Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 22

Institutions for pro-growth conduct in the knowledge

economy
Jan Goossenaerts1
Abstract
The private sector is an important engine of growth and innovation. Yet, a private
sector without an accordingly performant and developed public sector would it
develop? In a thought experiment, let us imagine a market place where all land and
water-surface is privately owned, and where the right of way for consumers and
producers of goods and services must be negotiated with landowners. With all private
individuals seeking maximal utility and minimal risk, decision problems and
transaction costs would prohibit the emergence of an economic system beyond barter
trade among neighbours producing goods within enclosed resource endowments.
Under the conditions in the thought-experiment, mankind's discovery journey
(Boorstin, 1983) would have been precluded, and so would have the agricultural,
industrial and knowledge revolutions. History has taken a different course. Commons
regimes have been gradually complemented with private property regimes, and
subjects and those in power alike have been gradually disciplined by fit institutions.
And indeed, those institutions have had a considerable impact on economic
performance (North, 1990).

Ill-designed institutions may lock-in an economy, and public sector enacted barriers
are rightly feared by reformers. Yet, also private sector principals may derive rents
from positions that act as barriers to others, as recognized by the Essential Facilities
Doctrine. Looking at the knowledge economy and the technology and content uses
that differentiate it from the industrial economy, it is not evident what exactly are the
essential facilities that help or prevent principals exploiting the interdependencies
among the division of labour, competence and market size.

This essay questions the fitness of industrial-age institutions for the globalizing and
knowledge-intensifying economy. Particularly in the software and content sectors it
identifies abuses of essential facilities and proposes enabling environment reforms to
curb these abuses so as to spur learning and private sector development. For some
institutional choice options, a pro-growth cause-effect chain is projected.

1
For details on the author, see http://www.citeulike.org/profile/jago

 2010 The author Page 1


1. Introduction
In interaction with the natural and artefactual resource endowments, mankind's

ingenuity and social capabilities give rise to an unfolding sequence of events in which

innovative institutions may become necessary to discipline those with dominant

positions in the socio-technical landscape. The knowledge economy, and the related

markets of software and content (media) have become contentious during the past

decades, as witnessed by attention given to intellectual property rights in general, and

to antitrust (or competition) law. Joseph Stiglitz, former chief economist at the World

Bank, is among the most prominent advocates of improved institutions for knowledge

as a global public good (Stiglitz, 1999). Beyond their role in capital markets, he sees

the provision of knowledge as one of the international public goods that will figure in

the mission of multilateral development banks during the coming decades (Stiglitz,

1998). Yet, in the information economy (Shapiro & Varian, 1999), fit institutions

develop slowly, and so does the competence of creating solutions that respond to local

needs2.

Observing on the one hand the pressing needs of many members of society

and the under-utilization of knowledge, and on the other hand the immense solution

delivery potential of science, technology and education, the Internet, and mobile

communication technologies, it is morally desirable to achieve the knowledge

infrastructure3 that can coach and enable principals4 in developing their livelihood by

2
Leach & Scoones (2006) contrast the slow race to citizens’ solutions, a race to make investment in
science and technology work for the poor, with the two races that generate most excitement: the race
to global economic success and the race to find a universal fix for the problems of developing countries.
3
An infrastructure is a particular set of resources that meets three demand-side criteria (Frischmann,
2005, p 956): (i) the resource may be consumed non-rivalrously; (ii) social demand for the resource is
driven primarily by downstream productive activity (rather than by consumption) that requires the
resource as an input; and (iii) the resource may be used as an input into a wide range of goods and
services, including private goods, public goods and non-market goods.

 2010 The author Page 2


drawing in content and educational resources, as they construct value and mitigate

risks during their livelihood processes. The knowledge infrastructure would enable

the complementary methods of knowledge transfer5. But whereas it has been

envisioned by many, why has it not been created yet? What knowledge do we lack

and why do we fail to deliver in the myriad of livelihoods?

Reflecting earlier enlightened institution design, this essay aims to contribute a

systems architect's6 perspective in the debate, so as to spur more effective action. The

guiding vision is that in the global knowledge economy, control over certain essential

facilities7 will have to be transferred from current private control to a commons8

regime. Whereas the exhaustive pro-and-con argumentation on knowledge economy

reform is beyond the means of a single author, the presentation of the debate and fact-

finding along the phases of the regulative cycle9 provides a structure in which all

4
The term principal is here used to refer to a participant in economic and non-market interactions, who
is disciplined by institutions (accountability), but otherwise free (autonomy).
5
Horizontal methods are fit for transferring tacit knowledge and include apprenticeship, secondments,
imitation, study tours, cross-training, twinning relations and guided learning-by-doing. Vertical
methods are fit for knowledge that can be codified, transmitted to a central repository or library, and
then accessed by interested parties (Stiglitz, 2000).
6
Systems architecting is the discipline that strives for balance and compromise among the tensions of
multiple stakeholder needs and resources, interests and technology (Rechtin & Maier, 1997). Such fit is
achieved from a consideration of the full scope of the system of concern, from strategy to operations,
from product and service functions to technology and market trends.
7
An essential facility is one in which duplication of a given facility, for instance a railroad, local
telecoms network or oil pipeline, is precluded by the monopolist's inherent ownership advantages, but
without which competitors cannot access the market.
8
Commons is a resource management principle by which a resource is made openly accessible to all
within a community regardless of their identity or intended use (Frischmann, 2005, p 1022). By
providing resources as commons, some degree of inclusivity in the socio-technical system is ensured.
In many cultures, common property regimes have been prevalent for the sustainable management of
natural resources such as forests, watershores, grazing and farm lands (Bromley and Cernea, 1989).
These authors describe how market economists have often over-emphasized the enclosure of certain
commons, under-appreciating or neglecting the sustainable outcomes that many cultures had achieved
with common property regimes.
9
Originating in psychological practice, the regulative cycle (van Strien, 1997) has been extensively
applied also as a methodology of practice, geared towards the "interested" regulation of the behaviour
of groups or organizations in the desired direction. Where principals are engaged with the operations
and improvement of a work system such as a plant, a farm, a hospital or a service system, the cycle
includes the following activities: evaluation (of system operations with respect to an instrument or via
benchmarking), problem identification (selection from a problem mess), diagnosis (of the problem
situation – analysis), plan of action (design), and intervention (implementation).

 2010 The author Page 3


stakeholders, irrespective of their socio-economic preferences, can constructively

contribute to a consensus finding process.

In what follows, we first describe the current status quo in the knowledge

economy, paying attention to the public sector and private sector attitudes and

perceived problems. Next, the essential facilities doctrine and insights on

sociotechnical transition pathways (Geels & Schot, 2007) serve as a basis for

diagnosing cause-effect chains and setting an initial agenda for broad reform in the

knowledge economy. Aligning our processual anticipation with reform experience

(Jacobs, 2007) we describe reform drivers and factor choices that should be channeled

into a reform strategy. We identify and develop a small number choices and project

the virtuous cause-effect chains and pro-growth conduct they may enable at multiple

levels in the socio-technical landscape. The essay concludes with a concise project

charter for knowledge economy reform.

2. Public-Private Balance in the Knowledge-intensive


Socio-Technical Landscape
There is a general agreement that ill-guided institutional design is a major source of

barriers to development. This one-sided viewpoint must be balanced though, as

barriers to innovation may also result from an undisciplined appropriation, by private

sector principals, of assets that had better remained common. By recognizing the

patterns and agents of the latter barriers, the reformer can articulate those assets for

which private control must be avoided, so as to let a maximal number of principals

benefit from their non-exclusive10 use.

10
In the sectors addressed here (software, content and learning), several essential facilities are also non-
rivalrous.

 2010 The author Page 4


2.1 Public-Private balance: Received View and Regulatory
Trends in Network Markets
Markets need to be supported by non-market institutions to perform well. Market

economies are institutionally underpinned by a clearly delineated system of property

rights – enabling people and firms to keep the returns on their investments, make

contracts and resolve disputes –, a regulatory apparatus curbing the worst forms of

fraud, anti-competitive behaviour and moral hazard, a moderately cohesive society

exhibiting trust and social cooperation, ... (Rodrik, 1999). These are social

arrangements that economists and engineers usually take for granted. Yet, significant

regulatory reforms have been and are being implemented. Jacobs (1999) describes the

transition from state-led to market-led growth that is still ongoing in many OECD

member countries. (First generation) reforms have yielded major benefits such as

boosting consumer benefits and addressing the lack of flexibility and innovation in the

supply-side of the economy. Benefits have been pursued in network industries such

as telecommunications, electricity, gas, rail transportation and postal sectors. In these

sectors the past two or three decades have seen a paradigm shift concerning the

organization and regulation. The state has been withdrawing from the ownership and

from intervention in market entry, market exit and pricing. It has been recognized that

not all parts of the vertically integrated monopolies are "natural", and that sectors such

as telecommunications services and electricity generation exhibit no technological

features which would preclude workable competition. Developments have also given

rise to the notion that some natural monopolies may be transient as technical progress

makes room for the establishment of competing networks.

The change in views in network industries has induced a change of views

concerning the role of regulation: from a constraint on markets and on the exploitation

of monopoly power and markets, to a promoter of competition, in markets and among

 2010 The author Page 5


networks. Access regulation, the government-imposed requirement that the network

owner open his network for use by other firms, is a key tool for this purpose. This tool

is related to the so-called Essential Facilities Doctrine, a doctrine that has also been

linked to Intellectual Property Rights (Turney, 2005).

2.2 The Undisciplined Knowledge Economy


Since World War II the private sector has gone through a transition from an economy

based on materials to an economy based on the flow of information. Broadly, this

transition has challenged organizations to cope with interdependence, disembodiment,

velocity and power in their strategies (Child & McGrath, 2001), and it has produced

new-economy incumbents with dominant positions, globally and in niches. Van de

Ven (2005) argues that managing technological innovation in an increasingly

knowledge-intensive service economy requires taking a broader, institutional and

political view of information technology and knowledge management. Governments,

while withdrawing from ownership in the traditional network industries, are showing

reluctance to craft interventions in the knowledge economy. In a market where a

patchwork approach to intellectual property (Pendleton, 2005) coexists with a poor

understanding of the technical artefacts and the options they create, dominant

incumbents are free to abuse their control of essential facilities. In specific situations

during the industrialization, architecture11 had been recognized as a sectoral rather

than a private resource, because of its potential to block innovations12 in a broad

domain. Yet, such lessons have not been generalized nor have they been fully

11
IEEE 1471-2000 defines architecture as ―the fundamental organization of a system embodied in its
components, their relationships to each other, and to the environment, and the principles guiding its
design and evolution.‖
12
Stiglitz (2004) cites the example of airplane development: the conflicting airplane patents held by
the Wright Brothers and by Curtis impeded the development of the airplane, until in World War I, the
US government forced the pooling of patents. In the automobile sector, a patent granted to Ransom on
"a four wheel self propelled vehicle" was used to try to coordinate a cartel among automobile
producers; the cartel failed only because Ford challenged the patent—and won.

 2010 The author Page 6


appreciated in the software and information markets13. Varian and Shapiro (1999)

address supply-side tactics in these markets. Demand-side aspects have been largely

neglected in these tactics (Benkler, 2001; Frischmann, 2005), as well as sectoral

consolidation. The private control over architecture is of relevance here. Architecture

patenting (Ransom) has been rightly challenged in the past (Ford, see footnote 12). As

innovations diffuse from a niche to the level of the sociotechnical landscape, their

architecture may deserve classification as an infrastructure resource (Frishmann,

2005): it may be consumed non-rivalrously; demand is driven by downstream

productive activity that requires architecture as an input (rather than by consumption);

and it may be used as input to a wide range of goods and services. Though software

applications diffusion has risen to the landscape level, most applications remain silos

with proprietary architectures and content encodings that are barriers to

interoperability. Even most open-source software lacks an open architecture that

would enable users to compose or evolve their preferred desktop functionality, and

plug-in new services on their content resources. No reference architectures are

managed under a commons regime. On the contrary, successive architectural de-facto

standards have been determined by the agendas of dominant principals in the market.

In software and related patents, the architecture is often part of the claims of

originality. And on software markets, proprietary silo architectures and content

encoding are the backbone of the dominant positions, globally and in niches.

Resulting non-interoperabilities cause slow and expensive innovation: the demand-

side misses (a long tail of) improvements due to the prevailing silo-architecture of

software applications that work with proprietary content encodings. The supply-side

13
An example is the control by Microsoft and Intel of the architectural standards of Personal
Computers. Adopting an open but owned standards strategy Microsoft and Intel maintained a subtle
balance between aggressive diffusion and limited licensing of architectural standards (Borrus and
Zysman, 1997).

 2010 The author Page 7


selfishly pursues the lock-in of customers so as to derive rents from the high

switching-costs, low integration capability, and high customization costs.

In the area of scholarly content we see a rather different phenomenon. Large

parts of the outcome of scientific research, often funded by the public sector, is free-

rided by publishers and authors. For instance for textbooks, the copyright is managed

for the authored work as a whole. Usually the content builds upon a lot of knowledge,

cases and problems that have been developed by a large number of scholars in the

discipline. Authors of (good) textbooks become the champions of the discipline, and

the gatekeepers for innovation in its teaching. Mutually, the textbooks must be

sufficiently different, which encourages authors to re-word large chunks of

disciplinary knowledge without adding much substantially new. While (expensive)

textbooks with re-worded and re-copyrighted contents flood the bookstores,

consolidation and open access to consensus-knowledge that has long been in the

public domain are neglected. Dominant incumbents focus on the most profitable

segments of the market, which they serve with blockbuster-like author-branded books.

Textbooks loose their value even more quickly than would be justified by the progress

in their subject-matter. The essential facility of scientific knowledge is obscured as

there is no means in the work to distinguish the essential facility of science from the

original creativity of the author. Though the creativity of the author was in focus as

copyright law awarded a long period of copyright protection, the textbook-author

obtains a similar form of protection for what often is a derived work.

3. Diagnostics and Agenda


If non-articulated essential facilities figure prominently in the tactics of dominant

principals in the knowledge economy, what kind of reform could discipline these

 2010 The author Page 8


principals? And if some discipline can be achieved by institutional reform, would this

accelerate the construction of a knowledge infrastructure?

Ongoing innovation challenges the institution designer and justifies a self-

regulation approach, yet as the technology stabilizes and/or the polarization increases

between demand- and supply-side, there is ground for government to step in Grajzl &

Murrell, 2007). As was the case in post-Civil War United States14 scale-increase, now

caused by globalization, contributes to increased polarization between demand- and

supply-side principals. Therefore, the perspective that is explored here is one of

channeling landscape pressures into knowledge economy reform. In a global economy,

and because of its barrier-removing effects, such reform will also benefit private

sector development in emerging markets.

3.1 Institutional Fitness in an expanding socio-technical


landscape
In any emerging economy, the socio-technical landscape is an important determinant

of private sector development where the public sector, informed by suitable growth

theories, can invest in specific assets. Drawing upon the multi-level conceptualization

of socio-technical change processes and faced with the global sustainability challenge,

Morioka et al (2006) have proposed a technology transition management framework

to manage technology transition through the interaction of technology push, demand

pull and institutional design. Figure 1 instantiates Morioka's framework for demand-

supply interactions and it visualizes the institutional gap: demand-supply interactions

in information markets are problematic as "material economy" institutions turn out to

14
Djankov et al (2003) and Glaeser and Shleifer (2003) attribute the rise of the regulatory state in post-
Civil War United States to a response to the increased disorder caused by railroads and large firms:
industrialization and commercialization of the American economy undermined the pre-1900 courts as
the sole institution securing property rights.

 2010 The author Page 9


be ill-adapted to emerging forms of resource-exchanges and their supporting essential

facilities.

software, content & services


based demand-supply demand-supply interactions under
interactions without right-conditioned institutions
fit institutions & utilities facilitated by utilities designed for
efficient material/energy/financial
demand for content & flow & people mobility
services in the
principal lifecycle
improvement
misses due to
silo-architecture
institutions
non-interoperabilities
as cross-cutting
infrastructure
innovation decelerator; (utilities)
asset eroder; strategy to lock
incentive destroyer in customers by institution gap
vertical solutions utility gap

supply of software,
content and services

Figure 1: Problematic institutional fitness in an expanding socio-technical landscape15.

Given its ubiquitous appearance, the expansion of the socio-technical landscape with

software, content and derived services seems to call for an institutional intervention

that Jacobs (1999) would classify as a second generation reform: a structural reform

that must secure a longer-term, comprehensive alignment of state, market, and civil

society, and should be based on a longer-term, holistic approach to problems, rather

than focussing on incremental changes to individual sectors and policy decisions.

Several institutional approaches could inform such a knowledge economy reform:

Hess & Ostrom (2007) explore institution analysis and design for the knowledge

commons; The Open Source Movement (Lerner & Tirole, 2001) challenges the rents

that dominant software providers obtain under the winner-takes-it-all competitive

15
While the focus in this paper is on the institutional gap for the knowledge economy (it needs
dedicated institutions as it unfolds in a material economy), a similar need for differential institutions
may distinguish the industrial era and the agricultural era.

 2010 The author Page 10


outcomes in software markets; and the Creative Commons licensing contracts (Lessig,

2001) allows for innovative returns allocation in derivative works.

3.2 Reconfiguration by Concerted Regulative Cycles at


Multiple Levels
The discretionary powers that governments have must be applied with care. The

mock-up of the multi-level concerted regulative cycle depicted in Table 1 helps to

organize the issues that come with the multiple stakeholders. The impact expectations

of broad-based reform can be decomposed as response (regulative) cycles for the

various stakeholders involved. Hence Table 1 addresses agency, scope and design

knowledge sources for each of the levels in the socio-technical landscape. Each

stakeholder is engaged in the value-risk constellation around his or her livelihood with

its resource endowment and factor choices. By institutional design and innovation in

the socio-technical landscape, the factor choices available can be enlarged or

constrained. For each principal, the regulative cycle allows to make changes traceable

to (evidence-supported) needs in the real site work system (livelihood), or its

environment within which more aggregate, yet disciplined, principals determine the

rules or control the resources. At all times and all levels, autonomous persons as pico-

level principals, in group or as individuals make the choices in roles defined in the

institutions and organizations. The use of the terms sub or super indicates that for

some choices in his or her interactions, the principal in the sub-position abides by the

prescriptions enacted by the principal in the super-position.

Table 1: Mock-up of a Multi-level Concerted Regulative Cycle


Level Macro Meso Micro Pico
Aspect (Landscape) (Regime/sector) (Niche/firm)
Typical Principals International, Standards Corporations that persons in the
regional, national and organisations; own, maintain, role of workers,
local authorities Engineering and and/or operate engineers,
Science disciplines plants, land or managers,
service facilities. farmers, parents,
public servants

 2010 The author Page 11


Real site work the economic sectoral the farm, the the livelihood, the
system interactions in a interactions in a factory, the learning and/or
territory territory, or among delivery system work context of
members in a and/or office the person
community of environment that
practice sustain the value
creating processes
Sample Design Regulatory Reform methods of business and Kolbe;
Methods (Jacobs, 2007) scientific research; organization learning paths;
Constitutive engineering design; development Sustainable
Institutional Analysis standards methods Livelihoods
and Design (IAD) development; Framework (SLF)
(Hess & Ostrom, sectoral IAD (Scoones, 1998)
2007) (Hess & Ostrom,
2007)
Representative Parliament in the UK Photo Voltaic cells many exist in the many exist in the
Cases (North, 1990) (Nagamatsu et al, business literature literature on
Limited liability by 2006); psychology and
Law in New York GSM (Bekkers et pedagogy
State (Shiller, 2003) al, 2002)
TRIPS16
Approaches historical comparison comparison among benchmarking social comparison
feeding (North, 1990) sectors (Festinger)
problematization comparative
economics (Djankov
et al, 2003)
Issues growth, inclusivity, innovation competition, care of the self
sustainability, security productivity, and the family
market share

3.3 Factor Dependencies


Prudentially assuming the reality of the institutional gap depicted in Figure 1, Table 2

depicts the factor built-up for the members of an economy as institutions fail to

discipline dominant incumbents in the knowledge economy. The nesting relationships

among resource endowments (right to left along the row of the real site work systems

in Table 1) determines how factor choices or gaps of the public sector (macro and

meso) drive exogeneous factors for the private sector (micro and pico), as described in

Table 3.

At this point, and adopting the multi-level perspective (Schot et al, 1994), it is

important to stress the regime or meso-level as a factor of innovation and

consolidation. Having been present throughout the crafts era, in the industrial society,

16
TRIPS, Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights,
http://www.wto.org/english/docs_e/legal_e/27-trips.pdf

 2010 The author Page 12


meso-level facilities are present via standards and the architectures of dominant

designs that (to a large extent) are shared in an industry. In the knowledge economy

the meso-level sectoral entities are usually weak or absent. This is considered part of

the institutional gap.

Table 2: Factor landscape: the pico-micro impacts of meso-macro (institutional) failure.


Principal Factors Exogenous Factors
Pico - poor products/ low value

economy
polarized
competition)
product/service development (winner-takes-it-all)
innovation market for software, content, learning and
high entry barriers, highly priced, low variety/low
knowledge economy;
weak national institutions vis-a-vis global dominant incumbents in the

Insecurity, non-sustainability, non-inclusivity,

Biophysical environment (including geography, weather, biodiversity)


(person) proposition in niche
markets;
- low participation to the
economy
- persistent poverty
Micro demand - operational and transitional
(firm) inefficiencies;
- lock-in and high switching costs;
- little competition and variety;
- rapid depreciation (pursued by
supplier)
supply Software: monopolies; lock-in
tactics; proprietary control of
architecture; silo architecture and
proprietary content encoding.
Content: focus on reputation
(author-branding); no separation
of master-content and
presentation; much re-wording;
coarse-grained copyright regimes;
focus on high-end segment
Meso learning - lack of international sectoral standards
(sector) content - lack of shared and open architectures
software - obscurity regarding essential facilities
- unclear mandate
Macro nation - negligence of essential facilities for the national
(econo knowledge economy (language, national sectors,...)
my) - under-valueing of evidence base (monopolies)
globe - negligence of global essential facilities (science,
architecture,...);
- under-valueing of evidence base (monopolies)

The public sector neglects its evidence basedness and its scope: it fails to recognize

essential facilities in the knowledge economy and exhibits laissez-faire vis-à-vis the

monopoly positions, free-riding or rents derived from them. Dominant incumbents

 2010 The author Page 13


exploit the absence of fit institutions. In their high-end tactics, they ensure high entry-

barriers for competitors, high prices and high switching costs for their customers, and

low innovation pressures for themselves. As a result only a fraction of the potential

innovation and value construction takes place. Many innovators and potential

investors are discouraged by a winner-takes-it-all logic. Particularly in niche markets,

this causes inertia including the failure to produce content, services and products that

work for the poor. Whereas a knowledge infrastructure could at much lower cost

allow stakeholders with low resource-endowments to participate in the economy, such

participation is currently precluded17 by pricing targeting high-end markets and

obscurity regarding the essential facilities.

4. Designing reform to make knowledge match


development needs
We merge a strategy-pattern for broad-scale regulatory reform18 and concerted

regulative cycles that recognize the multi-level character of transition challenges. The

first section describes for the cause-effect dependencies identified in Table 2, factor

choices that could lead to a more inclusive economy. The second section evaluates the

reform design. The third section lists the main drivers of reform and their application

in the knowledge economy.

4.1 Choice factors driving Exogeneous Factors


Table 3 is built up in the same way as Table 2, but this time the essential facilities in

the knowledge economy are recognized, commons regimes are defined for them, and

suitable sectoral entities take charge of open architectures, open content encoding and

17
Frischmann (2005) broadens the commons versus private control debate to infrastructures such as
those for transportation and communication. These resources are an input to a wide range of goods and
services. Hence the value of the resource shows a high variability, making a commons-based approach
to providing them immensely valuable (Benkler, 2001).
18
Jacobs (2007) has outlined such a pattern that maximizes the chances of genuine and durable success
in environments resistant to reform.

 2010 The author Page 14


interface standards, possible limits to offerings (within open architectures) in areas

that are prone to lock-in.

Table 3: Factor choices available to principals at the multiple levels


Principal Choice Factors Exogenous Factors
Pico - livelihood;

economy
Inclusive
product/service development
market for authoring, learning and
Low hurdle, fairly priced, high variety

National know. economy institutions and utilities

Global knowledge economy institutions and utilities

Biophysical environment (including geography, weather, biodiversity)


(person) - suppliers during (life
long) learning;
- mobility;
- employment
Micro demand - fair prices;
(firm) - choice of supplier;
- rich and customized offer;
- depreciation horizon of the
investment
supply - niches to develop products and
services and establish distinctive
offer;
- (for choices in the supply chain,
see demand)
Meso learning - adopt learning path and portfolio standards
(sector) content - separation of master-content and
presentation;
- platform publications;
- marking open content in publications
software -open component reference architecture for
technical integration19;
-within the component reference
architecture: define horizontal limits to
product offers and/or interoperability duties
Macro nation - essential facilities for the national economy
(econo (knowledge, language, sector, territory and its
my) biophysical characteristics);
- commons regimes for these
globe - knowledge economy institutions recognizing global
essential facilities;
- commons regimes for the essential facilities of the
knowledge economy

Concise descriptions of the exogeneous environment that builds upon fit

choices by super-principals are given in the vertical columns drawn from the right

hand side of the table. For the private sector, qualities of the exogeneous factors are

included as well. In all cases where private sector activity is constrained, encouraged

19
See Reference Model for Technical Integration in INTEROP D9.1 (page 24) (Berre et al., 2004).

 2010 The author Page 15


or controlled by public sector design choices, the designer must understand the private

sectors drivers so as not to damage the market's performance because of local-

optimum seeking behaviour by market participants (shirking). At macro- and meso-

levels the consistency among the institutions is a critical design criterion. Linking the

macro- and meso-level on the one hand, and the micro- and pico-level on the other

hand are the means for enforcement and compliance and the related information needs.

4.2 A Tentative Evaluation of the Reform Design


The factor choices proposed in Table 3 have not been proven. They seek to form the

basis for the eventual replacement of the institutional patchwork and private essential

facilities holdings that currently prevail. Below, the impact of the choices is assessed

by contrasting their effects with those of the prevailing choices, as enforced by

dominant incumbents in the knowledge economy. The small differences indicate that

in the current status quo only (minor) niche innovations are required, and that the

proposed knowledge economy reform can indeed channel the landscape pressures into

a coherent reform.

4.2.1 Software: Component Based Reference Architecture


This choice must be contrasted with the stack wars that currently prevail in the

software world. Incumbents that have acquired dominant positions in (large) niche

markets seek to expand dominance to neighbouring markets. As applications – built

upon the platforms (technology stacks) controlled by different suppliers – must inter-

operate, customers face significant application integration investments. By adopting

at the sectoral level an open multi-tier component based reference architecture such as

the one proposed by Berre et al. (2004), component markets can emerge and the silos

favoured by dominant incumbents can be wrapped first and then gradually be replaced

by more fair solutions.

 2010 The author Page 16


4.2.2 Platform and Language Neutral Publishing
This choice is concerned with reducing the granularity of the item that is authored and

for which copyright is managed. By doing this, text-book publishers and authors will

be less enticed to confuse the (science) essential facilities in monolithic authored

works. Where the granularity of the book and the (archival) journal was suitable for

the age of the printing press, the web allows rights management, authoring, peer

review, royalty disbursement, and service composition on the basis of much smaller

content-chunks. Enabling this will allow the educators in niche markets to author their

own cases within peer-reviewed platforms so as to establish for their audience the

optimal learning content. These authors will also obtain (micro) royalties as their

cases or theory chapters are used by others in the market. In the near future, learning

services can sequence cases and problems for self-propelled (life-long) learners. As

(software) technologies are developed to store language neutral content, and to

present it in the language of the viewer, it will become feasible to produce learning

content in one language and present it or include in the learning curriculum in any

other language for which decoder exists20.

4.2.3 Pro-growth learning paths; portfolios


Finally learning. Current content production has a strong focus on support for the

vertical methods that are fit for knowledge that can be codified, transmitted to a

central repository or library, and then accessed by interested parties. Pro-growth

learning that enables learners to address the problems in their livelihoods or

businesses require improved support for horizontal methods that are fit for

transferring tacit knowledge and include apprenticeship, secondments, imitation,

20
See Universal Networking Digital Language Foundation. (www.undl.org) for the technology and
current language resources. See d Almost All Questions Answered, AAQUA. (www.aaqua.org) for a
running application.

 2010 The author Page 17


study tours, cross-training, twinning relations and guided learning-by-doing. The

concept of learning paths is borrowed from the educational theory; it encompasses the

consistent design and logical construction of a learning process. The education is

thought of as a continuous process. Learners must be able to learn from past

experience and that their learning process must be supervised or coached. A

prerequisite for learning from past experience is that learner and coach both have

insight into past performance of the former. Clear criteria for assessment of

competencies (end level and interim levels) must be used. So, an educational program

based on learning paths calls for a monitoring system that both facilitates learning and

supervision. Portfolios can be part of such a monitoring system. In their portfolios,

learners have to collect 'evidence', so they can prove they have achieved competencies

to a certain level. The aim of the portfolio is that learners actively engage in their own

education and development of knowledge and skills. However, the success of

portfolios depends largely on the extent and availability of coaching. Regular

consultations with a coach are a prerequisite for the success of portfolio learning.

Because portfolio learning is new, and as procedures have not been optimized, it risks

to become a labor-intensive coaching process. Another potential problem is that

learning paths presuppose the cooperation of coaches; they have to align their

activities, adjust assessment criteria etc. Mobility of both learner's and coaches

become possible as standardized processes are enacted, and coaches use standardized

criteria and forms for the assessment of competencies and capabilities. These must be

built upon software and content platforms that facilitate fair mechanisms both

regarding the recognition of essential facilities and commons and regarding the

incentives that will encourage coaches and learners to apply knowledge and create

solutions to local needs that are problematized in the learning path.

 2010 The author Page 18


4.3 Drivers of Reform

Knowledge economy reform will have to overcome vested interests in public and

private sectors, fears of the consequences of change, low skill levels, lingering anti-

market sentiments, and the complexity and uncertainty of reform in a complex and

dynamic socio-technical landscape.

Jacobs (2007) lists, reviews and illustrates the seven key drivers of reform that

have been identified in the academic debate and the development literature. Table 4

lists these drivers and their meaning. For each driver its pertinence to the knowledge

economy is added in the third column. One key driver must be broadened to reflect

the ferment in the knowledge economy: unfolding innovation drives the need for

unfolding reform. Ongoing innovation challenges the institution designer. The trade-

off between a self-regulation approach and a government regulation approach has

been analysed (Grajzl & Murrell, 2007).

Table 4: Drivers of reform in the Knowledge Economy

Key Driver Meaning Pertinence to the knowledge


economy
globalization regulatory competition to lower cost of the knowledge economy incumbents
and doing business; fear of falling behind; include many global players, some of
competitiveness rising cost of the status quo, reducing the whom achieved global status in a few years
cost of change time
crisis an event that upsets the balance of widespread extreme poverty and global
power that has preserved the status quo; warming are being recognized as crises
a high-risk approach to getting reform facing mankind
done
political the yeast that makes other drivers rise; at the leaders that are accountable to the
leadership it best when proactive rather than global society give limited attention to the
reactive; public choice theory feeds knowledge economy;
pessimism as to effectiveness
unfolding reforms in one area can increase the limited attention for reform in the
reform (and pressures for reform in other areas; an knowledge economy is contrasted with the
innovation) aspect is the sequencing of reforms broad-based innovations in the knowledge economy
which show an unfolding pattern
technocratic politicians and senior civil servants with prominent law specialists have analysed
drivers technical training develop reforms that and designed institutions for intellectual
operate on the basis of promotion of the property, including the knowledge
general good commons (Open Source, Creative
Commons)
changes in civil support by stakeholders such as firms incumbents with monopoly positions in
society and workers; Open dialogue and landscape or niche markets seek to protect

 2010 The author Page 19


communication on the cost and benefits their vested interests (rents in a poorly
to improve understanding on all sides of regulated market)
short- and long-term effects of action
and non-action
external pressure this can weaken the public choice driver; Instruments such as those enacted by
it includes international bodies and trade WTO21 (TRIPS) and WIPO22. The latter
agreements instruments are debated among the
specialists. Is there a need for enlightened
initiatives?

5. Conclusion and Outlook


Guy (2007) points out "that the scale economies of information products are

institutional as much as technological phenomena, and ... the contest between business

models for information products is as much political as commercial... In the contest

over the control of information products there is an extreme range of plausible

outcomes: small changes in competition policy and public procurement could easily

tip the world toward a free software model, or could shore up the proprietary software

monopolies."

In a global knowledge-intensive economy, emerging economies have limited

resource-endowments which make them vulnerable as the institutional neglicence of

essential facilities coincides with extreme tactics by dominant knowledge economy

incumbents. History has proven mankind's ability in redrawing institutions as

dominant myopic principals have abused their positions in the socio-technical

landscape. In the past, scale-enlarging shifts have been triggers both for extreme

tactics by myopic principals, and for enlightened institution design. Whereas

dominant principals have had the time to show how to shirk in the knowledge

economy, time has come to respond. With new institutional designs in place,

organizational redesigns will come to reflect them (Meyer and Rowan, 1978), leading

21
WTO, World Trade Organization, see http://www.wto.org/index.htm
22
WIPO, World Intellectual Property Organization, see http://www.wipo.int/portal/index.html.en

 2010 The author Page 20


to structural change in construction of value and the mitigation of risks from

information and knowledge.

Making better use of ICT23 and knowledge (as a global public good), mankind

will be armed to achieve bold targets, including beyond those of the Millenium

Development Goals and the Kyoto Protocol. To these ends, society must engage all

its principals at the pico to macro scales where the carrying capacity of natural,

physical and social assets is concerned and interventions are anticipated.

6. References
1. Bekkers, R., B. Verspagen, & Smits, J. (2002) Intellectual Property Rights and Standardization: the
case of GSM. Telecommunications Policy, 26 (3/4)
2. Benkler, Y. (2001) Property, Commons and the First Amendment: Towards a Core Common
Infrastructure, White Paper for the First Amendment Program, Brennan Center for Justice at NYU
Law School, available at http://www.benkler.org/WhitePaper.pdf
3. Berre, A.-J., A. Hahn, D. Akehurst, J. Bezivin, A. Tsalgatidou, F. Vermaut, L. Kutvonen, P. F.
Linington (2004) INTEROP Deliverable D9.1 “State-of-the art for Interoperability architecture
approaches - Model driven and dynamic, federated enterprise interoperability architectures and
interoperability for non-functional aspects. http://interop-vlab.eu/deliv/dap-domain-architecture-and-
platforms/D91/
4. Boorstin, Daniel J. (1983) The Discoverers – A history of man's search to know his world and
himself, Vintage Books, New York.
5. Borrus, M. and John Zysman (1997) Globalization with borders: The Rise of Wintelism as the future
of Global Competition. Industry and Innovation 4(2).
6. Bromley, D.W. and Cernea, M.M. (1989) The management of common property natural resources:
some conceptual and operational fallacies. World Bank Discussion Paper, Vol. 57, Washington
D.C., The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank.
7. Child, J. & R. G. McGrath (2001) Organizations unfettered: Organizational form in an information-
intensive economy. Academy of Management Journal; 44(6), pp. 1135-1148
8. Djankov, S., Glaeser, E., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. (2003) The New
Comparative Economics. Journal of Comparative Economics 31, pp. 595-619.
9. Frischmann, B.M. (2005) An economic theory of infrastructure and commons management,
Minnesota Law Review, 89, pp. 917-1030.
10.Geels, F.W. & J. Schot (2007) Typology of sociotechnical transition pathways. Research Policy 36,
pp 399-417
11.Grajzl, P. and P. Murrell (2007) Allocating lawmaking powers: Self-regulation vs government
regulation, Journal of Comparative Economics, 35, pp 520-545
12.Guy, F. (2007) Strategic bundling: Information products, market power, and the future of
globalization. Review of International Political Economy 14(1) 26-48
13.Hess, C. & E. Ostrom (eds) (2007) Understanding Knowledge as a Commons – From Theory to
Practice, The MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
14.IEEE 1471-2000. IEEE Recommended Practice for Architectural Description of Software-Intensive
Systems, IEEE Std 1471-2000.
15.Jacobs, S. H. (1999) The Second Generation of Regulatory Reforms, Proc. IMF Conference on
Second Generation Regulatory Reforms, November 8-9, 1999. Washington D.C. url:
www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/seminar/1999/reforms/jacobs.htm
16.Jacobs, Scott (2007) How Broad-based Reforms Succeed in Changing the Business Environment:
The Strategic Use of Drivers of Change, Jacobs & Associates, Washington DC.

23
ICT is the abbreviation for Information and Communications Technology

 2010 The author Page 21


17.Leach, M. & Scoones, I. (2006) The Slow Race, Making Technology work for the poor. Demos,
London, UK. www.demos.co.uk
18.Lerner, J. & Tirole J. (2001) The Open Source Movement: Key Research Questions. European
Economic Review, 45, 819-826.
19.Lessig, L. (2001) The Future of Ideas; The fate of commons in a connected world. New York,
Random House.
20.Meyer, J.W. & Rowan, B. (1978) Institutionalized Organizations: Formal Structure as Myth and
Ceremony. American Journal of Sociology 83(2) pp. 340-363
21.Nagamatsu, A., C. Watanabe, K.L. Shum, Diffusion trajectory of self-propagating innovations
interacting with institutions – incorporation of multi-factors learning function to model PV diffusion
in Japan. Energy Policy, 34, 2006, pp. 411-421
22.North, D.C. (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge.
Cambridge University Press.
23.Pendleton, Michael D. (2005) Balancing Competing Interests in Information Products: A
Conceptual Rethink. Information & Communications Technology Law, Vol. 14, nr. 3, October 2005
24.Rechtin, E, and M.W. Maier, The Art of Systems Architecting, CRC Press, New York, 1997.
25.Rodrik, D. (1999) Institutions For High-Quality Growth: What They Are and How to Acquire
Them, Proc. IMF Conference on Second Generation Regulatory Reforms, November 8-9, 1999.
Washington D.C. url: www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/seminar/1999/reforms/rodrik.htm
26.Schot, J., Hoogma, R., Elzen, B., 1994. Strategies for shifting technological systems: the case of the
automobile system. Futures 26, 1060–1076.
27.Scoones, I. (1998) Sustainable Rural Livelihoods: A Framework for Analysis. IDS Working Paper
No.72. Brighton: Institute of Development Studies.
28.Shapiro, C., & H.R. Varian (1999) Information Rules – A strategic guide to the network economy,
Harvard Business School Press, Boston, Massachusetts, US.
29.Shiller, Robert J. (2003) The New Financial Order – Risk in the 21st Century. Princeton University
Press, Princeton and Oxford.
30.Stiglitz, J. (1998) International Financial Institutions in the 21st century. EIB Papers 3(2) pp 116-
132, European Investment Bank.
31.Stiglitz, J. (2000) “Scan Globally, Reinvent Locally: Knowledge Infrastructure and the Localization
of Knowledge,” in Banking on Knowledge: the Genesis of the Global Development Network, Diane
Stone (ed.), Routledge, 2000, pp. 24-43. Also Chapter 6 in The Rebel Within, Ha-Joon Chang (ed.),
London: Wimbledon Publishing Company, 2001, pp. 194-219. (Originally Keynote Address to the
First Global Development Network Conference, Bonn, December 1999.)
32.Stiglitz, J.E. (2004) Towards a Pro-development and Balanced Intellectual Property Regime.
Keynote address presented at the Ministerial Conference on Intellectual Property for Least
Developed Countries, World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO), Seoul, October 25, 2004.
33.Turney, J. (2005) Defining the Limits of the EU Essential Facilities Doctrine on Intellectual
Property Rights: The Primacy of Securing Optimal Innovation. Northwestern Journal of Technology
and Intellectual Property, Vol. 3 no. 2, pp 179-202
34.van de Ven, A.H. (2005) Running in Packs to Develop Knowledge-Intensive Technologies, MIS
Quarterly Vol. 29 (2) pp 365-378
35.van Strien, P.J. (1997) Towards a Methodology of Psychological Practice, the Regulative Cycle.
Theory and Psychology, 7(5) pp. 683-700

 2010 The author Page 22

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi