Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 10

The SaversSpenders Theory of Fiscal Policy

By N. GREGORY MANKIW*
The literature on the macroeconomic effects
of fiscal policy and, in particular, of government
debt is founded on two canonical models. The
purpose of this paper is to suggest that both
models are deficient and to propose a new
model to take their place.
The first canonical model is the Barro-Ramsey
model of infinitely-lived families (Robert Barro,
1974). According to this model, the governments
debt policy redistributes the tax burden among
generations, but families, who want to smooth
their consumption over time, reverse the effects of
this redistribution through their bequests. Government debt is completely neutrala proposition
called Ricardian equivalence.
The second canonical model of government
debt is the Diamond-Samuelson model of overlapping generations (Peter Diamond, 1965). In
this model, people smooth consumption over
their own lifetimes, but there is no bequest
motive. When the government issues debt, it
enriches some generations at the expense of
others, crowds out capital, and reduces steadystate living standards.
In this paper, I first discuss the facts that lead
me to reject these canonical models. I then
propose an alternative model and develop
briefly its implications for fiscal policy.

consumption over time. There is much reason to


be skeptical about this assumption.
A large empirical literature, starting with
Robert Halls (1978) seminal random-walk theorem, has addressed the question of how well
households intertemporally smooth their consumption. Although this literature does not
speak with a single voice, the consensus view is
that consumption smoothing is far from perfect.
In particular, consumer spending tracks current
income far more than it should.
In our 1989 paper, John Campbell and I considered a world populated with two types of
consumers, some following the permanentincome hypothesis and some following the simple rule-of-thumb of consuming their current
income. In this world, consumption does not
follow a random walk: predictable changes in
income lead to predictable changes in consumption, depending on the prevalence of rule-ofthumb behavior. We estimated that about half of
income goes to rule-of-thumb consumers.
Subsequently, various papers have confirmed
the great influence of current income on consumer spending. John Shea (1995) used microeconomic data to examine predictable changes
in wages resulting from union contracts and
found that a predictable increase in the wage of
1 percent leads to an increase in consumption of
0.89 percent. Jonathan Parker (1999 p. 969)
examined predictable income changes resulting
from Social Security taxes. He reported that
the elasticity of expenditures on nondurable
goods with respect to the predictable declines in
income that are studied is around one-half.
Nicholas Souleles (1999 p. 956) examined the
effect of predictable income tax refunds and
concluded that the response of total consumption was found to be at least 35 percent of
refunds within a quarter, up to over 60 percent.
There are various ways to view this rule-ofthumb behavior. One possibility is that consumers deviate from the assumption of fully rational
expectations. Perhaps some consumers naively
extrapolate their current income into the future;
or perhaps all consumers weigh their current

I. Why We Need a New Model

Three facts persuade me that neither the


Barro-Ramsey model nor the DiamondSamuelson model is adequate for analyzing fiscal policy.
A. Consumption Smoothing
Is Far From Perfect
Both the Barro-Ramsey model and the
Diamond-Samuelson model assume that all
households use financial markets to smooth

* Department of Economics, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA 02138.


120

VOL. 90 NO. 2

MICROECONOMIC HETEROGENEITY IN MACROECONOMICS

income too heavily when looking ahead to their


future income because, as a psychologist might
explain, current income is the most salient piece
of information available (Amos Tversky and
Daniel Kahneman, 1973).
Alternatively, one can view the rule-ofthumb behavior as resulting from consumers
who face binding borrowing constraints. The
recent consumption literature on buffer-stock
saving (e.g., Christopher Carroll, 1997) can be
seen as providing a richer description of this
rule-of-thumb behavior. Buffer-stock savers are
individuals who have high discount rates and
often face binding borrowing constraints. Their
savings might not be exactly zero: they might
hold a small buffer stock as a precaution against
very bad income shocks. But the existence of
this small buffer does not alter the central result
that their current income has a large influence
over their consumption.
B. Many People Have Net Worth Near Zero
Examination of data on wealth holdings suggests that there are many households for which
saving is not a normal activity. One striking
comparison is between the income distribution
and the wealth distribution. According to the
U.S. Census Bureau, the lowest two quintiles of
the income distribution earn about 15 percent of
income. By contrast, Edward Wolff (1998) reports that the lowest two quintiles of the wealth
distribution hold only 0.2 percent of household
wealth.
A related and equally striking fact is the low
absolute level of wealth with which many
households operate. Wolff (1998) reports that
the mean net worth of the lowest two quintiles
of the wealth distribution is a mere $900. If we
exclude home equity on the grounds that it is
not always liquid, the mean for this group falls
to a negative $10,600, indicating that debts such
as credit-card balances exceed financial assets.
Net worth is zero or negative for 18.5 percent of
households; excluding home equity, the number
of households in the red rises to 28.7 percent.
Reflecting on these facts, one cannot help but
be drawn to a simple conclusion: many households do not have the financial wherewithal to
do the intertemporal consumption-smoothing assumed by much modern macroeconomic theory,
including the Barro-Ramsey and Diamond-

121

Samuelson models of fiscal policy. Acknowledging the prevalence of these low-wealth households
helps explain why consumption tracks current income as strongly as it does.
C. Bequests Are an Important Factor
in Wealth Accumulation
While many people have almost no wealth, a
few have much. The top 5 percent of the income
distribution has historically earned 1520 percent of all income. But the top 5 percent of the
wealth distribution holds 60 percent of the economys wealth and 72 percent of financial wealth
(i.e., wealth excluding home equity). This great
accumulation by a small part of the population
suggests that some households have motives
beyond normal life-cycle smoothing. A bequest
motive is the obvious candidate.
As a matter of accounting, each dollar of
wealth that a person holds will either be spent
during his lifetime or left as a bequest after he
dies. Laurence Kotlikoff and Lawrence Summers (1981) estimated the relative importance
of the two kinds of wealth. They concluded (p.
706) that intergenerational transfers account
for the vast majority of aggregate U.S. capital
formation. Any model that attempts to explain
how fiscal policy affects the economy must
come to grips with this fact.
II. A New Model

The three pieces of evidence I have just


discussed suggest that we need a new macroeconomic model of fiscal policy. Both the
Barro-Ramsey model and the DiamondSamuelson model are inconsistent with the
empirical finding that consumption tracks
current income and with the numerous households with near zero wealth. In addition, the
Diamond-Samuelson model is inconsistent
with the great importance of bequests in aggregate wealth accumulation.
A new model of fiscal policy needs a particular sort of heterogeneity. It should include both
low-wealth households who fail to smooth consumption over time and high-wealth households
who smooth consumption not only from year to
year, but also from generation to generation.
That is, there is a need for a model in which
some consumers plan ahead for themselves and

122

AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS

their descendants, while others live paycheckto-paycheck. To see what might be learned from
such a model, I sketch a simple example in the
rest of this paper.
Imagine that the economy is populated by
two sorts of people. One group, which I will call
savers, has behavior that is described by the
Barro-Ramsey model: they have an operative
intergenerational bequest motive and, thus, infinite horizons. A second group, which I will
call spenders, consumes their entire after-tax
labor income in every period. This savers
spenders model of fiscal policy is extraordinarily simple (and its antecedents in my empirical
paper with Campbell are obvious). But its policy implications could not be more radical, as
the following propositions make clear.
PROPOSITION 1: Temporary tax changes have
large effects on the demand for goods and services.
In early 1992, President George Bush pursued a novel policy to deal with the lingering
recession in the United States. By executive
order, he lowered the amount of income taxes
that were being withheld from spenders paychecks. The order did not reduce the amount of
taxes that spenders owed; it merely delayed
payment. The higher take-home pay that spenders received during 1992 was to be offset by
higher tax payments, or smaller tax refunds,
when income taxes were due in April 1993.
What effect should this policy have? According to the logic of either the Barro-Ramsey or
Diamond-Samuelson model of fiscal policy,
consumers should realize that their lifetime resources were unchanged and, therefore, save the
extra take-home pay to meet the upcoming tax
liability. By contrast, President Bush claimed
that his policy would provide money people
can use to help pay for clothing, college, or to
get a new car. That is, he believed that consumers would spend the extra income, thereby
stimulating aggregate demand and helping the
economy recover from the recession.
Evidence supports Bushs conjecture. Shortly
after the policy was announced, Matthew Shapiro and Joel Slemrod (1995) asked people what
they would do with the extra income. Fiftyseven percent of the respondents said they
would save it, use it to repay debts, or adjust

MAY 2000

their withholding in order to reverse the effect


of Bushs executive order. Forty-three percent
said they would spend the extra income. Thus,
for this policy change, most people were planning to act as standard theory posits, but many
planned to spend the extra income. This result is
easily explained by the saversspenders model
of fiscal policy.
PROPOSITION 2: Government debt need not
crowd out capital in the long run.
Although the saversspenders model gives
fiscal policy a strong influence in the short run,
it renders it less potent in the long run. In
particular, if taxes are lump-sum (or if they are
levied entirely on inelastically supplied labor),
then government debt does not influence the
steady-state capital stock. In a limited sense,
debt neutrality holds in the long run, even if
not in the short run. As Kent Smetters (1999)
puts it, Ricardian equivalence is a long-run
leviathan.
This result follows from the standard steadystate condition: f (k) . In the long run, the
marginal product of capital must equal the savers rate of time preference. (Including exogenous technological progress in the model would
alter this condition, but not in any important
way.) This equation pins down the steady-state
capital stock, regardless of the level of government debt.
How can the governments debt policy have a
strong short-run effect but no long-run effect?
Imagine that the government gives everyone a
one-time tax cut, financed by a permanently
higher level of debt (and thus higher taxes to
finance the interest payments). The initial response of the savers is to do nothing: They are
Ricardian in looking ahead to their future tax
liabilities. The spenders, however, immediately
consume their tax cut. This extra consumption
reduces investment, which in turn raises the
marginal product of capital and thus the interest
rate. The higher interest rate, in turn, induces
savers to save more. Their higher saving continues until the marginal product of capital is
driven back down to their rate of time preference. Hence, the debt-financed tax cut temporarily crowds out capital accumulation, but the
permanently higher level of debt does not depress the steady-state capital stock.

VOL. 90 NO. 2

MICROECONOMIC HETEROGENEITY IN MACROECONOMICS

PROPOSITION 3: Government debt increases


steady-state inequality.
Although Proposition 2 says that government
debt does not affect the steady-state capital
stock and national income, government debt
does influence the distribution of income and
consumption in the saversspenders model.
(For a similar result in a somewhat different
model, see Kevin Fletcher [1999 Ch. 2]). A
higher level of debt means a higher level of
taxation to pay for the interest payments on the
debt. The taxes fall on both spenders and savers,
but the interest payments go entirely to the
savers. Thus, a higher level of debt raises
the steady-state income and consumption of the
savers and lowers the steady-state income and
consumption of the spenders. The spenders,
however, already had lower income and consumption than the savers (for only the savers
earn capital income). Thus, a higher level of
debt raises steady-state inequality in income
and consumption.
PROPOSITION 4: Substantial long-run crowding out can occur if taxes are distortionary.
Proposition 2 regarding long-run debt neutrality holds if taxes are lump-sum. As in the
standard Barro-Ramsey model, things change
dramatically if taxes are distortionary. To see
how, suppose that taxes are raised with a proportional income tax with rate . The following
equations describe the steady state:
y fk

y rD g
r f k
1 r
where the notation is standard. The first equation is the production function. The second
equation states that tax revenue ( y) equals the
interest on the debt (rD) plus government
spending ( g). The third equation states that the
interest rate (r) equals the marginal product of
capital. (Both interest income and capital income are assumed to be taxed at the same rate,
so the tax does not affect this equation.) The

123

fourth equation states that the after-tax interest


rate equals the savers rate of time preference
(). Given these equations, it is straightforward
to see how an increase in government debt
affects the economy. Higher debt leads to
higher debt service; a higher debt service requires a higher tax rate; a higher tax rate leads
to a higher before-tax interest rate; and a higher
interest rate leads to a smaller steady-state capital
stock. As in the Diamond-Samuelson model, government debt crowds out capital, although the
mechanism here is completely different.
It is possible to calibrate the magnitude of this
effect. By differentiating this system of equations,
one can solve for an expression to show how
much debt crowds out capital:
dk/dD Df /f
1 ff / f 2 1 .
If the production function is Cobb-Douglas y
k , this becomes:
dk/dD 1 D/k
1 1 / 1 .
For the U.S. economy, taxes are about one-third
of income ( 13), capital earns about onethird of income ( 13), and the government
debt equals about one-sixth of the capital stock
(D/k 1 6 ). For these parameter values, dk/
dD 1.125. That is, an extra dollar of
government debt reduces the steady-state capital stock by slightly more than one dollar. Naturally, this numerical result is sensitive to
various assumptions. (Introducing depreciation,
so that the production function is f(k) k
k, reduces crowding out as measured by dk/
dD, whereas taking a broad view of capital, so
that is larger than 13, raises it.) Nonetheless,
this example shows that substantial steady-state
crowding out can occur simply because of distortionary taxation.
PROPOSITION 5: The optimal steady-state
capital tax from spenders standpoint is zero.
Suppose that spenders are in the majority and
therefore control tax policy. They have to pay
for an exogenous level of government spending

124

AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS

g, which can either be a public good or a


transfer payment. The choice this majority faces
is how much to tax labor income and how much
to tax capital income. In making this choice,
the goal is to maximize after-tax wages. Thus,
the spender majority ignores the welfare of the
saver minority.
To keep things simple, I start by comparing
alternative steady states. The issue of tax policy
then boils down to the following optimization
problem:
maximize 1 w
,

subject to
w fk f kk

w f kk g
1 f k .
The objective here is simply to maximize the
after-tax wage, (1 )w. In pursuing this goal,
the spender majority faces three constraints.
The first constraint says that labor earns its
marginal product, which by Eulers theorem
equals output left after capital is paid its marginal product. The second constraint is a government budget constraint, which says that
revenue from labor taxes plus revenue from
capital taxes must equal government spending.
The third constraint is the steady-state condition
stating that the after-tax marginal product of
capital equals the savers discount rate.
I will skip the details of the solution and go
straight to the result: 0. That is, the optimal
tax on capital income is zero. This is true even
though I have been doing the optimal tax problem from the standpoint of the spenders, who
hold no capital.
Why do spenders want to exempt capital income from taxation? The reason is that the
supply of capital is highly elastic in this model.
In the long run, it is infinitely elastic at rate .
When capital is taxed, the quantity falls, which
in turn depresses the real wage. This effect is
large enough to make any tax on capital income
undesirable, even from the perspective of people who own no capital.
In light of this result, one might wonder why
the populace is not clamoring to eliminate the

MAY 2000

taxation of capital income. One answer is that


people are not focused only on the steady state.
In the short run, spenders are tempted to confiscate all capital and enjoy a temporary consumption binge. Indeed, the same high rate of
time preference that induces spenders not to
save may lead them to favor capital taxation,
despite its adverse long-run effects. Of course,
the usual issues of time-consistency also arise
here, as in any analysis of capital taxation.
III. Conclusion

Economists use simple models to develop


and hone their intuition. For the macroeconomic
analysis of fiscal policy, the two dominant
models have been the Barro-Ramsey model of
intergenerational altruism and the DiamondSamuelson model of overlapping generations.
In my view, neither is satisfactory. A better
model would acknowledge the great heterogeneity in consumer behavior that is apparent in
the data. Some people have long time horizons,
as evidenced by the great concentration of
wealth and the importance of bequests in aggregate capital accumulation. Other people have
short time horizons, as evidenced by the failure
of consumption-smoothing and the prevalence
of households with near-zero net worth. The
saversspenders theory sketched here takes a
small step toward including this microeconomic
heterogeneity in macroeconomic theory, and it
yields some new and surprising conclusions
about fiscal policy.
REFERENCES
Barro, Robert J. Are Government Bonds Net

Wealth? Journal of Political Economy, NovemberDecember 1974, 82(6), pp. 1095


1117.
Campbell, John Y. and Mankiw, N. Gregory.

Consumption, Income and Interest Rates:


Reinterpreting the Time Series Evidence, in
Olivier Jean Blanchard and Stanley Fischer,
eds., NBER macroeconomics annual: 1989.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1989, pp. 185
216.
Carroll, Christopher D. Buffer-Stock Saving
and the Life Cycle/Permanent Income Hypothesis. Quarterly Journal of Economics,
February 1997, 112(1), pp. 155.

VOL. 90 NO. 2

MICROECONOMIC HETEROGENEITY IN MACROECONOMICS

Diamond, Peter A. National Debt in a Neoclas-

sical Growth Model. American Economic


Review, December 1965, 55(5), pp. 1126 50.
Fletcher, Kevin. Government Debt and the Intragenerational Distribution of Income. Ph.D
dissertation, Harvard University, September
1999.
Hall, Robert E. Stochastic Implications of the
Life CyclePermanent Income Hypothesis:
Theory and Evidence. Journal of Political
Economy, December 1978, 86(6), pp. 971 87.
Kotlikoff, Laurence J. and Summers, Lawrence
H. The Role of Intergenerational Transfers

in Aggregate Capital Accumulation. Journal


of Political Economy, August 1981, 89(4),
pp. 706 32.
Parker, Jonathan. The Response of Household
Consumption to Predictable Changes in Social Security Taxes. American Economic
Review, September 1999, 89(4), pp. 959 73.
Shapiro, Matthew D. and Slemrod, Joel. Consumer Response to the Timing of Income:

125

Evidence from a Change in Tax Withholding. American Economic Review, March


1995, 85(1), pp. 274 83.
Shea, John. Union Contracts and the LifeCycle/Permanent-Income Hypothesis. American Economic Review, March 1995, 85(1), pp.
186 200.
Smetters, Kent. Ricardian Equivalence: LongRun Leviathan. Journal of Public Economics, September 1999, 73(3), pp. 395 421.
Souleles, Nicholas S. The Response of Household
Consumption to Income Tax Refunds. American Economic Review, September 1999, 89(4),
pp. 94758.
Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel. Availability: A Heuristic for Judging Frequency and
Probability. Cognitive Psychology, September
1973, 5(2), pp. 20732.
Wolff, Edward N. Recent Trends in the Size
Distribution of Household Wealth. Journal
of Economic Perspectives, Summer 1998,
12(3), pp. 13150.

This article has been cited by:


1. Matthieu Charpe, Stefan Khn. 2015. Demand and supply effects of bargaining power shocks.
Economic Modelling 51, 21-32. [CrossRef]
2. J. Andrs, J. E. Bosc, J. Ferri. 2015. Household Debt and Fiscal Multipliers. Economica 82:10.1111/
ecca.2015.82.issue-s1, 1048-1081. [CrossRef]
3. Vivek Prasad. 2015. Balanced Budget Tax Cuts in a Liquidity-Constrained Economy. The Manchester
School 83:10.1111/manc.2015.83.issue-s3, 87-119. [CrossRef]
4. STEVEN G. CRAIG, EDWARD C. HOANG, DIETRICH VOLLRATH. 2015. Household
Response to Government Debt: Evidence from Life Insurance Holdings. Journal of Money, Credit and
Banking 47:10.1111/jmcb.2015.47.issue-5, 819-845. [CrossRef]
5. R. McManus. 2015. Austerity versus stimulus: the polarizing effect of fiscal policy. Oxford Economic
Papers 67, 581-597. [CrossRef]
6. Giorgio Motta, Patrizio Tirelli. 2015. MONEY TARGETING, HETEROGENEOUS AGENTS,
AND DYNAMIC INSTABILITY. Macroeconomic Dynamics 19, 288-310. [CrossRef]
7. Nora Traum, Shu-Chun S. Yang. 2015. When Does Government Debt Crowd Out Investment?.
Journal of Applied Econometrics 30:10.1002/jae.v30.1, 24-45. [CrossRef]
8. 2015. Economic Modelling 48. . [CrossRef]
9. Markus Leibrecht, Johann Scharler. 2015. Government Size and Business Cycle Volatility: How
Important are Credit Constraints?. Economica 82:326, 201. [CrossRef]
10. George Hondroyiannis, Dimitrios Papaoikonomou. 2015. When does it pay to tax? Evidence from
state-dependent fiscal multipliers in the euro area. Economic Modelling 48, 116. [CrossRef]
11. Hiroaki Sasaki. 2015. Positive and Negative Population Growth and Long-Run Trade Patterns: A
Non-Scale Growth Model. The International Economy . [CrossRef]
12. R. Chetty, J. N. Friedman, S. Leth-Petersen, T. H. Nielsen, T. Olsen. 2014. Active vs. Passive
Decisions and Crowd-Out in Retirement Savings Accounts: Evidence from Denmark. The Quarterly
Journal of Economics 129, 1141-1219. [CrossRef]
13. Edward F. Buffie. 2014. The Taylor principle fights back, Part II. Journal of Economic Dynamics and
Control . [CrossRef]
14. Luigi Marattin, Simone Salotti. 2014. Consumption multipliers of different types of public spending:
a structural vector error correction analysis for the UK. Empirical Economics 46, 1197-1220. [CrossRef]
15. Carlos J. Garcia, Wildo D. Gonzalez. 2014. Why does monetary policy respond to the real exchange
rate in small open economies? A Bayesian perspective. Empirical Economics 46, 789-825. [CrossRef]
16. Kazuo Nishimura, Carine Nourry, Thomas Seegmuller, Alain Venditti. 2014. PUBLIC SPENDING
AS A SOURCE OF ENDOGENOUS BUSINESS CYCLES IN A RAMSEY MODEL WITH
MANY AGENTS. Macroeconomic Dynamics 1-21. [CrossRef]
17. Xiaodan Gao, Viktoria Hnatkovska, Vadim Marmer. 2014. Limited participation in international
business cycle models: A formal evaluation. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 39, 255-272.
[CrossRef]
18. Lars Kunze. 2014. Life expectancy and economic growth. Journal of Macroeconomics . [CrossRef]
19. Francesco Furlanetto, Gisle J. Natvik, Martin Seneca. 2013. Investment shocks and macroeconomic
co-movement. Journal of Macroeconomics 37, 208-216. [CrossRef]
20. Florin O. Bilbiie, Roland Straub. 2013. Asset Market Participation, Monetary Policy Rules, and the
Great Inflation. Review of Economics and Statistics 95, 377-392. [CrossRef]

21. Gnter Coenen, Roland Straub, Mathias Trabandt. 2013. Gauging the effects of fiscal stimulus
packages in the euro area. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37, 367-386. [CrossRef]
22. Florin O. Bilbiie, Tommaso Monacelli, Roberto Perotti. 2013. Public Debt and Redistribution
with Borrowing Constraints. The Economic Journal 123:10.1111/ecoj.2013.123.issue-566, F64-F98.
[CrossRef]
23. Shafik Hebous, Tom Zimmermann. 2013. Estimating the effects of coordinated fiscal actions in the
euro area. European Economic Review 58, 110-121. [CrossRef]
24. Robert Kollmann, Marco Ratto, Werner Roeger, Jan int Veld. 2013. Fiscal policy, banks and the
financial crisis. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37, 387-403. [CrossRef]
25. Carlos J. Garca, Wildo D. Gonzlez. 2013. Exchange rate intervention in small open economies: The
role of risk premium and commodity price shocks. International Review of Economics & Finance 25,
424-447. [CrossRef]
26. Suman S Basu, Jan Gottschalk, Werner Schule, Nikhil Vellodi, Shu-Chun S. Yang. 2013. The
Macroeconomic Effects of Natural Resource Extraction: Applications to Papua New Guinea. IMF
Working Papers 13, 1. [CrossRef]
27. Gisle James Natvik. 2012. Government Spending Shocks and Rule-of-Thumb Consumers with
Steady-State Inequality*. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 114:10.1111/sjoe.2012.114.issue-4,
1414-1436. [CrossRef]
28. Raymond G. Batina. 2012. Capital tax competition and social security. International Tax and Public
Finance 19, 819-843. [CrossRef]
29. Florin O. Bilbiie, Roland Straub. 2012. Changes in the output Euler equation and asset markets
participation. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 36, 1659-1672. [CrossRef]
30. WEI-KANG WONG. 2012. CONSUMPTION RESPONSE TO GOVERNMENT TRANSFERS:
BEHAVIORAL MOTIVES REVEALED BY SAVERS AND SPENDERS. Contemporary Economic
Policy 30:10.1111/coep.2012.30.issue-4, 489-501. [CrossRef]
31. GIORGIO MOTTA, PATRIZIO TIRELLI. 2012. Optimal Simple Monetary and Fiscal Rules
under Limited Asset Market Participation. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 44:10.1111/
jmcb.2012.44.issue-7, 1351-1374. [CrossRef]
32. Robert Kollmann. 2012. Limited asset market participation and the consumption-real exchange
rate anomaly. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'conomique 45:10.1111/
caje.2012.45.issue-2, 566-584. [CrossRef]
33. Francesco Furlanetto, Martin Seneca. 2012. Rule-of-Thumb Consumers, Productivity, and Hours*.
The Scandinavian Journal of Economics no-no. [CrossRef]
34. Wenyi Shen, Shu-Chun S. Yang. 2012. The Effects of Government Spending Under Limited Capital
Mobility. IMF Working Papers 12, 1. [CrossRef]
35. Carlos J. Garcia, Jorge E. Restrepo, Scott Roger. 2011. Hybrid Inflation Targeting Regimes. Journal
of International Money and Finance . [CrossRef]
36. ANDREA COLCIAGO. 2011. Rule-of-Thumb Consumers Meet Sticky Wages. Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking 43:10.1111/jmcb.2011.43.issue-2-3, 325-353. [CrossRef]
37. Steven G. Craig, Edward C. Hoang. 2011. State government response to income fluctuations:
Consumption, insurance, and capital expenditures. Regional Science and Urban Economics . [CrossRef]
38. Carlos J. Garcia, Jorge E. Restrepo, Evan Tanner. 2011. Fiscal rules in a volatile world: A welfarebased approach. Journal of Policy Modeling . [CrossRef]
39. Jorge Restrepo, Carlos Garcia, Evan Tanner. 2011. Fiscal Rules in a Volatile World: A Welfare-Based
Approach. IMF Working Papers 11, 1. [CrossRef]

40. Lars Kunze. 2010. Capital taxation, long-run growth, and bequests. Journal of Macroeconomics 32,
1067-1082. [CrossRef]
41. Shafik Hebous. 2010. THE EFFECTS OF DISCRETIONARY FISCAL POLICY ON
MACROECONOMIC AGGREGATES: A REAPPRAISAL. Journal of Economic Surveys no-no.
[CrossRef]
42. Pierre Pestieau, Emmanuel Thibault. 2010. Love thy children or money. Economic Theory . [CrossRef]
43. Stefan Khn, Joan Muysken, Tom Van Veen. 2010. THE ADVERSE EFFECT OF
GOVERNMENT SPENDING ON PRIVATE CONSUMPTION IN NEW KEYNESIAN
MODELS. Metroeconomica 61:10.1111/meca.2010.61.issue-4, 621-639. [CrossRef]
44. Christopher Tsoukis, Frederic Tournemaine. 2010. SOCIAL CONFLICT, GROWTH AND
FACTOR SHARES. Metroeconomica no-no. [CrossRef]
45. Giovanni Di Bartolomeo, Marco Manzo. 2010. FISCAL POLICY UNDER BALANCED BUDGET
AND INDETERMINACY: A NEW KEYNESIAN PERSPECTIVE. Scottish Journal of Political
Economy 57:10.1111/sjpe.2010.57.issue-4, 455-472. [CrossRef]
46. Giovanni Di Bartolomeo, Lorenza Rossi, Massimiliano Tancioni. 2010. Monetary policy, rule-ofthumb consumers and external habits: a G7 comparison. Applied Economics 1-18. [CrossRef]
47. Naomi E Feldman. 2010. Mental Accounting Effects of Income Tax Shifting. Review of Economics
and Statistics 92, 70-86. [CrossRef]
48. Thomas Palley. 2010. The Relative Permanent Income Theory of Consumption: A Synthetic KeynesDuesenberry-Friedman Model. Review of Political Economy 22, 41-56. [CrossRef]
49. Manmohan S. Kumar, Emanuele Baldacci. 2010. Fiscal Deficits, Public Debt, and Sovereign Bond
Yields. IMF Working Papers 10, 1. [CrossRef]
50. Mankiw N. Gregory, Weinzierl Matthew, Yagan Danny. 2009. Optimal Taxation in Theory and
Practice. Journal of Economic Perspectives 23:4, 147-174. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with
links]
51. Michal Horvath. 2009. The effects of government spending shocks on consumption under optimal
stabilization. European Economic Review 53, 815-829. [CrossRef]
52. Kirill Borissov, Stphane Lambrecht. 2009. Growth and distribution in an AK-model with endogenous
impatience. Economic Theory 39, 93-112. [CrossRef]
53. Stefano Bosi, Thomas Seegmuller. 2009. On local indeterminacy and endogenous cycles in Ramsey
models with heterogeneous households. Portuguese Economic Journal 8, 53-58. [CrossRef]
54. GISLE JAMES NATVIK. 2009. Government Spending and the Taylor Principle. Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking 41:10.1111/jmcb.2009.41.issue-1, 57-77. [CrossRef]
55. Carlos Garcia, Jorge Restrepo, Scott Roger. 2009. Hybrid Inflation Targeting Regimes. IMF Working
Papers 09, 1. [CrossRef]
56. Gernot Mller, Giancarlo Corsetti, Andr Meier. 2009. Fiscal Stimulus with Spending Reversals. IMF
Working Papers 09, 1. [CrossRef]
57. Giovanni Di Bartolomeo, Lorenza Rossi. 2007. Effectiveness of monetary policy and limited asset
market participation: Neoclassical versus Keynesian effects. International Journal of Economic Theory
3:10.1111/ijet.2007.3.issue-3, 213-218. [CrossRef]
58. Jordi Gal, J. David Lpez-Salido, Javier Valls. 2007. Understanding the Effects of
Government Spending on Consumption. Journal of the European Economic Association 5:10.1162/
jeea.2007.5.issue-1, 227-270. [CrossRef]
59. Dennis Fredriksen, Kim Massey Heide, Erling Holmy, Ingeborg Foldy SolliChapter 5
Macroeconomic Effects of Proposed Pension Reforms in Norway 107-142. [CrossRef]

60. STEPHANE LAMBRECHT, PHILIPPE MICHEL, EMMANUEL THIBAULT. 2006. Capital


Accumulation and Fiscal Policy in an OLG Model with Family Altruism. Journal of Public Economic
Theory 8:10.1111/jpet.2006.8.issue-3, 465-486. [CrossRef]
61. Ludger Linnemann, Andreas Schabert. 2006. PRODUCTIVE GOVERNMENT EXPENDITURE
IN MONETARY BUSINESS CYCLE MODELS. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 53:10.1111/
sjpe.2006.53.issue-1, 28-46. [CrossRef]
62. Philippe Michel, Emmanuel Thibault, Jean-Pierre VidalChapter 15 Intergenerational altruism and
neoclassical growth models 1055-1106. [CrossRef]
63. Florin Bilbiie, Roland Straub. 2006. Asset Market Participation, Monetary Policy Rules, and the Great
Inflation. IMF Working Papers 06, 1. [CrossRef]
64. Helmuth Cremer, Pierre PestieauChapter 16 Wealth transfer taxation: a survey of the theoretical
literature 1107-1134. [CrossRef]
65. Gunter Coenen, Roland Straub. 2005. Does Government Spending Crowd in Private Consumption?
Theory and Empirical Evidence for the Euro Area*. International Finance 8:10.1111/
infi.2005.8.issue-3, 435-470. [CrossRef]
66. Philippe Michel, Pierre Pestieau. 2005. Fiscal Policy with Agents Differing in Altruism and Ability.
Economica 72:10.1111/ecca.2005.72.issue-285, 121-135. [CrossRef]
67. Woon Gyu Choi, Michael B. Devereux. 2005. Asymmetric Effects of Government Spending: Does
the Level of Real Interest Rates Matter?. IMF Working Papers 05, 1. [CrossRef]
68. Gnter Coenen, Roland Straub. 2005. Does Government Spending Crowd in Private Consumption?
Theory and Empirical Evidence for the Euro Area. IMF Working Papers 05, 1. [CrossRef]
69. Stephen Wright. 2004. Monetary Stabilisation with Nominal Asymmetries*. The Economic Journal
114, 196-222. [CrossRef]
70. Selma Mahfouz, Richard Hemming, Michael Kell. 2002. The Effectiveness of Fiscal Policy in
Stimulating Economic Activity: A Review of the Literature. IMF Working Papers 02, 1. [CrossRef]
71. Alexander Ludwig, Torsten Slk. 2002. The Impact of Changes in Stock Prices and House Priceson
Consumption in OECD Countries. IMF Working Papers 02, 1. [CrossRef]
72. William Scarth. 2000. GROWTH AND INEQUALITY: A REVIEW ARTICLE. Review of Income
and Wealth 46:10.1111/roiw.2000.46.issue-3, 389-398. [CrossRef]

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi