Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 8

Fulcrum Research Notes October 2014

Is economic growth permanently lower?*


Juan Antolin-Diaz(1), Thomas Drechsel(2) and Ivan Petrella(3)
The slow pace of recovery from the 2007-2009 recession has recently prompted questions about whether the long-run growth
rate of the US economy (and other industrialised economies) is lower now than it has been on average over the past few
decades. Indeed, for the last five years, forecasts of US and global real GDP growth have been persistently biased upwards. We
extend a state-of-the-art econometric model which tracks economic activity to make it robust to changes in long-run growth.
This allows us to uncover a substantial decline in long-run growth in the US and other industrialised economies.
Figure 1. US GDP: FOMC projections and actual outturn

Real activity forecasts have been persistently biased


upwards in recent years (Figure 1), both in the US and
in other industrialised economies. Every year since the

recovery from the Financial Crisis started economic

projections

revised

downwards as the year advanced. What accounts for

these persistent disappointments? In this note we use a

-2

state-of-the-art econometric model to provide evidence

-4

have

been

progressively

of a persistent decline in economic growth. Failure to


account for this decline in long-run growth may be
behind the persistent disappointments in forecasting
economic activity.

Evidence of breaks in the mean of GDP

Actual Outturn
Nov-11

-6
2009

2010

2011

Nov-09
Dec-12

2012

2013

Nov-10
Dec-13

2014

2015

18
2000-2014
2.25 %

As means of preliminary evidence of a slowdown in


6

GDP growth, we test for multiple breaks in the mean of


GDP growth. We find that there is evidence at the 5%

level in favour of at least one break. The most likely


second most likely break, which is not significant, is
estimated to have occurred in the second quarter of
1973.

-12
1960

1980

1990

2000

2010

(2014), who use Bayesian model averaging to calculate

5% significance

10% significance
6

sample were restricted to exclude the decade of the

2000's, a break date around 1973:Q1 would be the

most likely. This is also in line with the analysis of the

3
2000

labour productivity series by Fernald (2014), who finds

1970

Figure 3. Real-Time Result of the Bai-Perron Test

most likely break date in 2006:Q1. They note that if the

1960-1999
3.6%

-6

These results are similar to those of Luo and Startz


the posterior probability of a single break and find the

2017

Figure 2. Break in US GDP growth as detected by Bai-Perron Test

12

break is in the second quarter of 2000, while the

2016

Source: FOMC

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

* This note is an abridged version of the technical working paper Following the Trend: Tracking GDP when Long-Run Growth is Uncertain,
available for download here. (1) Fulcrum Asset management; (2) LSE; (3) Birkbeck and CEPR.

J. Antolin-Diaz et al., Is economic growth permanently lower?


evidence for three breaks in the mean growth rate of

other sources of idiosyncratic variation. Giannone,

productivity.

in

Reichlin and Small (2008) and Banbura et al. (2012)

1973:Q2, second, a speedup around 1995:Q3, and

have applied the DFM framework to the problem of

finally a second slowdown in the early 2000's. Given

nowcasting GDP; that is, obtaining early estimates of

the somewhat different results obtained with different

quarterly GDP growth by exploiting more timely

samples and methods, the precise number and timing

monthly indicators and the ability of the model to

of breaks remains unclear to us. However, we note that

incorporate quarterly and monthly time series within a

there is substantial evidence for at least one break in

unified framework.

First,

productivity

slowdown

the mean of GDP in the post-War sample, most likely


in the first half of the decade of the 2000's.
It is noteworthy that the early 2000's break detected by
the test only became significant at standard levels with
the recent vintages of National Accounts data, as
displayed in Figure 3. If the test is correct and the
break happened at the beginning of the decade, this
means that the break was not detected until almost
fifteen years later. This highlights the importance of an
econometric framework capable of detecting changes
in long-run growth in a timely and accurate manner.

Tracking GDP when long-run growth is


uncertain
Orphanides

(2003)

emphasized

that

real-time

To take seriously the possibility that long-run growth


might be shifting over time, we introduce two new
features into an otherwise standard DFM of real
activity

data:

time-varying

long-run

growth

component for GDP, and stochastic volatility (SV) in


the innovations to both factors and idiosyncratic
components. We apply the model to a broad panel with
26 variables of US real activity data, and calculate the
probability distribution of long-run GDP growth
(Figure 4).
Figure 4. Evolution of US GDP long-run growth
5

misperceptions about the long-run growth of the


economy can have a large role in monetary policy

mistakes, so the possibility of significant instabilities in


the mean of real output calls for a robust framework

capable of producing timely assessments of short- and


long-run GDP growth.

1
1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

Since the seminal contribution of Giannone et al.


(2008) the Dynamic Factor Model (DFM) has become

Note: This figure plots the posterior median (solid red), together

one of the most important tools to produce real-time

with the 68% and 90% (dashed blue) posterior credible intervals of

tracking estimates (also known as nowcasts) of GDP 1.

our long-run GDP growth estimate. Shaded areas represent NBER


recessions.

DFMs capture the idea that a small number of


unobserved factors drive the comovement of a possibly

An initial slowdown is visible around the late 1960's,

large number of macroeconomic time series, each of

close to the well-known 1973 productivity slowdown.

which may be contaminated by measurement error or

The acceleration of the late 1990's and early 2000's


associated with the productivity boom in the IT sector

Recently these authors have made their nowcasts available

is also clearly visible. Thus, until the middle of the

to financial market participants. See http://www.now-

decade of the 2000's, our estimate conforms well to the

casting.com

generally accepted narrative about fluctuations in

Fulcrum Research Notes October 2014

J. Antolin-Diaz et al., Is economic growth permanently lower?


Figure 5. Evolution of US GDP long-run growth in Real Time

potential growth. It must be noted, however, that


according to our estimates until the most recent part of

68th pctl

90th pctl

the sample, the historical average of 3.15% is always

5.0

Median

Recursive Mean

contained within the 90% credible interval. This is

4.5

consistent with the fact that the break tests do not find

4.0

significant breaks during 1973 or the mid-1990s.

3.5

Finally, from its peak of about 3.25% in late 1998 to its

3.0

level as of June 2014, 2.25%, the median estimate of

2.5

the trend has declined by one percentage point, a more

2.0

substantial decline than the one observed after the


original

productivity

slowdown

of

the

1970's.

Moreover, the decline appears to have happened


gradually since the start of the 2000's, with the
reductions in trend growth clustered around two

1.5
1.0
2000

2002

2004

2006

2008

2010

2012

2014

Note: The shaded areas represent the 68th and 90th percentile,
together with the median of the posterior credible interval of the

episodes: one around the middle of the decade, but

current value of long-run GDP growth, re-estimated daily from

before the Financial Crisis, and a second after the

January 2000 to September 2014 using the vintage of data

recession, at the beginning of the subsequent recovery.

available at each point in time. The blacked dashed line the


contemporaneous estimate of the historical average of GDP growth

Real-Time Evidence of a Slowdown in US

rate with the start of the sample fixed at Q1:1960.

GDP

Long-run growth fluctuations in the G7

As is well known, macroeconomic time series are

So far we have focused our discussion on the US

revised (sometimes heavily) over time, and in many

economy, where long-run growth had been remarkably

cases these revisions contain valuable information that

stable until the turn of century. The analysis of data

was not available at initial release. Therefore, it is

from other industrialized economies indicates that the

possible that our results are only apparent using the

post-War stability of the US long-run growth rate is an

current vintage of data, and our model would not have

exception rather than the rule.Figure 6 plots the

been able to detect the slowdown as it happened. To

estimate of long-run growth resulting from re-

address this concern, we reconstruct our dataset at

estimating our model with data for each of the other

each point in time, using vintages of data available

G7 economies. Large fluctuations in trend growth are

from the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ALFRED

apparent for most of the countries: during the 1960s,

database. We document how, by the summer of 2011

Germany, France and Italy were growing by 4% on a

the model would have concluded that a significant

sustained basis, while Japan was growing by about 7%.

decline in long-run growth was behind the slow

These high growth rates were a consequence of the

recovery. That is, three years before the break test gave

need to rebuild the capital stock from the destruction

a conclusive answer.

of World War II, and were bound to end as the


continental

European

and

Japanese

economies

converged towards US levels of output per capita.


The UK and Canada display a more stable profile,
similar to that of the US, although the slowdown in the
1970's is more clearly visible in the Canadian data.
Again, similar to the US, an acceleration in the late
Fulcrum Research Notes October 2014

J. Antolin-Diaz et al., Is economic growth permanently lower?


Figure 6. Posterior estimate of long-run growth (1960-2014)
Canada

Germany

4.5

3.5
3
3
2

2.5

2
1.5
1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

0
1960

1970

1980

United Kingdom

1990

2000

2010

2000

2010

2000

2010

France

4.5

3.5

3
3
2.5
2

1.5
1
1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

0
1960

1970

1980

Japan

1990

Italy

7
4

6
5

4
2

3
2

1
0

0
-1
1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

Fulcrum Research Notes October 2014

2010

-1
1960

1970

1980

1990

J. Antolin-Diaz et al., Is economic growth permanently lower?

1990's and a subsequent slowdown in the mid 2000's

It is worth noting that the weakness of productivity of

is observed. It is interesting to note that applying the

recent years is not confined to the US economy. Figure

break test to the other G7 economies breaks are

7 illustrates this point by plotting the five-year

detected for most countries, and once again breaks are

centered moving average of the growth in real output

clustered around two episodes, the early 1970's and the

per hour worked. A marked slowdown is visible in all

early 2000's. An exception is the UK, where no break is

countries, and all of the areas are experiencing

detected but our model estimates a substantial decline

productivity growth below 1%, an unprecedented

in trend growth, an issue that has been extensively

phenomenon in the post-War period. The case of the

discussed

real-time

UK, where measured productivity has been slightly

application to the US suggests that it is possible that

negative since the Financial Crisis, is particularly

our model is detecting the decline in long-run growth

striking. The coincidence in the timing of the current

earlier than the break test.

productivity slowdown across countries suggests a

in

UK

policy

circles.

Our

By applying a simple accounting identity, we can take a


first step at giving a more structural interpretation of
the estimated fluctuations in long-run growth. By this
identity, the growth rate of output is equal to the sum
of the growth rates of labour productivity, hours per
capita and population growth. This exercise reveals, as
expected, that secular movements in the growth rate of
productivity are behind the bulk of changes in long-run
growth. Sometimes, however, other factors can play an

driving common factor, and a more `structural'


interpretation of the decline in productivity growth
remains an interesting open question which we leave
for further research. Nevertheless, the possibility that
trends
different

in

productivity
currently

than

growth
they

are
were

substantially
historically

highlights the need to incorporate the uncertainty


about long-run growth into econometric models and
projections.

important role. In Japan and continental Europe,


population growth slowed down during the sample
1960-2014, making a negative contribution to overall
growth in the last decade in Germany and Japan, and
close to zero in France and Italy.
In the US, the productivity slowdown of the early
1970s was partially masked by an increase in hours per
capita (mainly a result of increases in female labour
force participation) and population growth during the
period 1973-2005, resulting in a broadly stable longrun growth rate of about 3% that has come to be
regarded as a stylized fact of the US economy.
However, as pointed out by Gordon (2014), in recent
years, the growth rates of productivity, hours per
capita

and

population

have

all

slowed

down

persistently, leading to a clear decline in long-run GDP


growth significant enough to be detected by structural
break tests.
Fulcrum Research Notes October 2014

J. Antolin-Diaz et al., Is economic growth permanently lower?

Figure 7. Labour productivity growth, % 5-year centered m.a.

CA

JP

Europe

UK

US

10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
-1
1960

1970

1980

1990

2000

2010

Note: Labour productivity calculated as the ratio of total real output to aggregate hours worked. Europe refers to the GDP weighted average of
Germany, France and Italy. Sources: Conference Board Total Economy Database, IMF World Economic Outlook.

Fulcrum Research Notes October 2014

J. Antolin-Diaz et al., Is economic growth permanently lower?

References

Banbura, M., Giannone, D., Modugno, M., and


Reichlin, L. (2012). Now-casting and
the real-time data flow, Working Paper.
Fernald, J. (2014). Productivity and potential
output before, during, and after the
great recession. NBER Macroeconomics Annual
2014, 29.
Giannone, D., Reichlin, L., and Small, D. (2008).
Nowcasting: The real-time informational
content of macroeconomic data, Journal of
Monetary Economics, 55(4):665676.
Gordon, R. J. (2014). The Demise of U.S.
Economic Growth: Restatement, Rebuttal,
and Reections, NBER Working Papers 19895,
National Bureau of Economic
Research, Inc.
Luo, S. and Startz, R. (2014). Is it one break or
on going permanent shocks that
explains US Real GDP? Journal of Monetary
Economics, 66:155(163).
Orphanides, A. (2003). The quest for prosperity
without inflation, Journal of Monetary
Economics, 50(3):633-663.

Fulcrum Research Notes October 2014

J. Antolin-Diaz et al., Is economic growth permanently lower?


Disclaimer
This material is for your information only and is not intended to be used by anyone other than you. It is directed at professional
clients and eligible counterparties only and is not intended for retail clients. The information contained herein should not be
regarded as an offer to sell or as a solicitation of an offer to buy any financial products, including an interest in a fund, or an official
confirmation of any transaction. Any such offer or solicitation will be made to qualified investors only by means of an offering
memorandum and related subscription agreement. The material is intended only to facilitate your discussions with Fulcrum Asset
Management as to the opportunities available to our clients. The given material is subject to change and, although based upon
information which we consider reliable, it is not guaranteed as to accuracy or completeness and it should not be relied upon as such.
The material is not intended to be used as a general guide to investing, or as a source of any specific investment recommendations,
and makes no implied or express recommendations concerning the manner in which any clients account should or would be
handled, as appropriate investment strategies depend upon clients investment objectives.
Funds managed by Fulcrum Asset Management LLP are in general managed using quantitative models though, where this is the
case, Fulcrum Asset Management LLP can and do make discretionary decisions on a frequent basis and reserves the right to do so
at any point. Past performance is not a guide to future performance. Future returns are not guaranteed and a loss of principal may
occur. Fulcrum Asset Management LLP is authorised and regulated by the Financial Conduct Authority of the United Kingdom (No:
230683) and incorporated as a Limited Liability Partnership in England and Wales (No: OC306401) with its registered office at
Marble Arch House, 66 Seymour Street, London, W1H 5BT. Fulcrum Asset Management LP is a wholly owned subsidiary of
Fulcrum Asset Management LLP incorporated in the State of Delaware, operating from 767 Third Avenue, 39th Floor, New York,
NY 10017.
2014 Fulcrum Asset Management LLP. All rights reserved.

Fulcrum Research Notes October 2014

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi