Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 27

TITLE:

DEMAND FOR MONEY: DOES ECONOMIC UNCERTAINTY MATTER


Abstract
A well organize monetary policy depends on the ability of the economy to make out a
stable demand for money. Therefore, the stability of the money demand function is a
necessary stance to address the efficiency of the monetary policy strategy of the central
bank. The purpose of this research is to investigate the relationship between the stability
of money demand with the economic uncertainty index. In doing so, this study postulates
that the optimal economic uncertainty index can serve as a predictive content for money
demand. Therefore, monetary targeting can serve as an important monetary policy
strategy as the uncertainty in the money demand can be pinpointed by using the optimal
economic uncertainty index. This study extends the Keyness money demand function by
including the optimal economic uncertainty index proposed by Gan (2014).

CHAPTER 1
INTRODUCTION
No proposition in macroeconomics has received more attention than that there exists, at
the level of the aggregate economy, a stable demand for money function.
Laidler, D. (1982, pg. 39)
1.1

Introduction

A well organize monetary policy depends on the ability of the economy to make out a
stable demand for money (Friedman and Schwartz, 1982; Laidler, 1982; BahmaniOskooee and Karacal, 2006; Ozturk and Acaravci, 2008). Sriram (1999) and Bathalomew
and Kargbo (2009) declare that a stable demand for money enables the monetary
aggregates to have a predictable impact on the economic variables such as output, interest
rate and inflation rate. Therefore, the stability of the money demand function is a
necessary stance to address the efficiency of the monetary policy strategy (i.e., monetary
targeting and inflation targeting) of the central bank. In line with this stance, numerous
countries used to conduct monetary policies to target certain key policy variables.
Monetary targeting had been a famous monetary policy strategy adopted by several
developed countries, namely Canada, Germany, Japan, Switzerland, United Kingdom and

United States.1 Other developing countries that adopted this strategy include Korea,
Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand.2 However, the failure of the growth of money to serve
as a predictive content has caused many countries shifted to other monetary policy
strategies (e.g., inflation targeting, exchange rate targeting and interest rate targeting).
Unfortunately, the newest strategies adopted by the policy makers of these countries still
cannot promote foreseeable economic outcomes. Even though the growth of money is
ineffective in the short-run business cycles, but it may be useful to manage inflation
(Dwyer, 2001). Therefore, a question raises that whether the growth of money still plays
an important role.
The demand for money may influence by the economic uncertainty (i.e., inflation
uncertainty, output uncertainty, exchange rate uncertainty and interest rate uncertainty).
Economic uncertainty refers to the situation where a little or unknown able future
economic events (Bloom et al., 2013). The first innovative work which discussed the
effects of uncertainty is done by Knight (1921). The economic uncertainty has increase
greatly after the eruption of the subprime crisis in early 2007. Following the global
financial crisis in 2008 that caused by the systemic financial risk, the worlds economic
recovery is in a slowing pace (Gan, 2014). Thereafter, the world economic uncertainties
continue to grow, such as the occurrence of the European sovereign debt crisis since 2009
that prolonged a severe recession, the uncertain Abenomic policy in projecting Japans
longer-term economic growth that kindled a more volatile financial environment, sub-par
economic growth in the United States and a slackening growth in emerging Asia
(International Monetary Fund, 2013).
Atta-Mensah (2004) and Tdter and Manzke (2007) explains that the economic agents
could shift out their nominal assets, including money, into tangible assets such as gold or
commodities when the inflation uncertainty increase as the inflation uncertainty may
cause the nominal asset become riskier and less predictable. Golob (1994) states that the
economy may influences by the inflation uncertainty via the increasing long term interest
rates and thus may affect the economic decision makes by the businesses and consumers.
The businesses may reduce their investment in the factories and equipment while the
consumers may decrease their investment in housing and other durable properties. Choi
and Oh (2003) argues that output uncertainty may also affect the demand for money as
the demand for money may increase resulting from the substitution effect, when the
output uncertainty increased. Bahmani-Oskoee et al. (2012) explain that individual may
prefer to substitute less volatile assets, such as real assets for cash when output
uncertainty increase. In line with this findings, Bahmani-Oskooee et al. (2013) suggest
1 Evidence is also obtainable from the central banks website. Among others, evidence of
monetary targeting is reported by (1) CanadaFreedman (2000), (2) GermanyIssing (2005),
(3) JapanWerner (2002), (4) SwitzerlandMishkin (2000), (5) United KingdomNelson
(2001) and (6) United StatesBrowne (2001).
2 Evidence is also obtainable from the central banks website. Among others, evidence of
monetary targeting is reported by (1) KoreaKim and Park (2006), (2) IndonesiaInoue et al.
(2012), (3) MalaysiaLeong et al. (2008) and (4) ThailandCharoenseang and Manakit (2007).

that the monetary targeting may plays an important role under significant output
uncertainty when the demand for money is stable.
On the other hand, Harvey (2012) states that the exchange rate uncertainty may
encourage the economic agents to invest in the riskier currency than compared to the
secured assets. Pozo and Wheeler (2000) state that the economic agents may prefer to
hold more foreign currency compared to the domestic currency when the exchange rate
uncertainty increase. Erdal (2001) claims that the real exchange rate uncertainty affects
the domestic and decisions on foreign investment negatively as the real exchange rate
uncertainty may cause reallocation of resources among sectors and countries and creates
uncertain environment for investment decisions. Chuderewicz (2002) argues that the
interest rate uncertainty may also influence the demand for money as economic agents
may prefer more liquid assets when interest rate uncertainty increased. Turnovsky (1971)
states that increase in interest rate uncertainty may increase the cash balances. Poole
(2005) documented that the increasing uncertainty on how the central bank set the
interest rate in the future may cause negative effects to the economic stability. Although
the economic uncertainty may influence the money demand, the literature which
discussed regarding the money demand and economic uncertainty are limited as research
in this field is still new (zdemir and Saygili, 2013).
1.2Matters of Study
The matter considered in the study of money demand is the economic uncertainty3 matter.
The scale variable is a measurement of transactions which relates to the economic
activity (i.e., income) while the opportunity cost of holding money is the difference
between the rate of return on assets against the money and the own-rate of money. The
opportunity cost of holding money is generally represented by the interest rate (zdemir
and Saygili, 2013). (Note that only the matters for chosen determinants which are
relevance to the interest of this study are discussed in the following section.)
1.2.1 Economic Uncertainty Matter
Economic uncertainty may influence the demand for the money by affecting the
willingness of the individual to hold the money. When uncertainty increased, the risk may
increase too. However, the discussion on the role of economic uncertainty in the literature
on money demand is mixed and not comprehensive. For example, Bruggerman et al.
(2003) find no evidence to prove that there is any relationship between money demand
and economic uncertainty. However, Atta-Mensah (2004) shows that the economic
uncertainty may lead to a higher M1 that agents willing to hold but the economic
3 The uncertainty of the economic conditions will be measured by the economic uncertainty
index. There are few researchers who have developed their own economic uncertainty index such
as Atta-Mensah (2004), Baker et. al (2013) and Gan (2013). However, the research in this study is
restricted to Gans approach because Gan (2013) has constructed an optimal economic
uncertainty index.

uncertainty affects M2 negatively. Bahmani-Oskooee and Xi (2011) find that the


measurement of uncertainty does affect the demand for M3 in both the long and short
run. However, Bahmani-Oskooee et al. (2012) argues that the measure of uncertainty
only affect the money demand in the short-run but not in the long-run.
Other than economic uncertainty per se, the uncertainty on macro variables and policy
variables may affect the demand for money, namely exchange rate uncertainty, interest
rate uncertainty, inflation uncertainty and output uncertainty. With respect to the
uncertainty on policy variables, Pozo and Wheeler (2000) find that the Singapores
money demand is affected by the fluctuations in the exchange rate uncertainty. Exchange
rate uncertainty may cause the demand for domestic currency to decrease and increase in
the demand for foreign currency in Singapore but not for Malaysia and Thailand (Harvey,
2012). Baum et al. (2001) and Azid et al. (2005) suggest that the estimation on overall
impact of the exchange rate uncertainty on the volatility of stock returns may lead to
improper implications regarding the underlying relationships. Ozturk (2006) reviews that
the profit and the benefits of the international trade are associated negatively with the
exchange rate uncertainty. Grydaki and Fountas (2009) argues that the uncertainty in the
money supply influence the exchange rate uncertainty positively. Bahmani and BahmaniOskooee (2012) say that the volatility of the exchange rate may affect the money demand
directly as the exchange rate volatility creates uncertainty in the wealth.
The interest rate uncertainty, on the other hand, Turnovsky (1971) declares that the
interest rate instability must be included in the money demand functions as the
explanatory variables. Mason (1977) postulates that the demand for money is positively
associated with the interest rate uncertainty as the interest-bearing assets are less
desirable when interest rate uncertainty increase. Golob (1994) argues that interest rate
uncertainty may lead the economic agents to postpone their decisions on investment and
the economic agents might prefer to invest in long-term fixed rate debt (i.e., to evade the
increasing short-term interest rates) when the interest rates uncertainty increased. Thus,
the money demand decreased when the interest rate uncertainty increased. Chuderewicz
(2002) claims that the interest rate uncertainty may embody useful and predictive
information over to forecast the money. Dixit (1992) and Chang and Feunou (2013)
highlight that the economy may influenced negatively by the interest rate uncertainty as
the interest rate uncertainty may cause the firms to delay their investment decision.
With respect to the uncertainty on macro variables, Atta-Mensah (2004) suggests that the
inflation uncertainty may cause nominal assets become riskier and unpredictable; thus, it
may induce the investors to transfer the nominal assets including money into other
tangible assets such as gold or other commodities. Belke and Polleit (2009) argue that the
individuals may not hold money if the future is uncertain. Higgins and Majin (2009) find
mixed effect of the inflation uncertainty on the money demand. The study reports that the
inflation uncertainty have a negative effect on demand for M1 while have a positive
effect on demand for M2. However, Klein (1977) find that the inflation uncertainty
affects the money demand positively; where individuals request for more money when
inflation uncertainty increased. Next, Mizrach and Santomero (1990) and Asilis et al.
(1993) argue that the inflation uncertainty may relate with the money demand negatively.

The output uncertainty, on the other hand, Choi and Oh (2003) prove that the output
uncertainty has a positive significant relationship with money demand but the money
demand relates negatively with the uncertainty of money growth. Longworth (2004)
states that the central bank of Canada includes numerous different and relevant variables
to reduce the uncertainty regarding the output gap estimation. Price (1995) who used the
conditional variance of GDP as a proxy of uncertainty proved that the uncertainty is
associated negatively with the investment decision by the investors. Coenen et al. (2001)
find that money still plays an important role in reducing the uncertainty in estimating the
output. Jongwanich and Kohpaiboon (2008) explain that the uncertain economic (e.g.
output uncertainty) creates higher opportunity cost in delaying the investment and thus
the investment from the firm may decrease. This may eventually reduce the money
demand. Dahmardeh et al. (2011) indicates that the economic uncertainty which
measured by the volatility of GDP has a negative relationship with the demand for money
in Iran.
1.3Motivation of the Study
There are two motivations in this study. The details of each motivation are presented at
below.
1.3.1 Is the monetary aggregates4 cannot serve as an important predictive content
for the monetary policy strategy?
The growth of money is sensible as a part of the eclectic modeling forecasting framework
adopted by the U.S. central bank as the growth of money still contain essential
information about the future economy development (e.g., CPI and output) (Bernanke,
2006). However, literatures find that the growth of money fails to serve as a predictive
content for the future economic development; the relationship between the growth of
money and the variables such as inflation and output are unstable at times. Baba et al.
(1992) and Choi and Oh (2003) state that the role of monetary aggregates in the monetary
policy have been reduced regarding the uncertainty in the velocity of M1, which cannot
be clarified by standard money demand models. Friedman and Schwartz (1963) state that
the instability of the money supply is one of the factors which caused the Great
Depression. Meyer (2001) argues that money does not have any role in todays consensus
macro model and thus money plays no role in the monetary policy. Undoubtedly, most of
the central banks have change their policy from money supply targeting that focused on
the monetary aggregate as intermediate target to inflation targeting as the central banks
may regulate the interest rates to stabilize the prices based on the prediction of inflation
(Baxa et al., 2010; Jahan, 2012; Lungu et al., 2012). On the other hand, there are
countries changed their policy into other monetary policy strategies (e.g. exchange rate

4 In this study, the demand for money will used to represent monetary aggregates as a predictive
content for the monetary policy strategy.

targeting and interest rate targeting). 5 Therefore, the question remains whether or not the
monetary aggregates can serve as the predictive content for the monetary policy strategy.
1.3.2 What is the response of economic uncertainty to money demand?
Atta-Mensah (2004) and Jackman (2010) find that economic uncertainty may influence
the economic agents decision on the quantity of money to hold. Bahmani-Oskooee and
Karacal (2006) and Opolot (2007) argue that the instability relationship between money
demand function and macro-variables can make policy formulation and predictions
difficult. Greiber and Lemke (2005) suggest that the measurements of uncertainty must
be included in the specifications of money demand because the variables of uncertainty
may improve the explanatory power of the estimated money demand function for euro
area M3. The uncertainty in the economics definitely will alter the directions of the future
economics. Thus, it is important to identify the uncertainty in an economic as the modern
economics still does not do well in predicting the uncertainty of the world. As stressed by
Bernanke (2010), researchers should put more effort to construct useful framework to
overcome the economic uncertainties as the current framework still cannot implies
meaningful outcomes. Consequently, this study will apply the optimal economic
uncertainty index proposed by Gan (2014) to investigate the relationship between the
economic uncertainty and demand for money.
1.4Objectives
The objectives of this research will be divided into two parts which is general objectives
and specific objectives.

1.4.1

General Objective

The general objective of this research is to investigate the relationship between the
stability of money demand with the economic uncertainty index. In this thesis, the
uncertain economic conditions will be determined by using the optimal economic
uncertainty index proposed by Gan (2014). By identifying the economic uncertainty
using the optimal economic uncertainty index, the central banks can achieve their
ultimate goals such as maintaining low inflation and increasing economic growth by
controlling the money supply in an economy.
1.4.2

Specific Objectives

5 The evidence of countries that pursue different monetary policy strategies are reported by (1)
Hong KongMcCallum (2007), (2) SingaporeParrado (2004) and (3) MalaysiaPoon and
Tong (2009).

The 6 selected developed countries namely Australia, Canada, Japan, New Zealand,
Switzerland and United States, and 12 selected developing countries, namely Brazil,
China, Colombia, India, Indonesia, Malaysia, Mexico, Republic of Korea, Singapore,
South Africa, Thailand and Turkey are taken up in this study. Below are the specific
objectives of this research.
1. To investigate the relationship between the economic uncertainty index and the
demand for money.
This study postulates that the optimal economic uncertainty index can serve as a
predictive content for money demand; the optimal economic uncertainty index is
created based on the simple macroeconomic model.
1.5

Significance of the Study

Besides that, this study is significance because it may help the policy makers in making
decisions for the monetary policy under the uncertain economic conditions. By using the
optimal economic uncertainty index, the policy makers may pinpoint the uncertainties in
the economy. Thus, this study may serve as a guideline for the monetary authorities to
improve the countrys economy by controlling the money supply as the optimal economic
uncertainty index can estimate the uncertain economic conditions. The optimal economic
uncertainty index can portrays the uncertainty level of macroeconomic conditions (Gan,
2014).
1.6 Framework of the Study
The framework of this study includes the money view (Hubbard, 1995) and modified
money view: economic uncertainty. The framework below assumes that the money
demand and the money supply are in an equilibrium level.

1.6.1 Standard Money View


Based on the Keynesian model, the money view indicates the effects of the monetary
aggregate on output through interest rate. The transmission mechanism can be explained
by the diagram below:

()

The diagram above shows that a tighten monetary policy (M) may cause the interest rate (
r ) to increase, which increase the opportunity cost of holding money and thus causing
the investment (I) to decrease. When investment decrease, the aggregate demand may
decrease and hence decrease the output ( y ). The decreasing output also implies that
the inflation ( ) is decreasing.
1.6.1.1 Modified Money View: Economic Uncertainty
This modified money view below is an extension form the standard money view. The
transmission mechanism can be explained by the diagram below:

EU

M uncertainty

Economic
Uncertainty
in, andOutcomes (i.e. macro variables and policy va

The diagram above shows that the economic uncertainty (EU) may cause uncertainty in
monetary policy used by the central bank and thus cause uncertainty in the interest rate
and output. Further, these uncertainties may influence the economic outcomes as the final
decision of the macro variables (e.g., output) and policy variables (e.g., interest rate) are
unknown. Golob (1994) states that the uncertainty in the interest rates and other
economic variables can affect the economic activity negatively; uncertainty may delay
investment decisions by the investors. Therefore, it is necessary to solve the economic
uncertainty by using the optimal economic uncertainty index. The optimal economic
uncertainty index which based on Gans approach (2014) may discard the continuous
effects of economic uncertainty on the monetary policy and economic outcomes.
1.7

Conclusion

In conclusion, the present chapter has discussed the background, matters and motivation
of this study. The remainder of the study will be organized as follows. Chapter 2 will
discuss the theoretical background of the demand for money and the empirical literature
of the demand for money will be discuss based on the matter presented in this chapter.
Next, the discussion regarding the methodology and data used in this study is included in
Chapter 3.

CHAPTER 2
LITERATURE REVIEW
2.1 Introduction
This chapter will discuss the past literature which related to this study. This chapter is
divided into the theoretical literature and empirical literature.
2.2 Theoretical Literature
The theoretical literature that discussed in this section is the Quantity Theory, the
Cambridge approach to Quantity Theory, Keynesian Theory and Friedman Theory of
Demand for Money. Although this section discusses variety theoretical literature of
money demand, this study will only apply the Keynesian liquidity preference theory.
2.2.1 Keynesian Money Demand
The standard money demand function developed by Keyness (1936) is as follows:
M dt =f ( y t , r t ) ( 2.1 )

where

M dt

is the demand for real money balances (i.e., the nominal value of demand

for money is divided by the price level) depends on the level of transactions in the
y
r
economy ( t -- real income) and the opportunity cost of holding money ( t -interest rate). Keynesian approach denotes that the demand for money is related
positively with real income but related negatively with the interest rate.
Furthermore, Keynes (1936) postulates that the individual holds the money for three main
reasons which is the transactions motive, precautionary motive and the speculative
motive. The motives of holding the money as stated by Keynes are discussed in detail in
the following section.
2.2.1.1 Transactions Motive
Keynes assumed that the first motive of holding the money is the transactions. This is
because the money is defined as the medium of exchange where the individual holds the
money for daily transactions. Money bridges the gap between the receipt of income and
eventual expenditures. The amount of money hold for the transactions purpose would
vary positively with the volume of transactions in which the individual engaged. Income
is assumed to be a measurement of the volume of transaction. Therefore, the transactions
motive of the money demand is predicted to positively relate to the level of income. The

relationship between the transactions and the level of income can be portrays in Figure
2.1 shown below.
No. of transactions, c
c (y)

Level of income, y

Figure 2.1 The relationship between the transactions and level of income

2.2.1.2 Precautionary Motive


Keynes believed that, beyond the money held for planned transactions, additional money
balances were held in case unexpected expenditures became necessary. For the
precautionary motives, the money will be hold for emergencies such as to pay unexpected
bills (i.e. medical bills and others). Keynes added the amount of money which hold by the
individual are positively related with the income. When the income increase, the money
hold by the individual for precautionary will increase too. In addition, the interest rate
will also be a factor when individuals tended to economize on the amount of money held
for the precautionary motive as interest rate rose. This is because the motives to hold
money for precautionary balances are similar with the motive of transactions demand.
The relationship between the precautionary and the level of income can be portrays in
Figure 2.2 shown below.
Precautionary motive, p
p (y)

Level of income, y

Figure 2.2 The relationship between the precautionary motive and level of income

2.2.1.3 Speculative Motive


The third motive to hold money postulates by Keynes is speculative motive (i.e., as a
store of wealth). Keynes assumed that the households may buy bonds as a speculative
motive; households may use the money to purchase bonds and may sell it in the future to
earn money. The value of bonds and money depends on interest rates. Therefore, the
uncertainty in the interest rates may eventually affect the quantity money demand from
the households. The investors may expect that the interest rates will rise in the future
during low interest rates and thus the bond prices are expected to fall. This implies that
the household will prefer to hold money compared to buy bonds during low interest rate
and thus the quantity of money demand increased; the opportunity cost of holding money
increased when the interest rate increased. Figure 2.3 below portrays the negative
relationship between the interest rates and quantity of money demanded.
Interest rates,

Quantity of money demand, M


0
Figure2.3 The relationship between interest rates and quantity of money demanded

2.2.1.4 Combining the Three Motives Together


In short, the motives of holding money as stated by Keynes, namely the liquidity
preference function can be expressed as the total money demand function as follows:
M d=L1 ( y ) + L2 ( i ) (2.2)
M =M 1+ M 2 =L1 ( y ) + L2 ( r )=L ( y , r ) (2.3)
Where

L1

denotes the motive of transaction and precautionary while

the motive of speculative of liquidity preference.


represents the interest rate.
2.2.2 Quantity Theory

L2

denotes

represents income and

The level of aggregate demand determines the quantity of money in the classical theory,
which in turn will affect the price level. The starting point of the classical quantity theory
of money is the equation of exchange which created by the most prominent American
quantity theorist, Irving Fisher (1911). He added that the total of expenditures is always
equals to the total income in a transaction. Thus, he has created an equation of exchange
as follows:
MV T =PT T ( 2.4 )
Where

represents the quantity of money,

circulation of money,

PT

VT

denotes the velocity of the

is the price level for the items which been traded and

represents the volume of transactions. Fisher regard

is the composition of cash and

VT

demand deposits. Therefore,


M =M 1+ M 2 ( 2.5 )
V =V 1 +V 2 ( 2.6 )
Fisher stated that among the four variables ( M ,
V

PT

and

T ),

and

is relatively stable and constant. This is because the development of an economy

does not depend on the quantity of money but it is affected by the natural resources and
the technical conditions. However, M and P are unstable variables because M
can be controlled by the monetary authorities. When T and V are relatively
constant,

will influenced T

and

P . In addition, the price level will change in

the amount of the velocity of circulation money with proportional change when the
velocity of circulation money and the volume of transaction are in the same conditions.
Thus, the price level will determine by the quantity of money rather than price level
determines the quantity of money.
2.2.3 The Cambridge Approach to the Quantity Theory
The Cambridge Approach to the Quantity Theory is developed by Marshall. He stated
that individuals will save their property and income in form of money as the reserve
purchasing power of people willing to maintain. He also stressed the influence of the time
and quantity of money hold by individuals to the velocity of money and thus the impact
of money value. Pigou (1917) has constructed a cash balance formula which named the
Cambridge equation as follows:

M =kPT (2.7)
Where

denotes the stock of money,

represents the fraction of income which


the community seeks to hold in the form of cash balance and demand deposits, P is
the general price level and T represents the total output.

2.2.4 Friedman Theory of Demand for Money


Milton Friedman (1956) has introduced his theory of demand for money in his famous
article named The Quantity Theory of Money: A Restatement. The demand for money
developed by Friedman is almost similar with the analysis of demand money as
introduced by Keynes and Cambridge compared to Fishers. Friedman equals the factors
which influence the demand for any asset with the factors that affect the demand for
money. Therefore, Friedman applied the theory of asset demand to the money.
The demand for money is a function of the resources available to individuals and
expected returns on the other assets relative to the expected return on money. Thus,
Friedman has constructed his own model of the demand for money as follows:
Md
=f ( Y p , r b , r m , r e , e , w , u ) (2.8)
P
Or
Md
=f ( Y p , r b r m , r e r m , er m ) (2.9)
P

Where

Md
P

income,

rm

bonds,

re

denotes the demand for real money balances,


represents the expected return on money,

rb

Yp

is the permanent

is the expected return on

denotes the expected return on equity (common stock),

is the

expected inflation rate, w represents the proportion of human wealth and non-human
wealth and u denotes the other factor which may affect the demand for money.
In the function of Friedmans money demand,

r br m

and

r e r m

represents the

expected return on bonds and the equity relative to the money. When the expected return
on bonds and equity relative to money increased, the relative expected return on money

will decrease and thus, this will cause the demand for money to decrease. Furthermore,
e r m denotes the expected return on goods relative to the money. When it increased,
the expected return on goods relative to money increased, and therefore the demand for
money decreased.
2.3 Empirical Literature
In this section, the empirical literature regarding the economic uncertainty will be
discussed.
2.3.1.5 Economic Uncertainty
There are varieties of study that investigates about the uncertainty. For instance, the
investment uncertainty and others are the study usually done by the researcher. Based on
the previous study, results shows that most of the theoretical and empirical literature
about investment under uncertainty stated that uncertainty would bring negative impact to
the countrys economic growth and investment (Lensink, 2001). Bernanke (1983) also
clarified that uncertainty might delay the investment.
In 2001, Lensink had carried out a research where the concept of the study is same with
this study which is create a model to find the effects of the policy uncertainty to the
countrys economic growth. The method used by Lensink is a standard cross-country
growth regression. Next, Baker, Bloom and Davis (2011) had construct an index from
three types of underlying components which include news coverage about policy-related
economic uncertainty, tax code expiration data and economic forecaster disagreement to
measure the policy-related economic uncertainty.
Review to the past literature, there are researcher done research related to the uncertainty
index. For example, Atta-Mensah (2004) tested the effect of economic uncertainty on the
demand of money for Canadian monetary aggregates (M1, M1++ and M2++) by using a
general-equilibrium theory. The economic uncertainty index (EUI) is introduced in the
research and it is estimated by using GARCH models. Quarterly data from 1960 until
2003 is used in this research. The findings of the result stated that economic agents will
keep the money for precautionary reasons when economic uncertainty increased and this
may cause the M1 balances to increase too. Moreover, the result also supports the view
that the agents will not willing to invest in a risky asset in a general economic
uncertainty. The empirical results of the study also found that the raise of economic
uncertainty will increased the desired M1 and M1++ balances that the agents would like
to hold but the economic uncertainty have negative effect on M2++.
Next, Baker et al. (2013) also have constructed a new index of economic policy
uncertainty (EPU) in their research. Three components which include the frequency of
news media references to economic policy uncertainty, the number of federal tax code
provisions set to expire and the extent of forecaster disagreement over future inflation
and government purchases were used to form the EPU. The EPU appears to propose a
good proxy for real policy-related economic uncertainty which based on the 5,000 human

audited news articles and external surveys such as the frequency of the word uncertainty
that appear in the FOMC Beige Book and the number of policy related jumps in the
stock-market. VAR analysis is used in this research to find the role of the new policyrelated uncertainty to the employment and GDP. The result of the study indicates that the
policy-related uncertainty is useful in the slow growth and irregular recovery of recent
years.
Furthermore, Gan (2014) has constructed an optimal economic uncertainty index in a
simple macroeconomic model by using grid search method which can serve as a policy
tool for central bank to reduce the uncertainty in macroeconomic conditions. Three
developed countries namely Canada, Japan and United States and four developing
countries namely Indonesia, Malaysia, Singapore and Thailand are examined in the
research. The research concludes that the optimal economic uncertainty index fulfills its
role as (i) a good information summary tool to characterize the uncertainty level of
macroeconomic conditions and (ii) a guiding policy tool for improving uncertainty levels
in macroeconomic conditions. Moreover, the estimated response function of the optimal
economic uncertainty index recommends that the exchange rate, inflation, interest rate
and output can be used as indicators to help the central banks in making decision while
the optimal economic uncertainty index helps to predict the uncertain economic
conditions.
On the other hand, Cronin and Kennedy (2007) have investigated the interrelationship
between the real growth of money and measures of macroeconomic and the uncertain
monetary in United States by utilizing the multivariate GARCH model. The model
estimated the uncertainty by using the conditional variance of the data series, to test the
impact of the macroeconomic uncertainty and the monetary uncertainty Granger-cause on
the real money. The findings of the result shows that the macroeconomic uncertainty are
positively related with the US real M2 growth at longer lag lengths so that a rise in
macroeconomic uncertainty will cause an increase in real money growth over a one to
two year horizon. In contrast, monetary uncertainty has no discernable causal effect on
real money growth at all lag lengths examined. Moreover, the result also shows that in a
short horizon, the changes of the real money will influenced the monetary uncertainty
positively.
Besides that, Ozdermir and Saygili (2013) have analyzed the parameter constancy of the
long-run money demand function in Turkey. The methodology used in the study is the
cointegrated VAR and quarterly data from 1992 quarter one to 2008 quarter three is
collected. The result shows that a suitable measurement of uncertainty is required to
estimate a stable and consistent function of money demand for Turkey. Next, Jackman
(2010) has examined the relationship between the economic uncertainty and the money
demand in Barbados by using the unrestricted error correction model developed by
Pesaran et al. (2001). The result shows that the effects of economic uncertainty on money
demand are different in the short term and long term. In short term, the increasing
economic uncertainty will encourage the money demand. However, in long period of
uncertain economic conditions, the nominal assets become less attractive regarding the
increasing risk in the nominal assets and thus caused the money demand to decrease.

CHAPTER 3
METHODOLOGY
3.1

Introduction

In this chapter, this thesis begins the discussion with the model apply in this study. The
model build in this thesis is based on the objectives discussed in Chapter One.
3.2

Model specification

The Keyness standard money demand function (i.e., the liquidity preference function) is
applied in this study. The inputs can be presented as follows:
M dt =f ( y t , r t ) ( 3.1 )
M dt

where

is the demand for real money balances (i.e., the nominal value of demand

for money is divided by the price level) depends on the level of transactions in the
y
r
economy ( t -- real income) and the opportunity cost of holding money ( t -interest rate) (see Choudhry, 1995). Keynesian approach denotes that the demand for
money is related positively with real income but related negatively with the interest rate.
In line with the aims of the study, Equation 3.1 is extended to encompass the optimal
economic uncertainty index. The inclusion of the optimal economic uncertainty index in
the money demand function is constructed based on the approach proposed by Gan
(2014); since the economic uncertainty index is not available in the reality, thus, on can
use Gans optimal procedure to develop the index. Therefore, the modified money
demand function that will be taken up in this study can be written as follows:
M dt =f ( y t , r t , U t ) ( 3.2 )

The specific form of the money demand function is as below:


M dt = 0 + 1 y t + 2 r t + 3 U t + t (3.3)
Note:
0 is a constant.
1

to

are the coefficient for each variable.

The economic rationale suggests that


where

M dt

1> 0

while

yt

and

3< 0

represents real output

, rt

is the economic uncertainty index.

is the real money demand (M1 or M2),

denotes the real interest rate and

2< 0

represents the shocks; all variables are in log form, except

r . Equation 3.3 also known

as Goldfeld-type (1973) money demand function.


Based on the model above, the money demand depends positively on the output. An
increase in output typically results in an increase in transactions. When the transactions
increase, thus, the money demand may increase too. The increasing output may invite
inflation. When inflation increase, the money demand may decrease as the money
become less desirable; the inflation may reduce the real value of the money.
On the other hand, an increase in interest rates reduces the money demand as the
opportunity cost of holding money increased. The investment may decrease when the
opportunity cost of holding money increased and this eventually reduce the money
demand. Besides that, the economic uncertainty also affects the money demand. The
positive economic uncertainty may increase the money demand. For example, an increase
in the expected output leads to increase the transactions and thus increase the money
demand. Furthermore, the interest rates uncertainty has a negative relationship with the
money demand. When the interest rates uncertainty is expected to increase, the economic
agents may delay their investment and thus reduce the money demand (Golob, 1994).
3.3

Empirical Methods

This section explains the methods that are applied in estimating the money demand
function, namely panel unit root and the panel autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL)
developed by Pesaran et al. (1997, 1999). The section also discusses the model of the
optimal economic uncertainty index at the end of this section since this study include the
optimal economic uncertainty index in the money demand function (see the box of Gans
(2014) optimal economic uncertainty index procedure).
3.3.1 Panel Unit Root
In this study, the panel unit root test developed by Levin, Lin and Chu (2002), Im,
Pesaran and Shin (2003) and Maddala and Wu (1999) are used to examine whether the
variables are stationary or non-stationary. The data from different countries are stacked
into variables before performing the panel unit root test. The variables are stationary if
the variables are integrated of order zero, I(0) and the variables are non-stationary if the
variables are integrated of one, I(1).
3.3.2 Panel Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL)

The panel autoregressive distributed lag model (ARDL) is used to examine the short run
and long run relationship between the money demand and the variables, namely real
output, real interest rate and economic uncertainty index. The advantage of using ARDL
approach is this approach allows the variables to be I(1) and I(0). The general panel
ARDL model is as follows:
y t =k x qt + t

(3.4)

k =1, , K ; q=1, , n

Therefore, the empirical specification of the panel ARDL model as specified above in
equation 3.4 is as follows:
p1

q 1

q1

q1

'
'
'
M it = i+ ^ ij M i , + ^ 1 ij y1 i , + ^ 2 ij r 2 i , + ^ 5 ij U 5 i , + ^i ( M i , ^ 1 i y 1i , ^ 2 i r 2i , ^ 5 i U 5 i ,
j=1

Where
r

t j

tj

j=0

t j

j=0

t j

j=0

^i

the long run parameters while

tj

denotes the real money demand (i.e., M1 and M2),

is the real output,


^ i
is the economic uncertainty index.
is

represents the real interest rate and

t1

are the error correction coefficients.

Box: Gans (2014) Optimal Economic Uncertainty Index Procedure


The optimal measure of the economic uncertainty index is subjected to the central bank
loss function. The general form of the economic uncertainty index can is defined as
follows:
Minimize the loss function

Et Lt +

=0

subject to
y i = 1 x 1,i + 2 x 2,i ++ k1 x k1,i + i ,
t

i=1, , N ; k =1, , K ; t=1, , T .

U t = k y i + t (3.6)
t

tj

where

is the economic uncertainty index.

is the dependent variable and

is the explanatory variable; these variables are in gap form at its equilibrium level (i.e.,
deviation of the actual value from the potential values). and are coefficients.
and

are errors.

L denotes the central bank loss function; it is assumed that

the current policy focus on low and stable inflation.


a. Theoretical Model
The optimal economic uncertainty index is constructed using the standard
macroeconomic model. The inputs of the small structural model are as bellows:
y g =1 y g 1 r g 1 e g + t
t

t1

t1

(3.7)

t 1

g = 2 y g + g 2 e g + t
t

t1

t 1

(3.8)

t1

e g = 2 r g + t
t

(3.9)

U t = 3 y g + g 3 e g 3 r g + t
t

r g =4 y g + g 4 e g +U t 1+ t
t

where

yg

rate gap6,

t1

is the real output gap,


rg

t1

t 1

is the inflation gap,

is the real interest rate gap, and

(3.10)
(3.11)
eg

is the real exchange

is the economic uncertainty index.

The gap of the variables is the deviations of the actual value form the potential values.
The total output of an economy (i.e., open economy IS curve) represented by equation
3.7. Equation 3.8 denotes the Phillips curve of an open economy while equation 3.9 is the
reduced form of the exchange rate. The contemporaneous economic uncertainty function
is represented by equation 3.10 and equation 3.11 is the monetary policy reaction
function.
3.4Data
The samples of this study are divided into two groups which is developed countries and
developing countries. The selected countries are grouped according to the source from the
United Nations (2012). Data from 6 developed countries (Australia, Canada, Japan, New
Zealand, Switzerland and United States) are chosen as part of this study. While data from
another 12 developing countries, namely Brazil, China, Colombia, India, Indonesia,
Malaysia, Mexico, Republic of Korea, Singapore, South Africa, Thailand and Turkey are
used as data from developing countries. The data are collected and analyzed according to
6 One may soften the economic policy to mitigate the negative level of the economic uncertainty
index if the above process is the other way round.

the model created. The quarterly data from 1994 quarter one until 2012 quarter four are
collected in this study. The proxy for the exchange rate is the real effective exchange rate
index and the interest rate represents the monetary policy variable. The data of the Real
Gross Domestic Product (RGDP) is obtained in this study to indicate the real national
output or the real income. This paper uses data from a variety of sources, namely, the
International Monetary Fund (IMF), International Financial Statistics (IFS), CD-ROM,
Bank for International Settlements Statistics (BIS Statistics) and ECONSTATS. The
features are as follows:
Real money stock: Data of M1 and M2 for each selected countries will be used in
this study.
Consumer price index: The quarterly series of the Consumer Price Index (CPI) for
each country is collected from IFS. The first difference of the log of the CPI level
is been evaluate to determine the inflation rates.
Real exchange rate: The quarterly series of the Real Effective Exchange Rate
(REER) with the index of 2010=100 is taken from BIS Statistics.
Real output: The quarterly series of the Nominal Gross Domestic Product
(NGDP) is collected from the IFS. The real output (RGDP) is obtained by
dividing the NGDP to the CPI.
Interest rate: The quarterly series of the money market rate is obtained from the
IFS to serve as the interest rate.
Economic uncertainty index:
3.5

Conclusion

This chapter has discussed the model and methodologies used in this study in detail in
Section 3.2 and 3.3 respectively.

CHAPTER 4
CONCLUSION
4.1 Conclusion
1. This study anticipates that the economic uncertainty index has short run and long
run relationship with the money demand function.
2. This study postulates that the optimal economic uncertainty index can serve as a
predictive content for money demand.
3. Therefore, monetary targeting can serve as an important monetary policy strategy
as the uncertainty in the money demand can be pinpointed by using the optimal
economic uncertainty index.
4. First limitation of this study is this this study only include 20 countries and three
variables in the money demand function, namely the real output, real interest rate
and economic uncertainty index. Other variables such as the exchange rate and
inflation can be included for future research.
5. Next, the estimation problem in measuring the optimal economic uncertainty
index can be extended for future investigations.

References
Asilis, C. M., Honohan, P. & Mcnelis, P. D. (1993). Money demand during hyperinflation
and stabilization: Bolivia, 1980-88. Economic Inquiry, 31(2) 262-273.
Atta-Mensah, J. (2004). Money demand and economic uncertainty. Bank of Canada
Working Paper, No. 2004-25.
Azid, T., Jamil, M, & Kousar, A. (2005). Impact of exchange rate volatility on growth and
economic performance: A case study of Pakistan, 1973-2003. The Pakistan
Development Review, 44(4), 749-775.
Baba Y., Hendry D. F. & Starr, R. M. (1992). The Demand for M1 in the U.S.A., 19601988. Review of Economic Studies, 59(198), 25-61.
Bahmani, S., & Bahmani-Oskooee, M. (2012). Exchange rate volatility
and demand for money in Iran. International Journal of Monetary
Economics and Finance, 5(3), 268-276.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M., & Karacal, M. (2006). The demand for money in Turkey and
currency substitution. Applied Economics Letters, 13(10), 635-642.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M., & Karacal, M. (2006). The demand for money in Turkey and
currency substitution. Applied Economics Letters, 13(10), 635-642.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M., & Xi, D. (2011). Economic uncertainty,
monetary uncertainty and the demand for money in Australia.
Australian Economic Papers, 50(4), 115-128.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M., Kutan, A. M., & Xi, D. (2013). The impact of economic and
monetary uncertainty on the demand for money in emerging economies. Applied
Economics, 45(23). 3278-3287.
Bahmani-Oskooee, M., Xi, D., & Wang, Y. (2012). Economic and monetary uncertainty
and the demand for money in China. The Chinese Economy, 45(6), 26-37.
Bathalomew, D., & Kargbo, S. M. (2009). Exchange rates and monetary dynamics in
Sierra Leone: Evidence from a modified money demand function. Journal of
Monetary and Economic Integration, 9(2), 114-137.
Baum, C. F. & Caglayan, M. & Barkoulas, J. T. (2001). Exchange Rate Uncertainty and
Firm Profitability. Journal of Macroeconomics, 23(4), 565-576.
Baxa, J., H., R., & Vasicek, B. (2010). How Does Monetary Policy Change? Evidence on
Inflation Targeting Countries. Working Papers 2010/02, Czech National Bank,
Research Department.
Belke, A. & Polleit, T. (2009). Monetary economics in globalized financial markets. New
York: Springer.
Bernake, B. S. (1983). Irreversibility, uncertainty, and cynical investment. Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 98, 85-106.
Bernanke, B. S. (2006). Monetary aggregates and monetary policy at the Federal
Reserve: A historical perspective. Speech at the Fourth ECB Central Banking
Conference, Frankfurt, Germany.
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20061110a.htm
Accessed 26 November 2013.
Bernanke, B. S. (2010). On the implications of the financial crisis for economics. Speech
Presented at the Center for Economic Policy Studies and the Bendheim Center for
Finance. Princeton, New Jersey.

Bloom, N., Kose, M. A., & Terrones, M. E. (2013). Held back by uncertainty. Finance
and Development, 50(1), 38-41.
Bruggeman, A., Donati, P., & Warne, A. (2003). Is the demand for euro area M3 stable?.
European Central Bank, Working Paper Series, No.255.
Chang, B. Y., & Feunou, B. (2013). Measuring uncertainty in monetary policy using
implied volatility and realized volatility. Bank of Canada Working Paper No.
2013-37.
Charoenseang, J., & Manakit, P. (2007). Thai monetary policy transmission in an
inflation targeting era. Journal of Asian Economics, 18, 144-157.
Choi, W. G., & Oh, S. (2003). A money demand function with output uncertainty,
monetary uncertainty, and financial innovations. Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking, 35(5), 685-709.
Choudhry, T. (1995). Long-run money demand function in Argentina during 1935-1962:
Evidence from cointegration and error correction models. Applied Economics,
27(8), 661-667.
Chuderewicz, R. P. (2002). Using interest rate uncertainty to predict the paper-bill spread
and real output. Journal of Economics and Business, 54, 293-312.
Coenen, G., Levin, A., & Wieland, V. (2001). Data uncertainty and the role of money as
an information variable for monetary policy. European Central Bank Working
Paper Series No. 84.
Cronin, D, & Kennedy, B. (2007). Does uncertainty impact money growth? A
multivariate GARCH analysis. Central Bank of Ireland Research Technical Paper
6/RT/07.
Dahmardeh, N., Pourshahabi, F., Mahmoudinia, D. (2011). Economic Uncertainty
Money demand Nexus in Iran application of the EGARCH model and the ARDL
approach. European Journal of Economics, Finance and Administrative Sciences,
38, 118-126.
Dixit, A. (1992). Investment and hysteresis. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 6, 107132.
Dwyer, G. P. (2001). Money growth and inflation in the United States. Federal Reserve of
Atlanta.
Erdal, B. (2001). Investment decisions under real exchange rate uncertainty. Research
and Monetary Policy Department, Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey,
Central Bank Review, 1(2), 25-47.
Fisher, I. (1911).
The purchasing power of money. New York:
Macmillan.
Freedman, C. (2000). Monetary aggregates and monetary aggregates in the twenty-first
century: discussion. Conference Series (Proceedings), Federal Reserve Bank of
Boston, 31-41.
Friedman, M. (1956). The quantity theory of money: A restatement. Studies in the
Quantity Theory of Money. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Friedman, M., & Schwartz, A. J. (1963). Monetary trends in the United States and the
United Kingdom: Their relation to income, prices and interest rates. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1867-1975.

Friedman, M., & Schwartz, A. J. (1982). Monetary trends in the United States and the
United Kingdom: Their relation to income, prices and interest rates, 1867-1975.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Gan, P. T. (2014). The optimal economic uncertainty index: A grid search application.
Computational Economics, 43(2), 159-182.
Golob, J. E. (1994). Does inflation uncertainty increase with inflation?. Federal Reserve
Bank of Kansas City Economic Review, 27-38.
Greiber, C., & W. Lemke (2005). Money demand and macroeconomic uncertainty.
Deutsche Bundesbank Discussion Paper, Series 1, Economic Studies, No.26/2005.
Grydaki, M., & Fountas, S. (2009). Exchange rate volatility and output volatility: A
theoretical approach. Review of International Economics, 17(3), 552-569.
Harvey, H. (2012). Exchange rate volatility and money demand in selected South East
Asian countries. Economics and Finance Review, 2(10), 1-7.
Higgins, M. L., & Majin, S. (2009). Inflation uncertainty and money demand. Applied
Economic Letters, 16, 1323-1328.
http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20100924a.htm.
Accessed 25 November 2013.
Hubbard, R. G. (1995). Is there a credit channel for monetary policy?. Federal Reserve
Bank of Saint Louis Review, 77(3), 63.
Im, K. S., Pesaran, M. H., & Shin, Y. (2003). Testing for unit roots in heterogenous
Panels. Journal of Econometrics, 115, 53-74.
Inoue, T., Toyoshima,Y., & Shigeyuki, H. (2012). Inflation targeting in Korea, Indonesia,
Thailand, and the Philippines: The impact on business cycle synchronization
between each country and the world. IDE Discussion Papers No. 328, 1-23.
International Monetary Fund (2013). World economic outlook April 2013, Hopes,
Realities, Risks. World Economic and Financial Surveys, 1-184.
Issing, O. (2005). Why did the great inflation not happen in Germany?. Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis Review, 87(2), 329-335.
Jackman, M. (2010). Money demand and economic uncertainty in Barbados. Central
Bank of Barbados, MPRA Paper No. 29360.
Jahan, S. (2012). Inflation targeting: Holding the line. Financial and
Development. http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/basics/target.htm.
Accessed 5 December 2013.
Jongwanich, J., & Kohpaiboon, A. (2008). Private investment: Trends and determinants
in Thailand. World Development, 36(10), 1709-1724.
Keynes, J. M. (1936). The general theory of employment, interest, and money.
Macmillan.
Kim, S., & Park, Y. C. (2006). Inflation targeting in Korea: A model of success?. BIS
Paper No. 31, 140- 164.
Klein, B. (1977). The demand for quality-adjusted cash balances: Price uncertainty in the
US demand for money function, Journal of Political Economy, 85, 691-715.
Knight, F. H. (1921). Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit. Boston. MA: Hart, Schaffner and
Marx; Houghton Mifflin Company.
Laidler, D. (1982). Monetarist Perspectives. Philip Allan Ltd., Oxford.
Lensink, R. (2001). Financial development, uncertainty and economic growth. De
Economist, 149(3), 299-312.

Leong, C. M., Puah, C. H., Mansor, S. A., & Evan, L. (2008). Testing the effectiveness of
monetary policy in Malaysia using alternative monetary aggregation. MPRA
Paper No. 10568, 1-23.
Levin, A., Lin, C. & Chu, C. J. (2002). Unit root tests in panel data: Asymptotic and
Finite-sample Properties. Journal of Econometrics, 108, 1-24.
Longworth, D. (2004). Monetary policy and uncertainty. Bank of Canada Review, 57-62.
Lungu, M., Simwaka, K., Chiumia, A., Palamuleni, A., & Jombo, W. (2012). Money
demand function for Malawi Implications for monetary policy conduct. Banks
and Bank Systems, 7(1), 50-63.
Maddala, G. S. ad Wu, S. (1999). A comparative study of panel data unit root tests and a
new simple test. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 61, 631-652.
Mason, J. M. (1977). The demand for money and the uncertainty of interest rates and
prices. Rodney L. White Centre for Financial Research Working Papers No. 1477.
McCallum, B. T. (2007). Monetary Policy in East Asia: The Case of Singapore. Institute
for Monetary and Economic Studies Discussion Paper No. 07- E-010, Bank of
Japan.
Meyer, L. H. (2001). Does money matter?. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 115.
Mizrach, B. & Santomero, A.M. (1990). A liquidity in advance model of the demand for
money under price uncertainty. Journal of Monetary Economics, 26(1), 143-159.
Opolot, J. (2007). A re-examination of the demand for money in Uganda: Nature and
implications for monetary policy. The Bank of Uganda Staff Papers Journal, 1(1),
5-32.
zdemir, K. A., & Saygili, M. (2013). Economic uncertainty and money demand stability
in Turkey. Journal of Economic Studies, 40(3), 314 333.
Ozturk, I. (2006). Exchange rate volatility and trade: A literature survey. International
Journal of Applied Econometrics and Quantitative Studies, 3(1), 87-102.
Ozturk, I., & Acaravci, A. (2008). The demand for money in transition economies.
Romanian Journal of Economic Forecasting, 2, 35-43.
Parrado, E. (2004). Singapores unique monetary policy: How does it work?. IMF
Working Paper WP/04/10, 1-21.
Pesaran, M. H. & Smith, R. P. (1995). Estimating long run relationships from dynamic
heterogeneous panels, Journal of Econometrics, 68, 79113.
Pesaran, M. H., & Shin, Y., & Smith, R. P. (1997). Pooled estimation of long-run
relationships in dynamic heterogeneous panels. Cambridge Working Papers in
Economics 9721, Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge.
Pesaran, M. H., Shin, Y., & Smith, R. (2001). Bounds testing approaches to the analysis
of level relationships. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 16, 289-326.
Pigou, A. C 1917, The value of money, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 32, pp.38- 65.
27.
Poole, W. (2005). How predictable is the Fed?. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Review, 87, 659-668.
Poon, W. C., & Tong, G. K. (2009). The feasibility of inflation targeting in Malaysia.
Economics Bulletin, 29(2), 1035-1045.

Pozo, S., & Wheeler, M. (2000). Exchange-rate uncertainty and dollarization: A structural
vector error correction approach to estimating money demand. Applied Financial
Economics, 10, 685-692.
Price, S. (1995). Aggregate uncertainty, capacity utilization and manufacturing
investment. Applied Economics, 27,147-154.
Sriram, S. (1999). Survey of literature on demand for money: Theoretical and empirical
work with special reference to error-correction models. IMF Working Paper
WP/99/64, 1-77.
Tdter, K., & Manzke, B. (2007). The welfare effects of inflation: A cost-benefit
perspective. Deutsche Bundesbank Discussion Paper, 1(33), 1-64.
Turnovsky, S. J. (1971). The demand for money and the determination of the rate of
interest under uncertainty. Journal of Money, Credit & Banking (Ohio State
University Press), 3(2), 183-204.
United Nations (2013). World economic situation and prospects 2013. 1-36.
Werner, R. A. (2002). Monetary policy implementation in Japan: What they say versus
what they do*. Asian Economic Journal, 16(2), 111-151.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi