Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 94

Impact of Investments in the

Housing Sector on GDP and


Employment in the Indian Economy

Sponsored
Study supported by DFID and Ministry of
Housing and Urban Poverty Alleviation

April 2014

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

ACKNOWLEDGEMENT

The Council would like to thank the officials of The Ministry of Housing
and Urban Poverty Alleviation (MoHUPA) for their valuable inputs during the
project review meetings and presentations. The study also benefited
immensely from the insights from comments by invitees from the Ministry of
Finance, Ministry of Labour, Planning Commission and the Central Statistical
Office to these presentations. The Council is particularly grateful to Support to
National Policies for Urban Poverty Reduction (SNPUPR) and DFID for their
support and funding, and to Mr. Kiran Avadhanula for facilitating the study
right from the start.

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

ii

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

PROJECT TEAM

Project Leaders
Poonam Munjal
P.C. Parida (till Dec, 2013)

Project Advisors
D.B. Gupta
Shashanka Bhide
Senior Consultant
Ramesh Kolli

iii

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

iv

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

CONTENTS
Section
No.

1.

2.

3.

4.
5.

Description
Executive Summary
Abbreviations and Acronyms
Introduction
Context of the study
Scope of Work and Study Objectives
Structure of the Report
Input-Output analysis
Introduction
Applications of IO Tables
Limitations of IO Tables
Input-Output Model for Impact Analysis
Static IO Model
Multipliers
Inter-industry Linkage Analysis
Methodology and Approaches to construct Housing Sector IO Table
Sectoral Aggregates
Estimates of Inter-Industry Linkages
Output Multiplier
Employment Multiplier
Income Multiplier
Tax Multiplier
Impact of Housing Demand on Economy
Simulation 1: 10% increase in final demand of residential
construction
Simulation 2: An increase of Rs. 1 lakh crore in final demand of
residential construction
Simulation 3: An increase of Rs. 1 lakh crore in final demand of
other construction
Summary of Findings
Appendices
Appendix 1: Aggregating 130 sectors of IO Table to 21 sectors
Appendix 2: About Input-Output table
Appendix 3: Input-Output table, 2009-10
Appendix 4: Leontief Inverse Matrix
Appendix 5: Extended Leontief Inverse Matrix
Glossary

Page no.
vii
x
1
1
3
4
5
5
6
7
7
7
9
11
12
16
21
22
26
31
33
37
37
41
45
51
55
57
61
65
73
76
79

National Council of Applied Economic Research

Table No.
2.1
2.2
2.3
2.4
2.5
2.6
2.7
2.8
2.9
2.10
2.11
2.12
2.13
2.14
2.15
2.16
2.17
2.18
2.19
3.1
3.2
3.3
3.4
3.5
3.6
3.7
3.8
3.9
3.10
3.11
3.12
4.1

Description of Tables
Aggregation Scheme
Mapping between 21 sectors and NIC codes
Identification of Formal/Informal workers
Sectoral share in key aggregates of IO Table (%)
Sectoral share in employment (%)
Sectors rank on share in respective aggregates
Capital and Labour to Output Ratios
Output Multiplier
Sectors ranking on Output multiplier
Output Multiplier of Residential Construction by sectors
Direct Employment Coefficient
Total (Direct + Indirect) Employment Linkage Coefficient
Type I Employment Multiplier
Total (Direct + Indirect + Induced) Employment Linkage
Coefficient
Type II Employment Multiplier
Type I Income Linkages
Type II Income Linkages
Type I Tax Linkages
Type II Tax Linkages
Type I impact of a 10% increase in Final Demand in residential
construction on the economy
Sectoral increase (Type I) in various parameters following
Simulation 1
Type II impact of a 10% increase in Final Demand in residential
construction on the economy
Sectoral increase (Type II) in various parameters following
Simulation 1
Type I impact of an increase of Rs. 1 lakh crore in Final Demand in
residential construction on the economy
Sectoral increase (Type I) in various parameters following
Simulation 2
Type II impact of an increase of Rs. 1 lakh crore in Final Demand
in residential construction on the economy
Sectoral increase (Type II) in various parameters following
Simulation 2
Type I impact of an increase of Rs. 1 lakh crore in Final Demand in
other construction on the economy
Sectoral increase (Type I) in various parameters following
Simulation 3
Type II impact of an increase of Rs. 1 lakh crore in Final Demand
in other construction on the economy
Sectoral increase (Type II) in various parameters following
Simulation 3
Salient Features of previous and present studies

April, 2014

Page no.
13
15
16
17
18
19
21
23
24
25
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
51

vi

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
The final report of the Study on Impact of investments in the housing sector on GDP
and Employment of Indian Economy is organised in four chapters.

Chapter 1 presents the overview of the housing sector, the objectives of the
present study and the key takeaways
Chapter 2 is devoted to the methodology adopted and the description of the
data sources used for the present study. The IO model, multipliers and
multiplier analysis to carry out policy simulations are also described and
presented in this chapter.
Chapter 3 outlines the policy interventions based on several simulations.
Chapter 4 presents the key findings of the study. This is followed by
annexures.

Overview
The study is based on Input Output Model (IO). An IO model describes the
interdependence between sectors in an economy. In other words, it simply shows the
transactions between the production sectors. The scope of transaction mainly covers
three purposes namely
(i)
(ii)
(iii)

sell or buy inputs


sell or buy goods for final consumption, and
sell or buy goods for future use.

Here, input implies raw material being used for producing another goods or services,
known as intermediate consumption while final goods and goods for future use refer
to final consumption and capital formation (i.e. investment), respectively. An output
may be transacted for all three purposes. In other words, output of sector may be
demanded for intermediate uses by itself and the other sectors.
Direct, indirect and induced effects
If the final demand of a particular product increases, there will be an increase in the
output of that product, as production increases to meet the increase in demand. This
is known as direct effect.
As producers need to increase their output, they would also need more inputs,
therefore, there will also be an increase in demand for inputs from their suppliers.
This process goes on over the entire supply chain. This is known as indirect effect. In
vii

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

In response to the direct and indirect effects, the level of household income increases
due to increased employment and a proportion of this increased income are re-spent
on consumption of final goods and services. This is called the induced effect.
Multipliers
When an industry increases its production, there is increased demand for inputs from
industries. In the IO model, this demand is referred to as backward linkage.
Backward linkage is also known as output multiplier. This analyses how a change in
final demand of a sector affects the final demand of the economy.
The ratio of direct and indirect changes to the direct change due to a unit increase in
final demand is termed as type I multiplier.
The ratio of total output changes (direct + indirect + induced) to the direct output
change due to a unit increase in final demand is termed as type II multiplier
Key findings
The construction sector is disaggregated into residential construction, nonresidential construction and other construction sector and the residential
construction sector is treated as housing sector. The key findings of the report are
as follows:
1. The residential construction (housing sector) accounts for
a. 1.24% of the total output of the economy (total construction sector is
11.39%)
b. 1.00% of GDP (total construction sector is 8.2%)
c. 6.86% of the employment (total construction sector is 11.52%)
2. Housing sector is fourth largest employment generating sector.
3. 99.41 per cent of the jobs in housing sector are informal jobs.
4. Its labour to output ratio i.e. number of persons employed to produce a lakh
units of output, is 2.34 and is the highest among all the sectors.
5. The type I output multiplier for housing sector is 2.33 and type II is 5.11 i.e.
the increase of 1 unit in the final demand of housing translates into induced
cumulative revenues of 5.11 units in the economy.
6. For every lakh invested in the housing sector, 2.69 new jobs (2.65 informal
and 0.4 formal) are created in the economy. With induced effect, the number
of jobs created would be 4.06 (3.95 informal and 0.11 formal).
7. For every investment in the housing sector, the household income increases
by Rs. 0.41. With induced effect, this is estimated to be Rs. 0.76.
8. For every unit of housing created the household income increases by 0.41
units. With induced effect, this is estimated to be 0.76 units.

viii

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

9. The type I income multiplier for housing sector is 1.54 and type II is 2.84. This
would mean that a unit of increase in the final expenditure in the housing
sector would generate additional income as high as 3 times the income
generated within the housing sector itself.
10. Every additional rupee invested in the housing sector will add Rs. 1.54 to the
GDP and with household expenditure considered, this is going to add Rs. 2.84.
11. For every rupee invested in creation of housing, Rs. 0.12 gets collected as
indirect taxes.

ix

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

ABBREVIATIONS AND ACRONYMS


Units used in the Report
1 crore = 10 million
1 lakh = 100 thousand

Abbreviations
CFC

Consumption of Fixed Capital

CIS

Change in stocks/change in inventories

COE/CoE

Compensation of Employees

CSO

Central Statistical Office

EUS

Employment and Unemployment Survey

EXP

Exports of goods and services

FU/FD

Final Use / Final Demand

GCE/GFCE

Government Final Consumption Expenditure

GDP

Gross Domestic Product

GFCF

Gross Fixed Capital Formation

GVA

Gross Value Added

IC

Intermediate consumption

IIHS

Indian Institute for Human Settlements

IMP

Imports of goods and services

I-O Table

Input-Output table

IOTT

Input output transaction table

NAS

National Accounts Statistics

NCAER

National Council of Applied Economic Research

NCS

Net capital stock

NIC

National Industrial Classification

NIT

Net Indirect tax

NSSO

National Sample Survey Office

OS/MI

Operating Surplus/Mixed Income

PFCE

Private Final Consumption Expenditure

UA

Urban Agglomeration

Val

Valuables

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

xi

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

1. INTRODUCTION

Context of the study


1.1.
India is currently experiencing rapid growth in population, both urban and
rural. Along with rapid, although somewhat haphazard, urbanization the Indian cities,
both large and medium, are also growing.1 For example in 2011 there were 53 million
plus UAs/cities compared to 35 in 2001. The urban population itself went up from
286.1 million in 2001 to 377.1 million in 2011. Similarly the number of towns in the
corresponding period increased from 5161 to 7935. This has led to steep increase in
demand for housing especially in urban areas. For example during the period 19612001, the total housing stock increased from 13.3 million units to 50.95 million
units.2
1.2.
The local urban governments are unable to meet this increase in demand for
housing, leading to growth of informal/unauthorized housing in the form of slums,
squatter settlements and jhuggi jhompri colonies The vast shortage of housing offers
a great opportunity to stimulate growth in the economy as housing sector is
recognized for its potential for generating income and employment3. In addition,
provision of housing, not only contributes to peoples well being and happiness,
reduced absenteeism, and higher productivity of workers, but also, as recent
researches have shown, in limiting the size of families and lower mortality and
morbidity.
1.3.
According to the Report of the Technical Group for the 11th Five Year Plan
2007-12 on Estimation of Urban Housing Shortage (HUPA), at the beginning of 2007
there was an estimated shortage of 24.71 million housing units, and that the total
housing requirement during 2007-12 was estimated at 26.53 million units. The
housing shortage in the beginning of 12th Five Year Plan (2012) is estimated at 18.78
million units. According to the Report of the Technical Group for the 12th Five Year
Plan, the housing shortage during the period 2012-17 may not increase if the rate of
growth in housing stock continues to be higher than the growth in number of
1

One or two facts about Indias pace of urbanization. One there are several other developing countries, including
China and Brazil, which have experienced higher rate of urbanization; two Indias urbanization compared to its
income growth has not been as rapid as of some other countries at similar stage of development.
2 The housing stock includes pucca, semi pucca and kutcha housing. It is interesting to point out that during the
decade 1991-2001, the growth in housing stock was lower compared to the two previous periods. Also over the
period, there was a decline in the kutcha housing units, perhaps due to various housing schemes of both the
Central government and the state governments.
3
New housing also involves development of raw land including construction of roads, laying of both civic and
physical infrastructure. These in turn have huge employment potential.

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

households in the 12th Five Year Plan as observed in the last decade. Apart from
housing sector, other critical sectors from the viewpoint of income and employment
are the construction and real estate.
1.4.
As per the National Accounts prepared by the CSO for 2009-10, the
contribution to GDP by the construction sector was 8.2 per cent and that of real
estate, ownership of dwellings and business services was 11.4 per cent; thus
construction and real estate contributing nearly one-fifth of Indias GDP. In terms of
employment during 2009-10, a little over 616 lakh workers were engaged in the
construction sector, and another 7.6 lakh in real estate.4
1.5.
Apart from rapid urbanization, India, in the recent period, has also
undergone through a significant structural transformation from a low skilled
economy to a relatively high skilled services oriented economy. For example the
share of agriculture in Indias GDP which was around 53 per cent in 1950-51 had
declined significantly to around 14 per cent in 2011-12. A consequence of this
structural change is reduced dependence on agriculture and increased migration
from agriculture to high value added sectors like services and industry, clearly in
search of employment.
1.6.
Since these sectors are largely located in urban areas, critical relevance of
urban areas as a trigger in promoting economic growth of the country needs no
further emphasis. This is clear from the fact that top 10 cities in India are estimated
to produce about 15 per cent of the GDP with 8 per cent of the population and just 0.1
per cent of land area (Indian Institute for Human Settlements, IIHS). Also the 53
million plus cities in the country are estimated to produce 32 per cent of the GDP
with 13.3 per cent of the population and just around 0.2 per cent of the land area. The
corresponding percentages for 100 largest cities of the country are 43 per cent GDP,
16 per cent of the population and just 0.24 per cent of land area.
1.7.
As far as the built up area is concerned, there is huge area outside the
purview of urban local bodies, although with far less population density. An
interesting feature of urban growth in the past two decades, especially in the case of
largest 10 cities, has been the pace of growth of built up area which is seen to be
faster than the growth of population in these cities.
1.8.
Another feature of current urban scenario is the relatively higher
concentration of economic output around the major urban centres and urbanized
4

It may be noted that this employment does not mean that all the workers in these sectors had full time
employment.

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

states. Real estate activity is also found to be concentrated largely in large cities and
metropolitan cities as well as in the more prosperous states too. Because of
employment opportunities in urban areas compared to the rural ones, there is
considerable inflow of migrants to larger cities leading to acute housing shortages.
1.9.
In view of the importance of both housing and construction sectors as critical
sectors from the viewpoint of employment and income, the present study using the
input-output framework has attempted to study the impact of investment in housing
and construction on both employment and income. In doing this we have broadly
attempted to update an earlier study conducted by IIM-A faculty. The following is
broadly the scope of work for the study.

Scope of Work and Study Objectives


1.10. (a) The present study attempts to update and substantiate the findings of the
July 2000 Report on Impact of Investment in the Housing Sector on GDP and
Employment in the India Economy. In addition the study has attempted to:

Study and assess the model used in the July 200 report including the
relevance of its assumptions, and to refine them if required.
Assess, based on the validated model, the inter-industry linkages of
housing investment: A study of direct/indirect linkages with broad
sectors of Indian economy. The study also attempts updating the inputoutput data of Indian economy to reflect the contemporary reality.
Assess impact of housing investment on income generation: A
comparative study of housing with other sectors on expenditure made,
and resulting growth and income generation. The study attempts to
reassess the income multiplier parameters and suggest the most
appropriate methodology to ascertain income multiplication through
housing.
Assess impact of housing investment on Employment Generation: A
comparative study of expenditure on sectors and resulting employment
generation. The study will attempt to reassess the change in labor
intensity and coefficients across sectors and sector-wise employment
multiplier assumptions to update the comparative employment
potential of the housing sector in terms of volumes and investments.

(b)
The study attempts to assess on a broad basis the inter-linkages between
housing, construction and construction materials and to the extent practicable, the
real estate development sectors, drawing inferences on the drivers of growth and key
points on inter linkages.
3

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

(c)
The study attempts to draw possible inferences for short and long term
policy interventions.

Structure of the Report


1.11
The report is presented in four sections. The first section is introductory and
broadly outlines the importance of housing and construction sectors as generator of
income and employment provider. Inter alia, it also provides an idea of the scope of
study. The second section discusses in detail the methodology used to construct the IO table and the data used. The IO model, multipliers and multiplier analysis to carry
out policy simulations are also described and presented in this section. The following
section contains the results of policy simulations using output, employment, income
and tax multipliers. The concluding section summarizes the major findings of the
study. Inter alia, we indicate briefly the limitations of the study.

National Council of Applied Economic Research

2.

April, 2014

INPUT-OUTPUT ANALYSIS

Introduction

2.1.
Any economic activity of a region has both direct and indirect economic
benefits. Same is the case with construction sector, a vital component of housing
sector. It is evident that when the demand for this sector increases, its output
increases in order to meet this growing demand. This is clearly the sectors direct
impact on the economy. However, in order to meet this demand, the output of those
sectors also increases which provide inputs to construction sector and hence have
strong backward linkages with the sector. These input-providers produce the indirect
impact on the economys output and employment. While the value of output of the
construction sector may reflect the value of inputs, income generated by the
construction sector does not fully account for the income and employment that is
generated by the input suppliers. The multiplier effects of development of the
housing sector on income and employment need to be captured to understand the
impact of development of this sector on the economy.

2.2.
There are a number of ancillary industries which support the growth of
construction sector, like steel, cement, glass, brick, wood and certain consumer
durables etc. Further, the industries that provide the inputs to these ancillary
industries also gain momentum. Hence, due to the inter-linkages among all the
sectors of economy, the overall economic impact of a particular sector far exceeds the
direct impact. The impact arising from such inter-linkages is called indirect impact or
the second-round impact or the spill-over impact.
2.3.
The Input-Output (IO) model is a widely used and scientific method to
measure these inter-linkages and hence arrive at direct as well as indirect impact of
an economic sector. The need for input-output analysis arises from the fact that the
researchers, businesses and government policy makers may want to understand the
inter-industry linkages, linkages between final uses and output and impact of policy
decisions in the economy in terms of employment, income and taxes it generates and
also what capital and imports it needs to grow. The impact analysis can be in terms
of how other industries depend on the industry under study or how this industry
impacts on other industries. An IO model enables these impact analyses as this model
in its simplest form is a full articulation of inter-industry analysis and facilitates
impact analysis.

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

2.4.
With the quantification of these inter-linkages, it is possible to see how, an
additional demand in a particular sector affects other sectors of the economy through
its backward linkages and vice-versa through the forward linkages. Although some of
these questions can be answered intuitively, but the advantage of the IO model is that
it quantifies the impact through a value of the multiplier by which a particular sector
is expected to grow following a change in demand in the housing sector.
2.5.
The impact estimates derived from the IO analysis is based on the economic
activity during one specific year, for which IO table is constructed. However, the IO
multipliers can be assumed to remain stable during a certain period, typically up to 5
years, unless the economys structure changes significantly.

Applications of IO Tables

2.6.
Input-Output tables, now prepared by most of the economies, are powerful
tools and are applied for various purposes. The primary advantage of input-output
tables is the generation of multipliers output, income and employment multipliers.
Unlike economic base multipliers5, which calculate only one multiplier, input-output
multipliers are calculated for all the industries. It is able to reveal the impact of
growth or decline in one industry on all the other industries of the economy.
Similarly, it generates employment multipliers for all the sectors.

2.7.
Further, with the multiplier analysis, input-output tables can be used for
impact assessment. It brings out the impact of change in final demand of one sector
on the output of that sector as well as the output of all other sectors of the economy.
Another use of these tables is in projections of sectoral level output. By multiplying
the vector of projected or forecasted value of final demand of each industry by the
input coefficient matrix, one arrives at the projected value of output of each industry.

The economic base multiplier corresponds to the economic base theory, which assumes that any local economy
can be divided into two economic activities basic and non-basic. Basic activities are those that produce goods
(services) for export and non-basic activities are those that produce goods (activities) for local use. An increase
(or decrease) in basic activities leads to an increase (decrease) in income flow in the local economy. This results in
the increased (decreased) local demand for goods and services, which in turn increases (decreases) the non-basic
activities. This is called the multiplier effect. The economic base multiplier is usually calculated in terms of
employment and is expressed as the change in total employment in basic and non-basic activities with respect to
change in employment in basic activities.

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Limitations of IO Tables

2.8.
The model derived from the table assumes that the present coefficients will
remain constant under the projected conditions. Therefore, it can be used for shortterm projections. In the longer range, coefficients are affected by changes in relative
prices, appearance of new industries or elimination of outdated industries, and
technological change in the production processes (Berke, Godschalk, and Kaiser,
2006). The prices of inputs change over time which may result in the industries
switching to alternative inputs or change the balance between labour and capital
inputs. The greater the rate of economic change in the system, the lesser reliable is
the fixed input-output coefficients. However, the price adjustments could be done
using the price ratios of base year to projected year. By specifying the changes in
technology input-output coefficients can be modified for applications in longer term
projections or analysis.

Input-Output Model for Impact Analysis


2.9.
Input-output analysis starts with the calculation of input-output coefficients.
They are calculated by dividing each entry of the IO table by the corresponding
column total. The input coefficients can be interpreted as the corresponding shares of
costs for goods, services and primary inputs in total input (equals total output). As
the input coefficients cover all inputs including the residual variable operating
surplus, they add up to unity. The primary inputs consist of intermediate imports,
taxes less subsidies on products, compensation of employees, other net taxes on
production, and gross operating surplus.
2.10. The output coefficients describe the output structure of produced goods and
services. The output coefficients are calculated by dividing each entry of the inputoutput table by the corresponding row total. They can be interpreted as the shares in
total output (revenue) or market shares for products and primary inputs. For value
added, they reflect the distribution of primary inputs. The final use here consists of
final consumption expenditures (by households, non-profit institutions serving
households (NPISH) and government), gross fixed capital formation, changes in
inventories and exports of goods and services.
Static IO Model
2.11. The input and output coefficients are used to prepare IO models which are
required for impact analysis and understanding inter-industry linkages. A well
known input-output model is the static input-output system of Wassily Leontief. It is
a linear model which is based on Leontief production functions and a given vector of
7

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

final demand. The objective is to calculate the unknown activity (output) levels for
the individual sectors (endogenous variables) for the given final demand (exogenous
variables).

2.12. As we have seen earlier, the IO table depicts all the inter-industry
transactions of the economy. A row in an I-O table shows the sales made by one
economic sector to various sectors and final uses, whereas a column shows what the
sector purchased from different sectors for its intermediate consumption and
primary inputs, consisting of taxes less subsidies on production and imports, imports
of goods and services, compensation of employees, consumption of fixed capital and
net operating surplus/mixed income. The IO table with n sectors is shown below:
Intermediate uses
123......j.....n

1
2
.
.
I
.
N
Primar
y
inputs

x 11 x 12 ....xi J....x1n
x 21 x 22 ....x2j....x 2n
...............................
..............................
x i1 x i2.......x ij......x in
. .............................
x n1 x n2......xnj.....x nn
p1 p2 ........... pj............. pn

Final uses
Consumpti Capital
on
Formati
expenditur on
e
c1
f1
c2
f2
.
.
.
.
ci
fi
.
.
cn
fn
C
F

Net
Expor
ts
e1
e2
.
.
ei
.
en
E

Gross
output

X1
X2
.
.
Xi
.
Xn

The above matrix represents the following set of n balance equations:x i = x i1 + x

i2 ..................+x in

+y i, i =1,2......n, Yi is final use

Denoting aij for input output coefficient representing the output of sector i absorbed
by sector j per unit of output of sector j, we get,
xi=a i1 x1 + a i2 x 2...........a inx n +y i, i = 1,2........n,

xij=aijxj

These equations can be written in matrix notations as


X=
X=

AX + Y or (I-A)X=Y
(I-A)-1Y
8

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

2.13. A is the input-output coefficient matrix, (I-A) is known as Leontief matrix and
(I-A)-1 is the Leontief inverse matrix. This is the static open input-output model. It is
clear from above that the input-output system attains equilibrium in terms of supply
and demand: when there is a change in the final demand conditions, the application
of input-output system indicates the new set of output levels of sectors that establish
a new equilibrium to meet the changed final demand conditions. Thus, the inputoutput analysis is an economic application of general equilibrium theory, when we
have the coefficient matrix A, and a given final demand vector y.
2.14. On the diagonal of Leontief matrix, net output is given for each sector with
positive coefficients (revenues) while the rest of the matrix covers the input
requirements with negative coefficients (costs). The Leontief inverse (I-A)-1 reflects
the direct and indirect requirements for domestic intermediates for one unit of final
demand. The difference between Inverse Matrix and A matrix corresponds to the
indirect input requirements of the economy for one unit of FD. The column sum of the
inverse can be interpreted as output multiplier which reflects the cumulative revenues
of the economy which are induced by one additional unit of final demand of a certain
product. For example, if the output multiplier of an industry is 2.12 then the increase
of 1 unit in the final demand for this industry translates into the induced cumulative
revenues of 2.12 units in the economy. Further description of multipliers is given in
the section below.

Multipliers
2.15. If the final demand of a particular product increases, there will be an increase
in the output of that product, as production increases to meet the increase in demand.
This is known as direct effect. However, as producers need to increase their output,
they would also need more inputs, therefore, there will also be an increase in demand
for inputs from their suppliers. This process goes on over the entire supply chain.
This is known as indirect effect. The most frequently used types of multipliers in
input-output analysis are those that estimate the effects of the exogenous changes of
final demand (consumption, investment, exports) on outputs of the sectors in the
economy and value added.
2.16. In addition to the indirect effects which arise as a result of inter-industry
linkages, there are induced effects on output, income and employment which are
triggered by the household consumption expenditure. In response to the direct and
indirect effects, the level of household income increases due to increased
employment and a proportion of this increased income are re-spent on consumption
of final goods and services. This is called the induced effect. Hence, these effects
9

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

reflect the changing pattern of households spending with the increase in income due
to additional production. To arrive at the induced effects, the household account is
endogenised into the input-output framework. The household account refers to the
household income (compensation of employees) and expenditure (private final
consumption expenditure).
2.17. As mentioned above, an output multiplier for a sector j is defined as the total
value of production in all sectors of the economy that is necessary at all stages of
production in order to produce one unit of product j for final demand. The inverse
coefficients indicate how many commodities i must be produced in order to satisfy
one unit of final demand for goods and services j. By including the interdependencies
between all activities it is therefore possible to determine the total outputs, i.e.
directly and indirectly required to satisfy a given final demand. The output multiplier
depicts the cumulative revenues of the economy which are induced by one additional
unit of final demand of a certain commodity. Due to this additional unit the output
(production) multipliers are equal to 1 or above 1. The higher the multipliers, the
larger are the effects on the input-output system of the economy.
2.18. The output multiplier is called Type I output multiplier when only direct and
indirect effects are taken into account. This is expressed as the ratio of direct and
indirect output changes to the direct output change due to a unit increase in final
demand. However, when induced effects are also added to direct and indirect effects
by endogenising household account, the multiplier so obtained is called Type II output
multiplier. This is, therefore, expressed as the ratio of total output changes (direct +
indirect + induced) to the direct output change due to a unit increase in final demand.
In other words, multiplying a change in final demand for an industrys output by that
industrys output multiplier (Type I and Type II) will generate an estimate of direct +
indirect effects (in case of Type I) and direct + indirect + induced effects (in case of
Type II).
2.19. The induced effects represent the response by all local industries caused by
increased expenditures of new household income and inter-institutional transfers
generated from the direct and indirect effects of the change in final demand for a
specific industry.
2.20. Similarly, the employment multiplier for jth sector is defined as the ratio of the
total (direct + indirect in case of Type I employment multiplier and direct + indirect +
induced in case of Type II employment multiplier) employment changes per rupees
change of final demand in sector j to the direct employment change per rupees
change of final demand in sector j. The direct employment effect of a rupee worth of
increase in final demand in sector j is obtained from jth sector's employment to output
ratio or employment coefficient. The total employment change per rupees change of
10

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

final demand in a sector j is estimated by multiplying the row vector of the


employment coefficient with the Leontief Inverse matrix (Mij).
2.21. Income multipliers measure the change in income (compensation of
employees) which occurs throughout the economy as a result of a unit change in
income in a sector. They show the ratio of direct plus indirect (plus induced if Type II
multipliers are used) income changes to the direct income change.

Inter-industry Linkage Analysis


2.22. In the framework of the input-output model, industry production has two
kinds of economic effects on other industries in the economy. These are the
absorption effects and the diffusion effects. When industry i increases its production,
there is increased demand for inputs from industries. In the input-output model, this
demand is referred to as backward linkage. This analyses how a change in final
demand of a sector affects the final demand of the economy. Backward linkage is also
known as output multiplier. An industry with higher backward linkages than other
industries means that expansion of its production is more beneficial to the economy
in terms of causing other induced productive activities. On the other hand, an
increase in production by other industries leads to additional output required from
industry i to supply inputs to meet the increased demand. This supply function is
referred to as forward linkage and helps in analysing how a change in the rest of the
sectors influences a particular one. An industry with higher forward linkages than
other industries means that its production is relatively more sensitive to changes in
other industries output.
2.23. The direct link between final demand and industrial output describes the
deliveries of finished goods and services to the various final demand categories. It
does not take into account the intermediate outputs, i.e. raw materials and semifinished goods which are required to produce finished goods. These intermediates
represent the indirect links between final demand and output levels. The direct and
indirect link can be identified by multiplying the Leontief Inverse with the matrix of
final demand categories ((I-A)-1 * Y). The resulting matrix shows the industrial
output levels directly and indirectly necessary to meet the final demand
requirements. In other words, it indicates the total importance of each category of
final demand for the production of different product groups. In this compilation, all
intermediate consumption part of the domestic output is transferred to the final
demand by using Leontief Inverse.

11

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

2.24. Further, the interrelation between primary inputs and one unit of production
induced by final demand can be disclosed by multiplying the primary input
coefficients with the Leontief Inverse. The resulting matrix depicts how many
primary inputs are directly and indirectly used within the whole production process
in order to satisfy one unit of final demand for goods and services j. Due to the fact
that the intermediate inputs are converted into primary inputs, the total input
coefficients for primary inputs per unit of production add up to one.
2.25. The multipliers for primary inputs [B (I-A)-1] (B is input coefficients for
primary inputs) are multiplied with a matrix of final demand by category to assess
the direct and indirect primary input requirements for the various categories of final
demand (consumption, investment, exports).

Methodology and Approaches to construct Housing Sector IO Table


2.26. In India, the input-output tables are compiled by CSO periodically, once in
every five years. These tables have complete coverage of the economy and are
consistent with the national accounts. The latest IO table is available for 2007-08.
However, for the present study, we have updated it for 2009-10.
2.27. The detailed IO table consists of 130 sectors, but for a meaningful inputoutput analysis, it is desirable that the sectors are aggregated such that the
aggregation scheme is aligned to the purpose of the analysis. Evidently, the sectors of
interest and the ones which these sectors are closely related to are kept separately,
subject to the availability of their data.
2.28. The aim of the present study is to assess the impact of investment in the
housing sector on GDP and Employment of the Indian Economy. Further, the
objective is to assess the inter-linkages between housing, construction, construction
materials and the real estate development sectors, drawing inferences on the drivers
of growth and key points on inter-linkages.
2.29. In this regard, the CSOs 130 sectors of the 2009-10 IO table are aggregated
to 21 broad sectors6. The list of sectors and their aggregation scheme are given in the
table below:

It may be mentioned that sectors in the input-output tables are not additive, as the information contained in the
IO table is not observable. The observable information (which comes from surveys and administrative data)
forms the basis for compiling supply and use tables, which in turn are converted to IO tables through
transformation models and technology assumptions. The sectors in the supply and use tables are additive.

12

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 2.1: Aggregation scheme


Sr No

Proposed IO Sectors - Housing Study

Concordance with 130 sectors

Agriculture incl. Livestock

Forestry and Logging

25

Fishing

26

Mining and Quarrying

Construction related Manufacturing

Other Manufacturing

Residential Construction

Non-Residential Construction

Other Construction

10

Electricity, Water Supply

11

Trade

116

12

Hotel and Restaurants

117

13

Railways

109

14

Transport by Other Means

15

Storage

114

16

Communication

115

17

126

19

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and Business
Services
Banking and Insurance

20

Public administration and defence

18

21
Other Services
Source: NCAER study team

1-24

27-37
55, 56, 62, 64, 69, 74-77, 79-82, 89
38-54, 57-61, 63, 65-68, 70-73, 78,
83-88, 90-105
106
107, 108

110-113

120, 123-125, 127


118, 119
130
121, 122, 128, 129

2.30. Broadly, the sector classification is the same as followed by CSO in their
National Accounts Statements. However, keeping in view the objectives of the study,
some sectors are further disaggregated to capture the inter-linkages of housing
sector. This disaggregation of sectors is as follows:

Manufacturing sector is split into Construction related manufacturing and


Other Manufacturing. The sectors that include Construction related
manufacturing were Furniture and fixtures, wood & wood products, plastic
products, coal tar products, paints, varnishes & lacquers, non-metallic mineral
products, ferrous and non-ferrous metals & products, electrical cables & wires.

Therefore for a condensed IO table, one needs to recompile the supply and use tables at that condensed dimension
and then the transformation models and technology assumptions are applied to get to an aggregated IO table.

13

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Construction sector is divided into residential construction, non-residential


construction and other construction activities. Residential construction
refers to the general construction of residential buildings, carried out on ownaccount or on a fee or contract basis. Non-residential construction is the
construction of non-residential buildings, like schools, offices, and hospitals
etc, carried out on own-account or on a fee or contract basis. All other
construction activities construction and maintenance of roads, rail-beds,
bridges, tunnels, pipelines, rope-ways, ports, harbours, runways, power,
telecommunication and transmission lines, waterways, hydro-electric projects
etc. come under Other Construction.
The NAS sector, Real Estate, Ownership of dwellings and business services is
disaggregated into Real Estate and Ownership of dwellings and business
services.

Hence we arrive at an IO table of 21 broad sectors.


2.31. As indicated in the aggregation scheme, barring the three components of
Construction sector, all other sectors are arrived by aggregated the existing 130
sectors of the detailed IO table. The values for these three components, that is,
residential construction, non-residential construction and other construction, are
obtained by splitting each cell of the row of the total Construction sector in the
proportion of the share of their value of output in total. The values of output are
taken from the NAS.
2.32. The CSOs IO tables do not provide employment information. However,
NCAER while updating the IO table to 2009-10 also included the employment in the
IO table. To arrive at the number of persons employed in each sector, the unit level
data of NSSO large scale survey on Employment and Unemployment for 2009-10
was analysed. The 21 sectors were mapped with the NIC 5-digit codes, the industrial
codes used to identify the sector of engagement of each employed person. The
mapping of 21 sectors with the NIC codes is given in the table below:

14

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 2.2: Mapping between 21 sectors and NIC codes


Sr No

Proposed IO Sectors - Housing Study

Concordance with NIC-2004

Agriculture incl. Livestock

01111-01500

Forestry and Logging

02001-02006

Fishing

05011-05023

Mining and Quarrying

Construction related Manufacturing

Other Manufacturing

Residential Construction

Non-Residential Construction

Other Construction

10

Electricity, Water Supply

11

Trade

12

Hotel and Restaurants

13

Railways

60101-60109

14

Transport by Other Means

60211-63090

15

Storage

63021-63023

16

Communication

64110-64204

17

70101-70200

19

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and Business
Services
Banking and Insurance

20

Public administration and defence

75111-75302

18

21
Other Services
Source: NCAER study team

10101-14299
19202(part), 20101-20299, 23101-23109,
24221-24229, 25201-27209, 27320, 2811128129, 28920-28932, 28939, 28991-28999,
31300, 36101-36103, 37100-37200
15111-15127, 15131-15209, 15315-15429,
15424-15549, 16001-16009, 17111-17134,
17137-19209, 21011-22300, 23201-24219,
24231-25119, 27310, 28131-28910, 28933,
29111-29309, 30001-31200, 31401-35999,
36104-35999, 36104-36933, 36994-36999,
40200, 50404, 52601-52609
45201
45202
45101-45102, 45203-45500
40101-40109, 40300, 41000
50101-50103, 50300, 50401-50403, 50500,
51101-51909, 52110-52599
55101-55109, 55201-55209

71110-74999
65110-67200
80101-80904, 85110-85320, 90001-99000

2.33. Construction, by its nature of activity, generates a large proportion of


informal employment which mostly comprises of casual labour. On the other hand,
construction companies or the factor owners fall into the formal employment
category. Hence, it is worthwhile disaggregating the total employment of all the 21
sectors into formal and informal categories. By doing this, we can not only generate
the total employment coefficients and employment multipliers but also formal and
informal employment coefficients and multipliers.

15

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

2.34. For identifying the formal and informal nature of job, the person employed is
classified accordingly using the information on his/her status of work and the
enterprise in which employed. On the basis of this information, a person is identified
as formal and informal using the mapping given in table below:

Table 2.3: Identification of Formal/Informal workers (EUS)


Enterprise Type
1. Proprietary male
2. Proprietary female
3. Partnership with members of same household
4. Partnership with members of diff household
5. Public sector
6. Public/Private limited company
7. Co-operative societies/trust/other non profit
institutions
8. Employer's households
9. Others
Source: NCAER study team

Formal

Informal

None

All

Status=Regular wage
earner
Status= Regular wage
earner
Status= Regular wage
earner and number of
workers > 5 and job
contract is written and is
for more than 1 year

Status=Others
Status= Others

Rest

2.35. All the employees working in the proprietary and partnership types of
enterprises are considered as informal. Barring the regular wage earners, all others
are considered to be informal in public sector or public ltd. enterprises.

2.36. In rest of the enterprises, like cooperatives, household enterprises etc., those
regular wage earners are considered formal who work in enterprises that employ
more than 5 workers and who have written job contract and the duration of contract
is more than a year. Rest all are considered informal.
Sectoral Aggregates
2.37. Apart from the inter-industry transactions, the input-output table presents
various aggregates for all the sectors, like Gross Value of Output, Gross Fixed Capital
Formation (GFCE) and Indirect taxes. Besides, employment numbers are estimated
using the NSSO survey data. The tables below present the share of each sector in total
for these aggregates.

16

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 2.4: Sectoral share in key aggregates of IO Table (%)


Gross output
at factor cost
1

Agriculture incl. Livestock

Net Capital
Stock

GFCF

Indirect
Taxes on
production

10.83

8.71

9.98

5.00

Forestry and Logging

0.96

0.07

0.16

0.24

Fishing

0.48

0.58

0.32

0.18

1.65

3.91

2.99

0.87

8.59

8.05

7.72

13.81

Mining and Quarrying


Construction related
Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing

26.55

20.22

19.47

44.12

Residential Construction

1.24

0.54

0.49

1.36

Non-Residential Construction

6.71

2.63

2.41

7.83

Other Construction

3.44

1.27

1.16

4.15

10

Electricity, Water Supply

2.09

6.30

6.67

2.19

11

Trade

9.24

6.70

6.60

3.03

12

Hotel and Restaurants

2.10

1.48

1.10

1.45

13

Railways

0.76

1.54

1.66

0.62

14

Transport by Other Means

6.89

2.86

2.29

9.83

15

Storage

0.05

0.09

0.11

0.04

16

Communication

0.95

3.61

1.97

0.64

17

0.24

0.51

0.60

0.15

6.01

14.16

16.52

1.65

19

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and
Business Services
Banking and Insurance

3.11

0.47

0.71

0.70

20

Public administration and defence

3.19

10.08

11.79

0.00

21

Other Services

4.94

6.23

5.27

2.14

100.00

100.00

100.00

100.00

18

Source: NCAERs 21-sector IO Table

17

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 2.5: Sectoral share in employment (%)

Agriculture incl. Livestock

0.86

57.99

54.17

Share of
Informal in
Total
employme
nt (%)
99.89

Forestry and Logging

0.18

0.23

0.23

94.87

Fishing

0.09

0.34

0.33

98.24

2.59

0.45

0.59

70.80

3.27

2.60

2.64

91.71

Mining and Quarrying


Construction related
Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing

12.54

7.68

8.01

89.53

Residential Construction

0.61

7.31

6.86

99.41

Non-Residential Construction

0.13

0.44

0.42

97.86

Other Construction

1.66

4.42

4.24

97.38

10

Electricity, Water Supply

2.72

0.06

0.24

23.38

11

Trade

2.70

8.37

7.99

97.74

12

Hotel and Restaurants

0.46

1.25

1.20

97.41

13

Railways

2.62

0.03

0.20

12.46

14

Transport by Other Means

3.18

3.47

3.45

93.83

15

Storage

0.22

0.02

0.03

57.11

16

Communication

2.77

0.17

0.35

46.44

17

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and
Business Services
Banking and Insurance
Public administration and
defence
Other Services

0.12

0.14

0.14

94.22

4.76

0.71

0.98

67.55

6.71

0.32

0.75

39.82

26.10

0.05

1.79

2.55

25.71

3.94

5.40

68.17

100.00

100.00

100.00

93.31

18
19
20
21

Source: NSSO

66th

Formal
employment

Informal
Employment

Total
employment

Round survey, 2009-10

18

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

2.38. The relative importance of each of these sectors can be assessed by ranking
the sectors in decreasing order of their share in respective aggregates.

Table 2.6 : Sectors rank on share in respective aggregates


Gross
output
at
factor
cost

GFCF

Net
Capital
Stock

Indirec
t Taxes
on
produc
tion

Formal
employ
ment

Inform
al
Emplo
yment

Total
employ
ment

14

Agriculture incl.
Livestock
Forestry and Logging

16

21

20

17

18

15

18

Fishing

19

16

19

18

21

13

16

14

13

12

11

13

15

17

18

12

15

12

10

19

12

14

Mining and Quarrying


Construction related
Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing
Residential
Construction
Non-Residential
Construction
Other Construction

15

14

13

10

Electricity, Water Supply

13

18

17

11

Trade

10

12

Hotel and Restaurants

12

14

15

11

16

10

13

18

13

13

16

11

20

19

11

11

15

Railways
Transport by Other
Means
Storage

21

20

21

20

17

21

21

16

Communication

17

10

12

15

16

15

20

18

17

19

20

17

20

10

10

11

11

19

16

14

14

12

10

21

19

5
6
7
8

14

17

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling
18
and Business Services
19 Banking and Insurance
Public administration
20
and defence
21 Other Services
Source: NCAERs 21-sector IO Table

2.39. Other Manufacturing which refers to all manufacturing sectors excluding


construction related manufacturing ranks first in the share in total value of output,
fixed investment (GFCF), inventory (Net Capital Stock) and Indirect taxes. The rank of
residential construction is 15th among 21 sectors with regard to its share in total
value of output. Its rank in fixed investment and inventory is even lower at 17th and
19

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

18th respectively. However, the sectors share in both total employment and total
informal employment is fourth which means that residential construction sector is
highly labour intensive sector as compared to other sectors. While agriculture
accounts for 54 per cent in total employment, share of residential construction stands
at 6.9 per cent. Excluding agriculture, its share goes up to 15 per cent, next only to
other manufacturing and trade.
2.40. The capital to output ratio (Table 2.7) of residential construction, expressed
as a unit value of capital stock per 100 unit value of output, is 0.61. This means that
for residential construction, Rs. 0.61 lakh of capital stock produces Rs. 1 crore of
output. As compared to this, the capital to output ratio for all the sectors of economy,
put together, is higher at 1.53.
2.41. On the other hand, labour to output ratio of residential construction is the
highest, at 2.34, among all the 21 sectors. The overall labour to output ratio is 0.42.
This means that on an average 0.42 persons are required to produce a lakh unit of
output whereas for residential construction, 2.34 persons are required to produce a
lakh unit of output, accentuating the fact that residential construction is a highly
labour generating sector and is less capital intensive as compared to other sectors of
the economy.
2.42. Further, as given in Table 2.5, the share of informal employment in total
employment in residential construction is 99.41 per cent, second highest share
among all the sectors, next only to agriculture. This share in overall employment for
the economy is 93.31 per cent.

20

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 2.7 : Capital and Labour to output ratios

Capital to Output Ratio


(units of capital per 100
units of output)

Labour to Output Ratio


(persons per lakh unit of
output)

Agriculture incl. Livestock

1.41

2.11

Forestry and Logging

0.26

0.10

Fishing

1.01

0.29

2.78

0.15

1.38

0.13

Mining and Quarrying


Construction related
Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing

1.12

0.13

Residential Construction

0.61

2.34

Non-Residential Construction

0.55

0.03

Other Construction

0.52

0.52

10

Electricity, Water Supply

4.89

0.05

11

Trade

1.09

0.36

12

Hotel and Restaurants

0.80

0.24

13

Railways

3.35

0.11

14

Transport by Other Means

0.51

0.21

15

Storage

3.36

0.29

16

Communication

3.19

0.15

17

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and
Business Services
Banking and Insurance
Public administration and
defence
Other Services

3.84

0.25

4.21

0.07

0.35

0.10

5.65

0.24

1.63

0.46

1.53

0.42

18
19
20
21

Overall
Source: NCAERs 21-sector IO Table

Estimates of Inter-Industry Linkages


2.43. Using the Leontief Inverse matrix, various multipliers can be obtained like
output multiplier, employment multiplier and income multiplier, which gives an
estimate of direct and indirect effects resulting from change in final demand of a
sector, hence referred as Type I multipliers. Further, the extended Leontief Inverse
Matrix, where households are included in the analysis and considered a separate
sector, gives the measure of direct, indirect and induced effects resulting from change
in final demand of a sector, referred as Type II multipliers. In the extended Leontief

21

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Inverse Matrix, a row and column are added for compensation of employees (CoE)
and private final consumption expenditure coefficients respectively.

2.44.
A=

The structure of the extended technical coefficients matrix is as follows:


AII
AHI

AIH
AHH

where,
AII is the i X j technical coefficient matrix A.
AIH is the column vector of household expenditure coefficients and refers to the
amount of industry i required per unit of total household income
AHI is the row vector of income coefficients and refer to the income paid to
households per unit of output of industry i (compensation of employees divided by
the total output of the industry)
AHH is the household expenditure per unit of household income (this cell is set to
zero)

2.45.
The multipliers obtained using Leontief Inverse Matrix and extended
Leontief Inverse Matrix are described in the following sections.
Output Multiplier
2.46. As mentioned in the previous section, the column sum of the Leontief Inverse
Matrix, called Type I output multiplier, is the measure of inter-industry linkages and
gives an estimate of direct and indirect effects of an industry on the overall economy.
Similarly, the column sum of the extended Leontief Inverse Matrix (excluding the
element of row for compensation to employees), called Type II output multiplier, is
also the measure of inter-industry linkages where household is included as an added
industry. The following table presents the output multiplier of each of the 21
industries. Also given are sectors CoE to output ratio (CoE/Q). It should be noted that
sectors with high CoE/Q ratio have high values of Type II multipliers as the
proportion of household income in total output is high and therefore, the changes in
their final demand gets translated into increased household income faster than
sectors with low CoE/Q ratio.

22

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 2.8: Output Multiplier

CoE/Q

Type I Output
Multiplier

Type II Output
Multiplier

Agriculture incl. Livestock

0.1160

1.6042

2.8481

Forestry and Logging

0.0512

1.3337

1.9270

Fishing

0.0838

1.3046

2.0593

0.2094

1.5257

3.3793

0.0398

2.5887

4.0237

Mining and Quarrying


Construction related
Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing

0.0479

2.6369

4.2071

Residential Construction

0.2689

2.3322

5.1148

Non-Residential Construction

0.2419

2.4174

5.0807

Other Construction

0.2271

2.4641

5.0621

10

Electricity, Water Supply

0.1829

2.2257

4.6008

11

Trade

0.1239

1.4037

2.5706

12

Hotel and Restaurants

0.0918

2.2477

3.7982

13

Railways

0.4334

1.8970

5.5860

14

Transport by Other Means

0.0932

2.3670

3.9168

15

Storage

0.2031

1.9180

4.0741

16

Communication

0.2886

1.5719

3.9428

17

0.0207

1.4207

1.8313

0.0610

1.3734

2.1414

19

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and
Business Services
Banking and Insurance

0.2566

1.3211

3.3497

20

Public administration and defence

0.8880

1.0000

6.9693

0.4479

1.4728

4.9103

18

21
Other Services
Source: NCAER computation

2.47. An output multiplier of 2.33 for residential construction means that a unit
increase in final demand for residential construction is expected to result in an
overall increase in the economys output by 2.33 units owing to its inter-industry
linkages with other sectors of the economy. With induced effects, the overall increase
in economys output is expected to be 5.11 units.
2.48. The table below gives the ranking of the 21 sectors with respect to both Type
I and Type II output multipliers.

23

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 2.9: Sectors ranking on Output multiplier


Rank on Type I
Output
Multiplier

Rank on Type II
Output
Multiplier

Agriculture incl. Livestock

11

16

Forestry and Logging

18

20

Fishing

20

19

Mining and Quarrying

13

14

Construction related Manufacturing

10

Other Manufacturing

Residential Construction

Non-Residential Construction

Other Construction

10

Electricity, Water Supply

11

Trade

16

17

12

Hotel and Restaurants

13

13

Railways

10

14

Transport by Other Means

12

15

Storage

16

Communication

12

11

17

15

21

17

18

19

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and Business
Services
Banking and Insurance

19

15

20

Public administration and defence

21

14

18

21
Other Services
Source: NCAER computation

2.49. Residential construction occupies sixth and third positions respectively


when Type I and Type II output multipliers of all the 21 sectors are arranged in
decreasing order. The highest Type I output multiplier is that of Other
manufacturing followed by Construction related manufacturing and then Other
construction and Non-residential construction. Hence, construction, as a whole,
has strong backward linkages with other sectors of the economy. An increase in final
demand in these sectors triggers economic activity in other sectors much faster, due
to their stronger spill-over effects. On the other hand, Type II output multiplier is the
highest for Public Administration and Defence followed by Railways which have
high income (CoE) to output ratios.
24

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

2.50. The following table presents the increase in output in each sector with a unit
increase in final demand of residential construction. In other words, this table
presents the break-up of the output multiplier (2.33) of residential construction.

Table 2.10: Output multiplier of Residential Construction by sectors


Unit increase in sectoral output with one unit increase in
final demand of Residential Construction
Type I Output Multiplier

Type II Output Multiplier

Agriculture incl. Livestock

0.0533

0.4864

Forestry and Logging

0.0452

0.0690

Fishing

0.0002

0.0223

Mining and Quarrying

0.1164

0.2521

Construction related Manufacturing

0.4378

0.5960

Other Manufacturing

0.2063

0.9908

Residential Construction

1.0136

1.0175

Non-Residential Construction

0.0737

0.0948

Other Construction

0.0378

0.0486

10

Electricity, Water Supply

0.0493

0.1074

11

Trade

0.1288

0.3802

12

Hotel and Restaurants

0.0118

0.0960

13

Railways

0.0082

0.0327

14

Transport by Other Means

0.0679

0.2997

15

Storage

0.0007

0.0020

16

Communication

0.0029

0.0374

17

0.0015

0.0122

0.0187

0.2224

19

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and
Business Services
Banking and Insurance

0.0488

0.1496

20

Public administration and defence

0.0000

0.0000

21

Other Services

0.0093

0.1974

2.3322

5.1148

18

Overall
Source: NCAER computation

2.51. The table suggests that when the final demand of residential construction
increases by one unit, then the overall increase in total output of the economy is led
by additional economic activity spurred in other sectors due to inter-industry
linkages. For example, owing to direct and indirect effects, Construction related
manufacturing increases its output by 0.4378 units, other manufacturing by
25

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

0.2063, mining & quarrying by 0.1164, and so on, the aggregate Type I increase
being of 2.3322 units. The second column of the table presents the unit increase in
output on the back of direct, indirect and induced effects. The aggregate increase in
output of 5.1148 units is led by 0.9908 units increase in other manufacturing,
0.5960 units in construction related manufacturing and so on.

Employment Multiplier
2.52. As mentioned earlier, Type I employment multiplier for jth sector is the ratio
of the total (direct + indirect) employment changes per rupees change of final
demand in sector j to the direct employment change per rupees change of final
demand in sector j. Type II employment multiplier for jth sector is the ratio of the
total (direct + indirect + induced) employment changes per rupees change of final
demand in sector j to the direct employment change per rupees change of final
demand in sector j.

2.53. The direct employment change per rupees change in final demand in sector j
is obtained from jth sector's employment to output ratio or direct employment
coefficient. In case of Type I employment multiplier, the total employment change per
rupees change in final demand in a sector j (total linkage coefficient comprising direct
and indirect effects) is estimated by multiplying the row vector of the employment
coefficient with the Leontief Inverse matrix. For Type II employment multiplier, the
row vector of the employment coefficient is multiplied by the extended Leontief
Inverse matrix to arrive at total linkage coefficient comprising of direct, indirect and
induced effects.
2.54. The Type I and Type II employment multipliers are also obtained for formal
and informal types of employments. The employment coefficients and employment
multipliers for all the 21 sectors are given in the following tables:

26

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 2.11 : Direct Employment Coefficient

S.
No.

Sectors

Direct Employment coefficient (persons employed per lakh


unit of output)
Formal

Informal

Total

Agriculture incl. Livestock

0.0022

2.1081

2.1103

Forestry and Logging

0.0052

0.0959

0.1010

Fishing

0.0050

0.2805

0.2855

0.0443

0.1075

0.1518

0.0107

0.1189

0.1297

Mining and Quarrying


Construction related
Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing

0.0133

0.1139

0.1272

Residential Construction

0.0138

2.3266

2.3404

Non-Residential Construction

0.0006

0.0256

0.0261

Other Construction

0.0136

0.5061

0.5198

10

Electricity, Water Supply

0.0367

0.0112

0.0479

11

Trade

0.0082

0.3566

0.3649

12

Hotel and Restaurants

0.0062

0.2338

0.2401

13

Railways

0.0976

0.0139

0.1114

14

Transport by Other Means

0.0130

0.1981

0.2111

15

Storage

0.1229

0.1636

0.2865

16

Communication

0.0823

0.0714

0.1537

17

0.0144

0.2349

0.2493

0.0223

0.0465

0.0689

19

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and
Business Services
Banking and Insurance

0.0609

0.0403

0.1012

20

Public administration and defence

0.2304

0.0060

0.2364

21

Other Services

0.1468

0.3143

0.4611

0.0282

0.3936

0.4218

18

Overall
Source: NCAER computation

27

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 2.12 : Total (Direct + Indirect) Employment Linkage Coefficient


S.
No.

Sectors

Total (Direct + Indirect) employment linkage coefficient


Formal

Informal

Total

Agriculture incl. Livestock

0.0121

2.5362

2.5482

Forestry and Logging

0.0119

0.2059

0.2178

Fishing

0.0101

0.3678

0.3779

0.0575

0.2481

0.3056

0.0441

0.5179

0.5620

Mining and Quarrying


Construction related
Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing

0.0471

0.7440

0.7910

Residential Construction

0.0372

2.6533

2.6905

Non-Residential Construction

0.0255

0.3732

0.3987

Other Construction

0.0394

0.8652

0.9046

10

Electricity, Water Supply

0.0696

0.2760

0.3456

11

Trade

0.0179

0.4779

0.4958

12

Hotel and Restaurants

0.0212

1.4651

1.4863

13

Railways

0.1178

0.2419

0.3597

14

Transport by Other Means

0.0360

0.7771

0.8131

15

Storage

0.1445

0.3738

0.5184

16

Communication

0.0951

0.2292

0.3243

17

0.0243

0.3740

0.3983

0.0329

0.1509

0.1838

19

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and
Business Services
Banking and Insurance

0.0692

0.1391

0.2084

20

Public administration and defence

0.2304

0.0060

0.2364

0.1600

0.4796

0.6396

18

21
Other Services
Source: NCAER computation

2.55. The total employment linkage coefficient calculates the impact on


employment throughout the economy arising from a change in final demand for a
sector of 1 unit. According to Table 2.12, an increase of Rs. 1 lakh in final demand in
residential construction is expected to generate a total of 2.69 jobs in the economy
owing to the sectors direct and indirect linkages. Of these, 2.34 jobs are created as a
direct effect (Table 2.11). Hence, for every one job directly created in residential
construction, 1.15 additional jobs are created in the economy (Table 2.13).
2.56. As is evident, residential construction leads all other sectors, with the
highest value of direct and total employment linkage coefficient of 2.34 and 2.69
respectively. However, when it comes to Type I employment multiplier (ratio of total
employment linkage coefficient to direct employment coefficient), non-residential
28

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

construction notches the highest position, with the value of 15.25. This means that a
total of 15.25 jobs are created in the economy as a result of an increase in final
demand in non-residential construction which is enough to create one job in this
sector. In other words, for every one job directly created in non-residential
construction, 15.25 new jobs are created in the economy. Also, for every one formal
job directly created, 45.61 new formal jobs are created in the economy.
Table 2.13 : Type I Employment Multiplier

S.
No.

Sectors

Type I employment multiplier


Formal

Informal

Total

Agriculture incl. Livestock

5.4017

1.2031

1.2075

Forestry and Logging

2.2890

2.1482

2.1555

Fishing

2.0190

1.3113

1.3237

1.2965

2.3078

2.0125

4.1067

4.3540

4.3335

Mining and Quarrying


Construction related
Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing

3.5336

6.5340

6.2198

Residential Construction

2.6961

1.1404

1.1496

Non-Residential Construction

45.6094

14.5913

15.2546

Other Construction

2.8891

1.7095

1.7404

10

Electricity, Water Supply

1.8965

24.6384

7.2130

11

Trade

2.1731

1.3400

1.3589

12

Hotel and Restaurants

3.4037

6.2657

6.1914

13

Railways

1.2074

17.4237

3.2279

14

Transport by Other Means

2.7686

3.9232

3.8520

15

Storage

1.1763

2.2853

1.8096

16

Communication

1.1545

3.2109

2.1095

17

1.6869

1.5920

1.5975

1.4718

3.2441

2.6690

19

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and
Business Services
Banking and Insurance

1.1368

3.4543

2.0595

20

Public administration and defence

1.0000

1.0000

1.0000

1.0902

1.5260

1.3872

18

21
Other Services
Source: NCAER computation

2.57. The following tables present the impact of induced effects besides direct and
indirect effects. Table 2.14 depicts the total (direct + indirect + induced) employment
linkage coefficient and Table 2.15 presents the Type II employment multiplier.

29

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 2.14: Total (Direct + Indirect + Induced) Employment Linkage Coefficient


S.
No.

Sectors

Total (Direct + Indirect + Induced) employment linkage


coefficient
Formal

Informal

Total

Agriculture incl. Livestock

0.0439

3.1144

3.1583

Forestry and Logging

0.0270

0.4817

0.5087

Fishing

0.0294

0.7186

0.7480

0.1049

1.1097

1.2146

0.0808

1.1849

1.2657

Mining and Quarrying


Construction related
Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing

0.0872

1.4738

1.5610

Residential Construction

0.1084

3.9467

4.0551

Non-Residential Construction

0.0936

1.6111

1.7047

Other Construction

0.1058

2.0728

2.1786

10

Electricity, Water Supply

0.1304

1.3799

1.5103

11

Trade

0.0478

1.0203

1.0681

12

Hotel and Restaurants

0.0609

2.1857

2.2466

13

Railways

0.2122

1.9566

2.1687

14

Transport by Other Means

0.0757

1.4974

1.5731

15

Storage

0.1997

1.3760

1.5757

16

Communication

0.1557

1.3312

1.4870

17

0.0348

0.5648

0.5997

0.0525

0.5079

0.5604

19

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and
Business Services
Banking and Insurance

0.1211

1.0820

1.2031

20

Public administration and defence

0.3831

2.7806

3.1637

0.2479

2.0774

2.3253

18

21
Other Services
Source: NCAER computation

30

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 2.15 : Type II Employment Multiplier

S.
No.

Sectors

Type II employment multiplier


Formal

Informal

Total

Agriculture incl. Livestock

19.66

1.48

1.50

Forestry and Logging

5.22

5.03

5.03

Fishing

5.87

2.56

2.62

2.37

10.32

8.00

7.52

9.96

9.76

Mining and Quarrying


Construction related
Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing

6.55

12.94

12.27

Residential Construction

7.85

1.70

1.73

Non-Residential Construction

167.51

62.99

65.22

Other Construction

7.76

4.10

4.19

10

Electricity, Water Supply

3.55

123.19

31.52

11

Trade

5.79

2.86

2.93

12

Hotel and Restaurants

9.77

9.35

9.36

13

Railways

2.17

140.91

19.46

14

Transport by Other Means

5.81

7.56

7.45

15

Storage

1.63

8.41

5.50

16

Communication

1.89

18.65

9.67

17

2.42

2.40

2.41

2.35

10.92

8.14

19

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and
Business Services
Banking and Insurance

1.99

26.86

11.89

20

Public administration and defence

1.66

461.74

13.38

1.69

6.61

5.04

18

21
Other Services
Source: NCAER computation

Income Multiplier

2.58. Like employment coefficient, income coefficient is the income change per
rupees change in final demand in sector j and is obtained from jth sector's income
(compensation to employees) to output ratio. In the case of Type I income effects, the
total income change per rupees change in final demand in a sector j (total income
effects comprising direct and indirect effects) is estimated by multiplying the row
vector of the income coefficient with the Leontief Inverse matrix. For Type II income
effects, the row vector of the income coefficient is multiplied by the extended Leontief
31

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Inverse matrix to arrive at total linkage effects comprising of direct, indirect and
induced effects.

2.59. Type I income multiplier for jth sector is the ratio of the total (direct +
indirect) income change per rupees change of final demand in sector j to the direct
income change per rupees change of final demand in sector j. Type II income
multiplier for jth sector is the ratio of the total (direct + indirect + induced) income
changes per rupees change of final demand in sector j to the direct income change per
rupees change of final demand in sector j. The income linkages and multipliers are
given in the tables below:

Table 2.16: Type I Income linkages


Type I
Total Income (Direct +
Indirect) linkage

Income Multiplier

Agriculture incl. Livestock

0.1851

1.5959

Forestry and Logging

0.0883

1.7236

Fishing

0.1123

1.3405

0.2758

1.3168

0.2135

5.3596

Mining and Quarrying


Construction related
Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing

0.2336

4.8742

Residential Construction

0.4140

1.5395

Non-Residential Construction

0.3962

1.6382

Other Construction

0.3865

1.7022

10

Electricity, Water Supply

0.3533

1.9315

11

Trade

0.1736

1.4016

12

Hotel and Restaurants

0.2307

2.5126

13

Railways

0.5488

1.2661

14

Transport by Other Means

0.2305

2.4727

15

Storage

0.3207

1.5792

16

Communication

0.3527

1.2221

17

0.0611

2.9519

0.1142

1.8730

19

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and
Business Services
Banking and Insurance

0.3018

1.1759

20

Public administration and defence

0.8880

1.0000

0.5114

1.1416

18

21
Other Services
Source: NCAER computation

32

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 2.17: Type II Income linkages


Type II
Total Income (Direct +
Indirect + Induced)
Income Multiplier
linkage
1

Agriculture incl. Livestock

0.3411

2.9413

Forestry and Logging

0.1627

3.1766

Fishing

0.2069

2.4705

0.5082

2.4270

0.3934

9.8778

Mining and Quarrying


Construction related
Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing

0.4305

8.9833

Residential Construction

0.7629

2.8373

Non-Residential Construction

0.7302

3.0192

Other Construction

0.7123

3.1371

10

Electricity, Water Supply

0.6512

3.5598

11

Trade

0.3199

2.5832

12

Hotel and Restaurants

0.4251

4.6308

13

Railways

1.0114

2.3334

14

Transport by Other Means

0.4249

4.5573

15

Storage

0.5911

2.9105

16

Communication

0.6500

2.2523

17

0.1126

5.4405

0.2106

3.4520

19

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and
Business Services
Banking and Insurance

0.5562

2.1672

20

Public administration and defence

1.6366

1.8430

0.9425

2.1041

18

21
Other Services
Source: NCAER computation

2.60. For residential construction, Type I income multiplier of 1.5395 indicates


the total (direct + indirect) increase in income that results from a unit change in
income in this sector. With induced effects included, this multiplier goes up to 2.8373.

Tax Multiplier

2.61. Tax multiplier gives the extra indirect tax (on production) collected on
account of increase in production led by increase in final demand. Indirect tax, paid
by industries, is a row in the IO table. Tax coefficient for jth sector is its tax to output
ratio. In the case of Type I tax effects, the total change in tax collection per rupees
change in final demand in a sector j (total effects comprising direct and indirect
33

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

effects) is estimated by multiplying the row vector of the tax coefficient with the
Leontief Inverse matrix. For Type II tax effects, the row vector of the tax coefficient is
multiplied by the extended Leontief Inverse matrix to arrive at total linkage effects
comprising of direct, indirect and induced effects.

2.62. Type I tax multiplier for jth sector is the ratio of the total (direct + indirect)
tax change per rupees change of final demand in sector j to the direct tax change per
rupees change of final demand in sector j. Type II tax multiplier for jth sector is the
ratio of the total (direct + indirect + induced) tax changes per rupees change of final
demand in sector j to the direct tax change per rupees change of final demand in
sector j. The tax linkages and multipliers are given in the tables below:

Table 2.18: Type I Tax linkages


Type I
Tax to Output
ratio

Total Tax
(Direct +
Indirect)
linkage

Tax Multiplier

Agriculture incl. Livestock

0.0106

0.0234

2.2112

Forestry and Logging

0.0058

0.0140

2.4254

Fishing

0.0084

0.0164

1.9436

0.0121

0.0252

2.0787

0.0368

0.0767

2.0831

Mining and Quarrying


Construction related
Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing

0.0381

0.0773

2.0316

Residential Construction

0.0251

0.0600

2.3851

Non-Residential Construction

0.0267

0.0638

2.3851

Other Construction

0.0276

0.0659

2.3852

10

Electricity, Water Supply

0.0240

0.0523

2.1747

11

Trade

0.0075

0.0167

2.2263

12

Hotel and Restaurants

0.0158

0.0395

2.4925

13

Railways

0.0188

0.0419

2.2273

14

Transport by Other Means

0.0327

0.0664

2.0334

15

Storage

0.0176

0.0403

2.2856

16

Communication

0.0155

0.0308

1.9859

17

0.0140

0.0203

1.4540

0.0063

0.0137

2.1759

19

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and
Business Services
Banking and Insurance

0.0052

0.0122

2.3585

20

Public administration and defence

0.0000

0.0000

0.0099

0.0207

2.0893

18

21
Other Services
Source: NCAER computation

34

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 2.19: Type II Tax linkages


Type II
Total Tax (Direct +
Indirect) linkage

Tax Multiplier

Agriculture incl. Livestock

0.0503

4.7540

Forestry and Logging

0.0269

4.6469

Fishing

0.0327

3.8805

0.0653

5.3927

0.1078

2.9264

Mining and Quarrying


Construction related
Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing

0.1113

2.9246

Residential Construction

0.1202

4.7808

Non-Residential Construction

0.1214

4.5402

Other Construction

0.1221

4.4204

10

Electricity, Water Supply

0.1037

4.3142

11

Trade

0.0420

5.5938

12

Hotel and Restaurants

0.0730

4.6127

13

Railways

0.1218

6.4699

14

Transport by Other Means

0.1000

3.0603

15

Storage

0.0870

4.9314

16

Communication

0.0821

5.2970

17

0.0292

2.0896

0.0303

4.8167

19

Real Estate Services


Ownership of Dwelling and
Business Services
Banking and Insurance

0.0561

10.8343

20

Public administration and defence

0.1292

0.0951

9.5876

18

21
Other Services
Source: NCAER computation

2.63. For residential construction, tax to output ratio is 0.0251, that is, for every
unit output, 0.0251 units of indirect taxes are paid (as a direct effect). The sectors
Type I tax linkage coefficient is 0.06. This means that with one unit increase in final
demand in this sector, a total of 0.06 units of tax are collected in the economy, owing
to the sectors inter-linkages. With induced effects included, this linkage coefficient
goes up to 0.1202.

35

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

36

National Council of Applied Economic Research

3.

April, 2014

IMPACT OF HOUSING DEMAND ON ECONOMY

3.1.
The aim of the study is to assess the impact of increase in demand in the
housing sector (through investment or expenditure) on the overall GDP and
Employment of the Indian Economy. Having obtained the output and employment
multipliers, these objectives can be achieved through the multiplier analysis by
carrying out some simulations. This chapter presents these simulations and help in
analysing the relationship between increase in demand in a sector on subsequent
changes occurring in the overall production and employment generation.
Simulation 1: 10% increase in final demand of residential construction
3.2.
Since residential construction is the closest proxy for housing sector, first
simulation examines the impact of a 10 per cent increase in its final demand on the
overall GDP and employment. In absolute value terms, final demand of residential
construction is Rs. 1.28 lakh crore. A 10 per cent increase amounts to an increase by
Rs. 0.128 lakh crore in its final demand. The estimates of direct and indirect increase
in output and employment of all the 21 sectors, resulting from 10% increase in final
demand of residential construction are given in Table 3.1. This increase refers to
the Type I increase or the impact of direct and indirect effects. Type II impact is
shown in Table 3.2.
3.3.
The table suggests that a 10% increase in final demand in residential
construction leads to an increase in its own production by 8.26% and the overall
production or output of the economy gets a boost by 0.24% owing to the interlinkages with other sectors of the economy. The GDP (obtained using the GDP to
output ratio from the IO table) increases by 0.2 per cent. In absolute value terms, the
GDP at factor cost increases by over Rs. 12 thousand crore.
3.4.
Further, a 10% increase in final demand in residential construction
generates 34.4 lakh new jobs in the economy, an increase of 0.64 per cent. The overall
household income steps up by Rs. 5300 crore, equivalent to an increase of 0.27 per
cent. And an additional indirect tax worth Rs. 768 crore are expected to be paid by
the industries, on account of increased production. The sectoral increases in these
parameters are presented in Table 3.2. Similar interpretation can be done for the
Type II impact, given in Table 3.3. It can be checked that the absolute increase in each
parameter is equal to the product of the absolute increase in final demand of
residential construction and the respective multiplier.

37

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 3.1: Type I impact of a 10% increase in Final Demand in residential


construction on the economy
(Rs. lakh)
Type I effects

Output
Original

Agriculture incl. Livestock

Forestry and Logging

Fishing

Increased

Absolute
increase

%
increase

13,74,65,395

13,75,33,629

68234

0.05

1,21,35,201

1,21,93,036

57835

0.48

61,09,700

61,09,932

232

0.00

Mining and Quarrying

2,09,50,522

2,10,99,531

149009

0.71

Construction related
Manufacturing

10,90,36,600

10,95,97,016

560416

0.51

Other Manufacturing

33,71,47,774

33,74,11,815

264041

0.08

Residential Construction

1,57,08,719

1,70,06,264

1297545

8.26

Non-Residential Construction

8,51,46,005

8,52,40,410

94405

0.11

Other Construction

4,36,82,177

4,37,30,609

48432

0.11

10

Electricity, Water Supply

2,65,20,746

2,65,83,873

63127

0.24

11

Trade

11,73,30,313

11,74,95,224

164910

0.14

12

Hotel and Restaurants

2,66,84,675

2,66,99,792

15117

0.06

13

Railways

96,24,328

96,34,886

10557

0.11

14

Transport by Other Means

8,75,15,741

8,76,02,669

86928

0.10

15

Storage

6,39,577

6,40,435

858

0.13

16

Communication

1,20,30,753

1,20,34,404

3651

0.03

17

Real Estate Services

30,44,536

30,46,478

1942

0.06

18

Ownership of Dwelling and


Business Services

7,62,71,845

7,62,95,726

23881

0.03

19

Banking and Insurance

3,94,61,718

3,95,24,199

62482

0.16

20

Public administration and


defence

4,05,63,100

4,05,63,100

0.00

21

Other Services

6,27,18,121

6,27,29,987

11866

0.02

1,26,97,87,544

1,27,27,73,013

2985469

0.24

GDP at factor cost (Rs. Lakh)

60,91,48,501

61,03,71,786

1223285

0.20

Employment (numbers)

53,55,39,392

53,89,83,636

3444244

0.64

Income - CoE (Rs. Lakh)

19,34,17,100

19,39,47,011

529911

0.27

Indirect Tax (Rs. Lakh)

2,90,84,726

2,91,61,486

76759

0.26

Total Output (Rs. Lakh)

Source: NCAER computation

38

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 3.2: Sectoral increase (Type I) in various parameters following


Simulation 1
(Rs. lakh)
Type I effects

Increase in
Employment
(in number)

Value Added

CoE

Indirect Tax

Agriculture incl. Livestock

46,905

1,43,998

7912

723

Forestry and Logging

48,813

5,843

2962

334

Fishing

199

66

19

Mining and Quarrying

1,11,994

22,625

31204

1804

Construction related
Manufacturing

1,26,832

72,679

22322

20641

Other Manufacturing

49,572

33,579

12653

10049

Residential Construction

5,04,753

30,36,734

348894

32621

Non-Residential Construction

33,034

2,467

22832

2525

Other Construction

15,910

25,174

10997

1338

10

Electricity, Water Supply

24,968

3,025

11548

1517

11

Trade

1,31,361

60,170

20425

1237

12

Hotel and Restaurants

4,981

3,629

1388

239

13

Railways

6,386

1,177

4576

199

14

Transport by Other Means

32,291

18,350

8105

2839

15

Storage

508

246

174

15

16

Communication

2,726

561

1054

57

17

Real Estate Services

1,411

484

40

27

18

Ownership of Dwelling and


Business Services

19,053

1,644

1457

150

19

Banking and Insurance

52,513

6,321

16035

324

20

Public administration and defence

21

Other Services

9,076

5,471

5315

118

12,23,285

34,44,244

529911

76759

Overall

Source: NCAER computation

39

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 3.3: Type II impact of a 10% increase in Final Demand in residential


construction on the economy
(Rs. lakh)
Type II effects

Output
Original

Increased

Absolute
increase

%
increase

Agriculture incl. Livestock

13,74,65,395

13,80,84,862

619468

0.45

Forestry and Logging

1,21,35,201

1,22,23,089

87888

0.72

Fishing

61,09,700

61,38,142

28442

0.47

Mining and Quarrying

2,09,50,522

2,12,71,561

321039

1.53

Construction related
Manufacturing

10,90,36,600

10,97,95,740

759140

0.70

Other Manufacturing

33,71,47,774

33,84,09,657

1261884

0.37

Residential Construction

1,57,08,719

1,70,04,646

1295927

8.25

Non-Residential Construction

8,51,46,005

8,52,66,740

120735

0.14

Other Construction

4,36,82,177

4,37,44,117

61940

0.14

10

Electricity, Water Supply

2,65,20,746

2,66,57,598

136852

0.52

11

Trade

11,73,30,313

11,78,14,600

484287

0.41

12

Hotel and Restaurants

2,66,84,675

2,68,06,975

122300

0.46

13

Railways

96,24,328

96,66,010

41682

0.43

14

Transport by Other Means

8,75,15,741

8,78,97,510

381769

0.44

15

Storage

6,39,577

6,42,122

2545

0.40

16

Communication

1,20,30,753

1,20,78,435

47682

0.40

17

Real Estate Services

30,44,536

30,60,125

15589

0.51

18

Ownership of Dwelling and


Business Services

7,62,71,845

7,65,55,106

283260

0.37

19

Banking and Insurance

3,94,61,718

3,96,52,315

190598

0.48

20

Public administration and


defence

4,05,63,100

4,05,63,100

0.00

21

Other Services

6,27,18,121

6,29,69,569

251448

0.40

1,26,97,87,544

1,27,63,02,019

6514475

0.51

GDP at factor cost (Rs. Lakh)

60,91,48,501

61,21,63,773

3015272

0.49

Employment (numbers)

53,55,39,392

54,07,04,180

5164788

0.96

Income - CoE (Rs. Lakh)

19,34,17,100

19,43,88,799

971698

0.50

Indirect Tax (Rs. Lakh)

2,90,84,726

2,92,37,808

153082

0.53

Total Output (Rs. Lakh)

Source: NCAER computation

40

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 3.4: Sectoral increase (Type II) in various parameters following Simulation 1
(Rs. lakh)
Type I effects

Increase in
Employment
(in number)

Value Added

CoE

Indirect Tax

Agriculture incl. Livestock

4,25,832

13,07,293

71830

6559

Forestry and Logging

74,177

8,880

4500

508

Fishing

24,376

8,121

2382

240

Mining and Quarrying

2,41,291

48,745

67228

3887

Construction related
Manufacturing

1,71,806

98,452

30237

27960

Other Manufacturing

2,36,909

1,60,479

60470

48027

Residential Construction

5,04,123

30,32,946

348459

32580

Non-Residential Construction

42,247

3,156

29200

3229

Other Construction

20,348

32,195

14064

1711

10

Electricity, Water Supply

54,127

6,557

25034

3288

11

Trade

3,85,762

1,76,700

59981

3633

12

Hotel and Restaurants

40,299

29,358

11227

1936

13

Railways

25,213

4,645

18067

784

14

Transport by Other Means

1,41,813

80,589

35594

12470

15

Storage

1,507

729

517

45

16

Communication

35,606

7,331

13762

739

17

Real Estate Services

11,328

3,887

323

218

18

Ownership of Dwelling and


Business Services

2,25,992

19,506

17278

1783

19

Banking and Insurance

1,60,190

19,282

48914

987

20

Public administration and defence

21

Other Services

1,92,325

1,15,937

112631

2495

30,15,272

51,64,788

9,71,698

1,53,082

Overall

Source: NCAER computation

Simulation 2: An increase of Rs. 1 lakh crore in final demand of residential


construction

3.5.
The resultant increase in each parameter is the product of Rs. 1 lakh crore
with the respective multiplier. The impact (Type I and Type II) on output GDP,
employment, household income and tax is presented in Table 3.3 and 3.4 below:
41

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 3.5: Type I impact of an increase of Rs. 1 lakh crore in Final Demand in
residential construction on the economy
(Rs. lakh)
Type I effects

Output
Absolute
increase

%
increase

Original

Increased

13,74,65,395

13,79,98,378

532983

0.39

1,21,35,201

1,25,86,989

451788

3.72

Agriculture incl. Livestock

Forestry and Logging

Fishing

61,09,700

61,11,508

1808

0.03

Mining and Quarrying

2,09,50,522

2,21,14,545

1164024

5.56

Construction related
Manufacturing

10,90,36,600

11,34,14,444

4377844

4.02

Other Manufacturing

33,71,47,774

33,92,10,481

2062707

0.61

Residential Construction

1,57,08,719

2,58,44,775

10136056

64.53

Non-Residential Construction

8,51,46,005

8,58,83,470

737465

0.87

Other Construction

4,36,82,177

4,40,60,516

378339

0.87

10

Electricity, Water Supply

2,65,20,746

2,70,13,882

493136

1.86

11

Trade

11,73,30,313

11,86,18,559

1288246

1.10

12

Hotel and Restaurants

2,66,84,675

2,68,02,764

118089

0.44

13

Railways

14

Transport by Other Means

15

Storage

16

Communication

17

Real Estate Services

18

Ownership of Dwelling and


Business Services

19

96,24,328

97,06,800

82472

0.86

8,75,15,741

8,81,94,807

679066

0.78

6,39,577

6,46,280

6703

1.05

1,20,30,753

1,20,59,273

28520

0.24

30,44,536

30,59,705

15170

0.50

7,62,71,845

7,64,58,391

186546

0.24

Banking and Insurance

3,94,61,718

3,99,49,806

488089

1.24

20

Public administration and


defence

4,05,63,100

4,05,63,100

0.00

21

Other Services

6,27,18,121

6,28,10,813

92692

0.15

1,26,97,87,544

1,29,31,09,285

23321741

1.84

GDP at factor cost (Rs. Lakh)

60,91,48,501

61,87,04,460

9555959

1.57

Employment (numbers)

53,55,39,392

56,24,44,782

26905390

5.02

Income - CoE (Rs. Lakh)

19,34,17,100

19,75,56,614

4139514

2.14

Indirect Tax (Rs. Lakh)

2,90,84,726

2,96,84,355

599628

2.06

Total Output (Rs. Lakh)

Source: NCAER computation

42

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 3.6: Sectoral increase (Type I) in various parameters following


Simulation 2
(Rs. lakh)
Type I effects

Increase in
Employment
(in number)

Value Added
1

Agriculture incl. Livestock

Forestry and Logging

Fishing

CoE

Indirect Tax

3,66,381

11,24,781

61802

5644

3,81,309

45,647

23134

2611

1,550

516

151

15

Mining and Quarrying

8,74,873

1,76,740

243757

14093

Construction related
Manufacturing

9,90,781

5,67,755

174373

161244

Other Manufacturing

3,87,258

2,62,324

98846

78506

Residential Construction

39,42,984

2,37,22,103

2725459

254826

Non-Residential Construction

2,58,051

19,275

178360

19726

Other Construction

1,24,288

1,96,649

85903

10453

10

Electricity, Water Supply

1,95,044

23,629

90208

11849

11

Trade

10,26,161

4,70,037

159556

9663

12

Hotel and Restaurants

38,911

28,347

10840

1869

13

Railways

49,886

9,191

35747

1552

14

Transport by Other Means

2,52,248

1,43,347

63313

22182

15

Storage

3,968

1,920

1361

118

16

Communication

21,297

4,385

8231

442

17

Real Estate Services

11,024

3,782

314

212

18

Ownership of Dwelling and


Business Services

1,48,831

12,846

11379

1174

19

Banking and Insurance

4,10,219

49,379

125260

2528

20

Public administration and defence

21

Other Services

70,897

42,738

41519

920

95,55,959

2,69,05,390

41,39,514

5,99,628

Overall

Source: NCAER computation

43

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 3.7: Type II impact of an increase of Rs. 1 lakh crore in Final Demand in
residential construction on the economy
(Rs. lakh)
Type II effects

Output
Original

Agriculture incl. Livestock

Forestry and Logging

Fishing

Mining and Quarrying

Construction related
Manufacturing

Increased

Absolute
increase

%
increase

13,74,65,395

14,23,29,069

4863674

3.54

1,21,35,201

1,28,25,243

690042

5.69

61,09,700

63,33,007

223307

3.65

2,09,50,522

2,34,71,145

2520623

12.03

10,90,36,600

11,49,96,973

5960373

5.47

Other Manufacturing

33,71,47,774

34,70,55,473

9907699

2.94

Residential Construction

1,57,08,719

2,58,83,607

10174888

64.77

Non-Residential Construction

8,51,46,005

8,60,93,950

947945

1.11

Other Construction

4,36,82,177

4,41,68,498

486321

1.11

10

Electricity, Water Supply

2,65,20,746

2,75,95,235

1074489

4.05

11

Trade

11,73,30,313

12,11,32,675

3802361

3.24

12

Hotel and Restaurants

2,66,84,675

2,76,44,907

960232

3.60

13

Railways

96,24,328

99,51,588

327260

3.40

14

Transport by Other Means

8,75,15,741

9,05,13,188

2997447

3.43

15

Storage

6,39,577

6,59,560

19983

3.12

16

Communication

1,20,30,753

1,24,05,127

374374

3.11

17

Real Estate Services

30,44,536

31,66,933

122397

4.02

18

Ownership of Dwelling and


Business Services

7,62,71,845

7,84,95,843

2223998

2.92

19

Banking and Insurance

3,94,61,718

4,09,58,186

1496468

3.79

20

Public administration and


defence

4,05,63,100

4,05,63,100

0.00

21

Other Services

6,27,18,121

6,46,92,350

1974229

3.15

1,26,97,87,544

1,32,09,35,656

51148112

4.03

GDP at factor cost (Rs. Lakh)

60,91,48,501

63,28,22,726

23674225

3.89

Employment (numbers)

53,55,39,392

57,60,90,339

40550947

7.57

Income - CoE (Rs. Lakh)

19,34,17,100

20,10,46,334

7629234

3.94

Indirect Tax (Rs. Lakh)

2,90,84,726

3,02,86,642

1201915

4.13

Total Output (Rs. Lakh)

Source: NCAER computation

44

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 3.8: Sectoral increase (Type II) in various parameters following Simulation 2
(Rs. lakh)
Type I effects

Increase in
Value Added

Employment
(in number)

CoE

Indirect Tax

Agriculture incl. Livestock

33,43,369

1,02,64,050

563965

51500

Forestry and Logging

5,82,395

69,719

35335

3989

Fishing

1,91,385

63,758

18702

1883

Mining and Quarrying

18,94,485

3,82,720

527840

30517

Construction related
Manufacturing

13,48,934

7,72,990

237407

219531

Other Manufacturing

18,60,098

12,60,006

474784

377084

Residential Construction

39,58,090

2,38,12,983

2735900

255802

Non-Residential Construction

3,31,701

24,776

229266

25356

Other Construction

1,59,761

2,52,774

110420

13437

10

Electricity, Water Supply

4,24,980

51,486

196554

25818

11

Trade

30,28,797

13,87,352

470942

28520

12

Hotel and Restaurants

3,16,404

2,30,505

88147

15199

13

Railways

1,97,954

36,471

141849

6159

14

Transport by Other Means

11,13,442

6,32,743

279466

97911

15

Storage

11,829

5,725

4059

352

16

Communication

2,79,556

57,556

108048

5802

17

Real Estate Services

88,943

30,518

2533

1712

18

Ownership of Dwelling and


Business Services

17,74,358

1,53,148

135659

13999

19

Banking and Insurance

12,57,722

1,51,394

384044

7752

20

Public administration and defence

21

Other Services

15,10,023

9,10,275

884313

19589

2,36,74,225

4,05,50,947

76,29,234

12,01,915

Overall

Source: NCAER computation

Simulation 3: An increase of Rs. 1 lakh crore in final demand of other


construction

The impact of an increased demand in residential construction was


presented in the previous two simulations, which reflected the backward linkages of
this sector with other sectors of the economy. Conversely, this sector also gets
impacted due to backward linkages of other sectors, say, other construction. The
third simulation assesses the impact of increase of Rs. 1 lakh crore in the final
demand of other construction on the overall economy, and particularly on
residential construction.
3.6.

45

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 3.9: Type I impact of an increase of Rs. 1 lakh crore in Final Demand in
other construction
(Rs. lakh)
Type II effects

Output
Absolute
increase

%
increase

Original

Increased

13,74,65,395

13,80,51,088

585693

0.43

1,21,35,201

1,26,31,759

496558

4.09

Agriculture incl. Livestock

Forestry and Logging

Fishing

61,09,700

61,11,687

1987

0.03

Mining and Quarrying

2,09,50,522

2,22,29,700

1279178

6.11

Construction related
Manufacturing

10,90,36,600

11,38,48,227

4811627

4.41

Other Manufacturing

33,71,47,774

33,94,14,512

2266738

0.67

Residential Construction

1,57,08,719

1,58,58,263

149544

0.95

Non-Residential Construction

8,51,46,005

8,59,56,580

810576

0.95

Other Construction

4,36,82,177

5,40,98,024

10415847

23.84

10

Electricity, Water Supply

2,65,20,746

2,70,62,727

541981

2.04

11

Trade

11,73,30,313

11,87,46,110

1415797

1.21

12

Hotel and Restaurants

2,66,84,675

2,68,14,456

129781

0.49

13

Railways

96,24,328

97,14,964

90636

0.94

14

Transport by Other Means

8,75,15,741

8,82,62,037

746296

0.85

15

Storage

6,39,577

6,46,943

7366

1.15

16

Communication

1,20,30,753

1,20,62,095

31342

0.26

17

Real Estate Services

30,44,536

30,61,209

16674

0.55

18

Ownership of Dwelling and


Business Services

7,62,71,845

7,64,76,862

205017

0.27

19

Banking and Insurance

3,94,61,718

3,99,98,140

536422

1.36

20

Public administration and


defence

4,05,63,100

4,05,63,100

0.00

21

Other Services

6,27,18,121

6,28,19,981

101860

0.16

1,26,97,87,544

1,29,44,28,464

24640920

1.94

GDP at factor cost (Rs. Lakh)

60,91,48,501

61,86,60,487

9511986

1.56

Employment (numbers)

53,55,39,392

54,45,85,436

9046044

1.69

Income - CoE (Rs. Lakh)

19,34,17,100

19,72,81,902

3864802

2.00

Indirect Tax (Rs. Lakh)

2,90,84,726

2,97,43,727

659001

2.27

Total Output (Rs. Lakh)

Source: NCAER computation

46

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 3.10: Sectoral increase (Type I) in various parameters following Simulation 3


(Rs. lakh)
Type I effects

Increase in
Employment
(in number)

Value Added

CoE

Indirect Tax

Agriculture incl. Livestock

4,02,615

12,36,017

67914

6202

Forestry and Logging

4,19,095

50,170

25427

2870

Fishing

1,703

567

166

17

Mining and Quarrying

9,61,422

1,94,224

267871

15487

Construction related
Manufacturing

10,88,953

6,24,012

191651

177221

Other Manufacturing

4,25,563

2,88,271

108624

86271

Residential Construction

58,174

3,49,989

40211

3760

Non-Residential Construction

2,83,634

21,186

196042

21682

Other Construction

34,21,692

54,13,830

2364936

287782

10

Electricity, Water Supply

2,14,363

25,970

99143

13023

11

Trade

11,27,762

5,16,576

175354

10620

12

Hotel and Restaurants

42,764

31,154

11914

2054

13

Railways

14

Transport by Other Means

15

Storage

16

54,824

10,101

39285

1706

2,77,222

1,57,539

69581

24378

4,361

2,110

1496

130

Communication

23,404

4,818

9046

486

17

Real Estate Services

12,117

4,157

345

233

18

Ownership of Dwelling and


Business Services

1,63,567

14,118

12506

1291

19

Banking and Insurance

4,50,842

54,269

137664

2779

20

Public administration and defence

21

Other Services

77,910

46,966

45626

1011

95,11,986

90,46,044

38,64,802

6,59,001

Overall

Source: NCAER computation

47

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 3.11: Type II impact of an increase of Rs. 1 lakh crore in Final Demand in
other construction
(Rs. lakh)
Type II effects

Output
Original

Increased

Absolute
increase

%
increase

Agriculture incl. Livestock

Forestry and Logging

Fishing

61,09,700

63,18,486

208786

3.42

Mining and Quarrying

2,09,50,522

2,34,96,271

2545749

12.15

Construction related
Manufacturing

10,90,36,600

11,53,25,734

6289134

5.77

13,74,65,395

14,20,94,379

4628984

3.37

1,21,35,201

1,28,54,202

719001

5.92

Other Manufacturing

33,71,47,774

34,67,38,884

9591110

2.84

Residential Construction

1,57,08,719

1,58,94,518

185799

1.18

Non-Residential Construction

8,51,46,005

8,61,53,092

1007088

1.18

Other Construction

4,36,82,177

5,41,98,840

10516663

24.08

10

Electricity, Water Supply

2,65,20,746

2,76,05,500

1084754

4.09

11

Trade

11,73,30,313

12,10,93,380

3763067

3.21

12

Hotel and Restaurants

2,66,84,675

2,76,00,712

916037

3.43

13

Railways

96,24,328

99,43,508

319180

3.32

14

Transport by Other Means

8,75,15,741

9,04,26,562

2910821

3.33

15

Storage

6,39,577

6,59,343

19766

3.09

16

Communication

1,20,30,753

1,23,84,997

354244

2.94

17

Real Estate Services

30,44,536

31,61,321

116785

3.84

18

Ownership of Dwelling and


Business Services

7,62,71,845

7,83,79,102

2107257

2.76

19

Banking and Insurance

3,94,61,718

4,09,39,600

1477882

3.75

20

Public administration and


defence

4,05,63,100

4,05,63,100

0.00

21

Other Services

6,27,18,121

6,45,76,653

1858532

2.96

1,26,97,87,544

1,32,04,08,181

50620637

3.99

GDP at factor cost (Rs. Lakh)

60,91,48,501

63,18,41,816

22693315

3.73

Employment (numbers)

53,55,39,392

55,73,25,426

21786035

4.07

Income - CoE (Rs. Lakh)

19,34,17,100

20,05,40,032

7122932

3.68

Indirect Tax (Rs. Lakh)

2,90,84,726

3,03,06,044

1221318

4.20

Total Output (Rs. Lakh)

Source: NCAER computation

48

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Table 3.12: Sectoral increase (Type II) in various parameters following Simulation 3
(Rs. lakh)
Type I effects

Increase in
Employment
(in number)

Value Added

CoE

Indirect Tax

Agriculture incl. Livestock

31,82,040

97,68,773

536752

49015

Forestry and Logging

6,06,836

72,645

36817

4156

Fishing

1,78,940

59,612

17486

1761

Mining and Quarrying

19,13,369

3,86,535

533102

30821

Construction related
Manufacturing

14,23,338

8,15,627

250502

231640

Other Manufacturing

18,00,660

12,19,744

459613

365035

Residential Construction

72,277

4,34,838

49959

4671

Non-Residential Construction

3,52,396

26,322

243570

26938

Other Construction

34,54,811

54,66,231

2387826

290568

10

Electricity, Water Supply

4,29,039

51,978

198432

26065

11

Trade

29,97,496

13,73,015

466075

28226

12

Hotel and Restaurants

3,01,841

2,19,896

84090

14499

13

Railways

1,93,067

35,571

138346

6007

14

Transport by Other Means

10,81,263

6,14,456

271389

95082

15

Storage

11,700

5,662

4014

349

16

Communication

2,64,524

54,461

102239

5490

17

Real Estate Services

84,865

29,118

2417

1633

18

Ownership of Dwelling and


Business Services

16,81,219

1,45,109

128539

13264

19

Banking and Insurance

12,42,101

1,49,514

379274

7656

20

Public administration and defence

21

Other Services

14,21,530

8,56,929

832489

18441

2,26,93,315

2,17,86,035

71,22,932

12,21,318

Overall

Source: NCAER computation

49

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

50

National Council of Applied Economic Research

4.

April, 2014

SUMMARY OF FINDINGS

4.1.
The present study attempts to update and build on the findings of the July
2000 study carried out by IIM, Ahmedabad for HUDCO. In fact, this study is not just
an update but a refinement, to the extent possible, of the July 2000 study. While in
both the studies, the input-output model was used to study the impact of
investment/expenditure in housing sector on GDP and employment, there are
notable differences in the framework and methodology. These differences are
presented in the table below:

Table 4.1: Salient features of previous and present studies


July 2000 Study

Present Study (Feb 2014)

Reference year

Used Planning Commission IO


table of 1996-97

Number of Sectors

Original Table of 65 X 65 sector


aggregated to 14 broad sectors

Additional sectors

None

Used CSO IO table of 2007-08,


updated for 2009-10
Original Table of 130 X 130
sector aggregated to 21 broad
sectors
Construction sector split into:
Residential Construction
Non-residential
Construction
Other Construction

Housing sector

Aggregate Construction Sector

Employment

Overall employment by sectors

Residential Construction sector


Overall employment by sectors
with formal-informal breakup

IO Coefficient
matrix

Based on Domestic
Transactions Matrix
(discounting imported inputs)

Based on Total Transactions


Matrix (including imported
inputs)

Multipliers

Type I and Type II Output,


employment and income
multipliers computed

Type I and Type II Output,


employment (both formal and
informal), income and indirect
tax multipliers computed

4.2.
The present study assesses the impact of housing investment or housing
expenditure on GDP, employment, income generation and tax collection, through
various multipliers. Given the highly informal-labour extensive nature of the housing
sector, informal labour coefficients and its multipliers have also been computed.

4.3.
The study assesses the inter-linkages between housing, construction,
construction materials and real estate development sectors as these sectors have
51

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

been kept separately in the aggregated IO table. The residential construction refers
broadly to the housing sector. Besides, non-residential construction and other
construction represent the remaining part of the Construction sector. The linkages
with construction material and real estate development sectors can be assessed by
the derived linkage coefficients of Construction related manufacturing and real
estate services sectors respectively. The policy interventions have been studied
though the following simulations:

Impact of a 10% increase in final demand of residential construction


sector on the output of other sectors and on the economy as a whole

Impact of an increase of Rs. 1 lakh crore in final demand of residential


construction sector on the output of other sectors and on the economy
as a whole

Impact of an increase of Rs. 1 lakh crore in final demand of other


construction sector on the output of residential construction and other
sectors and on the economy as a whole

4.4.
The report is organised in four chapters. The overview of the housing sector,
the objectives of the present study and the key takeaways are presented in Chapter 1.
Chapter 2 is devoted to the methodology adopted and the description of the data
sources used for the present study. The IO model, multipliers and multiplier analysis
to carry out policy simulations are also described and presented in this chapter. In
Chapter 3, the policy interventions based on several simulations have been depicted.
The present chapter, Chapter 4, presents the key findings of the study.

Key Findings

4.5.
The housing sector (residential construction) accounts for 1.24 per cent of
the total output of the economy. Its share in the GDP is 1.00 per cent and in
employment is 6.86 per cent making this sector the fourth largest employment
generating sector. 99.41 per cent of the jobs in housing sector are presently informal
jobs.

4.6.
The sectors capital to output ratio is 0.61 which means that 0.61 units of
capital produces 100 units of output. Its labour to output ratio, number of persons
employed to produce a lakh unit of output, is 2.34 and is the highest among all the
sectors.

52

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

4.7.
The Type I output multiplier (capturing the direct and indirect effects) of the
housing sector is 2.33 and Type II output multiplier (capturing the direct, indirect
and induced effects) is 5.11. Hence, a unit increase in final demand for this sector is
expected to result in an overall increase in the economys output by 2.33 units, when
direct and indirect linkages are taken into account. With induced linkages added, the
economys output is expected to increase by 5.11 units.
4.8.
Of the total increase of 2.33 units, an increase of 1.01 units is expected in the
sectors own output. Besides other sectors get a boost, like output of construction
related manufacturing increases by 0.44 units and real estate services increases by
0.0015 units. Similarly, owing to Type II effect, an increase of 1.02 units is likely to
happen in the sectors own output while construction related manufacturing
increases by 0.60 units and real estate services increases by 0.0122 units.
4.9.
The Type I employment linkage coefficient of the housing sector is 2.69,
informal employment linkage coefficient being 2.65. Hence, 2.69 new jobs (2.65
informal and 0.4 formal) are created in the economy as the final demand of housing
sector increases by Rs. 1 lakh. Type II employment linkage coefficient is 4.06, of
which informal coefficient is 3.95.
4.10. Type I income and tax linkage coefficients of the housing sector are 0.41 and
0.06 respectively. This means that a unit increase in the final demand of this sector
results in an increase in household income by 0.41 units and in indirect tax by 0.06
units, owing to the direct and indirect linkages of the sector with other sectors of the
economy.
4.11. Type II income and tax linkage coefficients of the housing sector are 0.76 and
0.12 respectively. This means that with induced effects added, a unit increase in the
final demand of this sector results in an increase in household income by 0.76 units
and in indirect tax by 0.12 units.
4.12. As a concluding note, it is important to mention that IO models provide an
estimate of additional output that can be generated for a given amount of demand for
the goods and services produced by any sector but do not reflect the possible supply
constraints. The inputs required for generating the extra output are assumed to be
forthcoming through extra production by the input producers. If there are
constraints in this chain, then for meeting the fresh demand new production
capacities would have to be developed or supply sources established. This applies to
the additional demand created by residential construction as well. While the IO
multipliers assume that the industries linked with the residential construction will
produce the extra output that is required to meet the demand generated by the
housing construction but any supply constraints in this will constrain the output of
53

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

the housing construction output also. This feature of the I-O model draws attention to
the need for steps to ensure that the industries supporting housing development also
develop for a balanced development.

54

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Appendices

55

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

56

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Appendix 1: Aggregating 130 sectors of IO table to 21 sectors


130 sectorsCSO table

Description

21 sectorshousing Description
study

1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37

Paddy
Wheat
Jowar
Bajra
Maize
Gram
Pulses
Sugarcane
Groundnut
Coconut
Other oilseeds
Jute
Cotton
Tea
Coffee
Rubber
Tobacco
Fruits
Vegetables
Other crops
Milk and milk products
Animal services(agricultural)
Poultry & Eggs
Other liv.st. produ.
Forestry and logging
Fishing
Coal and lignite
Natural gas
Crude petroleum
Iron ore
Manganese ore
Bauxite
Copper ore
Other metallic minerals
Lime stone
Mica
Other non-metallic minerals

38

Sugar

39

Khandsari, boora

40
41

Hydrogenated oil(vanaspati)
Edible oils other than vanaspati

Agriculture incl. Livestock (1 to 24)

2
3

Forestry and logging (25)


Fishing (26)

Mining and quarrying (27 to 37)

construction related manufacturing


(55,56,62,64,69,74 to 77,79 to 82, 89)
other manufacturing (38 to 54, 57 to 61, 63,
65 to 68, 70 to 73, 78, 83 to 88, 90 to 105)

57

National Council of Applied Economic Research

130 sectorsCSO table


42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
61
62
63
64
65
66
67
68
69
70
71
72
73
74
75
76
77
78
79
80
81
82
83
84
85

Description

April, 2014

21 sectorshousing Description
study

Tea and coffee processing


Miscellaneous food products
Beverages
Tobacco products
Khadi, cotton textiles(handlooms)
Cotton textiles
Woollen textiles
Silk textiles
Art silk, synthetic fibre textiles
Jute, hemp, Mesta textiles
Carpet weaving
Readymade garments
Miscellaneous textile products
Furniture and fixtures-wooden
Wood and wood products
Paper, paper prods. & newsprint
Printing and publishing
Leather footwear
Leather and leather products
Rubber products
Plastic products
Petroleum products
Coal tar products
Inorganic heavy chemicals
Organic heavy chemicals
Fertilizers
Pesticides
Paints, varnishes and lacquers
Drugs and medicines
Soaps, cosmetics & glycerine
Synthetic fibres, resin
Other chemicals
Structural clay products
Cement
Other non-metallic mineral prods.
Iron, steel and Ferro alloys
Iron and steel casting & forging
Iron and steel foundries
Non-ferrous basic metals
Hand tools, hardware
Miscellaneous metal products
Tractors and agri. implements
Industrial machinery(F & T)
Industrial machinery(others)

58

National Council of Applied Economic Research

130 sectorsCSO table


86
87
88
89
90
91
92
93
94
95
96
97
98
99
100
101

Description

103
104
105
106

Machine tools
Other non-electrical machinery
Electrical industrial Machinery
Electrical wires & cables
Batteries
Electrical appliances
Communication equipments
Other electrical Machinery
Electronic equipments(incl.TV)
Ships and boats
Rail equipments
Motor vehicles
Motor cycles and scooters
Bicycles, cycle-rickshaw
Other transport equipments
Watches and clocks
Medical, precision & optical
instruments
Gems & jewellery
Aircraft & spacecraft
Miscellaneous manufacturing
Construction

107

Electricity

108
109
110
111
112
113

Water supply
Railway transport services
Land tpt including via pipeline
Water transport
Air transport
Supporting and aux. tpt activities

114
115
116
117
118
119

102

April, 2014

21 sectorshousing Description
study

7
8
9

Residential Construction
Non-Residential Construction
Other Construction

10

Electricity, Water Supply (gas will be in Sector


1 (gobar gas) and sector 6 (LPG)) - 107, 108

13

Railways (109)

14

Transport by other means (110 to 113)

Storage and warehousing


Communication
Trade
Hotels and restaurants
Banking
Insurance

15
16
11
12

Storage (114)
communication (115)
Trade (116)
Hotel and Restaurants (117)

19

banking and insurance (118, 119)

120

Ownership of dwellings

18

ownership of dwellings and other business


services (120, 123, 124, 125, 127)

121
122
123
124

Education and research


Medical and health
Business services
Computer & related activities

59

National Council of Applied Economic Research

130 sectorsCSO table


125
126
127
128
129
130

Description
Legal services
Real estate activities
Renting of machinery & equipment
O.com, social & personal services
Other services
Public administration

April, 2014

21 sectorshousing Description
study
17
21

real estate services (126)


other services (121, 122, 128, 129)

20

Public administration and defence (130)

60

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

APPENDIX 2: About Input-Output Table


Input-Output (IO) Table is the matrix representation of a nations economy,
and is used to analyse the inter-industry relations in an economy, depicting how the
output of one industry is used as input in other industries, thereby making each
industry dependent on other industries both as the user and as supplier. The credit of
the development of this analysis goes to Wassily Leontief (1906-1999) who won the
Nobel Prize in Economics for his work in this area7.
The standard IO table can be viewed as consisting of four major components
(also known as blocks or quadrants). The schematic structure of a standard IO
structure is given in the Table below:

Schematic structure of a standard IO Table


Sectors
Sectors

Final
Payments
Sectors

Total

Final demand
Sectors

Total

Block A
Inter-sector
Transactions

Block B
Final demand
(sales to
households,
visitors,
government,
investment, and
exports)

Total sector
output
(sales)

Block C
Primary payments
(payments for labour,
capital, land,
loans, taxes, and
imported goods)

Block D
Primary Inputs to
Final Demand sectors

Total
payments

Total sector input


(purchases)

Total
Expenditures

Wassily Leontief (August 5, 1905, Munich, Germany February 5, 1999, New York) was an economist notable for his
research on development of the linear activity model of General Equilibrium and the use of input-output analysis that results
from it.

61

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Each of these blocks consists of a series of rows and columns. The rows
represent the producing sectors that are used as the inputs in other sectors, while the
columns represent the purchasing sectors. These blocks are briefly described as
follows:

Block A
Block A presents the inter-sector transactions showing the intermediate sales
and purchases of goods and services among the production sectors of an economy.
The rows of this block depict the value of each sectors output being demanded by
other sectors as the inputs in their production process. And the columns give the
inputs that the sector purchases from other sectors.

Block B
This block, also called the block of final demand, shows the sales of goods and
services from row sectors to the final users, that is, users other than the producing
sectors. This derives from the fact that besides the use as inputs in other sectors, the
produce of all the sectors is also demanded by the final consumers, which comprise of

Households for their private consumption (termed as Private Final


Consumption Expenditure, PFCE);
Government units (as Government Final Consumption Expenditure, GFCE);
Investment demand (sectors demanded as the capital investment and for
addition of stock of inventories, termed as Gross Fixed Capital Formation,
GFCF and Changes in Stocks, CIS respectively)
Net Exports (the produce of sectors meant for export to other nations net of
imports).

Block C
This block is also termed as the block of primary inputs, and lies below Block
A. This block gives the cost of production of a sector other than the cost of inputs
from other sectors (given in Block A). This block together with the block A gives the
total cost of production of each sector. The primary inputs presented in this block are
the payments to the factor owners in the form of salaries and wages, and interest
payments and operating surplus. These are the land, labour and capital costs of a
production process. Other primary inputs are the indirect tax payments to the
government. The last two rows of this block are Gross Value Added and the Total
Value of Output for each sector.

62

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Block D
This block is an intersection of Block C and Block B and records the applicable
primary inputs into final demand components. This block lies below Block B.

An increased activity in any sector amounts to the generation of additional


output, value added and employment in the direct recipient sectors, but apart from
this direct impact, further increase is generated in other sectors of the economy due
to inter-industry relationships. Such direct and indirect impacts can be measured by
using Input-Output techniques. Input-Output analysis is a powerful econometric tool
to study the extent and pattern of inter-industry dependence and assess the
multiplier effect of increased activity in one sector on the economy as a whole. The
major advantage of this technique is that it concentrates on the links between various
economic activities operating in an economy. An input-output table is a worthwhile
system of accounting as a powerful model can be derived from it using the simple
assumptions. It assumes that the inputs used in producing a product are related to
the industry output by a linear and fixed coefficient production function.

63

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

64

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

APPENDIX 3: Input-Output Table, 2009-10 (Rs. Lakh)

S. No.

Industry

Agriculture incl. Livestock

Agriculture
incl.
Livestock

Forestry
and
Logging

Fishing

Mining
and
Quarrying

Construction
related
Manufacturing

Other
Manufacturing

Residential
Construction

NonResidential
Construction

17,349,954

3,833

158

1,510,698

34,220,001

131,099

755,847

Forestry and Logging

61,298

115,265

686

2,544,145

1,361,795

465,703

2,685,882

Fishing

10,945

131,042

6,715

220,121

26

Mining and Quarrying

1,935,103

176,344

14,825,142

40,759,567

303,703

1,750,804

Construction related Manufacturing

1,191,647

17,637

10,898

190,382

24,582,181

27,117,146

4,387,626

25,304,949

Other Manufacturing

10,542,451

575,903

520,540

2,028,322

17,113,159

90,592,655

371,328

2,140,429

Residential Construction

84,640

10,349

39,766

100,611

304,690

169,969

980,305

Non-Residential Construction

458,773

56,097

215,544

545,341

1,651,510

921,281

5,313,547

Other Construction

235,363

28,779

110,580

279,774

847,269

472,642

2,725,992

10

Electricity, Water Supply

1,050,591

12,421

382,699

2,077,837

5,353,634

332,483

1,917,517

11

Trade

5,597,873

105,802

108,957

319,382

8,941,466

29,788,744

849,795

4,900,740

12

Hotel and Restaurants

7,835

207,008

140,826

130

4,334

5,340

30,797

13

Railways

309,695

20,458

5,707

126,951

561,144

1,871,411

44,848

258,632

14

Transport by Other Means

2,404,572

461,385

48,683

342,551

4,584,144

15,115,938

373,591

2,154,452

15

Storage

5,785

16

Communication

58,038

23,553

10,679

117,858

1,004,987

4,463

25,730

17

Real Estate Services

397

45

17,533

101,125

18

Ownership of Dwelling & Business


Services

196,201

87,537

267,028

600,947

3,772,014

103,903

599,224

19

Banking and Insurance

1,740,274

6,642

7,675

359,375

1,962,407

9,204,306

307,480

1,773,284

20

Public administration and defence

21

Other Services

168,631

106,434

324,440

735,815

3,285,928

7,738

44,583

65

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

APPENDIX 3: Input-Output Table, 2009-10 (Rs. Lakh) (cont.)


S.
No.

Industry

22

IC at factor cost

23

Agriculture
incl.
Livestock

Forestry
and
Logging

Fishing

Mining
and
Quarrying

Construction
related
Manufacturing

Other
Manufacturing

Residential
Construction

NonResidential
Construction

43,404,282

1,839,103

833,501

5,041,498

81,089,516

266,476,095

9,270,530

53,463,866

Indirect taxes

1,455,594

70,146

51,526

253,643

4,016,016

12,831,749

394,926

2,277,537

24

Subsidies

1,890,440

16,150

11,627

90,904

745,779

5,457,089

67,519

389,359

25

IC at market prices

42,969,435

1,893,099

873,400

5,204,237

84,359,752

273,850,755

9,597,937

55,352,043

26

Gross value added at factor


cost

94,495,959

10,242,102

5,236,300

15,746,285

24,676,848

63,297,019

6,110,782

29,793,961

27

CoE

15,939,738

621,400

511,700

4,387,219

4,343,025

16,156,360

4,223,878

20,593,062

28

OS/MI

71,251,016

9,485,001

3,967,700

7,684,296

13,847,176

32,798,596

1,561,870

7,615,728

29

CFC

7,305,205

135,701

756,900

3,674,770

6,486,646

14,342,062

325,034

1,585,171

30

Gross output at factor cost

137,465,395

12,135,201

6,109,700

20,950,522

109,036,600

337,147,774

15,708,719

85,146,005

31

Employment (lakh)

2,901.00

12.26

17.44

31.81

141.41

428.77

75.02

365.76

32

GFCF (Rs. Lakh)

180,473

1,438

11,949

81,138

166,983

419,189

11,177

54,503

33

NCS (Rs. Lakh)

1,941,986

31,665

61,469

582,026

1,501,290

3,788,195

95,984

468,081

34

Formal employment (lakh)

3.07

0.63

0.31

9.29

11.72

44.89

2.17

0.48

35

Infl. Employment (lakh)

2897.93

11.63

17.14

22.52

129.69

383.87

365.47

21.78

36

Total employment (lakh)

2901.00

12.26

17.44

31.81

141.41

428.77

367.64

22.25

37

Indirect taxes net of subsidies

-434846

53996

39899

162739

3270237

7374660

327407

1888177

66

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

APPENDIX 3: Input-Output Table, 2009-10 (Rs. Lakh) (cont.)


S. No.

Industry

Agriculture incl. Livestock

Forestry and Logging

Fishing

Mining and Quarrying

Construction related Manufacturing

Other
Construction

Electricity,
Water Supply

Trade

Hotel and
Restaurants

Railways

Transport
by Other
Means

Storage

Communication

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

400,483

33,764

596,145

11,036,013

5,671,415

1,423,342

5,567

50,087

48

14

159

3,708

14,190

927,611

3,959,846

833,932

2,119

15,361

18

13,409,938

255,697

1,790,850

76,131

2,390

1,704,743

15,750

75,329

1,133,981

3,810,762

4,800,016

2,785,490

1,543,092

26,060,345

70,474

1,731,011

519,506

53,396

68,605

14,043

73,506

76,337

2,350

14,162

Other Manufacturing

Residential Construction

Non-Residential Construction

2,815,880

289,421

371,859

76,118

398,426

413,771

12,737

76,762

Other Construction

1,444,621

148,481

190,773

39,051

204,403

212,275

6,535

39,381

10

Electricity, Water Supply

1,016,148

4,160,229

948,345

72,721

801,998

566,643

90,234

237,861

11

Trade

2,596,982

1,164,840

1,149,974

2,753,043

204,186

4,860,723

11,408

236,510

12

Hotel and Restaurants

16,321

151,539

1,820,879

264,164

14,414

6,981,403

8,925

37,717

13

Railways

137,052

68,105

76,899

145,166

14,749

286,524

2,246

25,177

14

Transport by Other Means

1,141,669

584,783

3,695,634

1,114,232

99,150

2,604,686

10,352

170,572

15

Storage

572,755

518

11,643

16

Communication

13,633

65,930

157,035

6,026

3,925

423,131

38,609

17

Real Estate Services

53,591

3,717

2,733

18

Ownership of Dwelling & Business


Services

317,543

45,615

1,163,026

13,594

101,052

2,037,537

13,675

42,304

19

Banking and Insurance

939,708

1,131,494

4,898,771

97,184

140,351

1,017,768

15,655

32,827

20

Public administration and defence

21

Other Services

23,613

63,298

76,635

16,842

135,322

260,558

2,034

163,637

67

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

APPENDIX 3: Input-Output Table, 2009-10 (Rs. Lakh) (cont.)

S. No.

Industry

22

IC at factor cost

23

Indirect taxes

24

Subsidies

25

Other
Construction

Electricity,
Water Supply

Trade

Hotel and
Restaurants

Railways

Transport
by Other
Means

Storage

Communication

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

28,331,636

15,992,926

23,265,930

18,526,644

3,752,374

53,193,239

262,382

2,924,592

1,206,907

637,250

880,063

422,376

181,131

2,858,693

11,281

186,459

206,322

598,859

275,938

1,057,145

130,776

1,045,091

12,691

63,998

IC at market prices

29,332,220

16,031,317

23,870,054

17,891,875

3,802,728

55,006,841

260,972

3,047,053

26

Gross value added at factor cost

14,349,956

10,489,429

93,460,259

8,792,800

5,821,600

32,508,900

378,605

8,983,700

27

CoE

9,918,114

4,851,387

14,531,960

2,449,600

4,171,600

8,159,500

129,901

3,472,200

28

OS/MI

3,668,230

653,054

76,235,710

5,605,000

523,200

21,432,000

219,003

3,791,100

29

CFC

763,613

4,984,988

2,692,589

738,200

1,126,800

2,917,400

29,701

1,720,400

30

Gross output at factor cost

43,682,177

26,520,746

117,330,313

26,684,675

9,624,328

87,515,741

639,577

12,030,753

31

Employment (lakh)

176.16

12.71

428.10

64.06

10.73

184.74

1.83

18.50

32

GFCF (Rs. Lakh)

26,254

130,537

138,800

30,671

31,929

59,212

1,789

74,895

33

NCS (Rs. Lakh)

225,476

1,297,284

1,284,392

214,713

322,435

446,096

21,489

383,500

34

Formal employment (lakh)

5.95

9.74

9.68

1.66

9.39

11.39

0.79

9.91

35

Infl. Employment (lakh)

221.09

2.97

418.42

62.39

1.34

173.35

1.05

8.59

36

Total employment (lakh)

227.05

12.71

428.10

64.06

10.73

184.74

1.83

18.50

37

Indirect taxes net of subsidies

1000584

38391

604125

-634768

50355

1813602

-1410

122461

68

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

APPENDIX 3: Input-Output Table, 2009-10 (Rs. Lakh) (cont.)

S. No.

Industry

Real Estate
Services

Ownership
of Dwelling
& Business
Services

Banking and
Insurance

Public
administration
and defence

Other
Services

IC

PFCE

GFCE

17

18

19

20

21

22

23

24

1,363

41,188

545,631

72,297,597

61,683,993

1,543,887

Forestry and Logging

203

138

8,714,159

3,876,037

60

Fishing

42

386,973

5,340,469

Mining and Quarrying

40

8,731

3,272

65,501,597

197,558

89,673

17,477

409,245

187,085

623,461

101,370,563

7,820,656

537,425

11,037

1,438,770

962,592

4,461,708

172,694,066

94,654,114

7,485,338

Agriculture incl. Livestock

Construction related Manufacturing

Other Manufacturing

Residential Construction

172

265,707

58,453

70,868

2,907,434

64,761

98,759

Non-Residential Construction

933

1,440,212

316,834

384,127

15,759,172

351,024

535,303

Other Construction

479

738,867

162,544

197,067

8,084,876

180,084

274,625

10

Electricity, Water Supply

1,611

1,113,940

587,419

234,047

20,958,379

3,819,316

1,743,027

11

Trade

4,190

255,456

151,869

787,705

64,789,643

29,280,691

1,398,654

12

Hotel and Restaurants

150,711

1,533,083

1,077,950

1,590,785

14,044,160

11,907,744

732,772

13

Railways

219

55,021

138,197

52,733

4,200,936

3,812,346

466,024

14

Transport by Other Means

1,767

305,787

585,790

960,745

36,760,484

38,698,833

3,575,339

15

Storage

590,701

7,818

41,059

16

Communication

9,539

174,542

444,395

248,390

2,830,463

7,008,420

1,350,404

17

Real Estate Services

298,970

404,499

882,612

2,161,924

18

Ownership of Dwelling & Business


Services

228,127

4,061,074

216,465

781,833

14,648,699

42,676,346

1,790,459

19

Banking and Insurance

8,271

1,272,871

1,150,890

1,443,749

27,510,981

10,346,188

1,458,546

20

Public administration and defence

40,563,100

21

Other Services

56,730

1,633,457

160,294

1,944,936

9,210,926

41,553,905

11,961,829

69

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

APPENDIX 3: Input-Output Table, 2009-10 (Rs. Lakh) (cont.)

S. No.

Industry

22

IC at factor cost

23

Indirect taxes

24

Subsidies

25

IC at market prices

26

Gross value added at factor cost

27

CoE

28

OS/MI

29

CFC

30

Gross output at factor cost

31

Employment (lakh)

32

GFCF (Rs. Lakh)

33

NCS (Rs. Lakh)

34

Real Estate
Services

Ownership
of Dwelling
& Business
Services

Banking and
Insurance

Public
administration
and defence

Other
Services

IC

PFCE

GFCE

17

18

19

20

21

22

23

24

791,636

15,152,694

6,200,777

14,331,201

644,144,421

365,442,225

75,646,283

42,576

480,103

204,426

622,325

29,084,726

14,329,653

2,572,810

2,074

212,432

109,486

206,425

12,590,105

8,970,977

791,893

832,138

15,420,365

6,295,718

14,747,102

660,639,043

370,800,900

77,427,200

2,212,398

60,851,480

33,166,000

40,563,100

47,971,019

609,148,501

63,005

4,652,432

10,127,200

36,020,600

28,093,219

193,417,100

2,029,678

48,396,198

22,520,900

16,656,144

349,941,601

119,715

7,802,850

517,900

4,542,500

3,221,656

65,789,800

3,044,536

76,271,845

39,461,718

40,563,100

62,718,121

1,269,787,544

7.59

52.52

39.92

95.89

289.18

5,355.39

10,673

293,580

9,757

208,938

129,164

2,073,048

116,810

3,212,924

137,428

2,293,741

1,025,158

19,452,142

Formal employment (lakh)

0.44

17.04

24.03

93.45

92.05

358.05

35

Infl. Employment (lakh)

7.15

35.48

15.90

2.44

197.13

4997.34

36

Total employment (lakh)

7.59

52.52

39.92

95.89

289.18

5355.39

37

Indirect taxes net of subsidies

40502

267671

94941

415900

70

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

APPENDIX 3: Input-Output Table, 2009-10 (Rs. Lakh) (cont.)


S. No.

Industry

GFCF

Val

CIS

EXP

IMP

FU

Total

25

26

27

28

29

30

31

270,971

1,121,659

2,656,883

2,109,589

65,167,804

137,465,401

Forestry and Logging

68,546

180,298

703,899

3,421,043

12,135,202

Fishing

30,807

378,860

27,409

5,722,727

6,109,700

Mining and Quarrying

-1,614,972

9,793,501

53,016,833

-44,551,074

20,950,523

Construction related Manufacturing

12,691,177

3,766,359

7,341,708

24,491,291

7,666,034

109,036,597

Other Manufacturing

57,112,553

9,174,363

10,361,453

47,349,254

61,683,376

164,453,698

337,147,764

Residential Construction

12,607,111

61,912

31,258

12,801,285

15,708,719

Non-Residential Construction

68,334,352

335,580

169,426

69,386,833

85,146,005

Other Construction

35,057,349

172,162

86,920

35,597,300

43,682,177

23

5,562,366

26,520,746

9,291,969

1,197,551

1,893,128

9,478,676

52,540,670

117,330,313

12,640,516

26,684,675

486,682

62,724

99,156

496,461

5,423,393

9,624,328

3,727,377

480,385

759,409

9,153,714

5,639,800

50,755,256

87,515,740

Agriculture incl. Livestock

10

Electricity, Water Supply

11

Trade

12

Hotel and Restaurants

13

Railways

14

Transport by Other Means

15

Storage

48,876

639,577

16

Communication

1,191,629

350,163

9,200,290

12,030,753

17

Real Estate Services

2,161,924

3,044,536

18

Ownership of Dwelling & Business


Services

1,914,040

30,472,657

15,230,355

61,623,147

76,271,846

19

Banking and Insurance

756,203

610,200

11,950,737

39,461,718

20

Public administration and defence

40,563,100

40,563,100

21

Other Services

6,480,944

6,489,482

53,507,195

62,718,121

71

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

APPENDIX 3: Input-Output Table, 2009-10 (Rs. Lakh) (cont.)


S. No.

Industry

22

IC at factor cost

23

GFCF

Val

CIS

EXP

IMP

FU

Total

25

26

27

28

29

30

31

201,493,580

10,915,022

16,485,546

126,300,466

Indirect taxes

6,895,665

869,030

1,224,378

24

Subsidies

1,084,446

152,852

25

IC at market prices

207,304,800

11,631,200

26

Gross value added at factor cost

27

CoE

28

OS/MI

29

CFC

30

Gross output at factor cost

31

Employment (lakh)

32

GFCF (Rs. Lakh)

33

NCS (Rs. Lakh)

34

Formal employment (lakh)

35

Infl. Employment (lakh)

36

Total employment (lakh)

37

Indirect taxes net of subsidies

625,643,122

1,269,787,543

6,722,437

32,613,973

61,698,699

278,924

1,242,903

12,521,995

25,112,100

17,430,999

131,780,000

645,735,100

1,306,374,143

72

170,640,000

170,640,000

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

APPENDIX 4: Leontief Inverse Matrix for Direct and Indirect linkages

S. No.

1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21

Industry

Agriculture incl. Livestock


Forestry and Logging
Fishing
Mining and Quarrying
Construction related Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing
Residential Construction
Non-Residential Construction
Other Construction
Electricity, Water Supply
Trade
Hotel and Restaurants
Railways
Transport by Other Means
Storage
Communication
Real Estate Services
Ownership of Dwelling & Business Services
Banking and Insurance
Public administration and defence
Other Services
Output multipliers

Agriculture
incl.
Livestock

Forestry
and
Logging

Fishing

Mining
and
Quarrying

Construction
related
Manufacturing

Other
Manufacturing

Residential
Construction

1.1698
0.0025
0.0002
0.0452
0.0381
0.1628
0.0013
0.0073
0.0037
0.0179
0.0709
0.0055
0.0044
0.0350
0.0004
0.0017
0.0001
0.0065
0.0262
0.0000
0.0047
1.6042

0.0276
1.0109
0.0001
0.0173
0.0202
0.1043
0.0013
0.0073
0.0037
0.0061
0.0277
0.0227
0.0030
0.0488
0.0001
0.0028
0.0001
0.0112
0.0074
0.0000
0.0112
1.3337

0.0194
0.0012
1.0220
0.0211
0.0199
0.1402
0.0003
0.0018
0.0009
0.0048
0.0355
0.0026
0.0022
0.0181
0.0002
0.0007
0.0000
0.0031
0.0084
0.0000
0.0022
1.3046

0.0308
0.0027
0.0001
1.0425
0.0441
0.1810
0.0028
0.0153
0.0079
0.0306
0.0438
0.0124
0.0081
0.0328
0.0005
0.0019
0.0001
0.0186
0.0299
0.0000
0.0198
1.5257

73

0.0840
0.0346
0.0004
0.2454
1.3547
0.4027
0.0031
0.0165
0.0085
0.0503
0.1673
0.0152
0.0119
0.0937
0.0009
0.0045
0.0002
0.0215
0.0541
0.0000
0.0193
2.5887

0.1964
0.0116
0.0011
0.2227
0.1817
1.5277
0.0030
0.0165
0.0084
0.0460
0.1747
0.0155
0.0122
0.0960
0.0009
0.0067
0.0002
0.0279
0.0654
0.0000
0.0223
2.6369

0.0533
0.0452
0.0002
0.1164
0.4378
0.2063
1.0136
0.0737
0.0378
0.0493
0.1288
0.0118
0.0082
0.0679
0.0007
0.0029
0.0015
0.0187
0.0488
0.0000
0.0093
2.3322

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

APPENDIX 4: Leontief Inverse Matrix for Direct and Indirect linkages (cont.)

S. No.

1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21

Industry

Agriculture incl. Livestock


Forestry and Logging
Fishing
Mining and Quarrying
Construction related Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing
Residential Construction
Non-Residential Construction
Other Construction
Electricity, Water Supply
Trade
Hotel and Restaurants
Railways
Transport by Other Means
Storage
Communication
Real Estate Services
Ownership of Dwelling & Business Services
Banking and Insurance
Public administration and defence
Other Services
Output multipliers

NonResidential
Construction

Other
Construction

Electricity,
Water
Supply

Trade

Hotel and
Restaurants

Railways

Transport
by Other
Means

10

11

12

13

14

0.0448
0.0058
0.0002
0.0681
0.0715
0.3003
0.0097
0.0524
0.0269
0.1131
0.0710
0.0090
1.0051
0.0384
0.0004
0.0026
0.0002
0.0192
0.0379
0.0000
0.0204
1.8970

0.1870
0.0053
0.0004
0.0858
0.0977
0.5246
0.0025
0.0137
0.0070
0.0288
0.1373
0.0919
0.0088
1.0751
0.0008
0.0079
0.0003
0.0370
0.0425
0.0000
0.0124
2.3670

0.0567
0.0481
0.0002
0.1238
0.4658
0.2195
0.0145
1.0785
0.0403
0.0525
0.1371
0.0126
0.0088
0.0723
0.0007
0.0030
0.0016
0.0198
0.0519
0.0000
0.0099
2.4174

0.0586
0.0497
0.0002
0.1279
0.4812
0.2267
0.0150
0.0811
1.0416
0.0542
0.1416
0.0130
0.0091
0.0746
0.0007
0.0031
0.0017
0.0205
0.0536
0.0000
0.0102
2.4641

0.0547
0.0045
0.0002
0.2335
0.0711
0.3286
0.0041
0.0220
0.0113
1.2045
0.1025
0.0175
0.0076
0.0574
0.0006
0.0056
0.0001
0.0132
0.0749
0.0000
0.0117
2.2257

74

0.0321
0.0021
0.0001
0.0281
0.0378
0.1016
0.0012
0.0064
0.0033
0.0165
1.0304
0.0219
0.0022
0.0436
0.0050
0.0026
0.0001
0.0143
0.0508
0.0000
0.0033
1.4037

0.5216
0.0031
0.0008
0.0514
0.0501
0.2671
0.0018
0.0098
0.0050
0.0197
0.1632
1.0204
0.0094
0.0757
0.0008
0.0024
0.0001
0.0096
0.0296
0.0000
0.0061
2.2477

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

APPENDIX 4: Leontief Inverse Matrix for Direct and Indirect linkages (cont.)

S. No.

1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21

Industry

Agriculture incl. Livestock


Forestry and Logging
Fishing
Mining and Quarrying
Construction related Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing
Residential Construction
Non-Residential Construction
Other Construction
Electricity, Water Supply
Trade
Hotel and Restaurants
Railways
Transport by Other Means
Storage
Communication
Real Estate Services
Ownership of Dwelling & Business Services
Banking and Insurance
Public administration and defence
Other Services
Output multipliers

Storage

Communication

Real
Estate
Services

15

16

17

0.0456
0.0047
0.0002
0.0714
0.0838
0.2506
0.0054
0.0294
0.0151
0.1805
0.0667
0.0225
0.0070
0.0438
1.0004
0.0023
0.0002
0.0301
0.0490
0.0000
0.0093
1.9180

0.0364
0.0027
0.0002
0.0422
0.0444
0.2452
0.0020
0.0109
0.0056
0.0328
0.0534
0.0084
0.0045
0.0334
0.0003
1.0047
0.0003
0.0095
0.0170
0.0000
0.0182
1.5719

0.0337
0.0007
0.0001
0.0077
0.0162
0.0332
0.0006
0.0034
0.0018
0.0047
0.0152
0.0591
0.0010
0.0079
0.0001
0.0041
1.1094
0.0893
0.0084
0.0000
0.0241
1.4207

75

Ownership
of Dwelling
& Business
Services

Banking
and
Insurance

Public
administration
and defence

Other
Services

18

19

20

21

0.0216
0.0023
0.0001
0.0164
0.0314
0.0590
0.0045
0.0242
0.0124
0.0230
0.0199
0.0248
0.0019
0.0134
0.0001
0.0032
0.0063
1.0593
0.0247
0.0000
0.0250
1.3734

0.0255
0.0015
0.0001
0.0159
0.0230
0.0693
0.0021
0.0112
0.0058
0.0226
0.0206
0.0315
0.0047
0.0242
0.0001
0.0122
0.0001
0.0084
1.0361
0.0000
0.0061
1.3211

0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
1.0000
0.0000
1.0000

0.0447
0.0020
0.0001
0.0255
0.0374
0.1417
0.0018
0.0099
0.0051
0.0115
0.0379
0.0311
0.0026
0.0298
0.0002
0.0053
0.0001
0.0175
0.0336
0.0000
1.0350
1.4728

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

APPENDIX 5: Extended Leontief Inverse Matrix for Direct, Indirect and Induced linkages (cont.)

S. No.

1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21

Industry

Agriculture incl. Livestock


Forestry and Logging
Fishing
Mining and Quarrying
Construction related Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing
Residential Construction
Non-Residential Construction
Other Construction
Electricity, Water Supply
Trade
Hotel and Restaurants
Railways
Transport by Other Means
Storage
Communication
Real Estate Services
Ownership of Dwelling & Business
Services
Banking and Insurance
Public administration and defence
Other Services

CoE
Output Multiplier

Agriculture
incl.
Livestock

Forestry
and
Logging

Fishing

Mining and
Quarrying

Construction
related
Manufacturing

Other
Manufacturing

Residential
Construction

1.3634
0.0132
0.0101
0.1058
0.1089
0.5135
0.0031
0.0167
0.0086
0.0439
0.1833
0.0431
0.0153
0.1386
0.0010
0.0172
0.0049

0.1199
1.0160
0.0048
0.0462
0.0539
0.2715
0.0022
0.0117
0.0060
0.0185
0.0813
0.0406
0.0082
0.0983
0.0004
0.0102
0.0024

0.1369
0.0076
1.0280
0.0579
0.0628
0.3530
0.0014
0.0075
0.0038
0.0205
0.1037
0.0254
0.0088
0.0810
0.0005
0.0101
0.0029

0.3193
0.0186
0.0149
1.1329
0.1495
0.7036
0.0054
0.0293
0.0150
0.0693
0.2113
0.0685
0.0244
0.1872
0.0014
0.0249
0.0073

0.3073
0.0469
0.0118
0.3154
1.4363
0.8073
0.0051
0.0274
0.0141
0.0803
0.2969
0.0587
0.0245
0.2133
0.0016
0.0223
0.0057

0.4408
0.0250
0.0136
0.2993
0.2710
1.9704
0.0052
0.0283
0.0145
0.0788
0.3166
0.0630
0.0261
0.2269
0.0017
0.0262
0.0063

0.4864
0.0690
0.0223
0.2521
0.5960
0.9908
1.0175
0.0948
0.0486
0.1074
0.3802
0.0960
0.0327
0.2997
0.0020
0.0374
0.0122

0.0976

0.0546

0.0583

0.1543

0.1265

0.1428

0.2224

0.0713
0.0000
0.0888
0.3411
2.8481

0.0289
0.0000
0.0513
0.1627
1.9270

0.0358
0.0000
0.0532
0.2069
2.0593

0.0971
0.0000
0.1451
0.5082
3.3793

0.1061
0.0000
0.1164
0.3934
4.0237

0.1223
0.0000
0.1284
0.4305
4.2071

0.1496
0.0000
0.1974
0.7629
5.1148

76

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

APPENDIX 5: Extended Leontief Inverse Matrix for Direct, Indirect and Induced linkages (cont.)
S. No.
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21

Industry

Agriculture incl. Livestock


Forestry and Logging
Fishing
Mining and Quarrying
Construction related Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing
Residential Construction
Non-Residential Construction
Other Construction
Electricity, Water Supply
Trade
Hotel and Restaurants
Railways
Transport by Other Means
Storage
Communication
Real Estate Services
Ownership of Dwelling & Business Services
Banking and Insurance
Public administration and defence
Other Services

CoE
Output Multiplier

NonResidential
Construction

Other
Construction

Electricity,
Water
Supply

Trade

Hotel and
Restaurants

Railways

Transport
by Other
Means

10

11

12

13

14

0.6189
0.0374
0.0296
0.2479
0.2813
1.3403
0.0148
0.0803
0.0412
0.1902
0.4043
0.1206
1.0375
0.3458
0.0021
0.0484
0.0144
0.2893
0.1716
0.0000
0.2699
1.0114
5.5860

0.4282
0.0186
0.0128
0.1614
0.1859
0.9615
0.0047
0.0254
0.0130
0.0612
0.2773
0.1388
0.0225
1.2042
0.0016
0.0272
0.0063
0.1504
0.0987
0.0000
0.1172
0.4249
3.9168

0.4712
0.0709
0.0214
0.2537
0.6173
0.9703
0.0182
1.0986
0.0506
0.1081
0.3777
0.0932
0.0322
0.2941
0.0020
0.0361
0.0119
0.2149
0.1484
0.0000
0.1899
0.7302
5.0807

0.4629
0.0719
0.0209
0.2546
0.6289
0.9591
0.0186
0.1007
1.0517
0.1085
0.3763
0.0916
0.0319
0.2911
0.0020
0.0354
0.0117
0.2107
0.1478
0.0000
0.1859
0.7123
5.0621

0.4244
0.0249
0.0192
0.3493
0.2062
0.9982
0.0074
0.0399
0.0205
1.2541
0.3171
0.0894
0.0285
0.2552
0.0017
0.0351
0.0093
0.1871
0.1610
0.0000
0.1723
0.6512
4.6008

77

0.2138
0.0121
0.0094
0.0850
0.1041
0.4306
0.0028
0.0152
0.0078
0.0409
1.1359
0.0572
0.0125
0.1408
0.0056
0.0171
0.0046
0.0998
0.0931
0.0000
0.0822
0.3199
2.5706

0.7629
0.0164
0.0131
0.1270
0.1382
0.7042
0.0040
0.0215
0.0110
0.0521
0.3032
1.0673
0.0230
0.2049
0.0016
0.0216
0.0061
0.1231
0.0858
0.0000
0.1110
0.4251
3.7982

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

APPENDIX 5: Extended Leontief Inverse Matrix for Direct, Indirect and Induced linkages (cont.)

S. No.

1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21

Industry

Agriculture incl. Livestock


Forestry and Logging
Fishing
Mining and Quarrying
Construction related Manufacturing
Other Manufacturing
Residential Construction
Non-Residential Construction
Other Construction
Electricity, Water Supply
Trade
Hotel and Restaurants
Railways
Transport by Other Means
Storage
Communication
Real Estate Services
Ownership of Dwelling & Business Services
Banking and Insurance
Public administration and defence
Other Services

CoE
Output Multiplier

Storage

Communication

Real
Estate
Services

15

16

17

0.3812
0.0231
0.0174
0.1765
0.2064
0.8584
0.0084
0.0457
0.0234
0.2256
0.2615
0.0878
0.0260
0.2234
1.0014
0.0291
0.0086
0.1880
0.1271
0.0000
0.1551
0.5911
4.0741

0.4054
0.0230
0.0190
0.1578
0.1792
0.9136
0.0053
0.0288
0.0148
0.0823
0.2676
0.0802
0.0253
0.2309
0.0014
1.0341
0.0095
0.1831
0.1029
0.0000
0.1785
0.6500
3.9428

0.0976
0.0042
0.0033
0.0277
0.0395
0.1490
0.0012
0.0065
0.0033
0.0133
0.0524
0.0715
0.0046
0.0421
0.0003
0.0092
1.1110
0.1193
0.0232
0.0000
0.0519
0.1126
1.8313

78

Ownership
of Dwelling
& Business
Services

Banking
and
Insurance

Public
administration
and defence

Other
Services

18

19

20

21

0.1411
0.0089
0.0062
0.0538
0.0750
0.2756
0.0055
0.0300
0.0154
0.0391
0.0893
0.0481
0.0087
0.0774
0.0005
0.0128
0.0092
1.1155
0.0525
0.0000
0.0769
0.2106
2.1414

0.3413
0.0188
0.0162
0.1148
0.1384
0.6412
0.0049
0.0266
0.0136
0.0650
0.2039
0.0929
0.0226
0.1933
0.0011
0.0374
0.0079
0.1570
1.1096
0.0000
0.1433
0.5562
3.3497

0.9290
0.0511
0.0475
0.2910
0.3395
1.6829
0.0083
0.0452
0.0232
0.1247
0.5393
0.1807
0.0525
0.4973
0.0028
0.0742
0.0230
0.4371
0.2163
1.0000
0.4036
1.6366
6.9693

0.5797
0.0315
0.0275
0.1930
0.2329
1.1108
0.0066
0.0359
0.0184
0.0833
0.3485
0.1351
0.0329
0.3162
0.0018
0.0480
0.0134
0.2692
0.1582
0.0000
1.2674
0.9425
4.9103

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

GLOSSARY
Compensation of
employees
Consumption of
fixed capital
Economic activity

Employed
persons
Employed as per
principal activity
status
Employed as per
subsidiary
activity status
Exports of goods

Exports of
services

Final demand

Final
consumption
expenditure of
government
Final
consumption
expenditure of
households
GDP

Gross fixed
capital formation

Compensation of employees is the total remuneration, in cash or in kind,


payable by an enterprise to an employee in return for work done by the latter
during the accounting period.
Consumption of fixed capital represents the reduction in the value of the fixed
assets used in production during the accounting period resulting from
physical deterioration, normal obsolescence or normal accidental damage.
Any activity resulting in production of goods and services that add value to
national product is considered as an economic activity. Such activities include
production of all goods and services for market (market activities), i.e.
production for pay or profit, and, among the non-market activities, the
production of goods and household services with paid domestic employees
and owner occupied dwellings for own consumption and own account
production of fixed assets.
Number of persons usually employed in the principal and subsidiary statuses.
Those in labour force pursuing some economic activity for major time during
the reference period of 365 days
Those in labour force pursuing some economic activity for a relatively shorter
time (minor time) during the reference period of 365 days
Exports of goods consist of exports of the following items from residents to
non-residents: generally with a change of ownership being involved: general
merchandise, goods for processing, goods procured in domestic ports by nonresident carriers and non-monetary gold.
Exports of services consist of exports of the following services provided by
residents to non-residents: transportation; travel; communications;
construction; insurance; financial; computer and information; royalties and
licence fees; other business services; personal, cultural, and recreational
services; and government services n.i.e.
Transactions that involve purchases of produced goods and services for final
uses are presented in final demand table. The final use for a good or service
is that it is not used up entirely in the reference year as an intermediate input
in the production of some other good or service. Transactions for goods and
services that are completely used to produce other goods and services are
shown in the intermediate input (or use) table of the accounts.
Government final consumption expenditure consists of expenditure, including
imputed expenditure, incurred by general government on both individual
consumption goods and services and collective consumption services.
Household final consumption expenditure consists of the expenditure,
including imputed expenditure, incurred by resident households on individual
consumption goods and services, including those sold at prices that are not
economically significant.
Is the total market value of goods and services produced in the economy
within a given period after deducting the cost of goods and services used up in
the process of production but before deducting allowances for the
consumption of fixed capital. Thus gross domestic product, as here defined, is
at market prices.
Gross fixed capital formation is measured by the total value of a producers
acquisitions, less disposals, of fixed assets during the accounting period plus

79

National Council of Applied Economic Research

Gross value
added

Imports of goods

Imports of
services

Input-output
model

Input-output
tables

Intermediate
consumption
Leontief inverse
(input-output)
table
Multipliers

Output
Output multiplier

Total economy

April, 2014

certain additions to the value of non-produced assets (such as subsoil assets


or major improvements in the quantity, quality or productivity of land)
realised by the productive activity of institutional units.
Gross value added is the value of output less the value of intermediate
consumption; it is a measure of the contribution to GDP made by an individual
producer, industry or sector; gross value added is the source from which the
primary incomes of the SNA are generated and is therefore carried forward
into the primary distribution of income account.
Imports of goods consist of imports of the following items from non-residents
to residents, generally with a change of ownership being involved: general
merchandise, goods for processing, goods procured in foreign ports by
domestic carriers, and non-monetary gold.
Imports of services consist of the following services purchased by residents
from non-residents: transportation; travel; communications; construction;
insurance; financial; computer and information; royalties and licence fees;
other business services; personal, cultural, and recreational services; and
government services n.i.e.
It provides a detailed breakdown of economic activity among business
industries and a detailed breakdown of their inputs and outputs by
commodity associated with some arbitrarily fixed exogenous demand. It also
provides supply requirements from other sources such as imports and
government production of goods and services. The input-output model is a
structural model dealing primarily with resource allocation in the economy
corresponding to an exogenously given demand.
Input-output tables are derived from Supply and Use Tables, which show the
process of flows of goods and services through the economic system between
producers and consumers. The transactors involved in the production process
are individuals (persons or households), establishments (production units of
businesses and governments), non-business entities such as non-profit
institutions, and governments. An input-output table presents a detailed
analysis of the process of production and the use of goods and services
(products) and the income generated in that production.; they can be either in
the form of (a) supply and use tables or (b) symmetric input-output tables.
These tables include the Imports Use and Domestic Use matrices, industry by
industry and product by product matrices plus the Leontief inverse,
multipliers and other analyses of their structure.
Intermediate consumption consists of the value of the goods and services
consumed as inputs by a process of production, excluding fixed assets whose
consumption is recorded as consumption of fixed capital; the goods or
services may be either transformed or used up by the production process.
The columns of the Leontief inverse (input-output) table show the input
requirements, both direct and indirect, on all other producers, generated by
one unit of output
An I-O multiplier is a quantitative measure created by a particular I-O based
economic model. It is an analytical answers to a hypothetical question about
how a certain expenditure is expected to impact the economy. The multipliers
allow users to make estimates of the whole economy impacts of small changes
in the economy
Output consists of those goods or services that are produced within an
establishment that become available for use outside that establishment, plus
any goods and services produced for own final use.
output multiplier for a particular industry is defined to be the total of all
outputs from each domestic industry required in order to produce one
additional unit of output: that is, the column sums (i ) from Leontief inverse
matrix (Lij).
The total economy consists of all the institutional units which are resident in
the economic territory of a country.

80

National Council of Applied Economic Research

April, 2014

Total final
expenditure /
Final Demand

This is the sum total of final consumption, gross capital formation and exports
of goods and services. Total final expenditure is the same as total demand by
final buyers and is equal to total final output.

Total
intermediate
consumption

The total intermediate consumption of each industry is the industrys total


purchases of the outputs of other industries as well as purchases of imports of
goods and services and intra-industry purchases for use in its production
process. This is adjusted for the change in inventories of materials and fuels
and excludes primary inputs.
The total output of an industry is the aggregate value of the goods and services
together with the work-in-progress produced by the industry. It is equal to the
value of the industrys sales plus any increase (and less any decrease) in the
value of its inventories of finished products and work-in progress. Output is
thus measured after deducting holding gains. The outputs of the distribution
and service trades industries are measured on a gross margin basis.
Valuables are produced assets that are not used primarily for production or
consumption, that are expected to appreciate or at least not to decline in real
value, that do not deteriorate over time under normal conditions and that are
acquired and held primarily as stores of value.

Total output

Valuables

81

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi