it may ated circularity problems when comparing
be necessary to use some kind of time lag when Commerce’s findings to petitioners’ allegations.
determining whether increasing imports and For petition dumping margins, we used compa-
declining operating profits are substantially cor- ny-specific allegations if available; otherwise, we
related. Specifically, the effect of increasing used either the simple average of the lowest and
imports on a domestic industry’s profitability highest rates alleged or the countrywide average
may not be immediate. In such cases, imports rate if one was alleged. We then calculated the
during one period would have to be compared to simple average of all the petition rates thus
profitability during a somewhat later period. derived from all original investigation determina-
tions during 2001 in which Commerce calculated
60. Appellate Body Report on United States—Anti- a company-specific rate not based on adverse facts
Dumping Measures on Certain Hot-Rolled Steel Products available.
from Japan, WT/DS184/AB/R, July 24, 2001, para. 228.
66. Panel Report on Guatemala—Definitive Anti-
61. Although these decisions concern the Dumping Measures on Grey Portland Cement from
Agreement on Safeguards rather than the Mexico, WT/DS156/R, October 24, 2000.
Antidumping Agreement, the conceptual issues
regarding causation of injury are identical in the 67. See Commission of the European Communities,
two agreements. Accordingly, Appellate Body “Nineteenth Annual Report from the Commission
interpretations of the Safeguards Agreement on to the European Parliament on the Community’s
this point are very likely to be followed when the Anti-Dumping and Anti-Subsidy Activities (2000),”
same issue arises under the Antidumping October 12, 2001.
Agreement.
68. These figures were compiled as of August 14, 2002,
62. Appellate Body Report on United States— from data available on the ITC website, www.usitc.gov.
Safeguard Measures on Imports of Fresh, Chilled or
69. These figures were derived from Lindsey,
Frozen Lamb Meat from New Zealand and Australia,
“Rhetoric versus Reality,” Table 2, Appendix.
WT/DS177/AB/R, WT/DS178/AB/R, May 1,
2001, para. 168, quoting Appellate Body Report on 70. Lindsey and Ikenson, “Coming Home to
United States—Definitive Safeguard Measures on Imports Roost,” p. 15.

41
Trade Briefing Papers from the Cato Institute
“Rethinking the Export-Import Bank” by Aaron Lukas and Ian Vásquez (no. 15, March 12, 2002)

“Steel Trap: How Subsidies and Protectionism Weaken the U.S. Steel Industry” by Dan Ikenson, (no. 14, March 1, 2002)

“America’s Bittersweet Sugar Policy” by Mark A. Groombridge (no. 13, December 4, 2001)

“Missing the Target: The Failure of the Helms-Burton Act” by Mark A. Groombridge (no. 12, June 5, 2001)

“The Case for Open Capital Markets” by Robert Krol (no. 11, March 15, 2001)

“WTO Report Card III: Globalization and Developing Countries” by Aaron Lukas (no. 10, June 20, 2000)

“WTO Report Card II: An Exercise or Surrender of U.S. Sovereignty?” by William H. Lash III and Daniel T. Griswold (no.
9, May 4, 2000)

“WTO Report Card: America’s Economic Stake in Open Trade” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 8, April 3, 2000)

“The H-1B Straitjacket: Why Congress Should Repeal the Cap on Foreign-Born Highly Skilled Workers” by Suzette Brooks
Masters and Ted Ruthizer (no. 7, March 3, 2000)

“Trade, Jobs, and Manufacturing: Why (Almost All) U.S. Workers Should Welcome Imports” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 6,
September 30, 1999)

“Trade and the Transformation of China: The Case for Normal Trade Relations” by Daniel T. Griswold, Ned Graham, Robert
Kapp, and Nicholas Lardy (no. 5, July 19, 1999)

“The Steel ‘Crisis’ and the Costs of Protectionism” by Brink Lindsey, Daniel T. Griswold, and Aaron Lukas (no. 4, April 16,
1999)

“State and Local Sanctions Fail Constitutional Test” by David R. Schmahmann and James S. Finch (no. 3, August 6, 1998)

“Free Trade and Human Rights: The Moral Case for Engagement” by Robert A. Sirico (no. 2, July 17, 1998)

“The Blessings of Free Trade” by James K. Glassman (no. 1, May 1, 1998)

From the Cato Institute Briefing Papers Series


“The Myth of Superiority of American Encryption Products” by Henry B. Wolfe (no. 42, November 12, 1998)

“The Fast Track to Freer Trade” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 34, October 30, 1997)

“Anti-Dumping Laws Trash Supercomputer Competition” by Christopher M. Dumler (no. 32, October 14, 1997)

42
Trade Policy Analysis Papers from the Cato Institute
“Antidumping 101: The Devilish Details of ‘Unfair Trade’ Law” by Brink Lindsey and Dan Ikenson (no. 20, November 26, 2002)

“Willing Workers: Fixing the Problem of Illegal Mexican Migration to the United States” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 19, October 15,
2002)

“The Looming Trade War over Plant Biotechnology” by Ronald Bailey (no. 18, August 1, 2002)

“Safety Valve or Flash Point? The Worsening Conflict between U.S. Trade Laws and WTO Rules” by Lewis E. Leibowitz (no. 17,
November 6, 2001)

“Safe Harbor or Stormy Waters? Living with the EU Data Protection Directive” by Aaron Lukas (no. 16, October 30, 2001)

“Trade, Labor, and the Environment: How Blue and Green Sanctions Threaten Higher Standards” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 15,
August 2, 2001)

“Coming Home to Roost: Proliferating Antidumping Laws and the Growing Threat to U.S. Exports” by Brink Lindsey and Dan
Ikenson (no. 14, July 30, 2001)

“Free Trade, Free Markets: Rating the 106th Congress” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 13, March 26, 2001)

“America’s Record Trade Deficit: A Symbol of Economic Strength” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 12, February 9, 2001)

“Nailing the Homeowner: The Economic Impact of Trade Protection of the Softwood Lumber Insudstry” by Brink Linsey,
Mark A. Groombridge, and Prakash Loungani (no. 11, July 6, 2000)

“China’s Long March to a Market Economy: The Case for Permanent Normal Trade Relations with the People’s Republic of
China” by Mark A. Groombridge (no. 10, April 24, 2000)

“Tax Bytes: A Primer on the Taxation of Electronic Commerce” by Aaron Lukas (no. 9, December 17, 1999)

“Seattle and Beyond: A WTO Agenda for the New Millennium” by Brink Lindsey, Daniel T. Griswold, Mark A.
Groombridge and Aaron Lukas (no. 8, November 4, 1999)

“The U.S. Antidumping Law: Rhetoric versus Reality” by Brink Lindsey (no. 7, August 16, 1999)

“Free Trade, Free Markets: Rating the 105th Congress” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 6, February 3, 1999)

“Opening U.S. Skies to Global Airline Competition” by Kenneth J. Button (no. 5, November 24, 1998)

“A New Track for U.S. Trade Policy” by Brink Lindsey (no. 4, September 11, 1998)

“Revisiting the ‘Revisionists’: The Rise and Fall of the Japanese Economic Model” by Brink Lindsey and Aaron Lukas (no. 3,
July 31, 1998)

“America’s Maligned and Misunderstood Trade Deficit” by Daniel T. Griswold (no. 2, April 20, 1998)

“U.S. Sanctions against Burma: A Failure on All Fronts” by Leon T. Hadar (no. 1, March 26, 1998)

43
Board of Advisers CENTER FOR TRADE POLICY STUDIES
James K. Glassman
American Enterprise
Institute T he mission of the Cato Institute’s Center for Trade Policy Studies is to increase public
understanding of the benefits of free trade and the costs of protectionism. The center
publishes briefing papers, policy analyses, and books and hosts frequent policy forums and
Douglas A. Irwin conferences on the full range of trade policy issues.
Dartmouth College Scholars at the Cato trade policy center recognize that open markets mean wider choices
and lower prices for businesses and consumers, as well as more vigorous competition that
Lawrence Kudlow encourages greater productivity and innovation. Those benefits are available to any country
Kudlow & Co. that adopts free-trade policies; they are not contingent upon “fair trade” or a “level playing
field” in other countries. Moreover, the case for free trade goes beyond economic efficiency.
José Piñera The freedom to trade is a basic human liberty, and its exercise across political borders unites
International Center for people in peaceful cooperation and mutual prosperity.
Pension Reform
The center is part of the Cato Institute, an independent policy research organization in
Razeen Sally
Washington, D.C. The Cato Institute pursues a broad-based research program rooted in the
London School of traditional American principles of individual liberty and limited government.
Economics
For more information on the Center for Trade Policy Studies,
George P. Shultz visit www.freetrade.org.
Hoover Institution
Other Trade Studies from the Cato Institute
Walter B. Wriston
Former Chairman and
CEO, Citicorp/Citibank
“Antidumping 101: The Devilish Details of ‘Unfair Trade’ Law” by Brink Lindsey and Dan
Ikenson, Trade Policy Analysis no. 20 (November 26, 2002)
Clayton Yeutter
Former U.S. Trade “Willing Workers: Fixing the Problem of Illegal Mexican Migration to the United States” by
Representative Daniel T. Griswold, Trade Policy Analysis no. 19 (October 15, 2002)

“The Looming Trade War over Plant Biotechnology” by Ronald Bailey, Trade Policy Analysis
no. 18 (August 1, 2002)

“Rethinking the Export-Import Bank” by Aaron Lukas and Ian Vásquez, Trade Briefing
Paper no. 15 (March 12, 2002)

“Steel Trap: How Subsidies and Protectionism Weaken the U.S. Steel Industry” by Dan Ikenson,
Trade Briefing Paper no. 14 (March 1, 2002)

“America’s Bittersweet Sugar Policy” by Mark A. Groombridge, Trade Briefing Paper no. 13
(December 4, 2001)

Nothing in Trade Policy Analysis should be construed as necessarily reflecting the views of the
Center for Trade Policy Studies or the Cato Institute or as an attempt to aid or hinder the pas-
sage of any bill before Congress. Contact the Cato Institute for reprint permission. Additional
copies of Trade Policy Analysis studies are $6 each ($3 for five or more). To order, contact the
Cato Institute, 1000 Massachusetts Avenue, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20001. (202) 842-
0200, fax (202) 842-3490, www.cato.org.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi