Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 9

25-8-2014

The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

Page info: *Author: Mathiesen, H.


*Document version: 2.2.
*Copyright 1997-2014,
ViamInvest. Legal notice.

Model: The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets


1

Introduction

This appendix presents proofs of a modern version of the Modigliani and Miler propositions on the
irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets. Note: Footnotes and highlighted text can be
clicked for more info.
The propositions on capital structure made by Modigliani and Miller (M&M) are among the
most important contributions in the theory of corporate finance. The theorems were first stated in the
seminal papers [1958, 1963] on the cost of capital, corporate valuation and capital structure. The first
versions were very simple. They assumed that debt could be only of the risk-free type, and that all
firms belonged to the same risk class. The latter assumption meant that the expected future cash flow
in all firms should be perfectly correlated, and only allowed to vary by a scale factor. E.g. CFi,t =
aCFj,t, where CF is cash flow in firm i and j, respectively, a is the scale factor, and t count the future
periods. These assumptions are certainly unrealistic, but fortunately, later developments in the theory of
corporate finance made them redundant. Independent of the capital structure theory Sharpe [1963,
1964] and Treynor [1961] built the first model that could price risky assets on individual terms. This
model has now come to be known as the capital asset pricing model (CAPM). Rubinstien [1973]
merged the CAPM model with the original M&M framework on capital structure. This was possible
because the M&M framework and the CAPM model are built on almost the exact same assumptions
on perfect capital markets. The gain was that the more realistic assumption of risky debt replaced the
one of risk-free debt. Equally, the assumption that firms belonging to the same risk class were replaced
by the assumption that firms have the same beta b risk. E.g. b i = COV[ki,km]/VAR[km], where
COV[ki,km] is the covariance between the returns of the asset under valuation (ki) and the market
portfolio (km), and VAR[km] is the variance of the market portfolio. The equal beta assumption is
much less restrictive, because there are indefinitely many and not perfectly correlated future cash flows
that produce the same beta. Rubinsteins model represented an important progress, but it could not
generalize all of the M&M propositions on capital structure (To be exact, Rubinstein was the first to
prove the basic M&M irrelevance theorem using a mean-variance approach, but Stiglitz [1969] had
already introduced risky debt by using a state-preference approach. But this was only of theoretical
relevance, since the nature of the state preference theory prevent it from being tested empirically).
Hsia [1981] generalized the remaining propositions and this progress was also contingent on another
and independent discovery in the field of option pricing. This discovery was provided by Black and
Scholes [1973] who developed the first option pricing model (OPM) in continuous time. This model is
http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp

1/9

25-8-2014

The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

also built on the assumptions of perfect capital markets, so Hsia was able to merge the CAPM, and
the OPM with the M&M framework on capital structure and thereby generalize the remaining
propositions. Rubinsteins and Hsias versions are perhaps the most general that have been produced
so far. The price to be paid for this generalization is that the proofs behind the M&M propositions
have become considerably more complicated from a mathematical point of view. This text reproduces
the full Rubinstein argument. The proofs of Hsia arguments are by large omitted but the results will be
stated. However, both the Rubinstein- and the Hsia argument is proved by a simple and easily
comprehendible numeric example that illustrates all of the generalized M&M propositions.

Theory

What Rubinstein generalized, was the most basic of the M&M propositions: The proposition on the
irrelevance of capital structure.
Proposition I: The market value of any firm is independent of its capital structure and is given by
capitalizing its expected return at the rate r appropriate to its class, Modigliani and Miller [1958,
page 268]. In modern terms, capital structure is irrelevant, and firm value is equal to the present value
of the free cash flow discounted at the relevant cost of capital.
Rubinstein used the following assumptions explicitly or implicitly:
1)

2)
3)
4)
5)
6)
7)

Capital markets are perfect

Markets are frictionless. I.e., there is no transaction cost (Implication: the borrowing
rate equals the lending rate), no taxes, and all assets are perfectly divisible and marketable
(Implication: e.g. human capital is non-existing (it is not divisible and it cant be owned as an
asset), and there are no constraining regulations.

Perfect competition in product and securities markets. Among other things, this imply
that all producers and consumers are price takers.

Information efficiency. That is, information is costless, and is received simultaneously


by all individuals, both corporate insiders and outsiders (this implies no signaling).

Agents are perfectly rational and use it to maximize there utility


There is no cost to bankruptcy.
Firms issue risky debt and equity, and have the same beta b risk.
All cash flow streams are perpetuities, and no growth is allowed.
Allowing for proportional corporate tax eases the no-tax assumption above.
Managers always maximize the shareholders wealth (imply no agency costs).
Homemade leverage is a perfect substitute for corporate leverage. That is, there is no
difference between corporate and personal borrowing (necessary for arbitrage arguments).

The assumptions above are primarily associated with the original M&M framework. First and
[1]
foremost, in order to apply the CAPM model, the following assumptions are needed.
http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp

2/9

25-8-2014

8)
9)
10)
11)
12)

The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

Investors are risk averse individuals.


Investors have homogenous expectations (beliefs) about asset returns (Implication: all investors
perceive identical opportunity sets).
Asset returns are distributed by the normal distribution.
A risk free asset exists, and investors may borrow or lend unlimited amounts of this asset at a
constant rate: the risk free rate (kf).
There are a definite number of assets and their quantities are fixed over time.

These were the assumptions. The following proofs draw heavily on Copeland and Weston [1988,
pages 462-471]. According to the CAPM model, the equilibrium cost of capital for debt (b for
bonds) and for equity (s for stocks) in any firm is:

(1)
(2)
where,
E[kb ] is the expected cost of capital on bonds.
E[ks ] is the expected cost of capital on stocks.
kf is the expected return on a risk-free portfolio; that is, a portfolio that yields constant return
period after period with certainty.
E[km] is the expected return on the market portfolio.
b b , or b s is the systematic risk. That is, the risk that cant be diversified away. b measures the size
of risk contrary to (E[km] - kf) that measures the price of risk.
COV(kb ,km), or COV(ks ,km) is the expected covariance in returns between the capital being
priced and the overall market portfolio.
VAR(km) is the expected variance of the market portfolio.
Assuming that there is no growth and that investment equals depreciation (I=Dep), the return on
equity, ks , of any firm can also be expressed by its accounting definition.

(3)
where,
NOI is net operating income. That is, revenues less variable and fixed cash expenses from
operations and less deprecations.
http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp

3/9

25-8-2014

The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

B is the market value of debt.


tc is the corporate tax rate.
SL is the market value of equity in a levered firm.
Taking the expectation to (3) yields

(4)
Substituting (3) into the COV[ks ,km] from (2) yields

(5)
Substituting (5) into (2) yields
(6)
Substituting (6) into (4) yields

(7)
<=>
E[NOI](1-tc) - E[kb ]B(1-tc) =
(8)
Making an analog argument for an non-levered firm, where B=0 and SL=VU (VU is the market value
of an non-levered firm) yields:

(9)
Substituting E[NOI](1-tc) from (8) into (9) yields

http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp

4/9

25-8-2014

The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

[2]
=>

[3]
=>

<=>
kf (VL-B) = kf VU -kf B(1-tc) <=> VL-B = VU - B(1-tc) <=> VL = VU + Btc

(10)

Q.E.D.
If tc = 0, then firm value is independent of leverage, and proposition 1 is proved to hold.
Hsia [1981] generalized the rest of the M&M propositions. They will not be proved, only presented.
Essentially, what Hsia does, is extending the Rubinstein framework by the Black-Scholes OPM
formula. Then, he uses the fact that the value of equity in a levered firm is identical to the value of a call
option written on the firm, and that the value of risky debt in a levered firm is the same as the value of
risk-free debt plus a short put option on the value of the firm. Both options are of the European type,
and has an exercise price equal to the future value of the risk-free debt, and a maturity equal to the
[4]
maturity of the risk-free debt. The rest of the Hsia argument is purely mathematical .
Proposition II: The required rate of return on equity, or cost of equity (ks ), increases with financial
leverage (B/[B+S]).
This proposition can be proved by the following formula on the cost of equity:

(11)
http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp

5/9

25-8-2014

The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

where,

N(.) is the cumulative normal probability of the unit normal variate, d1.
kV is the return on the firms asset.
T is the maturity time of the firms bonds.
s is the standard variate of returns on the firms assets.
D is the future value of the zero coupon bond, or face value.

Proposition III: The required rate of return on debt or cost of debt (kb ) increases with financial
leverage (B/[B+S]).
This proposition can be proved by the following formula on the cost of debt:

(12)
Proposition IV: In a world without taxes, the weighted average cost of capital (WACC) is invariant
to changes in the capital structure of the firm.
Proposition 4 can easily be proved by inserting (11) and (12) in the definition for the average cost of
capital:
WACC = kb *B/V + ks *S/V, and V = B+S
= {kf + N(-d1)[kV - kf]V/B}*B/V + { kf + N(d1)[kV - kf]V/S }*S/V
= kf{(B+S)/V} + [kV - kf]*{ N(-d1) + N(d1)}
= kf + [kV - kf]*{ 1- N(d1) + N(d1)}
= kV

(kV is the same as r in proposition 1)

(13)

Q.E.D.
The WACC formula may be generalized to include any number of financial instruments and different
tax assumptions.

Illustrating the M&M propositions

The generalized Modigliani and Miller theorems may seem complicated when looking at the
mathematics. But fortunately, the propositions are very simple to illustrate in a figure. This is done in
figure I below.
http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp

6/9

25-8-2014

The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp

7/9

25-8-2014

The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

Note that all four theorems are fulfilled in figure G. Also very interestingly, the figure version of the
M&M framework does not require returns to follow the normal distribution. Actually, any underlying
risk distribution may do! What matters, is that firm cash flow is unrelated to capital structure, and this
is always so in the perfect M&M world. One might think that the M&M theorems are trivial. But they
are not. Before the invention of the M&M, framework many corporate treasurers in fact believed that
leveraging did increase corporate risk. By verbal logic, they argued something like this: If you agree
that levering up the corporate capital structure makes the remaining equity riskier, and you also agree
that any junior debt added to the capital structure must, necessarily, be riskier debt carrying a lower
rating, and a higher interest than on any debt outstanding before the higher leveraging, then you must
also agree that leveraging does increase corporate risk, thereby decreasing the market value of the
firm. Propositions 2 and 3 do indeed agree that both the risk of debt and equity increase when
leverage increases. However, proposition 4 proofs that this does not increase the corporate risk, and
when this is true, proposition 1 about corporate value must also be valid. The old-fashioned treasurer
simply forgets to take into account the changing weights.

Evidence
Despite all the propositions of the M&M world, when the real world is considered, all firms and
branches behave as if an optimal capital structure existed. Empirically, branches and firms have
capital structures that do not change much over time. Another stylized fact is that some firms are
entirely financed by equity, but no firms are entirely debt financed. Neither of these observations are
consistent with the M&M propositions. There are several extensions of the M&M capital structure
theory that may explain the existence of an optimal capital structure. Click here to go to the hypothesis
exhibition in order to find some of these explanations.

- Copyright 1997-2014, ViamInvest. Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction
prohibited without permission. Legal notice.

http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp

8/9

25-8-2014

[1]
[2]

The irrelevance of capital structure in perfect capital markets

For proof of the CAPM model click here.


Use the fact that the value of a levered firm, VL, is equal to the value of the firms stocks, SL, plus the value of its

bonds, B: VL= SL + B <=> SL = VL - B.


[3]
Substituting (E1) into E[kb].
[4]
Proof of the Black-Scholes OPM model may be found in Copeland and Weston [1988, pages 296-299]. In the same
book [pages 464-469] some of the Hsia proofs may be found.

http://e.viaminvest.com/A7CapitalStructures/Perfect/Model_IrrelevOfCapStruc.asp

9/9

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi