Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 60

The North American Model

of Wildlife Conservation

Technical Review 12-04


December 2012
1

The North American Model


of Wildlife Conservation
The Wildlife Society and The Boone and Crockett Club
Technical Review 12-04 - December 2012
Citation
Organ, J.F., V. Geist, S.P. Mahoney, S. Williams, P.R. Krausman, G.R. Batcheller, T.A. Decker, R. Carmichael,
P. Nanjappa, R. Regan, R.A. Medellin, R. Cantu, R.E. McCabe, S. Craven, G.M. Vecellio, and D.J. Decker. 2012.
The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation. The Wildlife Society Technical Review 12-04. The Wildlife
Society, Bethesda, Maryland, USA.

Series Edited by
Theodore A. Bookhout

Copy Edit and Design


Terra Rentz (AWB), Managing Editor, The Wildlife Society
Lisa Moore, Associate Editor, The Wildlife Society
Maja Smith, Graphic Designer, MajaDesign, Inc.

Cover Images
Front cover, clockwise from upper left: 1) Canada lynx (Lynx canadensis) kittens removed from den for
marking and data collection as part of a long-term research study. Credit: John F. Organ; 2) A mixed flock of
ducks and geese fly from a wetland area. Credit: Steve Hillebrand/USFWS; 3) A researcher attaches a radio
transmitter to a short-horned lizard (Phrynosoma hernandesi) in Colorados Pawnee National Grassland.
Credit: Laura Martin; 4) Rifle hunter Ron Jolly admires a mature white-tailed buck harvested by his wife on
the familys farm in Alabama. Credit: Tes Randle Jolly; 5) Caribou running along a northern peninsula of
Newfoundland are part of a herd compositional survey. Credit: John F. Organ; 6) Wildlife veterinarian Lisa
Wolfe assesses a captive mule deer during studies of density dependence in Colorado. Credit: Ken Logan/
Colorado Division of Wildlife.
TWS would like to thank The Boone and Crockett Program at the University of Montana for providing financial
support for publication. This report is copyrighted by TWS, but individuals are granted permission to make
single copies for noncommercial purposes. To view or download a PDF of this report, or to order hard copies,
go to: wildlife.org/publications/technical-reviews.

ISBN: 978-0-9830402-3-1
The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

ii

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

Technical Review Committee on The North


American Model of Wildlife Conservation
John F. Organ (Chair, CWB)*, **

Gordon R. Batcheller (CWB)

Ruben Cantu (CWB)

U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service

New York State Div. of Fish, Wildlife &

Texas Parks and Wildlife Department

300 Westgate Center Drive

Marine Resources

151 Las Lomas Ct.

Hadley, MA 01035 USA

625 Broadway

San Angelo, TX 76901 USA

Albany, NY 12233 USA


Valerius Geist*

Richard E. McCabe*

Faculty of Environmental

Thomas A. Decker (CWB)

Wildlife Management Institute

Design (Emeritus)

Vermont Fish and Wildlife Department

1424 NW Carlson Road

2500 University Dr. NW

103 South Main Street

Topeka, Kansas 66615 USA

University of Calgary

Waterbury, VT 05671 USA

Calgary, Alberta, T2N 1N4 CA

Scott Craven
Robert Carmichael

Department of Wildlife Ecology

Shane P. Mahoney*

Delta Waterfowl Foundation

Room 226 Russell Laboratories

Sustainable Development and

Site 1, Box 87

University of Wisconsin

Strategic Science Branch

Keewatin, Ontario POX 1C0 CA

1630 Linden Drive

Department of Environment

Madison WI 53706 USA

and Conservation

Priya Nanjappa

P.O. Box 8700

Association of Fish and

Gary M. Vecellio

St. Johns, NL A1B 4J6 CA

Wildlife Agencies

Idaho Fish and Game

444 North Capitol Street, NW,

4279 Commerce Circle

Steven Williams*

Suite 725

Idaho Falls, ID 83401 USA

Wildlife Management Institute

Washington, DC 20001 USA


Daniel J. Decker (CWB)

1440 Upper Bermudian Road


Ronald Regan (CWB)*

Human Dimensions Research Unit

Association of Fish and

206 Bruckner Hall

Paul R. Krausman (CWB)*

Wildlife Agencies

Department of Natural Resources

Boone and Crockett Professor of

444 North Capitol Street, NW, Suite 725

Cornell University

Wildlife Conservation

Washington, DC 20001 USA

Ithaca, NY 14853 USA

College of Forestry and Conservation

Rodrigo A. Medellin

32 Campus Drive

Instituto de Ecologa, UNAM

*Professional members of the Boone


and Crockett Club

University of Montana

Ap. Postal 70-275

Missoula, Montana 59812 USA

04510 Ciudad Universitaria, D. F.

Gardners, PA 17324 USA

Wildlife Biology Program

MEXICO

** The findings and conclusions in this


article are those of the author and do
not necessarily represent the views of
the U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service.

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

iii

iv

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

Table of Contents
Foreword vi
Acknowledgements vii
Executive Summary
viii
Introduction

Historical Overview 3
Canada and the United States

6
Implementation in Canada and the United States
Canada 6
United States 8

Review of Model Components 11
11
1. Wildlife Resources Are a Public Trust
2. Markets for Game Are Eliminated 14
3. Allocation of Wildlife Is by Law 16
18
4. Wildlife Can Be Killed Only for a Legitimate Purpose
19
5. Wildlife Is Considered an International Resource
6. Science Is the Proper Tool to Discharge Wildlife Policy
20
7. Democracy of Hunting Is Standard 23
Sustaining and Building Upon the Model 24
Funding 25
Wildlife Markets 25
Firearms Rights and Privileges 25
Habitat Considerations 26
Taxa Inclusivity 28
Governance 28
The Future of the Model 29
Summary and Recommendations 30
Literature Cited 31
Appendix: Status of Wildlife Management in Mexico
35

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

Foreword
P

residents of The Wildlife Society (TWS)


occasionally appoint ad hoc committees to
study and report on selected conservation issues.
The reports ordinarily appear as technical reviews
or position statements. Technical reviews present
technical information and the views of the appointed
committee members, but not necessarily the views of
their employers.
This technical review focuses on the set of
principles known as the North American Model
of Wildlife Conservation and was developed in
partnership with the Boone and Crockett Club. The
review is copyrighted by TWS, but individuals are
granted permission to make single copies for noncommercial purposes. All technical reviews and
position statements are available in digital format at
www.wildlife.org/. Hard copies may be requested or
purchased from:
The Wildlife Society
5410 Grosvenor Lane, Suite 200
Bethesda, MD 20814
Phone: (301) 897-9770
Fax: (301) 530-2471
TWS@wildlife.org
www.wildlife.org

Weighing a fawn during studies of density dependence in Colorado.


Courtesy of the Colorado Division of Wildlife.

vi

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

Acknowledgments

Commissioners representing Canada, Mexico, and the United States at the 1909 North American Conservation Congress. President
Theodore Roosevelt sits at center. Credit: Forest History Society.

e acknowledge the support of TWS



Presidents in office during preparation of
this report, including President Paul R. Krausman
and Past Presidents Tom Ryder, Bruce Leopold,
Tom Franklin, and Dan Svedarsky. We are grateful to
Theodore Bookhout for his thorough editing. Members
of The Wildlife Society Council John McDonald, Rick
Baydack, Darren Miller, and Ashley Gramza (Student
Liaison) provided comments and support. The Wildlife
Society editors Laura Bies, Terra Rentz, and Christine

Carmichael provided encouragement, invaluable


suggestions, and edits. This review was approved for
development in March 2007 by then-President John
F. Organ and approved for publication in October 2012
by then-President Paul R. Krausman. We would like
to recognize the financial support provided by both the
Boone and Crockett Club and The Boone and Crockett
Program at the University of Montana for publication,
printing, and distribution.

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

vii

Executive Summary

Bison (Bison bison ) in Yellowstone National Park. Credit: Jim Peaco, NPS.

he North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

whether we are prepared to address challenges that

is a set of principles that, collectively applied,

lay ahead. Simply adding to, deleting, or modifying the

has led to the form, function, and successes of wildlife

existing principles will not in itself advance conservation.

conservation and management in the United States and

Understanding the evidentiary basis for the principles

Canada. This technical review documents the history and

is essential to preventing their erosion, and necessary

development of these principles, and evaluates current

for the conceptual thinking required to anticipate future

and potential future challenges to their application.

challenges. A brief summary of some of the challenges

Describing the Model as North American is done in

and concerns follows:

a conceptual, not a geographical, context. Wildlife


conservation and management in Mexico developed

1. Wildlife resources are a public trust. Challenges

at a different time and under different circumstances

include (1) inappropriate claims of ownership of wildlife;

than in the U.S. and Canada. The latter two were hand

(2) unregulated commercial sale of live wildlife; (3)

in hand. The history, development, and status of wildlife

prohibitions or unreasonable restrictions on access to

conservation and management in Mexico are outlined

and use of wildlife; and (4) a value system endorsing an

separately as part of this review.

animal-rights doctrine and consequently antithetical to the


premise of public ownership of wildlife.

It is not the intent or purpose of this review to revise,

viii

modify, or otherwise alter what has heretofore been

2. Markets for game are eliminated. Commercial trade

put forward as the Model. Indeed, the Model itself is

exists for reptiles, amphibians, and fish. In addition, some

not a monolith carved in stone; it is a means for us to

game species are actively traded. A robust market for

understand, evaluate, and celebrate how conservation

access to wildlife occurring across the country exists in the

has been achieved in the U.S. and Canada, and to assess

form of leases, reserved permits, and shooting preserves.

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

3. Allocation of wildlife is by law. Application and


enforcement of laws to all taxa are inconsistent. Although
state authority over the allocation of the take of resident
game species is well defined, county, local, or housingdevelopment ordinances may effectively supersede state
authority. Decisions on land use, even on public lands,
indirectly impact allocation of wildlife due to land use
changes associated with land development.
4. Wildlife can be killed only for a legitimate purpose.
Take of certain species of mammals, birds, reptiles, and
amphibians does not correspond to traditionally accepted
notions of legitimate use.
5. Wildlife is considered an international resource.
Many positive agreements and cooperative efforts have
been established among the U.S., Canada, Mexico, and
other nations for conserving wildlife. Many more species
need consideration. Restrictive permitting procedures,
although designed to protect wildlife resources, inhibit
trans-border collaborations. Construction of a wall to
prevent illegal immigration from Mexico to the U.S. will
have negative effects on trans-border wildlife movements
and interactions.
6. Science is the proper tool to discharge wildlife
policy. Wildlife management appears to be increasingly
politicized. The rapid turnover rate of state agency
directors, the makeup of boards and commissions,
the organizational structure of some agencies, and
examples of politics meddling in science have challenged
the science foundation.

Trapping raccoons (Procyon lotor) in Missouri, biologist Dave Hamilton


(now deceased) helped assess traps for the BMP program. Courtesy of
Thomas Decker.

7. Democracy of hunting is standard. Reduction in, and


access to, huntable lands compromise the principle of
egalitarianism in hunting opportunity. Restrictive firearms
legislation can act as a barrier hindering participation.

To help address these challenges, this review presents
several recommendations. These are offered as
actions deemed necessary to ensure relevancy of the
Model in the future.

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

ix

Introduction

International trade in wildlife products came under greater scrutiny with the ratification of CITES by the U.S. in 1975. Credit: John and
Karen Hollingsworth, USFWS.

ildlife conservation varies worldwide in


its form, function, and underlying
principles. In recent years, efforts have been directed
to describe the key attributes that collectively make
wildlife conservation in North America unique.
Although efforts to articulate wildlife conservation in
North America have come of late, awareness among
practitioners in the U.S and Canada that their wildlife
conservation programs differed from others around
the world has existed for decades. Describing these
attributes or principles can serve many purposes:
foster celebration of the professions maturation

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

and accomplishments; serve as an educational tool;


and identify gaps, shortcomings, or areas in need
of expansion to address contemporary or future
challenges. The intent of this technical review is to
contribute to all of these purposes.
A model is a description of a system that accounts
for its key properties (Soukhanov 1988). The concept
that wildlife conservation in North America could be
described as a model was first articulated by Geist
(Geist 1995, Geist et al. 2001), who coined the term
North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

(Model). Geists direct knowledge of and familiarity


with wildlife conservation programs of other nations
provided a perspective on Canada and the U.S. The
concept was further developed by Mahoney (2004).
Today, the Model has become the basis for policies
developed by the Association of Fish and Wildlife
Agencies (Prukop and Regan 2005) and The Wildlife
Society (The Wildlife Society 2007). It was the key
underpinning for U.S. Executive Order 13443 that led
to the White House Conference on North American
Wildlife Policy (Mahoney et al. 2008, Sporting
Conservation Council 2008a) and fostered the
Recreational Hunting and Wildlife Conservation Plan
(Sporting Conservation Council 2008b).
Seven components or principles describe the key
properties of the Model (Geist et al. 2001, Organ et
al. 2010):
1. Wildlife resources are a public trust.
2. Markets for game are eliminated.
3. Allocation of wildlife is by law.

development, current status, threats and challenges,


and differences and commonalities in application
within Canada and the U.S. This information is then
used to further define the Model.

Wildlife conservation in Canada and the U.S.
developed under unique temporal and social
circumstances, and the resulting Model reflects
that. Had it formed in another time and under
other circumstances it would likely be different.
Use of the term North American to describe
the Model is conceptual rather than geographic.
Mexicos wildlife conservation movement began its
development and evolution at a different time and
under different circumstances. It is unrealistic to
expect that movement to mirror those of the U.S.
and Canada. A description of the evolution and
current status of wildlife conservation in Mexico is
provided in Appendix I. Further work is warranted
to compare how different temporal and social
circumstances have led to different conservation
approaches, identify what can be learned from those
comparisons, and what is needed to advance wildlife
conservation within Canada, Mexico, and the U.S.

4. Wildlife can be killed only for a legitimate purpose.


5. Wildlife is considered an international resource.
6. Science is the proper tool to discharge
wildlife policy.
7. Democracy of hunting is standard.

These seven components formed the foundation for
wildlife conservation in Canada and the U.S., but
questions have arisen as to the validity of certain
components in contemporary times and whether
scrutiny of conservation programs would deem
many of these operationally intact. Additionally,
the question as to whether the Model is inclusive
of all wildlife conservation interests or exclusively
narrow in its application has been posed (Beuchler
and Servheen 2008). To address these questions we
describe and analyze each component in terms of its

Peregrine falcons were protected in the United States


under the 1973 Endangered Species Act. Recovery efforts
succeeded in their restoration and removal from the federal
Endangered Species List. Credit: Craig Koppie, USFWS.

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

Historical Overview
T
he exploration of North America by the
French and English was fundamentally
motivated by the wealth of the continents renewable
natural resources and an unfettered opportunity
by individuals to exploit them (Cowan 1995). Today,
wildlife conservation in Canada and the U.S. reflects
this historic citizen access to the land and its natural
resources. Indeed, the sense that these resources
belong to the citizenry drives the democratic
engagement in the conservation process and is the
raison detre of North Americas unique approach
(Krausman, P., Gold, silver, and souls, unpublished
presentation at The Wildlife Society Annual
Conference, 22 September 2009, Monterey, CA, USA).

Resource exploitation fueled the expansion of
people across the continent and led to eventual
disappearance of the frontier (Turner 1935). As
elsewhere, the Industrial Revolution brought
changes to North American society that altered
the land and its wildlife. In 1820, 5 percent of
Americans lived in cities; by 1860 20 percent were
urban dwellers, a 4-fold increase that marks the
greatest demographic shift ever to have occurred in
America (Riess 1995). Markets for wildlife arose to
feed these urban masses and festoon a new class
of wealthy elites. Market hunters plied their trade
first along coastal waters and interior forests. Then,
with the advent of railways and refrigeration, they
exploited bison (Bison bison), elk (Cervus elaphus),
and other big game of western North America for
transport back to cities in eastern North America.
The market hunter left many once-abundant species
teetering on the brink of extinction. Ironically, the
sheer scale of this unmitigated exploitation was to
have some influence on engendering a remarkable
new phenomenon: protectionism and conservation
(Mahoney 2007).

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

The increasing urban population, meanwhile, found


themselves with something their countrymen
on the farms did not have: leisure time. Hunting
for the rigors and challenges of the chase under
conditions of fair play became a favored pastime
of many, particularly among those of means. This
developed in situ, but there can be no doubt that
European aristocratic perspectives toward hunting
exerted some influence on these emerging trends
(Herbert 1849). Threlfall (1995) noted that European
commoners never ceased desiring to participate
in the hunt, despite the best and brutal efforts of
nobility to discourage them. In the U.S., conflicts
soon arose between market hunters who profited
on dead wildlife and this new breed of hunters
who placed value on live wildlife and their sporting
pursuit of it. These sport hunters organized and
developed the first refuges for wildlife (Carrolls
Island Club 1832, Gunpowder River in Maryland;
Trefethen 1975) and laws to protect game (e.g., New
York Sportsmens Club 1844; Trefethen 1975).
Representative of these sport hunters was the highly
influential George Bird Grinnell, a Yale-educated
naturalist who accompanied George Armstrong
Custer on his Black Hills expedition and who
acquired the sporting journal Forest and Stream in
1879. Over the next 3 decades, Grinnell would turn
Forest and Stream into a call for wildlife conservation
(Reiger 1975). In 1885, he reviewed a book written
by a fellow New Yorker about his hunting exploits
in the Dakotas (Grinnell 1885). Grinnells review
was laudatory, but he criticized the author for some
inaccuracies. The author, Theodore Roosevelt, went
to meet Grinnell and the two realized that much
had changed during the 10 years that divided their
respective times in the West, and that big game
animals had declined drastically. Their discussion
inspired them to form the Boone and Crockett Club

in 1887, an organization whose purpose would


include to take charge of all matters pertaining to
the enactment and carrying out of game and fish
laws (Reiger 1975:234).

Roosevelt and Grinnell were also nation builders
who felt America was a strong nation because, like
Canada, its people had carved the country out of a
wilderness frontier with self-reliance and pioneer
skills. This harkened back to ideals regarding the
impact of the frontier on shaping what it is to be
an American; ideals articulated in the late 19th
century by Turner (1935). Turner described the
romantic notion of primitivism, for which the best
antidote to the ills of an overly refined and civilized
modern world was a return to a simpler, more
primitive life (Cronon 1995). With no frontier and
a growing urban populace, Roosevelt and Grinnell
feared America would lose this edge. They believed
Americans could cultivate pioneer skills and a
sense of fair play through sport hunting, and thereby
maintain the character of the nation (Cutright
1985, Miller 1992, Brands 1997). The Boone and
Crockett Club had many influential members, and
this was used to great effect in support of these
ideals. Two of North Americas most important and

enduring conservation legacies were written by


club members: the Lacey Act (Congressman John
Lacey from Iowa, 1900) and the Migratory Bird Treaty
Convention (Canadian Charles Gordon Hewitt, 1916).
And, of course, President Theodore Roosevelt did
more to conserve wildlife than any single individual
in U.S. history through the institutionalization
and popularization of conservation and by greatly
expanding federal protected lands (Brinkley 2009).

Canada did not embrace the policies and practices of
wildlife ownership and management as accepted in
Great Britain, foremost among these being the tie of
wildlife and hunting to landownership, and the sale
of wildlife as a commodity in the marketplace. Even
more remarkable is the fact that some of Canadas
negotiators and movers who were instrumental in
creating this new system of wildlife conservation
were Englishmen, immigrants to Canada.
It appears that at the turn of the century, when both
nations had become cognizant of wildlifes plight and
grappled for solutions, like-minded elites arose on
both sides of the border who knew and befriended
each other, learned from each others successes and

Early settlers killed wolves and other predators with abandon, blaming them for declines in game populations. Courtesy of
Thomas J. Ryder.
The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

Some 40,000 bison pelts in Dodge City, Kansas await shipment to the East Coast in 1878evidence of the rampant exploitation of the
species. The end of market hunting and continuing conservation efforts have given bison a new foothold across parts of their historic
range, including Yellowstone National Park. Courtesy of National Archives.

failures, and acted on them with insight and resolve.


The Canadian effort revolved around the Commission
on Conservation, which was constituted under
The Conservation Act of 1909. The Commission
was chaired until 1918 by Sir Clifford Sifton and
consisted of 18 members and 12 ex-officio members
(Geist 2000).
By the early 20th century, considerable wildlife
conservation infrastructure was in place, but by
the 1920s it was clear that the systems emphasis
on restrictive game laws was insufficient in itself
to stem wildlifes decline. Aldo Leopold, A. Willis
Robertson, and other conservationists published
an American Game Policy in 1930 (Leopold 1930)
that proposed a program of restoration to augment
conservations legal framework. They called for
a wildlife management profession with trained
biologists, stable, equitable funding to enable their
work and university programs to train them. Within

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

10 years much of what the policy called for had


been realized, with the first game management
curricula established at the University of Michigan
and the University of Wisconsin and the creation of
Cooperative Wildlife Research Units, the formation
of The Wildlife Society, and the passage of the
Pittman-Robertson Wildlife Restoration and
Duck Stamp Acts. These accomplishments were
all initially founded in the U.S. but many were
endorsed and mirrored by various Canadian
policies and programs.
Subsequent decades brought expanded legislation
(e.g., U.S. Endangered Species Act, Canadian
Species at Risk Act) and programs (e.g., Migratory
Bird Joint Ventures, Teaming With Wildlife), but
their principles had been set firmly in place. These
principles arose amidst social and environmental
circumstances that were unique to the world in their
temporal juxtaposition.

Implementation in Canada
and the United States
Canada
Governance. Responsibility for wildlife conservation
is assigned by the Canadian Constitution and is
shared between the provinces or territories and the
federal government. Variations on almost all of the
following occur in many parts of Canada, but the
general situation is described below.
Provincial and territorial authority is detailed in the
sub-federal jurisdictions acts and laws respecting
wildlife. Any authority not specified is considered
residual and falls to the federal government,
which is also responsible for wildlife on designated
federal lands (i.e., national parks), all migratory
wildlife that crosses international boundaries,
marine mammals, and, in some instances, where
the range or migration of a species occurs in
2 or more provinces or territories. The federal
Species at Risk Act (2002) may have application
where provincial or territorial measures to protect
endangered and threatened wildlife are considered
insufficient. The Act authorizes designation of
threatened species and identification of measures
to recover them. Exceptions and variations to
the foregoing exist across Canada specially in
Quebec (civil code derived from French law) and
the territories of Nunavut, Northwest Territories,
and Yukon (territorial jurisdiction is more limited
than is provincial in some matters) but the basic
model is that migratory, marine, and other federal
trust species fall to the federal government, and
everything else is within the purview of the provinces
and territories. Federal, provincial, and territorial
governments have established public wildlife
agencies (e.g., the federal Canadian Wildlife Service)

to devise and implement conservation programs.


Tacitly or explicitly, the fundamental tenets of the
Model are accepted and practiced in Canada.

Treaty Indians have jurisdiction over all animals on
their Indian Reserves, except where endangered
species legislation may be applied, and many
aboriginal communities do not accept the legitimacy
of any outside authority. In regards to aboriginal
communities, courts in Canada are still defining
matters of governance. Rights of access to wildlife
by aboriginal people (i.e., they are allowed to take
wildlife at any time on land to which they have
right of access) was confirmed in the Constitution
Act of 1982. These rights may be abrogated by
government only after extensive consultation, and
only for purposes of sustaining wildlife populations.
A restriction on access to wildlife on aboriginal lands
applies automatically to all Canadians.
Systematic consultation among federal, provincial,
territorial, and, more recently, aboriginal authorities
is extensive. Complexities of Canadian law and
tradition have made apparent to wildlife managers
that effective conservation programming requires
close consultation among all jurisdictions. For
decades, the annual Federal-Provincial Wildlife
Conference was a fixture in Canada; it now has
evolved into a structured contact among the
jurisdictions through regular meetings of provincial,
territorial, and federal wildlife-resource directors
employed by public wildlife agencies. Other groups
such as the Committee On the Status of Endangered
Wildlife In Canada (COSEWIC) also operate on a
foundation of inter-jurisdictional consultation and
cooperation. In general, the goal of such groups
is to agree on basic policy and program initiatives,

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

but leave implementation to the legal authority,


where it can be done in keeping with widely varying
circumstances across Canada.
Canada is signatory to several international
treaties and conventions, including the Migratory
Bird Treaty with the U.S. and Mexico, its derivative
North American Waterfowl Management Plan, the
Convention on International Trade in Endangered
Species of Fauna and Flora (CITES), and the
Ramsar Convention on Wetlands (RAMSAR) the
international treaty for maintaining wetlands of
international importance.
Management authority over wildlife is public.
Although laws differ widely among jurisdictions
with respect to captive animals, the basic principle
is that wildlife is a public trust, and no private
ownership is allowed. Landowners may be given
special access privileges in recognition of their
role in sustaining populations of certain species,
but only in accordance with public law. Private
conservation organizations have a vital role in
conservation and work closely with public agencies.
There are advisory boards in some provinces and
territories, but public stewardship prevails. The
governance model for wildlife conservation decision
making is typically at the (elected) ministerial
level. Boards and commissions do not have the
significant role in Canada that they do in the U.S.
Canadas political structure is based on the British
parliamentary system, which affords less direct
participation in public affairs than does the American
congressional system.
Funding. As mentioned above, Canada is governed
under (its derivative of) the British parliamentary
system, of which a fundamental aspect is the
general revenue system of public finance, meaning
no dedicated funds. All tax revenues, regardless
of source, go into a central account and are then
allocated by government according to its priorities.
Canadian political tradition is that representatives
are not elected to carry out the will of the people,
but to exercise their good judgment on behalf of the

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

people as to how tax money should be allocated.


The peoples will is expressed at election time.
The rule of thumb is, for example, a gasoline tax
or any portion thereof does not go to highway
infrastructure. Instead, the government will
decide how much goes to highways and what goes
elsewhere, according to its priorities.

With regard to wildlife, the general revenue system
explains why wildlife agencies in the U.S. are,
overall, far better staffed and funded than are their
Canadian counterparts. Canadian public agencies
depend on general revenue tax dollars for their
basic operations. Canada has no equivalent to the
Pittman-Robertson Wildlife Restoration Program,
and no dedicated sales tax. The Canadian funding
mechanism also explains why research has all but
disappeared from provincial and territorial agencies.
Compounding this systemic reality is competition
for public funds in Canada at all levels of
government. Wildlife therefore must compete
directly with health, education, and social services
for funds on an annual basis. The result is that
wildlife does not, in almost all circumstances,
receive what its proponents and managers believe
is its due. Usually, there is no provision for carrying
over unspent funds from one fiscal year to the next,
which tightens finances even further.
Recently, provincial governments are beginning
to understand that many wildlife programs (i.e.,
hunting) generate significant dollars for the public
purse. However, those dollars cannot be sustained
with wildlife management funded under general
revenue financing. Fortunately, certain old rules are
gradually being relaxed, and dedicated funds are
appearing in some provinces. The future for wildlife
management will very much depend on how quickly
and effectively the need for a new funding basis is
communicated to governments.

At present, investment by non-governmental
organizations, federal, provincial, and territorial
cost-sharing agreements, and leveraged funds
from outside Canada are critical to conservation

programming in nearly all parts of the country. For


example, revenues from the U.S. play a large role
in Canadian waterfowl management. Provincial
and territorial hunting programs usually depend on
general revenues to a much higher degree than do
endangered wildlife or habitat programs.
Scope. What wildlife is and who manages it
depends on which part of Canada is considered.
Wildlife managed by a Wildlife Branch in one
province or territory may not be considered wildlife
in another, similar to different classifications of
wildlife in different states in the U.S. There is general
accord, however, on some major groups of species:
ungulates, waterfowl, most furbearers, and birds are
wildlife and the responsibility of professional wildlife
managers everywhere. Wildlife legislation has,
overall, become much more inclusive of late, and
now commonly includes amphibians, reptiles, plants,
and, in some instances, invertebrates. The structure,
purview, and emphasis of provincial and territorial
agencies vary significantly.
Defining which taxa constitute wildlife is essentially
up to each province or territory. There is no overarching federal legislation in this regard, although
the federal government does make specific
reference to species under its jurisdiction. Species
defined as wildlife in the provinces and territories
are accorded protection under legislation that differs
in scope and type of application.
Wildlife agencies are the sole managers of
problem wildlife in some provinces, while sharing
or not having this responsibility in others. Always
prefaced with the qualifier generally, ungulates or
waterfowl cannot be killed in defense of property;
furbearers such as beaver (Castor canadensis) or
predatory species that take livestock, including gray
wolves (Canis lupus), can be. Species such as ground
squirrels (Spermophilus sp.), pigeons (Columba
livia), and English sparrows (Passer domesticus) are
normally not given any protection under provincial or
territorial legislation.

Some provinces and territories have outright


prohibitions on holding species defined as wildlife
in captivity, whereas others allow it for specific
purposes, such as elk ranching or roadside zoos.
In some provinces, a species is considered wildlife
if not confined, and not wildlife if it is legally
held. Responsibility for captive wildlife may be
vested within a wildlife agency or other division of
government such as agriculture.

United States
Governance. Governance over wildlife management
in the U.S. is divided between the federal
government and individual states. The Public Trust
Doctrine established the states as trustees of
wildlife (Batcheller et al. 2010) except where the
Constitution provided for federal oversight (Bean
1983). Three clauses of the Constitution provide for
federal oversight: the Commerce Clause, Property
Clause, and Supremacy Clause (federal treatymaking power). At the federal level, responsibilities
for wildlife are assigned to agencies within the
Departments of the Interior (Fish and Wildlife
Service, Bureau of Land Management, National
Park Service, Bureau of Reclamation, Bureau of
Indian Affairs, Geological Survey), Agriculture
(Forest Service, Animal and Plant Health Inspection
Service, Natural Resource Conservation Service),
Commerce (National Marine Fisheries Service for
certain marine mammals), Environmental Protection
Agency, and Department of Defense.

Within states, 2 governance models predominate:
boards or commissions that make policy decisions
and oversee an agency, and political appointees that
make policy decisions and oversee an agency. Both
models are products of representative democracy
(Jacobson and Decker 2008). Representative
democracy is the appointment or election of
individuals responsible for making decisions that
ostensibly fulfill public trust mandates.

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

Dead bison. Credit: Wisconsin Historical Society.

Funding. Fish and wildlife conservation funding


in the U.S., at least at the state level, typically is
characterized as a user-pay, user-benefit model.
From the earliest days of active management and
enforcement by nascent state fish and wildlife
agencies, hunters, anglers, and trappers have
funded restoration and conservation initiatives.
License and permit fees, a motor boat fuels tax, and
excise taxes on hunting, shooting sports, and angling
products provide dedicated funding for habitat
conservation, harvest management, research,
restoration, and monitoring initiatives by state
agencies. The excise tax programs have permanent,
indefinite appropriation status, which means that the
revenues are automatically distributed to the states
each year and not subject to congressional whim.

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

To this day, the combination of sportsmen-derived


funds described above comprise between 60 and 90
percent of the typical state fish and wildlife agency
budget (U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service, unpublished
data). In addition, sportsmen and women also donate
volunteer time and dollars to national, regional,
and local conservation organizations (e.g., Ducks
Unlimited, National Wildlife Turkey Federation,
Pheasants Forever, Rocky Mountain Elk Foundation,
Quail Unlimited, Ruffed Grouse Society, The
Nature Conservancy), in effect multiplying the
conservation power of the agencies. Clearly the
success of the Model is in no small measure
indebted to hunter- and angler-conservationists
and visionary industry leaders.

For more than 2 decades, state fish and wildlife


agencies have recognized the need for broader
programs in light of new mandates, new threats,
enhanced management attention to non-harvested
species, and new constituent demands (e.g., bird
watchers). Indeed, with the strong support of state
fish and wildlife directors, the Association of Fish
and Wildlife Agencies initiated the Teaming With
Wildlife Program to focus action on securing new
funding for wildlife diversity. At the national level,
concerted attention has been given to developing a
new excise tax on birding, hiking, camping, and other
recreational equipment, one that would build off the
success of the same tax for hunting, shooting sports,
and angling equipment. This has yet to bear fruit,
however, given the strong political opposition to new
taxes, and potentially because the broader public
may lack the vested interest that sportsmen and
women have demonstrated in supporting user fees.
More recently, dedicated funding efforts have
focused on royalties from energy development and
carbon credits from climate change legislation as
ways to fund wildlife adaptation programs. Even
though dedicated funding has proved elusive,
since 2000 the U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service with
congressional authorization has implemented the
State Wildlife Grants program, which has provided
more than $600 million to state fish and wildlife
agencies for species of greatest conservation need.
At the state level, direct appropriations from the
general fund, sales tax and lottery allocations,
voluntary contributions via income-tax check-offs,
and special license plates have been used to fund
new programs by state fish and wildlife agencies.
Funding at the federal level is determined annually
through the appropriations process and embedded
in legislation such as the Farm Bill and the
Interior Appropriations Act. The Land and Water
Conservation Fund is an important source of revenue
for federal national wildlife refuge land acquisition.
Dedicated funding from the sale of federal Migratory
Bird Hunting and Conservation Stamps also supports
national wildlife refuge acquisitions.

As noted elsewhere, all wildlife species are public


trust resources. The Model has thrived in large
part because of the support of the hunting, angling,
shooting sports, and boating communities, and
industries for habitat and species management and
conservation. Long-term declines in both hunter
and angler participation place into question the
sustainability of such a funding approach and beg
the need for new funding to address new challenges.
A few state fish and wildlife agencies, most notably
Missouri and Arkansas, have successfully secured
alternate funding to augment traditional sources
(Jacobson et al. 2010a). Jacobson et al. (2010b)
reflect on the difficult and all-too-real challenges
facing fish and wildlife agencies in the midst of
stable-to-declining traditional revenues such as
hunter and angler license dollars.
Scope. Wildlife conservation in the U.S. is
broad, encompassing most terrestrial, aquatic,
and marine vertebrates and invertebrates, and
plants. The degree to which a given taxa receives
conservation attention depends upon its legal status
(e.g., furbearer, game, special concern, nongame,
threatened, or endangered), whose jurisdiction it
is under (i.e., federal trust species or state), the
availability of funding, and its relative priority (e.g.,
species of greatest conservation need identified in a
State Wildlife Action Plan).

Wood turtles and other reptile species are receiving


increased management and protection in the U.S. with
funding from the federal State Wildlife Grant Program,
but international trade in turtles remains a threat to
sustainability of their populations. Credit: John F. Organ.

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

10

Review of Model Components


1. Wildlife Resources Are a
Public Trust

respects habitations, monuments, and the


buildings, which are not, like the sea, subject
only to the law of nations. (Roman Law)

The keystone component of the Model is the concept


that wildlife is owned by no one and is held in trust
for the benefit of present and future generations by
government (Geist and Organ 2004). This is the legal
foundation for federal, provincial, and state wildlife
agencies. The common law basis in the U.S. is the
Public Trust Doctrine, a Supreme Court decision
in 1842 that declared certain resources could not
be taken into private ownership (Martin v. Waddell;
Batcheller et al. 2010).

The roots of the Public Trust Doctrine in Roman law


are complex. Joseph Sax, the pre-eminent scholar
of the Public Trust Doctrine, traced these roots so
that we may better understand the modern context
(Sax 1970, 1999). The Romans had an elaborate
property system that recognized different kinds
of property serving different functions. Certain
property belonged to the gods, certain property
belonged to the state, and certain property belonged
to individuals. Each of these kinds of property had
a special status and had to be treated in a certain
way. For example, the property might not be capable
of being bought and sold. Other kinds of property
included common property (res communis). Common
property (1) could not be privately owned, and (2) was
for common use by everyone. Roman law included
wildlife (ferae naturae) within the law of things
owned by no one (res nullius). These categories
were probably for what the Romans perceived to
be the nature of things that were abundant and not
appropriate for private possession and sale (Horner
2000). Ownership of a wild animal occurred only
when it was physically possessed, most typically
when killed for food.

Historical Development. The U.S. Supreme Court


ruling in 1842 denied a landowners claim to exclude
all others from taking oysters from certain mudflats
in New Jersey (Martin v. Waddell; Bean 1983, Organ
and Batcheller 2009). Chief Justice Roger Taney, in
determining that the lands under navigable waters
were held as a public trust, based the decision on
his interpretation of the Magna Carta. The Magna
Carta, in turn, had drawn upon Roman law that was
first written as the Institutes of Justinian (A.D. 529;
Adams 1993). The written codes of Justinian were
based upon the 2nd century Institutes and Journal
of Gaius, who codified the natural law of Greek
philosophers (Slade et al.1977). The application
of this fundamental concept of the public trust to
natural resources, first written for posterity by the
Romans, is as old as civilization itself. What the
Romans recorded was, in part:

By the law of nature these things are


common to all mankind - the air, running
water, the sea, and consequently the shore
of the sea. No one, therefore, is forbidden
to approach the seashore, provided that he

11

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

Roman civil law was adopted in substance by the


English after the Magna Carta (A.D. 1215; Slade
et al. 1977). English common law also recognized
special kinds of property, but provided its own
context. English common law disliked ownerless
things, so the ownership of public resources was
placed in the king (Horner 2000). These properties
were owned by the king, but not for his private use.
The king was a trustee, owning certain properties for
someone else, which became a special responsibility
(Sax 1999).

English law applied in the American colonies, yet


after independence and the formation of the U.S.,
there was no king to be the trustee. It was not until
1842 and the Supreme Court decision in Martin v.
Waddell that trustee status was ascribed to the
states. To understand how the ancient concept of
public trust and the modern Public Trust Doctrine
neither one specific to wildlife have both become a
pillar of wildlife conservation, we must look at their
legal essence.

states of Massachusetts, Maine, and New Hampshire


added fowling as a right. It was not until 1896 that
wildlife became firmly established in law as a public
trust resource of the states. Geer v. Connecticut
became judge-made law that is the heart and soul
of the modern day public trust in wildlife (Horner
2000:21). While transforming this principle into
modern American law, and making the concept of
wildlife as public trust resources distinctly American,
the court stated:

Public Trust as Law. Sax (1999) identified 4


fundamental concepts of public trust:

Whilst the fundamental principles upon


which the common property in game rests
have undergone no change, the development
of free institutions has lead [sic] to the
recognition of the fact that the power or
control lodged in the State, resulting from the
common ownership, is to be exercised, like all
other powers of government, as a trust for the
benefit of all people, and not as a prerogative
for the advantage of the government, as
distinct from the people, or for the benefit of
private individuals as distinguished from the
public (161 U.S. 519, 1896).

1. Public trust is common law. There is no legal


code specific to the Public Trust Doctrine because it
has never been officially enacted. It is judge-made
law that is interpreted and evolves through court
decisions. For the last century or so, most of our
laws have been statutory coded laws, but for most
of the development of the Anglo-American legal
system, common law prevailed.

2. Public trust is state law. As such, there is no


single law but many. Yet each embodies a unifying
principle of the fundamental rights of all citizens.

3. Public trust is property law. One of the great


strengths of the Public Trust Doctrine is that in
asserting it, the state is asserting its own property
rights - property rights that belong to the public - so
the issue of taking becomes moot as one cannot be
taking a property right from another while asserting
such right.

4. Public trust is a public right. Trust property is


owned by the public and held in trust for the benefit
of the public. One does not have to have special
status to make a claim but only must be a member
of the public.
Because the Public Trust Doctrine is common law,
and judge-made, it can never be repealed by a
legislature. The traditional applications of public
rights under the Public Trust Doctrine were for
navigation, fishing, and commerce. The New England

The trustee status of states in regard to wildlife is


transferred to the federal government in the U.S.
when wildlife falls within parameters of the U.S.
Constitutions Supremacy Clause (federal treatymaking power), Commerce Clause, and Property
Clause. Chief Justice Taney, in articulating the
Public Trust Doctrine in Martin v. Waddell in 1842
acknowledged this when he wrote that the powers
assumed by the states were subject only to the
rights since surrendered by the Constitution to the
general government (41 U.S. 367 1842).
Current Status, Threats, and Challenges. A review
of the Public Trust Doctrine was completed recently,
including an evaluation of current and anticipated
threats that may weaken this pivotal doctrine
(Batcheller et al. 2010). Several threats have been
identified that directly or indirectly undermine
existing state, provincial, and federal laws (Geist and

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

12

Organ 2004). These threats include (1) inappropriate


claims of ownership of wildlife; (2) unregulated
commercial sale of live wildlife; (3) prohibitions or
unreasonable restrictions on access to and use of
wildlife; (4) and a value system endorsing an animalrights doctrine and consequently antithetical to the
premise of public ownership of wildlife (Organ and
Mahoney 2007, Organ and Batcheller 2009).

In many jurisdictions, domesticated native or
exotic animals with recently descended from wild
stock may be owned. Typical uses of these animals
include game farms and more traditional farms
to produce meat from wild animals. Some game
farms practice genetic husbandry to produce trophy
class antlers or horns; others provide shooting
opportunities in enclosed and fenced natural or
semi-natural settings. The legal status of animals
held in captivity under these conditions is equivocal.
At its core, the key question is: do wild animals held
in captivity, including fenced enclosures, remain as
trust resources or are they private property? Is there
a distinction between the status of a wild animal held
within a fence (e.g., a wild ungulate jumping into an
enclosure and then held in pseudo-captivity), and
an animal deliberately housed within an enclosure
and husbanded via traditional livestock practices?
Although these are central issues germane to the
Public Trust Doctrine, they have not been widely
addressed in case law, thereby raising great
uncertainty about its application to these situations.
Moreover, commercialization places a monetary
value on wildlife or wildlife parts and a concomitant
incentive for their use, which threatens the premise
of public ownership of wildlife.

From our history, we know that some forms of
commercial use of wildlife are unsustainable,
especially in the absence of strong legal
and regulatory controls on harvest and
marketing. However, in most jurisdictions some
commercialization of wildlife is permissible under
highly regulated legal regimes. For example,
trapping is an important wildlife conservation
tool and a legitimate use of renewable wildlife
resources, but only under a system of strict controls

13

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

to limit harvest and to provide for legal commerce.


The regulation of commercial furbearer harvest
is generally mature, but other forms of wildlife
commercialization are poorly regulated, and
some evidence suggests that the commercialization
of taxa such as amphibians and reptiles may be
harmful to native, wild populations. If the Public
Trust Doctrine is to be fully applied to all
wild fauna, these loopholes in the control of
commercial use of reptiles and other taxa would
need to be closed. An all-taxa approach to wildlife
management would help ensure that all species
receive benefits associated with public valuation and
public ownership.

A central premise of the Public Trust Doctrine is
access to wildlife, yet there is growing evidence that
the public has a more difficult time finding places to
hunt or trap on private land, and even in gaining easy
access to public lands (Responsive Management/
National Shooting Sports Foundation 2008). In some
instances, high fees are charged to gain access to
private lands, or to use convenient private points
of access to public lands. Many public wildlife
agencies charge high fees for limited permits to
hunt certain big game species. However, a large
number of people cannot afford to pay high user
fees (Duda et al. 1998). They may stop hunting if
they are unable to find a place to hunt, cannot
afford the fees, or are discouraged by crowding on
public lands (Responsive Management and National
Shooting Sports Foundation 2008). Worse, in some
states, certain guides use baiting as a means
of attracting game from public lands to private
lands, where they are shot under an exclusive (and
expensive) arrangement with the client. In a manner
similar to fencing, these practices jeopardize
another tenet, the democracy of hunting, and
significantly weaken the social benefits associated
with the Public Trust Doctrine (Dunkley and Cattet
2003, Ermer et al. 2005).

The foundational notion of public ownership
implies that society values wildlife and, by
implication, understands the premise of wildness.
The growth of certain wildlife populations and

the associated human conflicts stemming from


interactions between people and animals may lead
to a devaluation of wildlife and wild places. For
example, when coyotes (Canis latrans) attacked 2
small children in a suburban New York community,
tolerance of coyotes diminished among community
residents, with 9 out of 10 residents expressing
concern about coyotes in their community (Siemer
and Decker 2011). If those citizens learn that open
and green spaces attracted coyotes in the first
place, will they retain their value of wild places
and creatures, or will they gravitate toward a
devaluation of green spaces altogether? Similarly,
the widely discussed notion of nature deficit disorder
(Louv 2008) suggests that citizens may be growing
increasingly ambivalent toward nature. If that is true,
why should they care about maintaining wildlife in
perpetual public trust? Finally, persons who accept
an animal-rights world view categorically reject
the concept of ownership of animals, rendering the
central legal principles of the Public Trust Doctrine
irrelevant. Strong leadership and concerted efforts
on the part of wildlife professionals will be required
to make the case that wild places are important, and
that wildlife needs to be protected for one and all, as
posited by the Public Trust Doctrine.

Batcheller et al. (2010) evaluated the status of the
Public Trust Doctrine in the U.S. and Canada. In
the U.S., the Public Trust Doctrine in its traditional
form is strongly based in statutory and case law,
especially as applied to navigable waterways.
Recently, the Public Trust Doctrine has been applied
to broader applications in case and statutory law,
and specifically to other natural resources including
wildlife. However, relatively few states have
specific case law that clearly recognizes wildlife
as a public trust resource. Many states, on the
other hand, use either explicit or implicit statutory
language to confer public trust status to wildlife
resources. Batcheller et al. (2010:22) concluded
that bringing wildlife into the Public Trust Doctrine
through statutory measures appears to be the
best way to accomplish the goal of extending the
Public Trust Doctrine in this area. To this end,
statutory language that clearly puts wildlife in public

ownership is necessary. In Canada, about one-half


of the provinces and territories have language on
the public ownership of wildlife in their statutes,
but Canadas wildlife conservation institutions also
would benefit from a comprehensive strengthening
of the Public Trust Doctrine.
Canada, although following Great Britain in modeling
much of its legal system, opted for the same basic
policies governing wildlife as did the U.S. In Great
Britain, wildlife became de facto private property
of landowners (Threlfall 1995). An account of this
effort to protect Canadas wildlife in cooperation with
the U.S. was discussed by Hewitt (1921), including
the establishment of wildlife treaties between the
2 countries. Historically, wildlife became a public
resource in part by default because the Crown was
the ward of huge tracts of land not claimed for
settlement and was thus the de facto owner of the
wildlife it contained. Moreover, as wildlife fed native
populations, Canadas government had little choice
but to safeguard that food supply.
Batcheller et al. (2010) provided model statutory
language that would give an unequivocal legal
underpinning to sustain the Public Trust Doctrine
vis--vis wildlife conservation indefinitely.

2. Markets for Game Are


Eliminated
The unregulated trafficking in meat, hides, and
other parts of game animals and nongame birds
in the 19th century led to drastic and, in some
instances, catastrophic declines in populations.
Elimination of markets for game animals and
nongame birds was an essential step in halting
declines of these particular species. It has since
been held in principle that markets for game and
nongame wildlife are unacceptable because they
privatize a common resource and lead to declines.
Exceptions have been made for furbearers because
there is an active market in Canada and the U.S.
for furbearer pelts and in some instances meat

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

14

(e.g., muskrat [Ondatra zibethicus] and raccoon


[Procyon lotor]). The underlying premise for fur
markets is that they are highly regulated and serve
a conservation purpose because harvests are within
normal population fluctuation levels consistent with
sustainable-use principles, help manage conflicts
between furbearers and humans, and foster support
for habitat conservation (Boggess et al. 1990, Geist
et al. 2001, Prescott-Allen and Prescott-Allen
1996). Markets for taxa other than game, nongame
birds, and furbearers exist in North America, but
regulations and enforcement vary, and impacts on
populations are not well understood.
Historical Development. The first concerted efforts
to eliminate markets for game animals were
those of the New York Sportsmens Club, formed
in 1844 (Trefethen 1975) with objectives confined
to protection and preservation of game, and funds
appropriated solely for those purposes. The clubs
membership included many influential lawyers,
judges, and politicians, who often acted in their
official positions on behalf of the club. At a time
when there was limited or no government oversight
on wildlife, they drafted, led efforts to enact, and
enforced the first game laws directed against market
hunting. These laws were local to New York City,
but because of the market that locale provided, the
impact was notable.

The Boone and Crockett Club was responsible for
important legislation at the state and federal levels.
Co-founder George Bird Grinnell used his weekly
journal Forest and Stream to communicate the need
for elimination of game markets (e.g., Grinnell
1894). Club member Congressman John Lacey of
Iowa sponsored the Yellowstone Park Protection Act
which passed in 1894, becoming the first federal
law to protect game from market hunting (Trefethen
1975). The Lacey Act of 1900 effectively made
market hunting illegal nationwide and remains the
most powerful legal tool to combat this activity.
The Migratory Bird Treaty of 1916 between the
U.S. and Canada, and subsequently many other
nations including Mexico and Japan, provided the

15

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

constitutional grounding for the Migratory Bird


Treaty Act of 1918 and extended international
protection for bird species from the market. The U.S.
Endangered Species Act of 1973 and the Canadian
Species at Risk Act of 2002 extended protection from
the market to a multitude of other species.
Current Status, Threats, and Challenges.
Commercial trade for reptiles, amphibians, and
fish is thriving (Nanjappa and Conrad 2011). In
addition, some game species that we would expect
to fall under the principles of the Model are actively
traded. Deer (Odocoileus spp.), elk, ring-necked
pheasants (Phasianus colchicus), quail, chukar
(Alectoris chukar), and more exotic wildlife species
are commonly bought and sold (Freese and Trauger
2000). Related to wildlife markets are contests and
tournaments common in rural areas of the country.
Big buck contests, coyote hunts, crow (Corvus spp.)
hunts, and numerous other commercial contests
imply a market-based hunting situation. The sale of
furbearers, seal (Phocidae) fur, antlers, reproduced
antlers, and a variety of other wildlife parts needs to
be considered in light of the principle that markets
for wildlife are eliminated. A robust market for
access to wildlife occurring across the U.S. and
Canada exists in the form of leases, reserved
permits, and shooting preserves.
In contrast to hunting contests and tournaments,
where a hunting (or fishing) license is required,
markets for trade in amphibians, turtles, and
reptiles are not consistently regulated (Nanjappa
and Conrad 2011). Markets for pets, both native
to North America and from international sources,
are relatively open (Niraj et al. 2012). In addition,
amphibians and turtles, in particular, are traded
for meat. Freshwater turtles are declining sharply
(Turtle Conservation Foundation 2010, International
Union for Conservation of Nature 2009), primarily
because of demands from Asian food markets.
However, turtle harvests have been difficult to
track because regulations are not widespread, and
reporting requirements vary across states.

3. Allocation of Wildlife
Is by Law
Access to wildlife has been an inherent part of the
North American experience, unlike many other
nations where access is reserved for those with
special privilege (e.g., aristocracy; Manning 1993).
Wildlife is allocated to the public by law, as opposed
to market principles, land ownership, or other
status. Democratic processes and public input into
law-making help ensure access is equitable.
Historical Development. The seemingly unlimited
resources of the New World were used to attract
colonists from the Old World with prospects of
pelts, hides, and feathers for trade and food for
survival. These images mitigated the harsh reality
of eking out an existence in the unforgiving wilds of
North America. It was not long before the colonies
began to enact regulations specific to wildlife. The
first regulations on record focused on protection
of livestock, essential to the survival and livelihood
of settlers. In 1630 the General Court of the
Massachusetts Bay Colony passed an act offering a
reward to anyone who killed a wolf. In 1632 Virginia
established a bounty on wolves (Trefethen 1975).

In a relatively short time game animals started to
become scarce and protective regulations were
warranted. In 1646, Portsmouth, Rhode Island,
closed the white-tailed deer (Odocoileus virginianus)
season from May 1 to November 1 and established
a penalty of 5 pounds for hunting out-of-season.
Connecticut adopted a law that stated that the killing
of deer at unseasonable times of the year would be
against the interests of the colony because it would
result in decreased production (Trefethen 1975).
In 1705, the General Assembly at Newport, Rhode
Island, noted that large numbers of deer had been
killed out of season, and deemed this detrimental
to the future of the colony, and indeed the whole
country if not prevented.

Alarming decreases in numbers of deer prompted


the General Court of Massachusetts in 1739 to step
up enforcement of the deer-season law it enacted in
1698. Each town was instructed to appoint 2 deer
reeves to enforce the closed season. The fine for
a conviction was 10 pounds, probably $1,000 today,
with one-half the fine going to the deer reeve as
his fee. Azariah Seldon of Hadley, Massachusetts,
was convicted in 1763 of killing a deer out of season
and assessed the full fine of 10 pounds. Another
individual, unable to raise the fine, was put on the
auction block and sold to the highest bidder for
2 months of forced labor. These laws and their
enforcement probably served as a deterrent, but the
continued habitat destruction and long open season
with no bag limit took their toll. By the time of the
American Revolution, many towns in the colonies
abandoned the deer reeve office because there were
so few deer to protect. Nevertheless, these laws
and regulations reflected the thinking of the time,
highlighted the need to preserve a food supply, and
established a mechanism for protecting wildlife.
The efforts of the New York Sportsmens Club
and Boone and Crockett Club in development of
game laws in the 19th century to address market
hunting have been noted earlier. In 1897, the
New York State Assembly passed the Adirondack
Deer Law (sponsored by assemblymen who were
Boone and Crockett Club members) that outlawed
jacklighting deer at night and shooting deer after
using hounds to drive them into deep water. Most
notable about this law was that shooting deer in
water was outlawed because of potential deleterious
effects on the deer population, and jacklighting
(e.g., spotlighting) was banned because it was
unsportsmanlike (these laws remain intact today).
The underlying principle was that a population or
species, entirely independent of whether it was
increasing or decreasing, should be protected from
cruel or unsportsmanlike methods of killing (Sanger
1897). Audubon societies (the first ones were formed
by Grinnell) and other nature groups allied with

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

16

sportsmen and began to lobby for legislation to


curtail the feather trade that was decimating many
nongame bird species (Dunlap 1988).
Game laws, game agencies, and game commissions
established by states in the late-19th and early20th centuries focused primarily on eliminating
commercial uses of wildlife (e.g., birds and the
millinery trade) and on regulating numbers of game
legally killed by sportsmen. Hunting methods were
regulated to conform to accepted standards of fair
chase as outlined by the Boone and Crockett Club,
which would ideally minimize opportunities for
hunters to exceed bag limits. Federal conservation
programs were developed for protection of migratory
birds through regulation, law enforcement, and
refuge establishment. Federal conservation efforts
also focused on predator control in an effort to
benefit game populations and livestock ranchers
(Meine 1988). At the beginning of the 20th century,
game and songbird populations were in decline,
and in some instances disastrously so, and both
sportsmen and bird lovers felt that control of
predators, including raptors, was necessary (Dunlap
1988, Mighetto 1991). As furbearer species such as
beaver were restored, states established regulated
fur trapping seasons so they could manage
furbearers as valued resources while effectively
minimizing human property and safety concerns
(Shaw 1948).
Passage of the Pittman-Robertson Wildlife
Restoration Act in 1937 ushered in an era
of restoration, and the increase in scientific
management led to fine-tuning the system of
seasons and bag limits. Prior to restoration
programs, population monitoring was limited.
Seasons and bag limits were either by too
conservative or too liberal. As more jurisdictions
began to monitor harvests, they began to see
population trends and responded with regulations
designed to increase or sustain populations. Many
states that had allowed either-sex deer seasons,
for example, initiated male-only (buck) laws. In
Massachusetts, where hunters could take 1 deer

17

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

of any sex, the reported deer harvest declined until


1967 when a buck law was imposed. Gradually,
female (doe) permits were re-issued on a county
basis in those areas that could sustain a reduction
in growth or had agricultural conflicts. Eventually,
during the 1980s, deer management zones were
established independent of political boundaries,
but representative of deer range differences. This
allowed greater control of the deer population
through adjusting the doe kill differentially based on
habitat and human influences. These examples typify
the focus of game regulations in the post-World War
II period.
Laws regulating access to species other than game,
migratory birds, and furbearers were uncommon
until the mid- to late-20th century. Passage of the
Bald Eagle Protection Act in 1940 was followed
by the Endangered Species Preservation Act of
1966, the Fur Seal Act of 1966, the Endangered
Species Conservation Act of 1969, the Marine
Mammal Protection Act of 1972, and the 1973
Endangered Species Act. These laws focus on the
take of animals, and represent an expansion of the
approach taken to stem market hunting toward a
broad array of other uses of wildlife. Several state
and federal laws protect wetlands, but few laws
focus specifically on protection of wildlife habitat.
A notable exception is Vermont Act 250, known as
the Land Use and Development Act of 1970, which
regulates impacts to certain wildlife habitats.
American alligators (Alligator mississippiensis)
provide a good example of how strictly regulated
markets can benefit populations. Because of
overharvest of alligators for meat and hides, and
resulting population declines, in 1967 (before
enactment of the Endangered Species Act) alligators
were classified by the U.S. Fish and Wildlife
Service as endangered. However, regulations did
not accompany this classification and overharvest
continued. In 1969, the Lacey Act, which prohibits
interstate transport or export of illegally harvested
species, was amended to include reptiles, and
subsequent enforcement of high profile cases

helped to curtail the illegal trade. Populations


quickly showed signs of recovery. In 1973, when the
Endangered Species Act was enacted, alligators
were listed as endangered. Between 1970 and
1979, certain states implemented controlled or
experimental commercial harvests, and in 1979
the federal government began allowing trade in
alligator meat while also downgrading alligators
on CITES to allow export of their skins. Controlled
harvest, including adults or eggs to supplement
captive-rearing facilities, continues by permit or tag
in the southern U.S. for the use of alligator meat and
hides. As a result of this regulated market, American
alligator populations have rebounded, the species
has since been delisted, and numerous states now
allow harvest.
Current Status, Threats, and Challenges. Clearly
defined laws exist regarding seasons, bag limits,
methods of take, and areas in which seasons
apply. What is not as clearly defined is the applied
enforcement of these laws. Enforcement priorities
often depend on available resources and societal
desires. Does the out-of-season take of a striped
skunk (Mephitis mephitis) merit the same level
of enforcement as a trophy elk? Although state
authority over the take of resident game species is
well defined, county, local, or housing development
ordinances may effectively supersede state authority.
De facto decisions regarding hunting opportunity and
access are routinely made at a level below that of
state government. Further, decisions on land use,
even on public lands, indirectly impact allocation
of wildlife because of land use changes associated
with land development. Competing land uses
which effectively destroy or degrade wildlife habitat
supersede the notion of allocation of wildlife by law.
Examples abound where public lands have been
dominated by one or more uses, thereby reducing
their wildlife value and allocation to the public.
Amphibians and reptiles, especially turtles,
may suffer as taxa whose uses are not broadly
considered as utilitarian (e.g., those traded or
used commercially as pets). In addition, these

species are secretive, often misunderstood, or


feared. Perhaps for these reasons, establishment
of regulations or enforcement thereof tend to be
lower priorities. Lack of specific permits or harvest
monitoring have caused some of the members of
the user community of these taxa to claim that
limits imposed, where they exist, are artificial or not
based in science. Further, lack of law-enforcement
capacity is another challenge. Herpetofauna are
relatively easy to conceal, and several species look
similar, thus routine enforcement checks or a lack
of identification skills may cause illegally harvested
individuals or species to be missed.
Among some members of the commercial pet
industry, hobbyist breeders, and photographers
of herpetofauna, the current perception is that
government is the enemy, harming small businesses
or reducing income through regulatory measures.
However, just as with game and fur markets, careful
and strategic engagement with these stakeholders
regarding allocation can provide mutual benefit,
particularly when regulated take is based in sound
science. Many states use fishing or hunting licenses
and permits for the collection or possession of
herpetofauna, and specific methods to track
herpetofauna, such as a specific license or stamp,
combined with reporting requirements,
may allow improved monitoring of numbers of
animals removed from the wild. Similarly, many
states permit or otherwise regulate wildlife
rehabilitators. Many species are removed from
the wild when perceived to be injured, ill, or
orphaned. Some are returned to the wild and
some are not. Monitoring or tracking can provide
reasonable allocation limits that can be agreeable to
stakeholders and can benefit populations.

4. Wildlife Can Be Killed Only


for a Legitimate Purpose
Historical Development. George Hallock, original
owner and editor of Forest and Stream, wrote that
those who killed merely for the fun of killing,

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

18

along with pot hunters (those who hunted solely


for food), debased sport hunting (Reiger 1975).
According to Grinnell, true sportsmen were those
who hunted for pleasure (never for profit), who in
the field allowed game a sporting chance, and who
possessed an aesthetic appreciation of the whole
context of sport that included a commitment to its
perpetuation (Cutright 1985). Grinnell, in a series of
powerful editorials, was to articulate what Reiger
(1975) referred to as the code of the sportsman. The
single most important element in the code was the
requirement of non-commercial use, without waste,
of all game killed. When this element was combined
with dissatisfaction over dwindling game and habitat,
an important catalyst in the conservation movement
was born.
The concept of a sportsman can be summarized as
one who, when hunting game:

does so primarily for the pursuit or chase;


affords game a sporting chance (fair chase);
seeks knowledge of nature and the habits of

align with the Model? How do longstanding predator


removal or control programs fit within this context?
How precisely evaluated are the concerns over
property protection, and how well justified should
such interventions be? Are hunters who secure only
the cape, antlers, or horns and discard the meat
consistent with our understanding of the Models
history and intent?
Further, do events such as turtle or frog races
or rattlesnake roundups have an impact on
populations? In some instances, animals are
gathered from various parts of a given state, if not
adjacent states, and brought to a race or roundup
location where they are either translocated (by
release, sometimes illegally) to an area nearby, or
killed (either intentionally or accidentally)
(Adams et al. 1994, Fitzgerald and Painter 2000,
Speake and Mount 1973). Particularly in the case
of snakes, directed persecution occurs along
with many in the public sharing the perception
that the only good snake is a dead snake,
thus hampering conservation efforts. A lack of
monitoring prevents our ability to determine
definitive impact on populations.

animals;

derives no financial profit from game killed;


will inflict no unnecessary pain or suffering
on game; and

will not waste any game that is killed.


Current Status, Threats, and Challenges. The
current examples of broad-scale prairie dog
(Cynomys spp.) shooting and crow hunting raise the
question of legitimate purpose. Reconciling this
practice within the principle of legitimate use does
not seem possible, given that no food or protective
benefits are derived. Pheasant stocking programs
that, in effect, create artificial populations may
qualify for evaluation in the context of the Model.
The culling of overabundant species (e.g., deer and
Canada geese [Branta canadensis] in urban settings)
is an accepted management practice, but how does it

19

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

5. Wildlife Is Considered an
International Resource
One of the greatest milestones in the history
of wildlife conservation was the signing of the
Migratory Bird Treaty Convention in 1916. This
was the first significant treaty that provided for
international management of wildlife resources. The
impetus was recognition that some wildlife migrate
across borders, and one nations management, or
lack thereof, has consequences to its neighbors.
Subsequently, international commerce can have
significant effects on the status of a species.
Historical Development. The recognition that
conserving waterfowl populations would require
coordinated and centralized regulations dates back
to the 19th century. Legislation giving the federal

government regulatory control over waterfowl


hunting in the U.S. was introduced initially in
1904, but was not passed until 1914 (Presidential
Proclamation: Regulations for the Protection
of Migratory Birds). The constitutionality of this
law was challenged and a district court ruling in
Arkansas (U.S. v. Harvey C. Shauver) deemed the
law unconstitutional. Supreme Court Justice Elihu
Root suggested the constitutional issue could be
addressed with a treaty between the U.S. and Great
Britain on behalf of Canada. Such a treaty would
invoke the Supremacy Clause of the Constitution,
which gives federal treaties supremacy over any
law of the land. A small group of U.S. and Canadian
conservationists drafted the Migratory Bird Treaty
and worked both sides of the border to get it ratified
in 1916 (Hawkins et al. 1984).
Expansion of international wildlife conservation
efforts beyond migratory birds occurred after WWII
with passage of endangered species legislation in
the 1960s and 1970s. Today, collaboration on a broad
suite of wildlife conservation issues among the North
American nations is common. For example, the
Northeast Association of Fish and Wildlife Agencies
is comprised of 13 northeastern states and 6 eastern
Canadian provinces, and technical committees under
its jurisdiction share management information and
collaborate on policy development for most resident
non-migratory species.
Current Status, Threats, and Challenges. Several
international treaties exist that prescribe cooperative
relationships and management programs between
the U.S. and other countries. However, other
opportunities exist for international treaties to
address species that cross borders into Canada or
Mexico. Exporting components of the Model to
other countries or continents, in particular to
Africa, has been successful in some instances, yet
very difficult and time-consuming to implement.
Complex permitting processes, traditional
economies and cultures, and travel and firearm
restrictions stand as barriers to sharing the
successful Model and American system of
conservation funding with other nations.

Many collaborative actions are occurring for


management and conservation of wildlife bilaterally
or trilaterally in North America. The overall results
are clearly positive, with plenty of examples with
migratory birds, waterfowl, and more specific
management efforts for the benefit of bighorn sheep
(Ovis canadensis), pronghorn (Antilocapra americana),
and more recently the translocation of bison into
Coahuila from South Dakota. One important challenge
is the construction of the wall between the U.S.
and Mexico, which is likely to have severe negative
implications for wildlife (Flesch et al. 2010, List 2007,
Lpez-Hoffman et al. 2009).

6. Science Is the Proper Tool


to Discharge Wildlife Policy
In his classic work titled Game Management, Leopold
(1933:17-18) stated the following:

The Roosevelt Doctrine of conservation


determined the subsequent history of American
game management in 3 basic respects.
1. It recognized all these outdoor resources
as one integral whole.
2. It recognized their conservation through
wise use as a public responsibility, and their
private ownership as a public trust.
3. It recognized science as a tool for
discharging that responsibility.
Science as a base for informed decision making
in wildlife management has become standard in
Canada and the U.S. Nevertheless, funding has been
largely inadequate to meet the research needs of
management agencies, and a trend toward greater
political influence in decision making threatens this
principle (Wildlife Management Institute 1987, 1997).
As Leopold wrote (Meine 1988:359-360):

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

20

One of the anomalies of modern ecology


is the creation of two groups, each of which
seems barely aware of the existence of the
other. The one studies the human community,
almost as if it were a separate entity, and
calls its findings sociology, economics and
history. The other studies the plant and
animal community and comfortably relegates
the hodge-podge of politics to the liberal arts.
The inevitable fusion of these two lines
of thought will, perhaps, constitute the
outstanding advance of this century.
The development of human dimensions of wildlife
as a discipline has moved us closer to realizing
Leopolds ideal. The integration of biological
and social sciences is necessary to meet the
conservation challenges of the 21st century.
Historical Development. The history of scientific
management of wildlife began when there was
little concern for any form of wildlife conservation
until fauna (especially large mammals) were on
the brink of extinction. The story is known by most
wildlife professionals but not as well by the layman.
By the late 1800s, North Americans were seeing
wildlife disappear before their eyes, much like we
see wildlife habitat disappear today. Thus began
the wildlife management experiment in North
America. At this point in history, market hunting
(i.e., unregulated hunting) was rampant and there
was little incentive for management of what was
perceived as an unlimited resource. Without a
drastic change in attitudes and recognition that
wildlife was not unlimited, the great American
experiment likely would have been over before
it began. Conservation grew from this point, and
leaders such as Theodore Roosevelt, Gifford
Pinchot, and William T. Hornaday in the U.S. and
Sir Wilfrid Laurier, Clifford Sifton, and C. Gordon
Hewitt in Canada worked together to ensure that
their nations had similar policies to protect wildlife
in those early days of conservation (Geist 1993).

21

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

Their efforts were instrumental in allowing others to


begin to take a conservation approach where wildlife
was concerned, and when Theodore Roosevelt was
president he demanded that science be part of the
conservation process (Lewis 1919).
Before 1900, wildlife interests centered on hunting,
control of wildlife problems (e.g., predators),
stocking, and some conservation of game with very
little interest in science or research. Wildlife was
considered a source of subsistence and profit only,
so action was needed for the proper conservation
and management of wildlife species and the habitats
they depended on. In the 1930 American Game
Policy, Leopold called for restoration of wildlife
and a corps of trained wildlife biologists that made
decisions based on facts, professional experience,
and an underlying set of principles for the emerging
profession. This was the true beginning of science
being actively used in management of North
Americas wildlife resources. Development of
wildlife management and all related policies must
be based on knowledge, and knowledge is advanced
by experience and fact finding (i.e., research and
science). Science based on research was required to
convert the professions newly minted principles
into policies. Today, limitations on use of wildlife
are based on science including surveys, population
dynamics, behavior and habitat studies, statistics,
and contemporary adaptive management and
structured decision making.
The scientific mandate has been followed since,
reinforced by the writings of Aldo Leopold and
embedded within The Wildlife Societys code of
ethics in that TWS members recognize research
and scientific management of wildlife and its
environments as primary goals

When Leopold emphasized the importance of
maintaining habitat for wildlife, the idea was
relatively new. In pursuing this notion, the new
wildlife management discipline applied the scientific
method that is the backbone of the acquisition
of knowledge. However, it became evident that

simply using the scientific method was not going


to be enough. Wildlife belonged to the public, and
unless the public understood how wildlife was being
managed they would be reluctant to support such
management. Simply understanding life history
characteristics of wildlife and wildlife habitat was
inadequate; people influence the system, and human
dimensions had to be an integral part of wildlife
management within the profession. Brown and
Decker (2001) summarized the evolution of human
dimensions into the science of wildlife management
through 12 steps:
1. State agencies have been collecting information
on wildlife from hunters at check stations since the
1930s, a practice called surrogate biology as it
used people to obtain information about harvests
and traits of harvested animals.
2. Most of the earlier human-dimensions studies
concentrated on conflicts between farmers and
hunters.
3. In 1955, the U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service
began the national survey of hunting and fishing,
which is conducted every 5 years. The survey
provides data on hunting and fishing trends and
has been expanded to provide estimates on nonconsumptive activities. Since 1980, the survey
has provided state-level estimates and national
estimates of wildlife recreation.
4. Although Leopold emphasized the importance
of human dimensions in wildlife in the 1930s, it was
not until 4 to 5 decades later that the social and
economic aspects of wildlife were beginning to be
seriously addressed.
5. This interest expanded into wildlife management
agencies and university research programs. The
Missouri Department of Conservation employed
human-dimensions specialists, which stimulated
other state agencies to follow.
6. The movement expanded, and the Human
Dimensions in Wildlife Study Group was formed in

the 1980s. Additional activity continued to occur in


agencies and universities.
7. In the 1990s, as public pressure increased for
more public involvement in wildlife management
decisions, agencies increased their incorporation
of human dimensions into wildlife management,
and universities included classes in the arena for
wildlife students.
8. Communication related to human dimensions
was greatly enhanced in the 1990s and the journal
Human Dimensions in Wildlife was created.
9. Interest in this new field blossomed in the
1990s: state and federal agency and university
partnerships for human-dimensions research
were established and universities hired humandimensions specialists.
10. Since the 1970s the field of human dimensions
has increased the understanding of human
perception of wildlife and human interactions with
wildlife. Specialists in the field have developed
conceptual approaches that assist managers in
understanding attitudes and behavior of different
stakeholders toward wildlife management issues.
11. The entire field of human dimensions continues
to grow and gain involvement in restoration projects,
human-wildlife interactions, communication
between stakeholders and agencies, and in policy
and decision making.
12. Wildlife management agencies rely heavily on
human-dimensions experts, and the field plays an
important role in success of agency policies and
practices.
Human dimensions has truly taken its spot as the
third leg of the wildlife management triad: wildlife,
habitat, and people (Giles 1978). As society struggles
with increasing human population and diminishing
wildlife habitat, new and different challenges have
arisen and will continue to arise, and science

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

22

(biological, ecological, and social) will continue to


contribute to the basis of effective management so
informed solutions can be obtained. Those decisions
will be much easier when science and human
dimensions are included in the mix.
Current Status, Threats, and Challenges. Although
the U.S. and Canada have led the way in advancing
the wildlife profession, wildlife management itself
appears to be increasingly politicized. A rapid
turnover rate of state agency directors, the makeup
of boards and commissions, the organizational
structure of some agencies, and examples of politics
meddling in science have challenged the science
foundation. Examples of the lack of rigor in surveys
and analyses, advocacy, and misuse of science
have prompted The Wildlife Society to publish a
position statement of the use of science in wildlife
management (2010). The multitude of environmental
and conservation organizations include some
organizations that appear to be more focused on
developing membership than on proper use of
science to advance wildlife policy.

7. Democracy of Hunting
Is Standard
Theodore Roosevelt believed that access for all to
have the opportunity to hunt would result in many
societal benefits (Roosevelt et al. 1902:18-20).
Leopold termed this democracy of sport (Meine
1988:169), and it sets Canada and the U.S. apart
from many other nations where the opportunity to
hunt is restricted to those who have special status,
such as land ownership, wealth, or other privileges.
The greatest historical standing of the public trust is
that certain interests are so intrinsically important to
people that their free availability marks the society
as one of citizens rather than serfs (Sax 1970). The
opportunity for citizens in good standing to hunt in
Canada and the U.S. is a hallmark of our democracy.
Current Status, Threats, and Challenges. Roosevelt
and Leopold envisioned a nation where all citizens

23

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

had an opportunity to engage in conservation and


hunting (Roosevelt et al. 1902, Meine 1988). Animalrights organizations work tirelessly to shift the
political debate to exclude hunters and hunting
at national, state, and local levels (Francione
1996). Without the political, social, and financial
support of hunters and anglers, agencies will be
severely challenged to be able to deliver effective
conservation programs for all wildlife into the future.
Ballot initiatives that often do not include adequate
opportunities for public information and debate
are offered each election cycle. Our profession has
taken a dim view of this form of policy development
(Williamson 1998). Are these ballot initiatives
undemocratic (Sabato et al. 2001) or do they lack the
deliberative process necessary for sound, long-term
conservation policy?
Finally, access to firearms and gun control
restrictions directly impact the publics ability
to hunt. This was recognized in the early 1900s,
when new immigrants in eastern industrial states
heavily hunted songbirds. Some states, including
Massachusetts and Pennsylvania, passed laws
forbidding immigrants from owning firearms
or hunting (Trefethen 1975). If such laws were
commonplace across the U.S., development of the
Model and the funding mechanism for conservation
itself might have been altered. These laws were
later repealed, but their direct purpose was related
to availability of firearms for inhabitants of a state.
More recently, federal gun control regulations in
Canada have posed challenges for hunters there and
led to widely expressed concerns, coming at a time
where other impediments to hunting are increasing
in that country.
Clearly most North Americans do not hunt in the
traditional sense of the word. We believe that our
current pluralistic democracy is necessary for the
Models survival. Without secure gun rights, the
average persons ability to hunt would likely be
compromised, along with indispensable sources of
funding for implementation of the Model.

Sustaining and Building


upon the Model
Our profession embarked into the 21st century
using a conservation model that matured during
the 19th and 20th centuries. The Model faces
challenges described above and perhaps many
more. We believe that a robust discussion must take
place among wildlife management policy makers
and practitioners.

As these discussions continue, we offer a few
recommendations. First, wildlife professionals
must engage in a campaign to inform and educate
leading academic and political entities in Canada,
the U.S., and Mexico about a history that has enabled
abundant and diverse wildlife on this continent.
Aspiring wildlife professionals at universities
across the continent must be made to understand
and appreciate the ramifications associated with
the Models principles and how these principles
currently drive the policy and practice of wildlife
management. The Conservation Leaders for
Tomorrow program (McCabe 2010) is one such
mechanism for informing students and professionals
alike about the Models origins and applications. The
public needs to be made aware that fish and wildlife
conservation is not an accidental process, but the
exercising of a method with established protocols
and proven results.

Second, application of the Model must include
all fish and wildlife species and their habitats.
Conservation has been approached largely by
separating wildlife into sport fish, wildlife that is
hunted or trapped, and nongame species. The Model
should be examined in a comprehensive context of
all taxa being part of fish and wildlife management.
Greater dialogue is needed among all stakeholders.

Third, as scientists, resource managers, and agents


of the trustees of wildlife, wildlife professionals
rarely engage in advocacy, and are not particularly
adept when doing so. A few key issues warrant
advocacy. Legislation should be developed, where
necessary, to improve definitions of public trust
responsibilities, authorities, and jurisdictions over
free-ranging and captive wildlife and their habitats,
clarifying any confusion, strategic or otherwise,
between such animals and domestic livestock.
Similar legislation should be developed to articulate
state and provincial authority to set seasons,
bag limits, and locales in coordination with local
authorities. Firearms and ammunition should not be
regulated in a manner that discourages individuals
from hunting or diminishes the financial support
that commerce in sporting firearms and ammunition
provides to conservation programs. The financial
support and use of science in policy decision making
should be advocated. Insistence from wildlife
professionals that policies emerge from scientific
investigation and debate not from a need or desire
to enhance membership and dollars is warranted.

Finally, a mechanism must be found to encourage
the non-hunting public to contribute financially
to conserve the fish and wildlife resources they
enjoy and have an equal responsibility to protect.
Adequate permanent funding to conserve all fish
and wildlife species must be attained, recognizing
the responsibility our profession has for biodiversity
in the most inclusive sense. Because hunters and
anglers remain the primary source of conservation
funding at the state level, recruitment and retention
programs have been implemented by many agencies
and organizations. These efforts should have clearly

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

24

defined objectives and be monitored and evaluated to


assess whether these objectives are being met and
are contributing to broader conservation outcomes.
Other types of wildlife uses and users should be
engaged and cultivated.

Funding
Application of the Model to all wildlife for the benefit
of all people will require broad-based, substantial
funding. Primary funding from hunters, anglers,
and trappers at the state level is inadequate to
meet current and anticipated wildlife conservation
challenges. Jacobson et al. (2010) outlined a vision
for broad societal funding in the U.S. independent of
special interests or user groups. User-based funding
would still be applied to those programs generating
the revenues, while broader-based funds would be
used to ensure application of conservation equitably.
Canada should consider dedicated user-based
funding to enhance its conservation programs at the
provincial level, while maintaining and increasing
general revenue funding.

Wildlife Markets
Elimination of legal markets for game was
unquestionably a turning point in North American
conservation. Leopold (1919) and Geist (1988, 1993)
made compelling arguments against opening
markets for wildlife. Many exceptions do exist,
and when a conservation purpose underlies the
exception (e.g., harvest and marketing of furbearer
pelts), it is consistent with the Model. Organ et
al. (2010) raised the notion that under limited
exceptional circumstances, a highly regulated
market for meat and potentially other products
from overabundant wildlife could yield conservation
benefits. Conceptually, where overabundant game
species such as white-tailed deer and Canada geese
result in human-wildlife conflicts, and where the
opportunities afforded sport hunters have proven
inadequate to meet population goals, a cadre of
specially certified licensed sport hunters would

25

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

be provided access as a means of implementing


population control and mitigating conflicts. In
return, they could take the meat to a regulated
processing facility and get paid. The meat would
enter the local market. Benefits of this approach
beyond mitigation of conflicts could be a fostering
of appreciation of the food value of a species or
populations of wildlife perceived as liabilities. Risks
in such an approach include the potential for illegally
harvested game to enter legal markets. Vercauteren
et al. (2011) have taken a different approach and
proposed establishment of a commercial deer
harvesters license to provide incentive to control
overabundant deer.

Any consideration of establishing regulated
markets for game must include the strengthening
of legal institutions to ensure that the unlawful
taking of wildlife is strongly enforced through law
enforcement and judicial systems. For example,
fines associated with the unlawful taking of wildlife
should be commensurate with the seriousness of
the offense. In many cases, fines are not adequate to
deter violations of law.
The principle that markets for wildlife are eliminated
should remain intact, but exceptions do and will
occur. These should remain exceptions, and be
warranted only where there is a conservation benefit
that cannot otherwise be achieved.
Consideration also needs to be given to restricting
or eliminating markets for certain taxa, such as
reptiles. As unregulated markets for North American
game species led to imperilment, other taxa face the
same vulnerabilities.

Firearms Rights and


Privileges
The ability of private citizens in the U.S. and Canada
to own firearms has in no small way shaped the
course of conservation and application of the
Model. In the United States, the 2nd Amendment

of the U.S. Constitution clearly establishes the


lawful basis for firearms ownership and use,
including hunting. Suppression of firearms
ownership would functionally eliminate hunting as
a management concern and as a management tool,
and hunters as the primary advocates and funding
source for conservation. Reiger (1975) outlined
the preeminent role hunters had in shaping the
conservation movement. Restrictive firearms laws
at the federal level in Canada and in some states
(e.g., Massachusetts) may inhibit recruitment and
retention of hunters. Legal access to sporting
firearms for all citizens in good standing is essential
to maintaining a core base of wildlife conservation
advocates and a critical funding source.

Habitat Considerations
The U.S. and Canada have an impressive network
of public lands, including a significant component
managed primarily for wildlife (e.g., national wildlife
refuges, state wildlife management areas). Private
lands with permanent protection from development
also contribute significantly to supporting wildlife
populations. The American Game Policy of 1930
(Leopold 1930) and the Pittman-Robertson Wildlife
Restoration Act of 1937 both emphasized the need
for habitat restoration. This network of protected
habitats was critical to restoration of game and
conservation of other species.
In articulating the 7 principles of the Model, Geist
et al. (2001) did not provide explicit treatment of
the importance of habitat conservation to wildlife
management in North America nor its foundational
influence in conservation history. Organ and
Mahoney (2007) reflected on the legal standing of
habitat values in terms of the Public Trust Doctrine,
and Regan and Prukop (2008) offered examples of
the stateside application of the Public Trust Doctrine
to contemporary habitat conservation issues. Habitat
conservation (i.e., protection, restoration, and
management) is a necessary pillar of any successful
management paradigm and merits consideration
as a precept in future treatments of the Model.

Consensus is lacking within the wildlife conservation


and management profession as to whether the
concept of habitat conservation and the role of the
private landowner rise to the level of a principle, or
are considered purely means to achieve the Models
principles. Indeed, consensus is lacking on how
to define habitat in other than the most general of
terms. Habitat is a relative concept and varies among
species. Most programs of habitat conservation are
in fact land protection efforts that provide habitat
by default. Simple land protection does not equal
habitat conservation in a strict sense, but that
recognition in no way devalues or demeans those
programs and the lands they protect.
Historical Development. It is self-evident that, for
sustainability, wildlife populations require adequate
habitat (i.e., food, water, shelter, and security).
In Man and Nature, Marsh (1864) recounted the
impacts to natural landscapes and waterways from
the advance of civilization. Subsequently, 19thcentury conservationists were eager to reserve
large landscapes for wildlife (e.g., Adirondack Park,
Yellowstone National Park). President Theodore
Roosevelt, with the support of Grinnell, Pinchot, and
others, made bison, migratory bird, and big game
habitat protection hallmarks of his conservation
advocacy (Brinkley 2009). The Boone and Crockett
Club (Roosevelt and Grinnell 1893) advocated for a
network of public protected game reserves. In other
words, habitat protection became synonymous with
wildlife stewardship for future generations.
Aldo Leopold (1933) squarely placed the conservation
of habitat into an applied management framework
similar to that used for forestry and agriculture.
He offered prescriptions or guidance for making
parcels of land more productive for wildlife through
active manipulation of vegetation structure. The Dust
Bowl, extensive loss of prairies and wetlands, and
overharvest of northeastern and Great Lakes forests
would validate the need for active management of
habitat. The American Game Policy (Leopold 1930)
advocated for subsidizing private landowners for
conservation initiated on their lands for the benefit

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

26

of wildlife and hunters. Habitat conservation became


a mainstream concept in America, following on the
heels of Leopold, when, in 1933, President Franklin
Roosevelt initiated the Civilian Conservation Corps,
whose outputs all supported improvement and
perpetuation of our land and water resources.
With advent of science-based habitat metrics
and funding from excise taxes and license fees,
government agencies were poised to explore
wildlife-habitat relationships, to develop populationhabitat models, to pioneer best habitat management
practices, and to transfer such information to
landowners and land managers. Over time, more
attention would focus on human disturbance,
fragmentation, development, and other influences
on habitat quality and use.
Although the initial focus may have been on
independent-parcel management planning, wildlife
science embraced emerging ecological principles
concerning habitat connectivity, gene flow, and
regional or ecoregional planning constructs to
meet wildlife needs. The North American Waterfowl
Management Plan, signed by the U.S. and Canada in
1986 and by Mexico in 1994, provided a continentalscale approach to habitat conservation and regional
delivery of conservation projects via joint ventures.
Fisheries managers have embraced a similar
approach for aquatic systems.
Current Status, Trends and Challenges. Habitat is
key to wildlife population viability, genetic integrity of
species, and a sustainable abundance of animals for
hunting, trapping, and wildlife-dependent recreation.
The future holds manifold challenges on the habitat
front, including fragmentation, suburban sprawl,
energy development, transportation infrastructure,
and climate change. State Wildlife Action Plans are
replete with strategies to address habitat threats,
and the Northeast Association of Fish and Wildlife
Agencies has pooled resources to examine habitat
conditions on a regional scale based on State Wildlife
Action Plan information.

27

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

Ownership of the landscape (forests in particular)


and, by extension, ownership of wildlife habitat,
varies across the continent. In the U.S., fully twothirds of westernmost forests and three-quarters
of those in the Rocky Mountain states are owned
publicly, primarily by the U.S. Forest Service and
the Bureau of Land Management (Law 2007). Both
agencies have conservation and perpetuation of
lands for wildlife habitat as central tenets in their
enabling legislation (USFS; P.L. 86-517, BLM; P.L.
94-579 ss103(c)). Private forest lands, however,
have no such direction or guarantee. It is of little
surprise then that landscape-level planning to
protect renewable resources and wildlife habitat,
particularly throughout the western U.S., are
underway by both the U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service
(through its Landscape Conservation Cooperatives)
and the Bureau of Land Management (via Rapid
Ecosystem Assessments). Thus the primary
governmental land management agencies in the U.S.
have recognized and acted upon the value of habitat
conservation as a primary function of their public
trust responsibilities.
Approximately 60 percent of U.S. land area is
privately owned, compared to 11 percent of
Canadas land area. Successful stewardship of
public wildlife resources is fostered via private and
public partnerships. State fish and wildlife agencies
often provide management assistance to forest
and farm landowners, especially for critical habitat
designations. Conservation titles of the Farm Bill
(P.L. 110-246, Food, Conservation, and Energy Act of
2008) provide due financial and technical assistance
to both landowner communities. Non-governmental
organizations, governmental and private landowner
partnerships have successfully conserved habitats
and provided public access through easements.
As noted above, Organ and Mahoney (2007) have
raised concerns about the ability of habitat features
to withstand legal challenges to the Public Trust
Doctrine, suggesting that government agencies need
to advance protection through case law, legislation,
and practice.

Instructor Bob Byrne, left, gives an enthusiastic thumbs up for two CLfT participants who each bagged a pheasant during a mentored
hunt at the Max McGraw Wildlife Foundation in Illinois. Held in January 2010, this was the first CLfT workshop offered exclusively to
non-hunters from state and federal natural resource management agencies. Courtesy of CLfT.

Taxa Inclusivity
The Model is intended to apply to all wildlife taxa,
except for those principles specific to game species.
Yet application of the Model historically has been much
narrower due primarily to restricted funding sources
and the primary stakeholder and advocacy base.
Application of the Model in recent decades has
broadened as management agencies have expanded
programs and new funding sources have emerged.
Broader-based funding will ensure greater and more
equitable application of the Model to all taxa.

Governance
The Model is implemented continentally by a
multitude of federal, state, and provincial agencies
that have some common governance attributes, but
also vary considerably. Jacobson and Decker (2008)
articulated how many current governance models do

not reflect contemporary societal needs. Jacobson


et al. (2010) offered a vision for a unifying theme of
governance, whereby trustees representing broad
societal interests would comprise the decisionmaking body. Agencies at the federal, state, and
provincial level function as agents of the trustees
providing the best available biological and social
science to the decision makers. Broad, stable, and
equitable funding would enable greater focus on
biodiversity conservation and landscape approaches.
Traditional uses and users would remain an
important funding source.

Governance models that are not in concert with
contemporary societal needs or address only
limited special interests risk having the wildlife
management enterprise lose relevance to society.
Too much is at stake in terms of biodiversity and
human health to warrant this risk. The institution
of wildlife management needs to take bold steps to
ensure that governance fosters relevance.

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

28

The Future of the Model

Application of the Models principles to landscape conservation


will enhance its future relevance. Credit: John F. Organ.

The Models future rests to a high degree on the


adaptability and application of its principles to
contemporary wildlife conservation needs. To remain
viable in the future, it must remain relevant. To that
extent, the Model must be viewed as a dynamic set of
principles that can grow and evolve. The underlying
principles established to address particular
concerns, some no longer an issue can serve as
bedrock and be applied more broadly, or modified
to facilitate expansion to emerging societal needs.
Dialogue and collaboration among administrators
and key stakeholders within the North American
wildlife management institution should be
encouraged and be constructive. In particular,
the Association of Fish and Wildlife Agencies, The
Wildlife Society, and the Wildlife Management
Institute, among others, should collectively foster
discussions about contemporary issues potentially
affecting interpretation or application of the Model.

Key to ensuring relevancy of the Model will be its
application to conservation of landscapes. The
Models principles were developed in large part

29

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

during an era when the direct taking of wildlife


was the preeminent concern in conservation.
Increasingly, the maintenance and fostering of
landscapes that can sustain viable populations of
all wildlife to ensure conservation of biodiversity
and human use and enjoyment are of paramount
concern. The Models context must be viewed in
the broad sense of its application to this and other
emerging needs, rather than in a historic context.
This may require evolution and expansion of
principles while ensuring that the original principles
are not abandoned.

Additionally, the wildlife management institution
must not rest purely on successes of the past.
DeStefano et al. (2005) discussed demographic shifts
in U.S. society, where increasing proportions of the
public live in urban vs. rural areas. This shift towards
urban demography can have significant wildlife
policy implications, as can shifts from traditional
based values towards wildlife to broader multicultural ones. Ballot initiatives within the last 30
years that have successfully restricted or eliminated
traditional wildlife uses have been in states where
greater than 70 percent of the public live in urban
areas (S. DeStefano and J. Organ, unpublished data,
presented at the 2010 Annual Conference of The
Wildlife Society). Decker et al. (1996, 2000) outlined
the implications of shifts in human dimensions to
the wildlife management enterprise and offered
approaches for governing effectively in a changing
social dynamic. This was addressed further by
Jacobson et al. (2010). In short, the Model was
formed during a time when wildlife management
was implemented under an expert authority
approach (Gill 1996). The Models future will rest
on its effectiveness within an institution fostering
greater participatory decision making. Riley et al.
(2002) offered a vision for how this may be facilitated.

Summary and
Recommendations
1. Manage all wildlife under the principles of the
Model. The Model is not exclusive to game species.
Game species have received greater management
attention because of public interest and desires,
funding mechanisms, and the management intensity
necessary for species that are harvested. Status of
game species in North America is generally quite
robust. Biodiversity conservation in North America
will be enhanced if the Models principles are
applied to all wildlife. Transformative processes will
be necessary to enable the wildlife management
institution to implement application of the Model to
all species as needed (Jacobson et al. 2010).
2. Initiate and expand efforts to inform North
Americans about the Model and the importance of
citizen engagement in sustaining the future
of biodiversity. Current efforts, such as those
initiated by Arizona Game and Fish Department
(www.azgfd.gov/h_f/documents/NAM%20Brochure.
pdf, accessed on 4 May 2011), need to be
broadened and expanded continentally. Significant
misconceptions exist regarding the Model. It is often
considered synonymous with the user-pay, userbenefit funding model, which is purely a mechanism
for funding the implementation of the Models
principles. Such misconceptions lead to the notion
that the Model is narrow in scope and exclusive of all
but game species.

strategies for consistent continental conservation


delivery. As part of this process, discussion should
address the following:
a. Should limited markets for meat harvested by
licensed sport hunters be established to address
management of overabundant wildlife? Would this
increase public appreciation for wildlife values and
foster the image of hunting as a management tool
with a civic purpose?
b. Will our programs of private and public habitat
conservation meet the needs of the future and lead
to conservation outcomes consistent with those
achieved historically through application of the
Model? With expanding human populations and
increased demand for resources, habitat protection
and landscape-level conservation will increase as
factors limiting biodiversity conservation.
4. Governance models that are not in concert
with contemporary societal needs or address
only limited special interests risk having the
wildlife management lose relevance to society.
The Models future will rest on its effectiveness
within an institutional framework fostering
greater participatory decision making. The wildlife
management institution needs to take bold steps to
ensure that governance fosters relevance.

3. Convene key administrators and stakeholders


in wildlife conservation and management in the
U.S., Canada, and Mexico every 10 years to revisit
the key challenges facing wildlife conservation in
North America, assess the Models principles and
their application and adequacy, and develop joint

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

30

Literature Cited
Adams, C.E., J.K. Thomas, K.J. Strnadel, and S.J. Lester. 1994.
Texas rattlesnake roundups: implications of unregulated
commercial use of wildlife. Wildlife Society Bulletin 22:324-330.
Adams, D.A. 1993. Renewable resource policy. Island Press,
Washington, D.C., USA.
Batcheller, G.R. M.C. Bambery, L. Bies, T. Decker, S. Dyke,
D. Guynn, M. McEnroe, M. OBrien, J.F. Organ, S.J. Riley, and
G. Roehm. 2010. The Public Trust Doctrine: implications for
wildlife management and conservation in the United States
and Canada. Technical Review 10-1. The Wildlife Society,
Bethesda, Maryland, USA.
Bean, M.J. 1983. The evolution of national wildlife law.
Praeger Publishers, New York, New York, USA.
Beuchler, M., and G. Servheen. 2008. The North American
Model of Wildlife Conservation: affirming the role, strength,
and relevance of hunting in the 21st century. Transactions
of the North American Wildlife and Natural Resources
Conference 73:163-179.
Boggess, E.K., G.R. Batcheller, R.G. Linscombe, J.W. Greer, M.
Novak, S.B. Linhart, D.W. Erickson, A.W. Todd, D.C. Juve, and
D.A. Wade. 1990. Traps, trapping, and furbearer management:
a review. Technical Review 90-1. The Wildlife Society,
Bethesda, Maryland, USA.
Brands, H.W. 1997. TR: The last romantic. Basic Books, New
York, New York, USA.
Brown, T.L., and D.J. Decker. 2001. Evolution of human
dimensions interest. Pages 23-38 in D.J. Decker, T.L.
Brown, and W.F. Siemer, editors. Human dimensions of
wildlife management in North America. The Wildlife Society,
Bethesda, Maryland, USA.
Brinkley, D. 2009. The wilderness warrior Theodore
Roosevelt and the crusade for America. Harper Collins, New
York, New York, USA.
Cowan, I. McT. 1995. Man, wildlife and conservation in North
America. Status and change. Pages 277-308 in V. Geist and
I. McT. Cowan, editors. Wildlife conservation policy. Detselig
Enterprises, Limited, Calgary, Alberta, Canada.

31

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

Cronon, W. 1995. The trouble with wilderness; or, getting


back to the wrong nature. Pages 69-90 in W. Cronon,
editor. Uncommon ground: rethinking the human place in
nature. W. Norton & Co., New York, New York, USA.
Cutright, P.R. 1985. Theodore Roosevelt, the making of
a conservationist. University of Illinois Press, Urbana,
Illinois, USA.
Decker, D.J., C.C. Krueger, R.A. Baer, Jr., B.A. Knuth, and M.E.
Richmond. 1996. From clients to stakeholders: a philosophical
shift for fish and wildlife management. Human Dimensions of
Wildlife 1:70-82.
Decker, D.J., T.M. Schusler, T.L. Brown, and G.F. Mattfeld.
2000. Co-management: An evolving process for the future of
wildlife management. Transactions of the North American
Wildlife and Natural Resources Conference 65:262-277.
DeStefano, S., R.D. Deblinger, and C. Miller. 2005. Urban
wildlife: lessons, challenges, and opportunities. Urban
Ecosystems 8:131-137.
Duda, M., S. Bissell, and K. Young. 1998. Wildlife and the
American mind: public opinion on and attitudes toward fish
and wildlife management. Responsive Management National
Office, Harrisburg, Virginia, USA. .
Dunkley, L., and M.R.L. Cattet. 2003. A comprehensive review
of the ecological and human social effects of artificial feeding
and baiting of wildlife. Canadian Cooperative Wildlife Health
Center. (digitalcommons.unl.edu/icwdmccwhcnews/21,
accessed on 4 May 2011.)
Dunlap, T.R. 1988. Saving Americas wildlife. Princeton
University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, USA.
Ermer, J., W. Jensen, M. Johnson, S. Dyke, D. Halstead,
and T. Phalen. 2005. A review of wildlife baiting and feeding
practices pertaining to North Dakota with special emphasis on
big game. North Dakota Game and Fish Department Report.
Bismarck, USA.
Fitzgerald, L.A., and C.W. Painter. 2000. Rattlesnake
commercialization: long-term trends, issues, and implications
for conservation. Wildlife Society Bulletin 28:235-253.

Flesch, A.D., C.W. Epps, W. Clinton, J.W. Cain , M. Clark , P.R.


Krausman, and J. R. Morgart. 2010. Potential effects of the
United States-Mexico border fence on wildlife. Conservation
Biology 24:171-181.
Francione, G.L. 1996. Rain without thunder: the ideology of
the animal rights movement. Temple University, Philadelphia,
Pennsylvania, USA.
Freese, H.C., and D.L. Trauger. 2000. Wildlife markets and
biodiversity conservation in North America. Wildlife Society
Bulletin 28:42-51.
Geist, V. 1988. How markets in wildlife meat and parts, and
the sale of hunting privileges, jeopardize wildlife conservation.
Conservation Biology 2:15-26.
Geist, V. 1993. Great achievements, great expectations:
successes of North American wildlife management. Pages 4772 in A. W. L. Hawley, editor. Commercialization and wildlife
management: dancing with the devil. Krieger Publishing,
Malabar, Florida, USA.
Geist, V. 1995. North American policies of wildlife
conservation. Pages 75-129 in V. Geist, V. and I. McT. Cowan,
editors. Wildlife conservation policy. Detselig Enterprises,
Limited, Calgary, Alberta, Canada.

Herbert, H.W. 1849. Frank Foresters field sports of the United


States and British provinces of North America. Stringer and
Townsend, New York, New York, USA.
Hewitt, C.G. 1921. The conservation of the wild life of Canada.
Charles Scribners Sons, New York, New York, USA.
Horner, S.M. 2000. Embryo, not fossil: breathing life into the
public trust in wildlife. University of Wyoming College of Law,
Land and Water Law Review 35:1-66.
International Union for the Conservation of Nature Red List
summary statistics: number of species in each Red List
category in each major animal taxonomic group (www.redlist.
org/documents/2008RL_stats_table_4a.pdf). Accessed on 8
April 2009.
Jacobson, C.A., and D.J. Decker. 2008. Governance of state
wildlife management: reform and revive or resist and
retrench? Society and Natural Resources 21:441-448.
Jacobson, C.A., D.J. Decker, and J.F. Organ. 2010a. Fish and
wildlife conservation and management in the 21st century:
understanding challenges for institutional transformation.
Transactions of the North American Wildlife and Natural
Resources Conference. 75:107-114.

Geist, V. 2000. The clubs legacy: a continental system of


wildlife conservation. Fair Chase 15:15-17.

Jacobson, C.A., J.F. Organ, D.J. Decker, G.R. Batcheller, and


L. Carpenter. 2010b. A conservation institution for the 21st
century: implications for state wildlife agencies. The Journal
of Wildlife Management 74:203-209.

Geist, V., S.P. Mahoney, and J.F. Organ. 2001. Why hunting has
defined the North American model of wildlife conservation.
Transactions of the North American Wildlife and Natural
Resources Conference 66: 175-185.

Law, M. 2007. ESRI map book. Volume 22. ESRI Press,


Redlands, California, USA.

Geist, V., and J. F. Organ. 2004. The public trust foundation of


the North American model of wildlife conservation. Northeast
Wildlife 58: 4956.

Leopold. A. 1919. Wild lifers vs. game farmers: a plea for


democracy in sport. Bulletin of the American Game Protective
Association 8:6-7.

Giles, R.H. 1978. Wildlife management. W.H. Freeman Co.,


San Francisco, California, USA.

Leopold, A. 1930. Report to the American game conference on


an American game policy. Transactions of the American Game
Conference 17: 281-283.

Gill, R.B. 1996. The wildlife professional subculture: the case


of the crazy aunt. Human Dimensions of Wildlife 1:60-69.

Leopold, A. 1933. Game management. Scribners, New York,


New York, USA.

Grinnell, G.B. 1885. New publications: hunting trips of a


ranchman. Forest and Stream 24: 450-451.

Lewis, W.D. 1919. The life of Theodore Roosevelt. The John C.


Winston Company, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, USA.

Grinnell, G.B. 1894. A plank. Forest and Stream 41:1.

List, R. 2007. The impacts of the border fence on wild mammals.


Pages 77 86 in A. Cordova and C.A. de la Parra, editors. A
barrier to our shared environment: the border wall between
Mexico and the United States. . SEMARNAT, Instituto Nacional de
Ecologa, El Colegio de la Frontera Norte. Mxico, D. F.

Hawkins, A.S., R.C. Hanson, H.K. Nelson, and H.M. Reeves,


editors. 1984. Flyways. U.S. Department of the Interior, Fish
and Wildlife Service, Washington, D.C., USA.

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

32

Lpez-Hoffman, L., L. E. McGovern, R.G. Varady, and K.W.


Flessa, editors. 2009. Conservation of shared environments:
learning from the United States and Mexico. University of
Arizona Press, Tucson, USA.

Niraj, S.K., P.R. Krausman, and V. Dayal. 2012. Temporal and


spatial analysis of wildlife seizures in India from 1992 to 2006.
International Journal of Ecological Economics and Statistics
24:79-109.

Louv, R. 2008. Last child in the woods: saving our children


from nature-deficit disorder. Algonquin Books, Chapel Hill,
North Carolina, USA.

Organ, J.F., and G.R. Batcheller. 2009. Reviving the public trust
doctrine as a foundation for wildlife management in North
America. Pages 161-171 in M.J. Manfredo, editor. Wildlife
and societythe science of human dimensions. Island Press,
Washington, D.C., USA.

Mahoney, S.P. 2004. The seven sisters: pillars of the North


American wildlife conservation model. Bugle 21:5.
Mahoney, S. P. 2007. Recreational hunting and sustainable
wildlife use in North America: a review with commentary
on the South African approach. Pages 266-281 in B. Dixon,
J. Hutton, and W.M. Adams, editors. Recreational hunting,
conservation and rural livelihoods, Blackwell Publishing,
London, United Kingdom.
Mahoney, S.P., V. Geist, J.F. Organ, R. Regan, G.R. Batcheller,
R.D. Sparrowe, J.E. McDonald, C. Bambery, J. Dart, J.E.
Kennamer, R. Keck, D. Hobbs, D. Fielder, G. DeGayner, and
J. Frampton. 2008. The North American model of wildlife
conservation: enduring achievement and legacy. Pages 7
24 in Sporting Conservation Council. 2008. Strengthening
Americas hunting heritage and wildlife conservation in the
21st century: challenges and opportunities. U.S. Department
of the Interior and U.S. Department of Agriculture,
Washington, D.C., USA.
Manning, R.B. 1993. Hunters and poachers: a social and
cultural history of unlawful hunting in England, 1485 1640.
Clarendon Press, Oxford, United Kingdom.
Marsh, G.P. 1864. Man and nature; or, physical geography as
modified by human action. Scribners, New York, New York, USA.
McCabe, R.E. 2010. Conservation leaders for tomorrow. The
Wildlife Professional 4: 72-75.

Organ, J.F., S.P. Mahoney, and V. Geist. 2010. Born in the


hands of hunters: the North American Model of Wildlife
Conservation. The Wildlife Professional. 4:22-27.
Prescott-Allen, R., and C. Prescott-Allen. 1996. Assessing
the impacts of uses of mammals: The good, the bad, and the
neutral. Pages 45-61 in V.J. Taylor and N. Dunstone, editors.
The exploitation of mammal populations. Chapman and Hall,
London, United Kingdom.
Prukop, J., and R.J. Regan. 2005. In my opinion: the value
of the North American model of wildlife conservation: an
International Association of Fish and Wildlife Agencies
position. Wildlife Society Bulletin 33:374-377.
Regan, R. J., and J. Prukop. 2008. A view from the trenches
reflections on the North American model of fish and wildlife
conservation from a state agency perspective. Transactions
of the North American Wildlife and Natural Resources
Conference 73:255-264.
Reiger, J.F. 1975. American sportsmen and the origins of
conservation. Winchester, New York, New York, USA.

Meine, C. 1988. Aldo Leopold: his life and work. University of


Wisconsin Press, Madison, Wisconsin, USA.

Responsive Management/National Shooting Sports


Foundation. 2008. The future of hunting and the shooting
sports: research-based recruitment and retention strategies.
Harrisonburg, Virginia, USA.

Mighetto, L. 1991. Wild animals and American environmental


ethics. University of Arizona Press, Tucson, USA.

Riess, S.A. 1995. Sport in industrial America, 1850-1920.


Harlan Davidson, Wheeling, Illinois, USA.

Miller, N. 1992. Theodore Roosevelt: a life. William Morrow &


Co. New York, New York, USA.

Riley, S.J., D.J. Decker, L.H. Carpenter, J.F. Organ, W.F.


Siemer, G.F. Mattfeld, and G. Parsons. 2002. The essence of
wildlife management. Wildlife Society Bulletin 30:585-593.

Nanjappa, P., and P.M. Conrad, editors. 2011. State of the


union: legal authority over the use of native amphibians and
reptiles in the United States. Version 1.03 Association of Fish
and Wildlife Agencies, Washington, D.C., U.S.A.

33

Organ, J.F. and S. P. Mahoney. 2007. The future of the public


trust. The Wildlife Professional 1:18-22.

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

Roosevelt, T., and G.B. Grinnell. 1893. The Boone and Crockett
club. Pages 9-15 in T. Roosevelt and G.B. Grinnell, editors.
American big game hunting. Forest and Stream Publishing
Company, New York, New York, USA.

Roosevelt, T., T. S. Van Dyke, D.G. Eliot, and A.J. Stone. 1902. The
deer family. MacMillan Company, New York, New York, USA.
Sabato, L., B.A. Larson, and H.R. Ernst, editors. 2001.
Dangerous democracy?: The battle over ballot initiatives
in America. Rowan and Littlefield Publishers, Lanham,
Maryland, USA.
Sanger, W.C. 1897. The Adirondack deer law. Pages 264-278 in
G.B. Grinnell and T.R. Roosevelt, editors. Trail and camp fire:
The book of the Boone and Crockett Club. Harper, New York,
New York, USA.
Sax, J.L. 1970. The public trust doctrine in natural resource
law: effective judicial intervention. Michigan Law Review
68:471-566.

Sporting Conservation Council. 2008a. Strengthening


Americas hunting heritage and wildlife conservation in the
21st century: challenges and opportunities. U.S. Department
of the Interior and U.S. Department of Agriculture,
Washington, D.C., USA.
Sporting Conservation Council. 2008b. Facilitation of hunting
heritage and wildlife conservation: the recreational hunting
and wildlife conservation plan as directed by Executive
Order 13443. White House Council on Environmental Quality,
Washington, D.C., USA.
The Wildlife Society. 2007. Final TWS position statement: The
North American model of wildlife conservation. The Wildlife
Society, Bethesda, Maryland, USA. (http://www.wildlife.org/
policy/position-statements/, accessed on 4 May 2011).

Sax, J.L. 1999. Introduction to the public trust doctrine.


Pages 5-12 in G.E. Smith and A.R. Hoar, editors, The public
trust doctrine and its application to protecting instream
flows. Proceedings of a workshop sponsored by the National
Instream Flow Program Assessment. NIFPA-08. Alaska
Department of Fish and Game and U.S. Fish and Wildlife
Service-Region 7, Anchorage, Alaska, USA.

Threlfall, W. 1995. Conservation and wildlife management


in Britain. Pages 27-74 in V. Geist and I. McTaggart Cowan,
editors, Wildlife Conservation Policy. Detselig Enterprises,
Limited., Calgary, Alberta, Canada.

Shaw, S.P. 1948. The beaver in Massachusetts. Research


Bulletin Number 11. Massachusetts Division of Wildlife
Research and Management, Boston, USA.

Turner, F.J. 1935. The frontier in American history. Henry Holt


& Sons, New York, New York, USA.

Siemer, W. F., and D. J. Decker. 2011. The new norm:


Westchester County residents risk perceptions and
experiences before and after local coyote attacks. Human
Dimensions Research Unit Series Publication 11-4.
Department of Natural Resources, Cornell University, Ithaca,
New York, USA.
Slade, D.C., R.K. Kehoe, and J.K. Stahl. 1977. Putting the
public trust doctrine to work: the application of the public
trust doctrine to the management of lands, waters, and living
resources of the coastal states. Coastal States Organization,
Inc., Washington, D.C., USA.
Soukanhov, A.H., editor. 1988. Websters II new Riverside
University dictionary. Riverside Publishing, Houghton Mifflin
Company, Boston, Massachusetts, USA.
Speake, D.W., and R.H. Mount. 1973. Some possible ecological
effects of rattlesnake roundups in the southeastern
coastal plain. Proceedings of the Annual Conference of the
Southeastern Game and Fish Commissioners 27:267-277.

Trefethen, J.B. 1975. An American crusade for wildlife.


Winchester, New York, New York, USA.

Turtle Conservation Foudation. 2002. A global action plan for


conservation of tortoises and freshwater turtles. Strategy and
Funding Prospectus 20022007. Conservation International
and Chelonian Research Foundation, Washington, D.C., USA.
Vercauteren, K.C., C.W. Anderson, T.R. Van Deelen, D. Drake,
W. D. Walter, S.M. Vantassel, and S.E. Hygnstrom. 2011.
Regulated commercial harvest to manage overabundant
white-tailed deer: an idea to consider? Wildlife Society
Bulletin 35:185-194.
Wildlife Management Institute. 1987. Organization, authority
and programs of state fish and wildlife agencies. Wildlife
Management Institute, Washington, D.C., USA.
Wildlife Management Institute. 1997. Organization, authority
and programs of state fish and wildlife agencies. Wildlife
Management Institute, Washington, D.C., USA.
Williamson, S.J. 1998. A strategic approach to ballot initiatives
in wildlife management. Transactions of the North American
Wildlife and Natural Resources Conference 63:563-561.

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

34

Appendix: Status of Wildlife


Management in Mexico
Mexico contains approximately 10 percent of the
worlds plant and animal species, making it the third
most important country in relation to biodiversity
(Toledo and Ordonez 1993). Wildlife management
and conservation practices in Mexico are currently
dynamic and evolving; managers are engaged in
maintaining viable populations and habitat for
an array of wildlife. These actions are critical for
management of megadiversity and the important
habitats that Mexico has for migrating North
American wildlife. In addition, the number of wildlife
professionals, professors of wildlife, university
programs in wildlife, and graduate students studying
wildlife are increasing in Mexico. Just as valuable,
other professionals are recognizing the importance
of these additions to the academic and practical
scene. These advances are relatively recent and
are found primarily in northern Mexico. Wildlife has
been largely ignored in southern Mexico and only
recently is wildlife management being incorporated
into agriculture, rangeland, and forestry programs
throughout Mexico (Valdez and Ortega-S in press).
Why has there been such a lag in active management
between Mexico and the rest of North America? It is
important to understand these differences so wildlife
conservation in Mexico can be placed in proper
context relative to the U.S. and Canada.
There are numerous differences between Mexico
and the rest of North America that influence
management and conservation of wildlife and
began centuries prior to any active forms of
management. Even before the Spanish conquest in
1521, Mexicos wildlife had been influenced by land
use, socio-economic factors, and politics (Valdez et
al. 2006). Europeans arrived in the U.S. and Canada

35

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

to escape suppression in their homelands, but they


arrived in Mexico much earlier as the suppressors.
Land ownership in Mexico (e.g., federal, private,
Indian communal landholdings, and ejidos [land
distributed to peasants but ownership resides
with the community and not the individual]) is
dominated by communal land holdings. Because of
minimal ownership and a lack of incentives
for conservation practices, wildlife was not
considered an economically viable resource.
Thus, no efforts were made toward management
(Guzman-Aranda 1995).
Subsequently, wildlife in Mexico was of little interest.
The first comprehensive book on wildlife in Mexico
was published in 1959 (Leopold 1959), whereas
numerous texts had been written about wildlife in
the rest of North America years before that time.
In addition, while there were many reports in the
popular press about declining wildlife populations
in the U.S. and Canada, authors were silent about
a similar plight in Mexico. Although the scientific
backbone of wildlife management was developing
in the U.S. and Canada with universities, societies,
state agencies, and non-governmental organizations,
the social, economic, and political support necessary
for a robust wildlife program in Mexico did not
develop because of socio-economic factors and
governmental natural resource policies (Valdez
and Ortega-S in press). Natural history was not
incorporated into the educational system, and the
government did not recognize the value of wildlife
in its policies or planning. In addition, there were
restrictions on gun ownership, no public hunting
areas, and no wildlife law enforcement to address
the unmanaged and depleted wildlife populations, all

resulting in a middle class that was not involved in


sport hunting. This hindered development of prohunting advocacy groups in Mexico, and the political
support for widespread conservation programs
lagged behind efforts in the U.S. and Canada (Valdez
and Ortega-S in press). Without widespread citizen
appeal, government support, and recognition of
the economic importance of wildlife, large-scale
conservation programs in Mexico did not emerge
until recently.
Although management of wildlife in Mexico is still
in a pioneering stage, the profession is rapidly
advancing on all fronts. The number of Mexican
wildlife ecologists and managers dedicated to
enhancing natural resource conservation is growing,
as is the job market in all segments of society. In
addition, Mexican universities are teaching wildlife
classes to prepare biologists for the job market
(Valdez and Ortega-S in press). Mexico has now
passed through the crossroad and is actively involved
in the conservation of North American wildlife. It is
meeting the challenge of developing sustainable and
economically viable wildlife enterprises in the rural
sector to alleviate poverty and curtail the further
degradation and loss of habitats in Mexico (Valdez
and Ortega-S. in press).
The initial steps towards wildlife conservation were
not taken until the first quarter of the 20th century.
Miguel Angel de Quevedo, a forestry engineer widely
credited with establishing many protected areas,
the Mexican forest service, and other conservation
initiatives, promoted creation of the Bureau of
Forestry, Game and Fisheries. The 1917 Mexican
constitution already contained elements to protect
wildlife and secure its benefits to the nation. But
implementation of this law was imperfect and
enforcement rare. In the process, species such as
pronghorn, jaguar (Panthera onca), and bighorn
sheep were declining. At the same time the federal
government established the Program for Predator
Control, which led to the extirpation of Mexican wolf
(Canis lupus baileyi) and the grizzly bear (Ursus arctos
horribilis) later in the century.

The first hunting law was not created until 1940,


and a modified, improved version was promulgated
in 1952. This law remained in effect for nearly half
a century. Those 50 years were the most crucial for
Mexicos wildlife, because much deforestation and
population extirpation occurred in the second half of
the 20th century. It was not until 2000 that the Zedillo
administration came up with a replacement law,
updating and integrating 50 years of improvements
into the General Law of Wildlife. This new law is
a significant improvement, but it still requires
modifications and, importantly, improvement in
its application across the country. The document
in itself is inclusive and combines many types of
wildlife harvesting, from orchid (Orchidacinae)
collecting and parrot (Psittacinae) nestling extraction
(banned in 2008) to hunting bighorn sheep. But its
implementation is still far from adequate.
In 1996, a new program based on the landowners
commitment to conservation through habitat and
wildlife management on their lands went into
effect under auspices of Units for Conservation,
Management, and Sustainable Harvest of Wildlife
(UMAs). The UMA program opened innovative
alternatives for wildlife conservation and promoted
productive diversification and poverty alleviation.
The UMA is still in effect and covers more than
15 percent of Mexicos territory, although it does
continue to require important improvements to
ensure its proper application.
The modern age of wildlife management in Mexico
can be considered to have started in 1995 with the
creation of the Ministry of the Environment and
1996 with the creation of the Direccin General de
Vida Silvestre, which increased its stature to an
executive level in the Mexican federal government.
A new wildlife program was created to promote
landowner interest and direct participation through
benefit sharing. This meant that a greater budget
and a larger number of human resources were
allocated. The obsolete 1952 federal law on hunting
was superseded by the General Law of Wildlife in
2000. This new law makes significant improvements

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

36

and enhances conservation through sustainable


use. But the old problems remain: the budget
increase is not enough; the level of training of
wildlife managers, biologists, government officials
is still not sufficient; and the old, ubiquitous debate
between preservation and sustainable use is strongly
polarized and radicalized in Mexico to such an extent
that it is paralyzing many conservation efforts. For
example, the UMA system, conceived to benefit
local landowners through sustainable use of their
wildlife (SEMARNAP 1997), had enticed the interest
of landowners to conserve parrots and their nesting
and feeding areas. The landowners had prepared
management plans with the aid of scientists and
non-governmental organizations, and were ready
to begin a legal, sustainable extraction of parrot
chicks, when a sudden movement in 2005 froze all
efforts by pressing the Senate to change the General
Law of Wildlife and ban all parrot harvest and trade
soon thereafter. Today many of those former parrot
conservation areas have been deforested and are
now producing meager corn crops or sustaining lowproductivity, erosion-prone cattle ranches.
An important threat that is affecting the future
of all wildlife management and conservation
efforts in Mexico is that, although in principle the
UMA system is clearly opening new hope for this
task, it is not yet properly applied, administered,
supervised, evaluated, or improved. Additional
registration of UMAs should probably cease and a
careful program of UMA evaluation, management
plan verification, and certification should be
initiated to ensure appropriate practices and
guarantee benefits to wildlife and landowners. In
Mexico which has the 13th largest economy in
the world making biological diversity a source of
sustainable development should be paramount.
However, over 47 percent of the population is below
poverty line. So people will only see the benefits of
wildlife conservation if it has a positive impact on the
economy of the nation.

37

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

Governance
The structure of the Wildlife Department in Mexico,
under the current name of Direccin General de Vida
Silvestre (DGVS, or the Federal Wildlife Bureau),
has changed continuously since the middle of
the last century. It has been variously part of the
ministries of Urban Development, Agriculture, and
more recently, Environment and Natural Resources
(Secretaria de Medio Ambiente y Recursos
Naturales, or SEMARNAT). In the Mexican federal
government, the lowest executive decision-making
position is that of a director general, usually 2 levels
below the minister or secretario. Historically, the
Wildlife Department never had been at an executive
decision level until 1995 when the DGVS was created.
Previously, it had been named Direccin de Fauna
Silvestre, Direccin de Aprovechamiento de los
Recursos Naturales, and Direccin de Caza. The
current structure is as follows:
Secretara de Medio Ambiente y Recursos
Naturales (Ministry of Environment and Natural
Resources)
Subsecretara de Gestin para la Proteccin
Ambiental (Management Undersecretary for
Enironmental Protection)
Direccin General de Vida Silvestre (General
Manager of Wildlife)
The DGVS has 3 main direcciones or bureaus under
it. Direccin de Conservacin de la Vida Silvestre
(Bureau of Wildlife Conservation), Direccin de
Aprovechamiento de la Vida Silvestre (Bureau
of Wildlife Harvesting), and Direccin de Manejo
Integral de la Vida Silvestre (Bureau of Integrated
Wildlife Management). Although responsibility for
wildlife rests with the federal government, some
authority has been decentralized to specific states.
The first steps for decentralization were taken
in 2006 to the states of Baja California, Sonora,
Chihuahua, Coahuila, Nuevo Len, and Tamaulipas,
representing the northern states bordering the

U.S. The main responsibility of DGVS is to allocate,


assign, organize, and systematize information and
wildlife management practices across the country.
Since 1995, any wildlife harvest in Mexico from
pet birds, reptiles, or invertebrates to ornamental
plants, deer, or any other hunting or taking can
be conducted only under the auspices of a UMA.
A few similar concepts exist in other countries,
such as the CAMPFIRE program in Zimbabwe
implemented in the 1990s (Kock 1996). Compared
with the protected-areas system, which today
encompasses about 11 percent of Mexico after 33
years of history, the UMA system is a significant
addition to biodiversity conservation through wildlife
management. Unfortunately, its implementation has
severe limitations, such as the scarcity of properly
trained wildlife managers who could prepare
management plans for the UMAs. The harvest rate
protocols determined by DGVS are still in need of
improvement, verification, evaluation, and follow-up.
Also, certification of how these management plans
are being implemented is deficient primarily because
of a lack of inspection personnel. As a result, some
wildlife populations continue to decline in several
regions, notably in the south (Weber et al. 2006),
although the program clearly is providing important
incentives for conservation, and habitat is improving
in many areas. In addition, many UMAs are now
subjected to additional incentives, such as payments
for ecosystem services by the National Forestry
Commission (CONAFOR). Overall, the program
has had positive impacts for conservation and also
for poverty alleviation in certain areas. It is one of
many areas where a well-designed, conceived, and
implemented collaborative international program
would make a major difference.

The DGVS has regulatory responsibilities but not
law-enforcement attributes. The latter fall under
the sphere of Procuradura Federal de Proteccin
al Ambiente, or PROFEPA for its Spanish acronym
(Federal Attorney General for the Protection of the
Environment, similar to the U.S. Environmental
Protection Agency). Currently, its responsibilities
include determining harvest rates for species

subjected to management of any kind from


cacti to orchids to pet birds and reptiles to hunted
species and granting research permits and, more
recently, determining critical habitat for endangered
species. It also has responsibility to compile the list
of species threatened and endangered in Mexico
(NOM-059).

Funding
The DGVS is part of SEMARNAT. This Ministry is
weak within the Mexican federal government, and
DGVS itself has suffered downsizing in recent years.
Most funds are federal and allocated by Congress
through each years budgetary exercise. However,
additional resources can be brought in through
agreements with the Mexican Commission on
Biodiversity (CONABIO), CONAFOR, or other sections
of the federal government. Clearly, funding is one
of the most severe limitations that prevent full and
adequate implementation of a policy that seems
promising for the future of Mexican wildlife.
Recognition of wildlife as a source of wealth and
an instrument for poverty mitigation is a concept
still extraneous in Mexico. The notion has been
permeating steadily but slowly, and the Ministry
of the Environment is still not robust enough to
advocate for it. Funding is growing, but insufficient.
More institutions, notably CONACYT (the Mexican
equivalent of the National Science Foundation)
CONABIO (the National Commission for the
Knowledge and Use of Biodiversity), the Forestry
Department, and others are investing more and
more in the UMA system to promote conservation on
private lands. However, funding for related matters
such as law enforcement and technical development
and training is even more meager and inadequate.

Scope
Wildlife management in Mexico is focused on
the UMA system, regardless of whether it is for
pet animals (e.g., amphibians, reptiles, birds,

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

38

mammals, and even butterflies), ornamental


plants, hunting, bird watching, or ecotourism.
Most management is for sustainable use, such
as hunting or pet markets, but some is also for
ecotourism. Management is conducted through UMA
management plans prepared by wildlife technicians
for the specific purpose established in the UMA
registration document. Because of this UMA focus,
the management focus is not on the population,
but on the individuals living in a particular UMA,
most often a subsection of a population. Efforts
have been initiated to promote population-focused
management by working in cooperation with
neighboring UMAs (a few UMAs harbor strong
viable populations, but this is far from the norm).
In all instances, wildlife management for purposes
of issues related to terrestrial wildlife and those
species protected under Mexicos Federal List of
Endangered Species or NOM-059-2001 (a new list is
forthcoming) are handled by DGVS. It is the agency
responsible for granting hunting and scientific
collecting permits, determining harvest quotas,
and organizing and administering the UMA system
entirely. Exceptions to these responsibilities are
those under the decentralization program to the
northern border states. The protocols to determine
take quotas are revised every few years, but the UMA
unit assigned by landowners rarely incorporates a
regional scope or wildlife populations, but rather
population sections contained in the individual
UMA to be assigned a quota. Fishing permits and
other biological diversity-related responsibilities
are managed by other agencies. The Program
of Priority Species was removed from DGVS
and transferred to the National Commission of
Protected Areas (CONANP) in 2005. The Priority
Species program includes 25 species and is in the
process of revision, but some representative species
include sea turtle (Chelonioidea), black bear (Ursus
americanus), jaguar, Mexican wolf, pronghorn, red
macaw (Ara macao), tapir (Tapirus bairdii), blue whale
(Balaenoptera musculus), and golden eagle (Aquila
chrysaetos). Other endangered or threatened species
included in the federal list NOM-059 are also the
responsibility of DGVS, although no specific actions

39

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

are conducted on particular species unless they


are initiated by an academic institution,
non-governmental organization, or individuals.
The General Law of Wildlife simply defines what
an endangered species is as part of the species
and populations at risk of extinction (Those
defined by the Secretary as probably extinct in
the wild, endangered, threatened, or subject to
special protection; General Law of Wildlife,
Article 3, Section XIX). Thereafter, the only reference
to endangered species is the indication of whether
harvesting, collecting, damaging, or otherwise
affecting an endangered species without a permit
is a felony.

Wildlife as Public Trust


Resources in Mexico
The concern for wildlife and other natural resources
in Mexico can be traced back to 2 origins. Native
Mexican cultures had a concern for biological
diversity, although primarily from a feudal point
of view, where protection of biodiversity was
justified simply to ensure Emperor Montezumas
enjoyment, and not as a public resource. Many
pre-Hispanic Mexican peoples used to benefit from
wildlife as a source of food, ornaments, and dress,
or for the pleasure of listening to songbirds or
simple contemplation, and were quite enthralled
with wildlife that surrounded them (Hernandez
1959). One of the strongest hypotheses to explain
the collapse of the great Maya empire in the 10th
century is the depletion of their natural resources,
including forests and wildlife (Deevey et al. 1979),
in combination with other factors such as drought
(Hodell et al. 1995).
Wildlife remains a public resource in Mexico, but
public trust status is complicated by lack of clear
designation of user rights and a land-tenure system
affording particular rights to landowners (Valdez et
al. 2006).

In Mexico (and much of the U.S. that once was


Spanish territory), lands were ceded through
Spanish and Mexican land grants. There were
various types of Spanish and Mexican land grants; 3
of these types are particularly relevant herein (Torrez
1997, Ebright 1997).

1. Community Grants. These were grants of large


tracts of land to a substantial number of people.
Each individual in the group was given a parcel of
land on which to build a home. The remainder of the
grant was not allocated to individuals, but reserved
for the common use and benefit of all settlers. Each
person in the grant had access to lands; hunting was
specifically provided for.

2. Private Grants. Private grants were made


to individuals for their personal use. The lands
became private property. Apparently wildlife was not
considered part of the property, although access to
wildlife was controlled by the landowner.

3. Quasi-Community Grants. These were large


tracts of land granted to one or a few individuals
with the requirement that the land be settled.
After settlement, the land would be operated like a
community grant.
The fundamental principles that date back to Roman
law regarding things that could be owned by no one
appear to have applied to wildlife under Spanish land
grants. Further research is warranted to confirm
this. Whereas the English explicitly gave the king
trustee status, and the Romans were mute on
this issue, in the Spanish territories the Governor
appears to have been the trustee.

Markets for Wildlife


The markets of ancient Mexico were abundantly
stocked with fresh meat from a variety of animals,
from axolotl (Ambystoma mexicanum) and iguanas
(Iguanidae) to curassows (Cracidae), turkey
(Meleaegris gallopavo), deer, and collared peccary
(Tayassu tajacu), and many edible invertebrates

from snails (Gastropoda) and spiders (Arachnida) to


grubs (Scarabaeidae, grasshoppers (Caelifera), and
ants (Formicidae). These prodigious markets also
offered hides and feathers of valued animals such as
jaguars, ocelots (Leopardus pardalis), otters (Lontra
spp.), quetzals (Pharomachrus spp.), macaws (Ara
spp.), and more (Daz del Castillo 1943). Obviously,
with no cattle previous to the Spanish conquest,
native Mexicans would have to use local animal
species for protein ingestion, so hunting vertebrates
and gathering invertebrates was an important
economic activity (Daz del Castillo 1943).
Currently, native cultures in Mexico use wildlife
extensively (Valdez et al. 2006), and markets for
some products exist.
The Spanish conquistadors, by contrast, had
witnessed mass destruction of natural resources
in their homeland, where forests were subjected
to a very heavy exploitation for 3 main reasons: to
continue building numerous huge ships as part
of the Spanish empire expansion policy under
Fernando and Isabella, to expand the agricultural
and cattle frontier, and to drive the Moors out of the
Iberian peninsula. Huge tracts of forest were burned
and cleared then and in subsequent centuries, many
of which remain deforested today (Fernandez 1990).

Allocation of Wildlife by Law


During the colonial period, wildlife was used by
many under no specific organizational plan, but often
the government placed restrictions for the wildlife
to be used only by rulers. In 1540, a great hunt was
organized to honor the first viceroy of the New Spain,
Antonio de Mendoza (Leopold 1959). The hunt for
pronghorn and deer was organized just northeast
of Mexico City. To find the pronghorn nearest to this
area now, one would have to travel north about 1,000
km. Hunting remained an activity exclusive to the
upper classes in Mexico for centuries. The first law
protecting Mexican wildlife and establishing the first
attempts to regulate hunting was promulgated in
1894, although little was done to enforce and apply
this law (Leopold 1959).

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

40

Not until the early 20th century did a major legal


instrument contemplate conservation of natural
resources in Mexico. Article 17 of the Mexican
Constitution (promulgated in 1917) defines wildlife
as all natural elements, including water, land,
forest, and other natural resources, and determines
that these natural resources are owned by the
nation for the benefit of all Mexican citizens. By
1922, the decline of several species was so severe
and evident that President Alvaro Obregon decreed
a total ban on hunting bighorn sheep for 10 years
and a permanent ban on pronghorn hunts. In 1933,
President Emilio Portes Gil extended the bighorn
ban for 10 more years, and in 1944 President Manual
Avila Camacho made it permanent, given that the
species continued to decline. Unfortunately, virtually
the only effort to protect the species was the ban
itself; no enforcement of any kind, nor any increase
in budget or enforcement personnel was granted.
Bighorn sheep continued to decline, together with
other species, including pronghorn.
Some progress was made, however, in the Mexican
conservation movement in the first half of the
20th century. One individual, Miguel Angel de
Quevedo, nicknamed the tree apostle, carried out
extraordinary efforts to promote conservation and
environmental sustainability. He created the first
forestry schools in Mexico and the Mexican Forestry
Society, increased the green surface in many
Mexican cities, and directed the Mexican Committee
for the Protection of Wild Birds. Under the
auspices of President Lzaro Crdenas (1934-1940;
recognized for the nationalization of oil), de Quevedo
also created the Mexican National Park System,
having declared green belt parks surrounding
every major city reaching up to more than 20
percent of the Mexican territory as protected areas,
compared to about 11 percent today. Unfortunately,
many of his parks were not protected after Cardenas
left office and were later urbanized (Simonian 1995).
Hunting of big game and birds is allocated through
a licensing and permit system. Protective laws
for vulnerable species exist, but resources for

41

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

enforcement are greatly lacking, and illicit trade is


problematic (Valdez et al. 2006).
The Mexican agency for environmental law
enforcement, PROFEPA, is grossly surpassed by
the needs of the country, not only in the context of
wildlife issues such as poaching, management plan
implementation, and protected area invasions, but
also in environmental impact assessment violations,
implementation of mitigation measures, and many
more. A crucial step to secure the future of wildlife
in Mexico would be to substantially strengthen
PROFEPA in all lines within its responsibilities.

Wildlife Can be Killed Only


for a Legitimate Purpose
At the beginning of the 20th century, predator control
in Mexico became an important activity within
the wildlife sector of the government as a result
of the concern of cattle ranchers primarily in the
north and likely as a reaction to the U.S.s predator
control program itself. At that time many wolves,
mountain lions (Puma concolor), and grizzlies were
killed in the context of the predator control program.
Not until the 1960s, after the grizzly had become
extirpated and the Mexican wolf virtually so, did the
government ban predator control and consider these
species at risk of extinction.

Other wildlife, particularly game species such as
deer, pronghorn, bighorn sheep, waterfowl, and
doves, had been taken for many centuries by the
common Mexican (back to the pre-conquest times)
primarily for food but also for other purposes. Some
organization was necessary, and that led to the
creation of 3 versions of wildlife laws. The legitimate
purpose for killing wildlife then became the benefit
of the nation. Article 5 of the General Law of
Wildlife states: The objective of the national policy
in matters related to wildlife and its habitat is its
conservation through the protection and the optimal
sustainable harvest so that its diversity and integrity
are maintained and promoted, simultaneously with

promoting the well-being of all Mexican citizens.


There are still, of course, conflicts with this
statement. For example, recently, scientists and
non-governmental organizations have been pointing
at the unsustainable, illegal killing of jaguars across
Latin America as the single most important factor
in continued declines and extirpation of this species
(Manzanos 2009, Alatorre 2009). The reasons to
kill jaguars are diverse from revenge of the cattle
rancher who has had losses, to simply a desire for a
jaguar pelt or its canines, or to kill the largest cat of
the Americas despite the fact that killing a jaguar,
at least in Mexico, is a federal offense punishable
with jail time (Manzanos 2009, Crdenas 2009).

Wildlife Is Considered an
International Resource
Mexicos international wildlife policy dates back
to about the middle of the 20th century, although
some specific agreements had occurred before.
The oldest international agreement for wildlife
between Mexico and the U.S. was signed in 1936.
The Convention for the Protection of Migratory Birds
and Game Mammals was a first attempt to join
forces on behalf of wildlife conservation. In 1971,
another international treaty was signed between
Mexico and the U.S., related to protecting wetlands
as habitat of migratory waterfowl. Several other
treaties came into effect in the second half of the
20th century. The primary objective of these treaties
was to cooperate for the conservation of shared and
migratory populations of wildlife moving between
Mexico and the U.S. Besides bilateral or trilateral
agreements in North America, probably the most
relevant international treaty was CITES. Mexico did
not become a signatory of this treaty until 1991. It
restricts international trade of species considered
threatened by trade itself (Appendix I) or those
species that, although not threatened, may become
threatened if the trade is not controlled. Clearly,
populations shared between any 2 countries should
be managed jointly between both countries for the
benefit of both.

Science Is the Proper Tool to


Discharge Wildlife Policy
Wildlife science as a discipline has a very short
history in Mexico. Forestry began around the turn
of the 20th century with Miguel Angel de Quevedos
formidable influence (Simonian 1995). Biology
began with Alfonso L. Herrera in the second half
of the 19th century, and ecology with the triad of
Jos Sarukhn, Arturo Gmez-Pompa, and Gonzalo
Halffter. Wildlife ecology was not established as a
discipline until late in the second half of the 20th
century. Even now, few Mexican universities carry a
conservation biology program or courses (Mndez
et al. 2007), and much fewer carry any wildlife
management related curricula. Use of science as a
tool to determine wildlife management practices,
primarily those related to harvest rates of game
species, is still a very nascent discipline in Mexico.
Endangered species determination and recovery
programs, on the other hand, are widespread,
diverse, and successful, and have placed Mexico at
the leading edge in many ways. The Mexican protocol
for determination of endangered species (MER)
was a science-initiated, science-driven process
that was later turned into federal law. The NOM059 the official list of endangered and threatened
species is based on the MER protocol (Snchez
et al. 2007). Furthermore, this protocol is currently
being adapted and tested in other Latin American
countries and beyond.

Wildlife harvest rates are established by the
government, primarily by DGVS but also by the state
governments to which this responsibility has been
decentralized, (e.g., the northern border states).
However, these protocols are still far from being
fully science-based. Information on population
trends, effects of management, habitat models,
genetic viability, and more are still necessary to
strengthen these harvest rate calculation protocols.

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

42

Currently, a severe shortage of wildlife professionals


exists in Mexico in the government and academic
sectors. Similarly, NGOs have a shortage of wildlife
professionals. Ecology and evolutionary biology are
the primary disciplines of most biologists in
Mexico, and many people working on wildlife issues
come from these disciplines and, therefore, must
adapt their knowledge to be able to address
Mexican wildlife management needs. Wildlife
science is beginning to gain traction in Mexico.
Historically, few publications or books on wildlife
ecology were produced, but in the last 2 decades
many books and papers, some of them with a high
impact factor in Mexico and abroad, have been
published. The Mexican community of wildlife
biologists is still growing, and it needs much more
attention, support, and collaboration within Mexico
and outside to become truly established and to
have a strong presence in the arena of wildlife
management and conservation.

Democracy of Hunting
Is Standard
In Mexico, all hunting is required to be conducted
through a hunting outfitter, or Organizador
Cinegtico. This adds another step to the process
and promotes monopolies for a few wellestablished, well-connected individuals. This greatly
affects benefits coming from hunting, because
outfitters act as middlemen, often renting UMAs for
a fixed price and depleting game in those areas. The
law has been clear about the need for outfitters,
who are registered with the Secretary of Defense
and Secretary of the Environment. Still, not enough
outfitters are registered, so the process is dominated
by a few.
Historically, wildlife in Mexico was a common
resource, without any sort of governing authority,
although some Aztec rulers issued regulations
to protect certain species in certain areas for the
benefit of the rulers themselves. But in 20th century
Mexico, wildlife was acknowledged as a public good,

43

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

owned by the nation. The first hunting law, dating


from 1940, defined it as such. The 1952 updated
hunting law and the current General Law of
Wildlife (2000) also contemplate wildlife as a
public good owned by the nation. This definition
of wildlife broadly includes all organisms living
subjected to the processes of natural evolution and
existing freely in their habitat, which obviously
encompasses all animals and plants. All Mexicans
are entitled by law to enjoy wildlife, but profiting
from wildlife through hunting, wildlife watching,
harvesting, or collecting for commercial purposes
can be done only under the UMA.
Current law in Mexico defines wildlife as all
plants and animals subjected to management
by landowners through the UMA system. Once
the landowner has proven that he or she has
invested in habitat protection and improvement
for the benefit of wildlife, the government (DGVS)
assigns the landowner a harvest quota, in effect
establishing a partnership with the nation. But if
each of these steps is not carefully monitored, (e.g.,
if a landowners investment in habitat protection is
not correctly conducted and actually supervised)
and if the harvest quota is not accurately calculated
on real data or appropriately administered, a risk
of depleting wildlife develops. In many situations,
however, simply declaring a piece of land as a
UMA determines that the habitat is not likely to be
converted to agriculture or cattle production, which,
at the very least, buys time for wildlife protection.
Much monitoring, evaluation, and certification of
UMAs are necessary before the program can be
deemed successful for wildlife management.
Gun ownership in Mexico is regulated through the
Ministry of Defense, which has jurisdiction over
guns and ammunition. Only a handful of shops,
strictly regulated by the Defense Ministry, provide
ammunition that can be purchased. Importing a
gun into Mexico requires Defense Ministry permits,
coupled with a hunting license obtained through
an outfitter. Despite this apparent control (which
is rather strict in many instances, especially for
large-caliber guns), .22-caliber rifles, .410 shotguns,

handguns, revolvers, and automatic firearms of


smaller calibers are common in rural areas of
Mexico. Local people commonly carry their guns
while working the fields, so much hunting happens
on the fringes of regulation.

Mexican Habitat
Considerations
As a megadiversity country, Mexico contains
significant habitat diversity on a global scale. Some
habitat models have been prepared for game species
and many more for threatened and endangered
species, but they have been prepared primarily
for northern species. Although most habitat types
have been severely depleted (notably the tropical
dry and tropical rainforests and the cloud forest),
some others (notably the Sonoran and Chihuahuan
deserts) are less impacted. However, exotic invasive
species are entering these deserts. Buffelgrass
(Pennisetum ciliare) is pervasive in the Sonoran
Desert with only limited pockets outside of it. The
most severe threats to many species are habitat
fragmentation and deforestation. With the advent
of UMAs, the habitat in many regions is improving
and remaining conserved, although wildlife has yet
to recover fully. This effect, known as the empty
forest (Redford 1992), threatens entire ecosystems
if a solution is not implemented in the near
future to secure habitat processes, such as forest
regeneration, grazing, browsing, and seed dispersal.
Because of the definition of wildlife in the Mexican
constitution, all taxa of plants and animals
are included in all legislation and regulations
pertaining to wildlife. In practice and in the context
of the federal government, wildlife is generally
referred to as vertebrates (primarily terrestrial),
cacti, orchids, cycads, palms, and other similarly
ecologically or economically important groups.
Wildlife management of mammals per se is focused
primarily on game species, although much research,
management, recovery, and conservation actions are
conducted on rodents, bats, primates, carnivores,

and other groups. Management models exist for


many species in many groups.
Public education about wildlife is very active in
Mexico for specific taxa and particular objectives.
Primarily in terms of sustainable development
and preservation of ecosystem services, public
education is mostly in the hands of the government,
the academic sector, and, notably, NGOs. A few
years ago, reintroduction of the Mexican wolf was
thwarted because many landowners had no desire or
awareness of the importance to have the wolf back
in their lands (Norandi 2008). Local campaigns raise
awareness and participation on the conservation
of black bears, pronghorn, jaguars, bats, birds of
many species, reptiles, and plants. However, public
awareness related to game species, notably deer
and collared peccary, is not common or strong.
Some basic information on large mammals and
birds is included in the free textbooks distributed in
all elementary schools in Mexico by the office of the
Secretary of Public Education.

Recommendations
1. Enhance the profile, the vision, and the potential
that wildlife represents as a source of wealth for all
Mexicans, both for contemplative, non-consumptive
uses, and for consumptive uses such as hunting.
2. Strengthen the academic programs related
to wildlife management across Mexico as an
educational priority. Given the vast proportion of
Mexico under the concept of UMAs, and the needs
of these UMAs to have adequately trained wildlife
professionals in charge of the management plans,
all academic institutions should be preparing
cadres of wildlife professionals at all levels. Only
with a strong critical contingent of well-trained
wildlife professionals as well as the rest of the
elements (political commitment, adequate law
enforcement, strong public awareness, involvement
and support, and substantial improvement in
funding) will the UMA system finally succeed and
show its full potential.

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

44

3. Continue to intensify and diversify the national,


international, and inter-sectorial collaboration
for wildlife. Some framework agreements already
are in place, but more specific and practical
implementation of these collaborative efforts
and others can make the difference. International
collaboration is a clear win-win situation if
properly implemented, and it can open new
opportunities to learn and improve conservation
and management practices.

The exploitation of mammal populations. Chapman & Hall.


London, United Kingdom.

4. Increase collaboration, information sharing,


and interjurisdictional agreements with Canada and
the U.S.

*Norandi, M. 2008. Se aproxima la liberacin del lobo gris


mexicano, anuncian. Peridico LA JORNADA.

Literature Cited*

*Sanchez, O., R. Medellin, A. Aldama, B. Goettsch, J. Soberon,


and J.M. Tombutti. 2007. Metado de evaluacion del riego de
extinction de las species silvestres en Mexico (MER). Instituto
Nacional de Ecologia (INE-Semarnat), Mexico.

*Alatorre, A. 2009. Urgen a frenar muerte de jaguar. Peridico


REFORMA.
*Crdenas, G. 2009. Nuevo SOS para salvar a jaguares en
Amrica. Peridico EL UNIVERSAL.
*Deevey, E. S. Rice, D.S., P. M. Rice, H. H. Vaughan, M. Brenner,
and M.S. Flannery. 1979. Mayan urbanism - impact on a tropical
karst environment. Science 206:298-306.
*Daz del Castillo, B. 1943. Historia verdadera de la conquista de
la Nueva Espaa. Facsimile. Edicin modernizada y prlogo de
Ramon Iglesia. Editorial Nuevo Mundo, Mxico D. F., Mxico.
*Ebright, M. 1997. Land grants in a nutshell. The Center for Land
Grant Studies. (www.southwestbooks.org/nutshell.htm, accessed
on 3 February 2006).
*Fernandez G., E. 1990. Pasado, Presente y Futuro de los bosques
de la Peninsula Ibrica. Acta Botnica Malacitana 15:135-143.
*Guzmn-Aranda, J. C. 1995. Landowner wildlife conservation
attitudes at Laguna de Baricora, Chihuahua, Mexico. Thesis, New
Mexico State University, Las Cruces, USA.
*Hernandez, F. 1959. Historia Natural de Nueva Espaa, 15171589, facsmile. Universidad Nacional Autnoma de Mxico,
Mexico D.F.
*Hodell, D.A., J. H Curtis, and M. Brenner. 1995. Possible role
of climate in the collapse of classic Maya civilization. Nature
375:391-394.
*Kock, M.D. 1996. Zimbabwe: a model for sustainable use of
wildlife and the development of innovative wildlife management
practices. Pages 229 249 in V.J. Taylor and N. Dunstone, editors.

45

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

*Leopold, A. S. 1959. Wildlife of Mexico, the Game birds and


mammals. University of California Press, Berkeley, USA.
*Manzanos, R. 2009. La muerte del jaguar mexicano. Revista
PROCESO, 64-65.
*Mendez, M., A. Gomez, N. Bynum, R. A. Medellin, A. L.
Porzecanski, and E. Sterling. 2007. Availability of formal
academic programs in conservation biology in Latin America.
Conservation Biology 21:1399-1403.

*Redford, K.H. 1992. The empty forest. BioScience, 42:412-422.

*SEMARNAP (Secretaria de Medio Ambiente, Recursos


Naturales y Pesca) 1997. Programa de conservacin de la vida
silvestre y diversificacin productiva en el sector rural. Instituto
Nacional de Ecologa, SEMARNAP, Mxico, D. F.
*Simonian, L. 1995. Defending the land of the jaguar: a history of
conservation in Mexico. University of Texas Press, Austin, USA.
*Toledo, M. V., and Ma. de Jesus Ordoez. 1993. The biodiversity
scenario of Mexico: a review of terrestrial habitats. Pages 757779 in T. P. Ramamoorthy, R. Bye, A. Lot, and J. Fa., editors.
Biological diversity of Mexico: origins and distribution. Oxford
University Press, New York, New York, USA.
*Torrez, R.J. 1997. New Mexicos Spanish and Mexican land
grants. New Mexico Genealogical Society. (www.nmgs.org/
artlandgrnts.htm, accessed on 3 February 2006.)
*Valdez, R., J. C. Guzmn-Aranda, F. J. Abarca, L. A. TarangoArmbula, and F. C. Snchez. 2006. Wildlife conservation and
management in Mexico. Wildlife Society Bulletin 34:270-282.
*Valdez, R., and J. A. Ortega-S., editors. In press. Wildlife
ecology and management in Mexico. Texas A&M Press, College
Station, USA.
*Weber, M., G. Garcia-Marmolejo, and R. Reyna-Hurtado. 2006.
The tragedy of the commons: wildlife management units in
southeastern Mexico. Wildlife Society Bulletin 34:1480-1488.

The cartoons of avid hunter and conservationist Jay Ding Darling spoke powerfully of the need for active game management to
ensure the health of species and habitats. A Pulitzer Prize-winning cartoonist, Darling designed the first Federal Duck Stamp in
1934. Courtesy of the J. N. Ding Darling Foundation.

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

46

47

The North American Model of Wildlife Conservation

The Wildlife Society


5410 Grosvenor Lane
Bethesda, MD 20814
P: 301.897.9770
F: 301.530.2471
www.wildlife.org
Promoting Excellence in Wildlife Stewardship
through Science and Education

Boone &
Crockett Club
250 Station Road
Missoula, MT 59801

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi