Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 14

Integrating Multiple Opinions: The Role of

Aspiration Level on Consumer Response to


Critic Consensus
PATRICIA M. WEST
SUSAN M. BRONIARCZYK*

Four studies examine the process by which consumers integrate critic opinions
and attribute information into their product evaluations and how critic consensus
affects this process. A reference-dependent model is proposed such that con-
sumer response to consensus depends on whether the average critic rating for
an alternative is above or below an aspiration level. Consensus is shown to be
preferred for alternatives above an aspiration level, whereas critic disagreement
is preferred for alternatives below an aspiration level. Consumers exhibited a
tendency to prefer critic disagreement for high-priced products or decisions asso-
ciated with high social risk because most alternatives fell below their high aspira-
tion levels.

O thers' opinions, such as reference groups and word-


of-mouth of friends, have been shown to influence
expectations, disagreement among critics raises the possi-
bility that the product may fall short of an acceptable
consumers' evaluations in addition to, or in place of, prod- level, and, hence, consumers prefer critic consensus. Al-
uct attribute information (Bearden and Etzel 1982; Rogers ternatively, when expectations are high, critic disagree-
1976). Although this research has demonstrated the im- ment improves the chance of meeting or exceeding the
portance of others' opinions, surprisingly little attention goal, and, thus, consumers favor critic disagreement.
has been devoted to examining the process by which the
individual consumer integrates the opinions of mUltiple Importance of Others' Opinions
others.
The purpose of this article is to examine the process Consumers are likely to seek others' opinions to reduce
by which consumers integrate critic opinions and attribute their cognitive effort or uncertainty as the perceived risk
information into product evaluations and how critic con- associated with a purchase increases (Dowling and Stae-
sensus affects this process. Consensus refers to the level lin 1994; Roselius 1971). Consumers may also seek out
of agreement between critics. A high level of agreement others' opinions for guidance on novel products, products
suggests that all concur on the product evaluation-albeit with image-related attributes (King and Summers 1970),
favorably or unfavorably. When critics disagree, both fa- or because attribute information is lacking or uninforma-
vorable and unfavorable evaluations will tend to be aired. tive. Attribute information is often conflicting or difficult
We identify conditions under which consumers' evalua- to ascertain for experience attributes such as the handling
tions are influenced to a greater extent by agreement or ability, comfort of ride, and driveability of an automobile
disagreement among critics using a simple argument (Bone 1995; Hoch and Ha 1986).
based on consumers' aspiration levels. An aspiration level Others' opinions are likely to be especially important
is a consumer's goal or expectation for the outcome of for experiential products because they offer indirect expe-
the decision. In situations in which consumers have low rience on sensory aspects not conveyed by tangible attri-
butes. Holbrook and Hirschman (1982) express dismay
at the traditional models of consumer evaluation, stating
that "many products project important nonverbal cues
*Patricia M. West and Susan M. Broniarczyk are both assistant pro-
fessors of marketing at the University of Texas, CBA 7.202, Austin,
that must be seen, heard, tasted, or smelled to be appreci-
TX 78712. Thanks to Mark Alpert, Bart Bronnenberg, Steve Hoch, ated properly" (p. 134). Examples of such products are
Wayne Hoyer, Jay Koehler, Leigh McAlister, and participants at semi- viewing a movie, eating at a restaurant, or sight-seeing.
nars at the Wharton School and the University of Chicago for their Consumers purposefully seek out the opinions of others
helpful comments on an earlier draft. Suggestions or feedback should for evaluating experiential products as demonstrated by
be forwarded to Patricia M. West.
surveys that show that over a third of Americans seek the
38
1998 by JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH, Inc. - Vol. 25 - June 1998
All rights reserved. 0093-5301/99/2501-0003$03.00
INTEGRATING OPINIONS 39

advice of critics when selecting a movie (Wall Street bility in sensory experiences, different latitudes of accep-
Journal 1994) and the advice of friends when selecting tance, or heterogeneity in personal preferences. Research
a restaurant (Walker 1995). in decision making suggests that a lack of consensus in
The importance of others' opinions is corroborated by opinions can create uncertainty for the consumer (Ells-
the existence of critics, ranging from institutional critics berg 1961; Hogarth 1989; Meyer 1981).
such as Consumer Reports to individual critics such as Prior research has shown that consumers respond nega-
Gene Siskel and Roger Ebert, whose specific purpose is tively to such uncertainty (Jaccard and Wood 1988). Spe-
to disseminate their evaluations of products. The influence cifically, consumers may completely reject an alternative
of critics on consumer judgments is substantial because with conflicting opinions or ignore the inconsistent infor-
critics' access to product previews typically makes them mation and use a discounted average value for the cate-
one of the first links in the diffusion of information about gory as a default valuation for the alternative (Jaccard
new products. Furthermore, their professional status lends and Wood 1988; Meyer 1981; Ross and Creyer 1992).
them credibility. Our research examines consumer use of Alternatively, consumers may use the critic information
others' opinions in the context of critic ratings of experi- by averaging the provided opinions but again discount
ential products. We focus on overall ratings rather than this value to adjust for critic disagreement (Meyer 1981 ) .
on the information content contained in reviews, because However, other research suggests that consumers' re-
overall ratings have been shown to be more influential sponse to uncertainty will depend on their reference point
than information content in affecting consumer interest (Kahneman and Tversky 1979; Levin et al. 1985; Payne,
(Wyatt and Badger 1990). Laughhunn, and Crum 1980, 1981). According to Kahne-
However, an overall rating is dependent on the other's man and Tversky's (1979) prospect theory, when a deci-
perceptions of, and weighting function for, product attri- sion outcome is framed as a gain (above the reference
butes and experiential aspects that may differ from one's point), individuals tend to be risk averse, preferring a
own (Einhorn and Koelb 1982). For example, a critic's certain outcome over an uncertain outcome with equiva-
opinion of a restaurant may depend equally on service, lent expected value. Conversely, when a decision outcome
atmosphere, and food quality, whereas your own opinion is framed as a loss (below the reference point), individu-
may be heavily influenced by food quality and less influ- als tend to be risk seeking, preferring an uncertain out-
enced by atmosphere. In addition, experiential products come to an equivalent certain outcome.
evoke many different emotional responses, thus rendering This reference-dependent explanation of how consum-
the possibility for multiple interpretations of product ex- ers respond to consensus is consistent with results ob-
perience (Eliashberg and Sawhney 1994; Hoch and Ha served by Meyer (1981), whose subjects were asked to
1986). This suggests that an individual critic's opinion evaluate restaurants given critic ratings. He found that for
may, or may not, be useful in assessing your own opinion. restaurants whose average critic rating exceeded the mean
When search costs are low, consumers may be moti- value across all restaurants, subjects exhibited decreased
vated to seek multiple critic opinions to resolve the prob- utility when the critics' disagreed about the restaurant
lem (Payne, Bettman, and Johnson 1993; Shugan 1980). quality. However, for restaurants whose average critic
In fact, some periodicals, such as Entertainment Weekly rating fell below the mean restaurant rating, critic dis-
and Premiere, compile film ratings of multiple critics in agreement did not increase utility but rather had no effect.
a matrix format for their magazine readers and web site Further support for the reference-dependent model
viewers. The forecasting literature suggests that seeking comes from Kahn and Meyer (1991), who found that
multiple opinions is the normatively correct strategy for consumer response to critic consensus regarding an attri-
dealing with the idiosyncrasies of others' opinions (Cle- bute's importance was dependent on whether the attribute
men 1989; Clemen and Winkler 1986; Hogarth 1977; was framed as a gain (utility enhancing) or a loss (utility
Winkler 1989). Taking an average of these opinions in- preserving) relative to an implicit reference point, the
creases the reliability of the sensory information and re- status quo. Their results show that in the face of critic
duces the influence of an outlier opinion. The simplicity disagreement, consumers increased the importance of uti1-
of an averaging strategy makes it attractive for consumers. ity-preserving attributes and decreased the importance of
The conclusion of a vast number of studies on information utility-enhancing attributes in their overall evaluations of
integration is that individuals combine separate pieces of the product. Our research extends and refines this work
information into an overall evaluation by averaging them by examining how shifting a consumer's reference point
(Anderson 1996; Kahn and Ross 1993). for the decision outcome will influence response to critic
consensus for overall product utility.
Critic Consensus and Aspiration Level We propose that to understand fully how a consumer
will respond to uncertainty in the form of critic disagree-
Anecdotal evidence suggests that critic disagreement ment one must know the individual's aspiration level or
is a salient cue to consumers. For instance, the popUlarity expectation for the decision outcome (Payne et al. 1980,
of movie critics Gene Siskel and Roger Ebert is partially 1981 ). Risk aversion is commonly observed for alterna-
a function of their spirited disagreements. Differences in tives that meet or exceed an individual's aspiration level,
critic ratings are frequent (Boor 1990) because ofunrelia- whereas risk seeking can occur when an alternative falls
40 JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

below an aspiration. For example, imagine two new mov- acceptable by a consumer (Bettman 1973). Thus, in study
ies have been released this week and rated by three critics. 2 we expect to find that as price increases, consumers'
Both movies received an average rating of three out of aspiration levels shift to a higher standard. Moreover,
four stars, but movie A had low consensus (two, three, the social risk associated with a decision is expected to
and four stars), whereas movie B had high consensus influence the location of the aspiration level. As social
(three ratings of three stars). We would predict that a risk increases, consumers' egos become more vulnerable
consumer with a high aspiration level (four stars) would and they are expected to set higher standards for an ac-
be more likely to choose movie A, whereas a consumer ceptable outcome as a protection mechanism (Dowling
with a low aspiration (two and one-half stars) would be and Staelin 1994; Jacoby and Kaplan 1972). Thus, in
more likely to choose movie B. In situations in which studies 3 and 4 we expect to find that as the perceived
consumers have high expectations, critic disagreement social risk increases, consumers' aspiration levels shift
improves the chance of meeting or exceeding the goal upward.
and, thus, consumers are expected to favor critic disagree- We propose that shifts in consumers' aspiration levels
ment. Alternatively, when expectations are low, disagree- that result from these changes in the decision context will
ment among critics raises the possibility that the product affect how they respond to critic disagreement. Specifi-
may fall short of an acceptable level and, hence, consum- cally, we hypothesize that
ers are expected to prefer critic consensus.
HI: Consumer response to critic consensus will de-
pend on the aspiration level evoked by the deci-
Determinants of Aspiration Level sion context such that
(a) consumers will evaluate an alternative
Tversky and Kahneman (1991) acknowledge that pros-
pect theory does not delineate the factors that influence more favorably when there is critic dis-
agreement than agreement if the average
a consumer's reference point. For a decision outcome,
this reference point is likely to be an individual's aspira- of its critic opinions is below an
aspiration
tion level as to what would constitute a satisfactory versus level;
(b) consumers will evaluate an alternative
an unsatisfactory outcome (Payne et al. 1980). For in-
stance, a wine connoisseur would be expected to have a more favorably when there is critic agree-
higher standard for an acceptable bottle of wine than an ment than disagreement if the average of
occasional drinker and thus a higher aspiration or refer- its critic opinions is above an aspiration
ence level. The connoisseur may therefore treat an aver- level.
age bottle of wine as a loss, whereas the occasional
drinker may treat the same experience as a gain. Critic Opinions and Personal Preference for
We are interested in examining how variables associ- Product Attributes
ated with the decision context affect consumers' aspira-
tion level and thus their response to critic consensus. Four Critic consensus may also have an impact on the rela-
studies are conducted to examine context factors that have tive weight consumers assign to critic opinions versus
been shown to influence consumers' aspiration levels: their personal preference for product attributes. That is,
( 1) consumer expectations of product quality in a given critic consensus may affect not only the valuation of the
category (Meyer 1981;-Ross and Creyer 1992), (2) the critic ratings (Hypothesis 1) but also the weight this infor-
price of a product alternative (Bettman 1973; Huber and mation receives in consumers' final judgments. In the face
McCann 1982; Levin, Johnson, and Faraone 1984), and of critic disagreement, consumers may rely more on their
(3) the degree of social risk involved (Jacoby and Kaplan personal preference for product attribute values when
1972). there is a lack of consensus among the critics than when
The aspiration level may be determined by the average there is agreement about the quality of a given alternative
quality in a given category, such that alternatives above (Jaccard and Wood 1988).
(below) the category average are viewed as gains H2: Consumers will respond to critic disagreement
(losses). This average quality level may be data driven by discounting the critic opinions and increas-
by the average of the critic ratings across the alternative ing their reliance on product attribute informa-
set (Meyer 1981) or theory driven by consumer expecta- tion in their evaluations.
tions from prior experience (Broniarczyk and Alba
1994). This is examined in study 1. Price may also influ-
ence consumers' aspiration levels, as prior research sug-
Infonnativeness of Critic Opinions
gests that consumers make price-quality inferences when Consumers may attempt to resolve inconsistency in
evaluating alternatives (Huber and McCann 1982; Levin critic opinions by focusing on only a subset of the infor-
et al. 1984), with higher prices associated with higher mation (Ganzach 1994). Differential attention to the indi-
quality levels. Higher prices are also associated with vidual critics is expected to be influenced by critic infor-
greater financial risk (Jacoby and Kaplan 1972) and thus mativeness. Assuming that each of the critics is equally
are related to a smaller percentage of outcomes deemed consistent in applying his or her judgment policy for eval-
INTEGRATING OPINIONS 41

uating alternatives, a critic whose ratings exhibit high TABLE 1


variance is more informative than a critic whose ratings CRITIC RATING INFORMATION
exhibit little variance (Coombs, Dawes, and Tversky
1970; Shannon and Weaver 1949). An earlier study Critic Critic Critic
(West 1996) found that consumers were sensitive to the Alternative A B C Average Variance
informativeness of others' opinions. Therefore, we expect
that they may weigh an informative critic's opinion more 1 9 9 4 7.33 8.33
heavily than the opinion of an uninformative critic. 2 9 5 6 6.67 4.33
3 8 4 6 6.00 4.00
H3: Consumers are sensitive to the informativeness 4 8 1 5 4.67 12.33
5 6 7 8 7.00 1.00
of critics when integrating their opinions for 6 5 6 4 5.00 1.00
evaluation of experiential products. 7 5 7 6 6.00 1.00
8 2 8 7 5.67 10.33
In summary, we expect to find that consumers use both 9 3 4 7 4.67 4.33
attribute information and critic opinions in evaluating 10 2 6 4 4.00 4.00
product alternatives. Critic opinions are used by consum- 11 10 10 5 8.33 8.33
ers to help predict their own preferences. These opinions 12 10 6 7 7.67 4.33
13 10 5 7 7.33 6.33
offer a form of indirect experience that is particularly 14 9 2 6 5.67 12.33
useful for experiential products. When multiple opinions 15 7 8 9 8.00 1.00
are provided, the consumer is faced with the task of inte- 16 6 7 5 6.00 1.00
grating the information. This task is relatively easy when 17 6 8 7 7.00 1.00
the individuals agree, but questions arise when there is a 18 3 9 8 6.67 10.33
19 3 4 7 4.67 4.33
lack of consensus. Consumers' response to disagreement 20 3 7 5 5.00 4.00
in critic opinions is expected to be influenced by the Average 6.20 6.15 6.15
aspiration level associated with their decision such that Variance 8.06 5.50 2.03
critic disagreement (agreement) results in more favorable
product evaluations for alternatives whose average critic
rating is below (above) the aspiration level. Consumers
may resolve critic disagreement by focusing more atten- cntlcs whose average ratings were approximately the
tion on product attribute values or attending to a subset same. Orthogonality among the critics was important to
of the critics who have shown a history of providing permit estimation of differential weighting of the three
informative opinions. critics; all critic intercorrelations in Table 1 are less than
.09. Second, in order to test the effect of aspiration level
METHODOLOGY on subjects' response to critic consensus we needed to
vary the average of the critic ratings as well as the level
Stimulus Development of agreement among the critics for a given alternative
(last column). In addition, we needed to have both high-
Two criteria guided the selection of product categories and low-consensus alternatives at all levels of average
for examining consumer response to critic consensus. First, critic rating. Critic consensus was operationalized as the
we required that the product category be relatively familiar variance among the three critic ratings for a given film.
to the subject. Familiarity with the evaluation task is im- This variance measure is consistent with Meyer (1981)
portant because it allows us to better capture how judgments and others who have examined cue consensus effects
are formed and how expectations and aspirations influence (Brannick and Brannick 1989; Ganzach 1994, 1995).
evaluations in a naturally occurring environment. This crite- Third, besides varying the level of critic disagreement,
rion rules out durable goods, which tend to be purchased we were also interested in manipulating individual critic
infrequently and for which many college students lack expe- informativeness. In order to accomplish this, the three
rience shopping. Second, we wanted a product for which critics must differ in the variance of their ratings across
consumers typically turn to the opinion of critics for advice. the set of 20 alternatives (last row). As indicated in the
The categories selected for testing were movies (study 1) table, Critic A (8.06) has a higher variance in ratings
and restaurants (studies 2-4). than Critic B (5.50), who has a higher variance in ratings
A core set of 20 alternatives, each induding three critic than Critic C (2.03). The set of alternatives presented in
ratings, was developed for use in studies 1- 3 (see Table Table 1 accomplishes all three of these objectives and
1 ) .1 Three goals were established for constructing this was used to construct the stimuli for the first three studies.
set of alternatives: First, we wanted to create orthogonal

STUDY 1
lIn study 4, subjects were asked to make choices given pairs of
alternatives that had a common mean critic rating but differing levels The purpose of this study was to examine how critic
of critic consensus. Therefore, a separate set of alternatives was con- opinions and attribute information are integrated by sub-
structed for this task. jects to form product evaluations. The product category
42 JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

used was movies, which is highly familiar to student parti- For each video, only the title, genre, and performer infor-
cipants. We tested how an aspiration level, based on an mation were provided, and subjects were instructed to
average movie quality, influenced subjects' response to rate only the videos they had seen. Finally, subjects se-
critic consensus. lected their five favorite performers from a list of 98
popular actors and actresses. The entire task took subjects
an average of 40 minutes to complete.
Subjects and Design
Aspiration Level. In this study, subjects' aspiration
Eighty-one undergraduate students participated in this level was not manipulated. Subjects' aspirations were based
study. The subjects were recruited from a marketing re- on their expectations of averages movie quality (i.e., priors
search class and given extra credit points and a coupon for the category) and the average of the critic ratings pro-
for a free video rental as payment for participating. Each vided (i.e., data driven by the alternative set). The average
subject's response to critic consensus was examined by rating (6.16) of previously viewed videos for the experi-
having individuals rate a series of 100 fictitious movie mental subjects was used as an estimate of "average movie
descriptions. Each description included three critic ratings quality." This estimate of average movie quality was simi-
(Critic A, Critic B, and Critic C), the film genre (action/ lar to that of an additional 60 pilot subjects and equivalent to
adventure, comedy, drama, drama/suspense, or romantic the average of the critics' ratings across the 20 alternatives
comedy), and the principal and supporting performers described in Table 1.
(chosen from a list of 50 top performers). The core set Measuring Personal Preference. The rank order of
of 20 alternatives, presented in Table 1, was used to con- genre and number of favorite performers were summed
struct 100 movie descriptions by matching each of the together to create a variable labeled "personal prefer-
five film genres to one of the 20 triples of critic ratings ence." To establish a rank ordering of the five film genres,
and then assigning a genre-appropriate cast of performers each subject's ratings of the previously viewed videos
to the film. 2 were regressed on a set of dummy variables. The number
The order of presentation of the film information (critic of favorite performers that a given fictitious movie con-
ratings vs. genre and performers) was counterbalanced tained was computed on the basis of subjects' self re-
by presenting half of the subjects with movie descriptions ported preference for popular actors and actresses.
that displayed the critic ratings on top of the description,
while the other half of the subjects saw the critic ratings Results
below the film genre and performers. The ordering of the The following aggregate-level regression model was
three critics was also counterbalanced between subjects. used to test all model predictions using subject ratings as
Each subject rated the 100 movies in one of three different the dependent variable:
random orderings. Rating = bo + b l Critic A + b2 Critic B
+ b3 Critic C + b4 Consensus + b5 AL
Procedure
+ b6 Consensus X AL + b7 Preference
Each subject was given a packet containing the experi-
mental materials. Subjects were told that the films that + bg Preference X Consensus (1)
they would be rating would soon be released in their area
and that a local cinema wanted to know about their level
+ b 9 Preference X AL
of interest in the movies. Each of the 100 fictitious movies + blO Preference X Consensus
was rated on either a lO-point "interest scale" (1 = not
X AL + e,
at all interested, 10 = extremely interested) or a lO-point
"liking scale" (1 = horrible movie, 10 = excellent where the independent variables include the three critic
movie) .3 Subjects completed the rating task at their own ratings, Critic A, Critic B, Critic C, the Consensus be-
pace. tween the three ratings; AL is a dichotomous variable
A follow-up task to assess personal preference for prod- representing whether the average of the critic ratings was
uct attributes and average movie quality had subjects rate above or below the aspiration level (6.16), and Preference
80 recently released videos on a lO-point liking scale. captures the subject's personal preference for the film's
genre and performers. All two-way and three-way interac-
tions between Consensus, AL, and Preference were in-
cluded. The average parameter estimates of the models
20ther factors are likely to influence consumer preference for a movie
including the director, film previews, and advertisements. However, for
are presented in Table 2.4
the purpose of experimental control we have restricted our focus to
genre and performers that are often used for classifying movies both in
video stores and books. In order to avoid unrealistic combination~ of 4For studies 1-3, hierarchical regressions including all main effects
genre and performers, two experts were asked to review the list of first and then interactions were performed to test the robustness of the
fictitious movies, and changes were made based on their input. predicted interaction between consensus and aspiration level. For all
3The results for the interest scale and liking scale were not statistically three studies, the hierarchical results are consistent with the estimates
different; therefore, the data were pooled together for all of the analyses. reported in Tables 2-3.
INTEGRATING OPINIONS 43

TABLE 2
RESULTS FROM STUDIES 1 AND 2

Study 1 Study 2

Source Estimate Standard error t-statistic Estimate Standard error t-statistic

Intercept 5.62 .06 102.20** 4.97 .03 164.63**


Critic A .19 .03 6.02** .49 .03 18.41**
Critic B .06 .04 1.54 .33 .02 13.37**
Critic C .07 .03 2.43* .16 .02 7.91**
Consensus -.22 .08 -2.77" -.26 .03 -10.10*'
AL .72 .11 6.35** 1.24 .05 22.59**
Preference .13 .02 6.99** .38 .02 16.08**
Consensus x AL .21 .12 1.80+ .16 .05 3.31*'
Preference x Consensus .01 .02 .69 -.01 .02 -.11
Preference x AL .12 .02 5.43** .11 .03 3.47**
Preference x Consensus x AL -.03 .03 -1.01 -.03 .03 -.93

+p '" .10.
'P'" .05.
"P'" .001.

Aspiration Level and Critic Consensus. We observed preference for product attributes in the face of critic dis-
a negative main effect of critic consensus, which indicated agreement (bPreference x Consensus = 0.01, t(8,077) = 0.69,
that overall, subjects responded less positively to alterna- p > .50 and bpreference x Consensus X AL = -0.03, t( 8,077)
tives when there was critic consensus than when there = -1.01, p > .30). Instead of discounting the critic opin-
was critic disagreement (bconsensus = -0.22, t(8,077) ions when they disagree, subjects continue to pay atten-
= -2.77, p < .006). Consistent with Hypothesis 1, we tion to the critics. However, the focus of their attention
observed a marginally significant interaction between as- appears to shift either to the highest of the three critic
piration level and critic consensus (bconsensus x AL = 0.21, opinions for below AL alternatives or to the lowest of
t(8,077) = 1.80, p < .07), which suggested that the the three critic opinions for above AL alternatives.
effect of critic consensus was dependent on consumers'
aspiration levels (see Fig. 1). 5 A follow-up analysis in Critic Informativeness. Finally, we found support for
which the data were split by AL revealed that when the Hypothesis 3, the prediction that subjects are sensitive to
average of the critic ratings fell below AL, subjects evalu- differences in the informativeness of individual critics,
ated alternatives more favorably when there was critic and differentially weight them accordingly. The most in-
disagreement than when there was critic consensus (p formative critic's opinion (Critic A) was weighted more
< .005, one-tailed). Although the difference is not sig- heavily than either the moderately informative critic
nificant, the pattern appeared to reverse when the critic (bcriticA-CriticB = .13, P < .01), or the least informative
average exceeded the aspiration level, with subjects tend- critic's opinion (bcriticA-CriticC = .12, P < .01), irrespec-
ing to evaluate alternatives less favorably when there was tive of the order of presentation of the three critic ratings.
critic disagreement, (p = .17, one-tailed). Thus, consumers are sensitive to the diagnosticity of the
ratings provided by the critics.
Personal Preference for Product Attributes. As ex-
pected, we observed that preference for a film's genre and Discussion
performers is strongly associated with subjects' movie
evaluations (bPreference = .13, t(8,077) = 6.99,p < .0001). These results suggest a number of important findings
We also observed that personal preference for product related to consumer information evaluation and predicted
attributes matters more for alternatives whose average preference. Not surprisingly, our results indicate that con-
critic rating exceeds the aspiration level than for alterna- sumers use more than product attribute information in
tives whose average critic rating falls below the aspiration evaluating alternatives. The interaction between aspira-
level (bPreferencexAL = .12, t(8,077) = 5.43,p < .0001). tion level and personal preference for product attributes
Inconsistent with Hypothesis 2, our analysis indicates indicates that an alternative needs to be high on both
that subjects do not rely more heavily on their personal average critic rating and preference for attributes in order
to receive a favorable evaluation. Surprisingly, critic opin-
ions are taken into consideration even in the face of critic
5For graphic illustration purposes, alternatives were classified as high disagreement. We did not observe consumers shifting
or low consensus on the basis of a median split of the data; however, their reliance to product attributes when there is a lack
consensus was represented as a continuous variable in the model. of critic consensus. Consumers are sensitive to both the
44 JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

FIGURE 1 is also clear that consumers are sensitive to the informa-


ASPIRATION LEVEL EFFECTS ON CONSUMER RESPONSE tiveness of others' opinions. Our results indicate that con-
TO CRITIC CONSENSUS sumers weight an informative critic's opinion more heav-
ily than an uninformative critic's opinion.
Study 1
8.50
STUDY 2
6.95
7.25
The purpose of this study was to replicate the results
5~82
C>

~ 6.00 -+- High Consensus found in study 1 in another product category, restaurants,
0:: ___ Low Consensus and to directly manipulate subjects' aspiration level via
4.75 5.42
the price of the alternatives.
3.50 - + - - - - - - + - - - - - - - 1
Below Above Subjects and Design
Aspiration Level
A total of 177 students (both business and nonbusi-
Study 2 ness) participated in the study and received either extra
course credit or payment of $7.00. Forty-five of the parti-
8.50 8.22 cipants were asked to provide additional information re-
garding their aspiration level.
7.25 Consumer reliance on critic opinions for evaluating
C>
c: various price-tier restaurants was examined by having
~ 6.00 subjects rate a series of 80 restaurant descriptions. Each
0:: -+- High Consensus
4.75 description included three critic ratings, the cuisine of the
--- Low Consensus
restaurant (Italian, Mexican, Chinese, or seafood), and
3.50
3.54
Below Above
the average price of the restaurants' entree offerings (low
= under $10; moderate = $10-$20; expensive = over
Aspiration Level $20). Once again, the core set of 20 alternatives, pre-
Study 3 sented in Table 1, was used to construct the 80 restaurant
8.50 descriptions by matching each of the four cuisines to one
7.79
of the 20 triples of critic ratings. As in study 1, the label-
7.25 ing of the three critics, as well as the order of presentation

4V
C> /57
c: of the critic ratings, cuisine, and price information, was
:a; 6.00 counterbalanced across subjects. Each subject rated the
0::
4.75 -+- High Consensus 80 restaurants in one of four different random orders. All
4.70 --- Low Consensus subjects were asked to rank order their preference for the
3.50 + - - - - - - - t - - - - - - - i cuisine types after completing the restaurant rating task
Below Above as a measure of personal preference.
Aspiration Level

Procedure
degree of consensus among the critics and the informa- The procedure used in this study was similar to that
tiveness of critic ratings. used in study 1. Subjects were given a packet containing
Consumers' response to critic consensus is influenced all experimental materials. The opening instructions de-
by their aspiration level. When the average rating of the scribed the rating task and explained that a new shopping
critics falls below the aspiration level, consumers prefer mall was going to open in the area and the management
variance in critic opinions because these alternatives offer was interested in getting students' opinions about poten-
some opportunity to meet or exceed the consumers aspira- tial restaurants to include. Subjects rated the hypothetical
tion level (one of the critics must have favorably evalu- restaurants at their own pace on the same 10-point interest
ated the product ). However, alternatives with equivalent scale or liking scale used in study 1. 6 After the rating
mean critic ratings that exhibit high critic consensus offer task, all of the subjects were asked to rank order the four
no hope of achieving the desired level of utility or satis- restaurant cuisines presented. Forty-five of the subjects
faction. Conversely, when the average rating of the critics were asked to provide additional information about their
exceeds the aspiration level, consumers prefer consensus aspiration level for the dining experience in the three
in critic opinions because these alternatives are sure win-
ners. In these situations, consumers respond negatively
to critic disagreement because there is a chance their ex- 60nce again, the results for the interest scale and liking scale were
perience may fall short of their expectations (one of the not statistically different; therefore, the data were pooled together for
critics must have evaluated the product unfavorably). It all of the analyses.
INTEGRATING OPINIONS 45

price-tier restaurants. The entire task took subjects on rating (bconsensusxAV = -0.09, t(8,618) = -1.90, p
average 30 minutes to complete. < .05). The price-tier-specific aspiration level, AL, was
then added to the model, along with interactions between
Aspiration Level. In order to check whether the price AL and Consensus, and AL and Preference. 7 When the
manipulation influenced subjects' aspiration levels, we aspiration level was included in the model, this interaction
asked 45 subjects to provide a self-report of their aspira- disappeared and instead we observed a positive interac-
tion level for the three price-tier restaurants. SpeCifically, tion between consensus and aspiration level (bconsensus x AV
we asked subjects to provide the minimum standard that = 0.08, t(8,618) = 0.90, p > .36; bconsensus x AL = 0.22,
they would find acceptable for an inexpensive, moderately t(8,618) = 2.95,p < .003) consistent with a reference-
priced, and expensive restaurant. The response scale used dependent model.
was identical to the restaurant rating scale (1 = horrible
restaurant and 10 = excellent restaurant). The average Personal Preference for Product Attributes. We ob-
aspiration level increased across the three price tiers served that preference for a restaurant's cuisine is strongly
(Xlnexpensive = 4.44, XModeratelyPriced = 6.24, XExpensive = 8.32; associated with subjects' ratings (bPreference = .38,
F(2, 122) = 97.24,p < .0001). t(13,229) = 16.08,p <.0001). Consistent with study 1,
we observed that personal preference for product attri-
butes matters more for alternatives whose average critic
Results
rating exceeds the aspiration level (bPreference x AL = 0.11,
A similar regression analysis to that performed in study t(13,229) = 3.47, p < .0005). Once again, we did not
1 was used to test for the effect of aspiration level on find support for Hypothesis 2; there is no evidence that
subjects' response to critic consensus. Subjects' aspiration subjects rely more heavily on their personal preference
level was defined in terms of price and based on the self- of product attributes in the face of critic disagreement
reports of 45 subjects (ALlnexpensive = 4.44, ALModerately Priced (bPreferencexConsensus = -0.01, t(13,229) = -0.11, p >
= 6.24, ALExpensive = 8.32). Personal preference for res- .90). Subjects continue to pay attention to critic opinions
taurant cuisine was based on each subject's rank ordering instead of discounting for disagreement. However, in the
of the cuisines. The parameter estimates of the aggregate face of disagreement the focus of their attention seems
model are presented in Table 2. to shift to either the high critic rating (below AL) or the
low critic rating (above AL).
Aspiration Level and Critic Consensus. Once again,
we observed a negative main effect of critic consensus, Critic Informativeness. The results support Hypothesis
which indicates that overall, subjects responded less fa- 3 and indicate the subjects are sensitive to differences in
vorably to product alternatives in the face of critic consen- the informativeness of individual critics, and differentially
sus than critic disagreement (bconsensus = -0.26, t( 13,229) weight them accordingly. The most informative critic's
= -10.10, p < .0001). Consistent with Hypothesis 1, opinion was weighted more heavily than either of the
we observed an interaction between critic consensus and other critics' opinions (bcriticA-CriticB = .16, P < .001;
aspiration level (bconsensusxAL = 0.16, t(13,229) = 3.31, bCriticA- CriticC = .33, p < .0001; bCriticB-CriticC = .17, P
p < .0001). The relationship between aspiration level < .001).
and critic consensus is illustrated in Figure 1. As in study
1, a follow-up analysis in which the data were split by Discussion
AL revealed that when the average of the critic ratings fell The results from study 2 indicate that aspiration level,
below AL, subjects evaluated alternatives less favorably rather than the average of the product category, influences
when there was critic consensus than when there was how consumers will respond to a lack of consensus among
critic disagreement (p < .0001, one-tailed). The direction critic opinions. Here, a high price creates high aspirations,
of results for average critic ratings that exceeded the AL and most product alternatives are likely to fall short of
was consistent with predictions; although marginally sig- subjects' expectations, placing them in the domain of
nificant (p = .09, one-tailed), subjects appeared to re- losses. Subjects respond with risk-seeking behavior,
spond move favorably when there was critic consensus whereby alternatives with critic disagreement are rated
than when there was critic disagreement. more favorably than alternatives with critic agreement.
A second regression analysis was performed in order Conversely, a low price creates low aspirations, and thus
to test whether the average of the product category or most product alternatives are likely to meet or exceed
aspiration level via price provides a better explanation of subjects' expectations, placing them in the domain of
subjects' response to critic consensus. This involved a gains. Here we observe risk aversion, resulting in alterna-
two-step process, similar to the procedure used for testing tives with high critic consensus being rated more favor-
for a mediating relationship between variables (Baron ably than alternatives where the critics disagree:
and Kenny 1986). The model was first estimated using
the average of the critic ratings, AV = 6.17, as a dichoto-
mous variable to test for differential response to critic 7Because the aspiration level for the moderately priced restaurants
consensus based on the set of alternatives. We observed a was equivalent to the average of the critic ratings across alternatives,
negative interaction between consensus and average critic we restricted this analysis to expensive and inexpensive restaurants only.
46 JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

Our other results are also highly consistent with those and a first date). Subjects rated the hypothetical restau-
of study 1. Once again, we observed an interaction be- rants using the same lO-point liking scale as in studies 1
tween aspiration level and personal preference for product and 2. After the rating task, all subjects were asked to
attributes, which indicated that critic opinions and/ or provide additional information about their perceptions of
product attributes appear to act as a screening mechanism the risk involved in choosing a restaurant for a first date
for evaluating alternatives. Again, we did not observe versus for dining with a friend, as well as their aspiration
consumers shifting their reliance to product attributes levels in the two dining situations. The task took an aver-
when there was a lack of critic consensus. Finally, con- age of 25 minutes to complete.
sumers were shown to be sensitive to the informativeness
of others' opinions and weight an informative critic's Aspiration Level. In order to check whether the social
opinion more heavily than an uninformative critic's opin- risk manipulation influenced subjects' aspiration levels,
we asked each of the subjects to provide a self-report of
Ion.
their aspiration level for the two decision contexts. As in
study 2, subjects were asked to provide the minimum
STUDY 3 standard that they would find acceptable for a restaurant
The purpose of this study was to replicate the aspiration given the social context of the dining experience. The
level results found in study 2 using another manipulation response scale used was identical to the restaurant rating
of aspiration level, in this case social risk rather than scale (1 = horrible restaurant and 10 = excellent restau-
price. This is important because the financial limitations rant). As expected, the average aspiration level for the
of our student subject population in study 2 may have led two social contexts differed significantly (XPriend = 5.41,
them to perceive high-price-tier restaurants as potential XPirstDate = 7.00; F(1, 104) = 36.99,p < .0001).
options only if someone else was paying. Unlike in study
2, we did not incorporate subjects' personal preference Results
for restaurant cuisine because the joint nature of the deci- A regression analysis similar to that used in studies 1
sion task renders individual preference less relevant. and 2 was used to test the effect of aspiration level on
subjects' response to critic consensus. Gender was included
Subjects and Design as a covariate in the analysis, as males and females may
differ in the perceived risk associated with dating. Al-
Fifty-three students participated in this study for com- though males tended to rate restaurants lower, on average,
pensation and a lottery chance. Consumers' response to than females (bGender = - .09, t( 2,056) = -2.13, p < .04),
critic consensus under different levels of perceived social there is no evidence of gender differences in response to
risk was examined by having subjects rate 20 restaurant critic consensus or aspiration level. A test for order effects
descriptions. Social risk was manipulated within subjects of the two scenarios revealed no difference in either sub-
by varying the decision context for evaluating restaurants, jects' evaluations or response to critic consensus.
either as a first date (high social risk) or dining with Subjects' aspiration levels were defined at the individ-
a friend (low social risk). Each restaurant description ual level based on their self-report for the two social
included only three critic ratings; alternatives were gener- contexts. The parameter estimates of the aggregate model
ated using the core set of 20 critic triples presented in are presented in Table 3.
Table 1. Similar to studies 1 and 2, the ordering of the
three critics, as well as the random order of restaurant Aspiration Level and Critic Consensus. We observed
presentation, was counterbalanced across subjects. Unlike a nonsignificant negative relationship between subject rat-
in study 2, subjects rated the 20 low-risk and the 20 high- ings and critic consensus (bconsensus = -0.02, t(2,056)
risk alternatives in separate blocks that were counterbal- = -1.03, p = .2). As predicted by Hypothesis 1, we ob-
anced across subjects. served a significant interaction between critic consensus and
aspiration level (bconsensus x AL = 0.07, t( 2,056) = 2.04, p
Procedure < .04). The relationship between aspiration level and critic
consensus is illustrated in Figure 1. A follow-up analysis in
The procedure used was similar to that used in studies which the data were split by AL indicates a negative effect
1 and 2. The opening instructions described a scenario in of critic consensus below AL (p < .05) and a positive effect
which the subject had accepted a job and moved to an of critic consensus above AL (p < .05).
unfamiliar city. The subject was asked to evaluate various As in study 2, we were interested in testing whether
local restaurants for dining with a friend who came to the average of the product category or a risk-defined aspi-
help them move or for dining with an attractive new ration level better explains subjects' response to critic
neighbor s/he met while moving in. Subjects were told consensus. Therefore, a second regression analysis was
that all of the restaurants were in the same price range performed with the same two-step process reported ear-
and given an explicit budget constraint ( "your company lier. We found that when the model was estimated using
provides a $35 dining allowance"). All subjects were the average of the critic ratings to test for differential
exposed to both decision contexts (dining with a friend response to critic consensus we observed a negative
INTEGRATING OPINIONS 47

TABLE 3
RESULTS FROM STUDIES 3 AND 4

Study 3 Study 4

Source Estimate Standard error t-statistic Estimate

Intercept 6.13 .05 131.40** .18 3.13*


Critic A .88 .02 37.15**
Critic B .70 .02 30.19**
Critic C .43 .02 20.03**
Consensus -.02 .04 -1.03 -.04 .11
AL -.09 .05 -1.90 -.10 .80
Gender -.09 .04 -2.13* -.14 1.80
Consensus x AL .07 .04 2.04* .21 3.99*
Gender x Consensus .03 .03 .79 -.22 4.11*
Gender x AL .03 .82 .41 -.09 .78
Gender x Consensus x AL .07 .08 .80 -.16 2.18

'p s; .05.
"p oS .001.

interaction between consensus and average rating uation. Our results indicate a positive effect of critic dis-
(bconsensus XAV = -0.11, t(2,111) = -2.03, p < .05). agreement when an alternative falls below expectations,
However, when subjects' aspiration levels were included and conversely a negative effect of critic disagreement for
in the model, this interaction disappeared and instead we alternatives exceeding expectations. This final study will
observed a positive interaction between consensus and examine whether the proposed model can also account for
aspiration level (bconsensus x AV - 0.11 , t (2,109 ) consumer choice. In choice, alternatives falling below the
= -1.49,p > .13; bconsensusxAL = 0.20, t(2,109) = 2.88, aspiration level may be discarded from consideration with
p < .004). minimal influence of critic consensus (Meyer 1981). As
Informativeness of Critics. Once again, the results in study 3, aspiration level is manipulated via the social
support Hypothesis 3 and indicate that the subjects are risk associated with the decision context.
sensitive to differences in the informativeness of individ-
ual critics and differentially weight them appropriately. Subjects and Design
The most informative critic's opinion was weighted One hundred thirty-nine students participated in this
more heavily than either of the other critics' opinions study for extra course credit. Response to critic consensus
(bcriticA-CriticB = .18, P < .001; bCriticA-CriticC = ,45, P in differing social contexts was examined by having sub-
< .0001; bCriticB-CriticC = .27, P < .001). jects choose between restaurant pairs with equal mean
critic ratings but differing levels of critic consensus. Each
Discussion restaurant in the pair was rated by three critics on a 100-
Consistent with studies 1 and 2, we observed that point scale (100 = excellent restaurant, 0 = horrible res-
changes in the decision context affect consumers' aspira- taurant).
tion levels and thus their response to critic consensus. As Two pairs of restaurant alternatives were constructed
social risk associated with the decision increased, subjects that varied in mean critic rating (40, 80); each pair con-
set a higher standard for acceptability, resulting in the tained a low-variance (10.69) and high-variance (170.7)
average ratings of most product alternatives falling below option (low variance = 36, 40, 44; 76, 80, 84; vs. high
their aspiration level. In this loss domain, subjects rated variance = 24, 40, 56; 64, 80, 96). Three filler pairs with
alternatives with critic disagreement more favorably than moderate variance were used to establish the range of the
critic consensus because those alternatives offered some scale (mean ratings of 30, 60, and 90). The presentation
possibility, albeit sometimes remote, that the aspiration of the alternatives was counterbalanced for mean critic
level could be achieved. However, low perceived social rating, position of the high-variance option, and order of
risk resulted in a low aspiration level, and subjects re- the critic ratings. As in study 3, social risk was manipu-
sponded with risk aversion for the predominately gains lated within subject by varying the decision context of
domain. The pattern of results corroborate the earlier the choice task, either as a first date (high social risk) or
findings that the effect of critic consensus on product dining with a former roommate (low social risk). Deci-
evaluations depends on consumers' aspiration levels. sion context was counterbalanced between SUbjects.

STUDY 4 Procedure
In each of the previous studies, we have examined the As in study 3, the opening instructions outlined the
effect of critic consensus and aspirations on alternative eval- decision scenario (dining with a former roommate or a
48 JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

first date). Subjects examined five pairs of restaurants in tions. The results from all four studies indicate support
each decision context and were asked to choose the pre- for the reference-dependent model. Consumers respond
ferred option in each pair. The three filler pairs preceded differently to critic disagreement depending on whether
the two focal pairs. A distracter task was completed prior or not product quality or performance is perceived as
to examining the second decision context and subsequent above or below their aspiration level. Our results show
choices for the same five restaurant pairs. After the choice that when experts' average opinions indicate that an alter-
task, subjects provided additional information about their native falls short ofthe aspiration level, consumers prefer
aspiration levels in the two dining scenarios. The task disagreement among opinions because at least one critic
took an average of 15 minutes to complete, including the rating (highest) suggests that they may meet or exceed
distracter task between the two decision contexts. their aspiration level. However, when the experts are in
consensus that an alternative falls short of a consumer's
Aspiration Level. As in studies 2 and 3, subjects were
aspiration level, the consumer has no hope of achieving
asked to provide the minimum standard that they would
the desired level of utility or satisfaction. Conversely,
find acceptable for a restaurant given the social context of
when experts' average opinions indicate that a product's
the dining experience. The average aspiration level for the
two social contexts differed significantly (XRoommate quality or performance meets or exceeds the aspiration
level, consumers no longer prefer variance among opin-
= 59.45, XPirstDate = 74.87; t(l, 138) = 11.38,p < .0001).
ions and may actually prefer consensus. This suggests
that consumers are concerned about falling below their
Results aspiration level and thus focus their attention on the low
A categorical analysis was performed to test the effect ratings. For these acceptable alternatives, consensus is
of aspiration level on response to critic consensus. A test preferred because disagreement raises the possibility that
for order effects for the two scenarios revealed no differ- their experience may fall short of their expectations.
ence in subjects' choices or response to critic consensus. Prior research has demonstrated that consumers' aspi-
Gender was included as a covariate in the model, but, rations are influenced by the perceived risk associated
unlike in study 3, we observed a gender difference in with a decision outcome. We directly manipulate the per-
response to critic consensus. In particular, males were ceived risk and thus aspirations via price and social risk.
more likely to choose the low-consensus alternative than Consumers exhibit a tendency to prefer critic disagree-
females (male = 57 percent, female = 45.5 percent, ment for high-priced products or decisions associated with
bGender x Consensus = -0.22, X2 (548) = 4.11, p < .05). high social risk. This is due to the high expectations asso-
Once again, aspiration level was defined at the individ- ciated with these contexts, which results in most alterna-
ual level on the basis of subjects' self-reports for the tives falling below the consumers' aspiration levels.
two decision contexts. A disproportionate number of our The interaction we observed between aspiration level
observations fell below (n = 425) rather than above (n and consensus is consistent with what Ganzach (1994,
= 123) subjects' aspiration level because of relatively 1995) refers to as evidence for use of simplifying heuris-
high minimum standards. Consensus in critic ratings was tics (i.e., conjunctive and disjunctive evaluation rules) to
represented as a dichotomous variable (low vs. high). deal with inconsistencies in information. Use of a disjunc-
The parameter estimates of the model are presented in tive rule is indicated by individuals' focusing more atten-
Table 3. tion on high than on low values. Conversely, use of a
Consistent with studies 1-3, we observed a significant conjunctive rule is indicated by individuals' focusing
interaction between critic consensus and aspiration level more attention on low than on high values. Cognitive
(bconsensusxAL = 0.21, X2(548) = 3.99, p < .05). When responses would need to be collected to confirm this pro-
the pair's mean critic rating fell below their aspiration cessing explanation.
level, subjects tended to choose the option with critic Our results also shed further insight into consumer re-
disagreement (56.2 percent) more often than the option action to information uncertainty (Jaccard and Wood
with critic consensus (43.8 percent). However, when the 1988). Counter to prior research, we did not observe a
mean critic rating of the pair was above their aspiration negative effect of disagreement on consumer evaluations;
level, subjects were less likely to choose the option in in fact, we observed that alternatives are rated more favor-
which critics disagreed (44.3 percent) than the option ably in the face of disagreement than consensus. How-
with critic consensus (55.7 percent). A test for the simple ever, this result was driven by the fact that our subjects
effects of the interaction once again indicates that critic had high aspiration levels, and thus the majority of alter-
consensus had a negative effect below AL (p < .01, one- natives fell within the domain of losses where we ex-
tailed), and perhaps because of low sample size there pected to see risk seeking. In addition, our mediation
was a nonsignificant positive effect above AL (p = .17, analyses point out the need to measure consumer aspira-
one-tailed) . tions (i.e., reference point) rather than rely on a central
tendency measure ( category average) to predict consumer
GENERAL DISCUSSION response to consensus. Finally, we did not find that con-
We investigated how consumers integrate critic opin- sumers attach less weight to critic opinions, relative to
ions and attribute information into their product evalua- product attribute values, in the face of critic disagreement.
INTEGRATING OPINIONS 49

This may be due to the fact that consumers recognize the In the real world, informativeness may act as a heuristic
deficiency of product characteristics in capturing experi- for deciding to attend to a particular critic opinion. A
ential products or the difficulty of predicting the interplay critic who consistently rates products as below or above
among attribute values. For instance, a consumer may average runs the risk that his or her opinion will no longer
like both Meryl Streep and Mel Gibson but be unsure if be valued by consumers. The task presented here did not
this acting combination has anyon-screen chemistry. allow subjects to assess the level of fit between their own
Consumers are more likely to face uncertainty for the opinion and the opinions of the individual critics. Future
experiential products studied here because of their sensory research examining how consumers use critic opinions
nature and the need for direct experience. The experiential when they have the opportunity to assess the value of
aspect of products is a continuum (Holbrook and Hirschman those opinions is warranted. Some research suggests that
1982) with even functional products composed of some critics may be hired on the basis of their ability to predict
experience attributes such as dependability, convenience, the preferences of their target market (Eliashberg and
ease of use, and performance quality. Future research should Shugan 1997). As our research design did not enable
examine the impact of critic consensus for functional prod- examination of the interaction between critic consensus
ucts and whether salience directed to experience attributes and informativeness, future research might also examine
reduces the importance of tangible attributes. this topic.
Of further interest is the integration of specific product This research allows us to extend the missing-informa-
attribute information and summary evaluative ratings. Our tion paradigm (Levin et al. 1985) to account for how
results indicate an interaction between aspiration level consumers respond in the face of conflicting or inconsis-
and preference for product attribute values, which sug- tent information. Camerer and Weber (1992) recently
gests that one of these sources may be acting as a screen- reviewed the research on ambiguity across multiple disci-
ing mechanism for evaluating potential alternatives. plines and concluded that "uncertainty about the compo-
Given our data, we cannot determine the exact order of sition of an urn of balls is just one kind of missing infor-
processing. However, it is clear that either personal pref- mation. Feeling ignorant about football or politics, having
erence for a product's attributes exerts a stronger influ- doubts about which of several experts is right, wondering
ence on consumer evaluations for those receiving favor- whether your child has a predisposition to the side effects
able critic evaluation, or critic ratings are given more of a vaccine, or being unsure about another country's
weight when an alternative's attributes are appealing. The economy are all manifestations of missing information"
collection of process data would be required to resolve (p. 360). Consumer research has focused on missing in-
this uncertainty. Future research also needs to examine formation about product attributes and needs to examine
the role of the informative content in critic reviews in other forms of consumer uncertainty (Muthukrishnan
shaping consumer learning of product attributes (West, 1995) . We expect that the results demonstrated here may
Brown, and Hoch 1996). generalize outside of the domain of critic opinions to
In addition, consumers appear to be sensitive to the differ- any source of information with repeated observations. For
ential informativeness of individual critics and weight their example, in financial markets where performance mea-
opinions accordingly. An alternative explanation is that con- sures are readily available, response to stock volatility
sumers base their judgments on the extreme opinions for a may depend on both expected returns and consumer aspi-
given alternative rather than learn the informational value rations.
of a given critic. However, our results cast doubt on this Finally, there are two limitations of this work that war-
alternative explanation, given that Critic A and Critic B rant consideration. First, although our results are theoreti-
were weighted differentially in studies 1-3 but were equally cally of interest and robust across decision contexts, driv-
likely to report extreme or outlier opinions. 8 ers of aspirations, evaluation, and intended choice, the
magnitude of the interaction between consensus and aspi-
ration level is not very large. This poses a practicallimita-
8Two scoring rules were used for judging opinion extremity: (I) the tion when there are individual differences in aspiration
number of alternatives that a given critic gave the highest or lowest level. However, it provides insight into why it may be
rating among the three critics; (2) the number of "outlier" opinions
based on the endpoints of the scale (ratings of I, 2, 9, or 10). On the difficult to observe main effects of consensus in practice.
basis of these scoring rules, and an examination of Table I, we observed Second, Bettman (1973, 1975) points out that the per-
little difference in the number of times that Critic A (18) and Critic B ceived risk involved in a decision is determined by the
( 16) gave the highest or lowest rating relative to Critic C (8). Similarly, importance of the decision outcome, as well as consum-
Critic A (7) and Critic B (5) provided outlier opinions with roughly
the same frequency as Critic C (0). The extremity hypothesis would
ers' perceptions of their chance of finding an acceptable
predict little difference in weight between Critic A and Critic B, but product. Although we have focused on the affect of aspi-
significantly less weight was assigned to Critic C. Alternatively, the ration level on consumers' response to consensus, the
informativeness hypothesis would predict a linear ordering of the three importance of the decision is also likely to influence their
in terms of weight: Critic A > Critic B > Critic C. Our results indicate response to uncertainty. As the importance of the decision
that for study I, Critic A > Critic B = Critic C; and for studies 2 and
3 Critic A > Critic B > Critic C. This pattern is more consistent increases, the potential regret associated with making a
with the informativeness hypothesis (Hypothesis 2) than the extremity bad selection may cause consumers to exhibit caution in
hypothesis. their choices.
50 JOURNAL OF CONSUMER RESEARCH

CONCLUSION Camerer, Colin and Martin Weber (1992), "Recent Develop-


ments in Modeling Preferences: Uncertainty and Ambigu-
Critic opinions play an important role in consumer ity," Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 325-370.
evaluation of products, particularly so for experiential Clemen, Robert T. (1989), "Combining Forecasts: A Review
products. But, critics do not always agree. Therefore, un- and Annotated Bibliography," International Journal of
derstanding how consumers react to critic disagreement Forecasting, 5, 559-583.
- - - and Robert L. Winkler ( 1986), "Combining Economic
is of vital importance to companies who rely on expert
Forecasts," Journal of Business and Economic Statistics,
opinions to disseminate information about their products. 4 (January), 39-46.
Our results suggest that consumers' expectations and aspi- Coombs, Clyde H., Robyn M. Dawes, and Amos Tversky
rations regarding the decision outcome playa crucial role (1970), Mathematical Psychology: An Elementary Intro-
in determining how a person will respond in the face of duction, Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
critic disagreement. The average expectation of product Dowling, Grahame R. and Richard Staelin (1994), "A Model
quality in a category, price of given alternative, and social . of Perceived Risk and Intended Risk-Handling Activity,"
risk associated with a decision are all shown to influence Journal of Consumer Research, 21 (June), 119-134.
a consumer's aspiration level. This aspiration level is im- Einhorn, Hillel J. and Clayton T. Koelb ( 1982), "A Psychomet-
portant because it determines whether a given product is ric Study of Literary-Critical Judgment," Modem Lan-
perceived as meeting (a gain), or falling short of (a loss), guage Studies, 12 (3), 59-82.
expectations. To the extent that consumers are driven to Eliashberg, Jehoshua and Mohanbir S. Sawhney (1994),
"Modeling Goes to Hollywood: Predicting Individual Dif-
meet or exceed their aspiration level, they are likely to ferences in Movie Enjoyment," Management Science, 40
respond favorably to critic disagreement. ( September), 1151-1173.
- - - and Stephen M. Shugan (1997), "Film Critics: Influ-
[Received April 1996. Revised August 1997. Brian encers of Predictors," Journal of Marketing, 61 (April),
Sternthal and Robert E. Burnkrant served as editors 68-78.
and Robert J. Meyer and Joel Huber served as Ellsberg, Daniel (1961), "Risk, Ambiguity and the Savage
associate editors for this article.] Axioms," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 75,643-669.
Ganzach, Yoav (1994), "Inconsistency and Uncertainty in
Multi-Attribute Judgment of Human Performance," Jour-
REFERENCES nal of Behavioral Decision Making, 7, 193-211.
Anderson, Norman (1996), A Functional Theory of Cognition,
- - - (1995), "Attribute Scatter and Decision Outcome:
Mahwah, NJ: Erlbaum. Judgment versus Choice," Organizational Behavior and
Baron, Reuben M. and David A. Kenny (1986), "The Modera- Human Decision Processes, 62 (April), 113-122.
tor-Mediator Variable Distinction in Social Psychological Hoch, Stephen J. and Young-Won Ha (1986), "Consumer
Research: Conceptual, Strategic, and Statistical Considera- Learning: Advertising and the Ambiguity of Product Expe-
tions," Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 51 rience," Journal of Consumer Research, 13 (September),
(June), 1173-1182. 221-233.
Bearden, William O. and Michael J. Etzel (1982), "Reference Hogarth, Robin M. (1977), "Methods for Aggregating Opin-
Group Influence on Product and Brand Purchase Deci- ions," in Helmut Jungermann and Gerard de Zaeuw, eds.,
sions," Journal of Consumer Research, 9 (September), Decision Making and Change in Human Affairs, Boston:
184-194. Dordrecht 231-255.
Bettrnan, James R. (1973), "Perceived Risk and Its Compo- - - - (1989), "On Combining Diagnostic 'Forecasts':
nents: A Model and Empirical Test," Journal ofMarketing Thoughts and Some Evidence," International Journal of
Research, 10 (May), 184-190. Forecasting, 5, 593-597.
- - - (1975), "Information Integration in Consumer Risk Holbrook, Morris B. and Elizabeth C. Hirschman ( 1982), "The
Perception: A Comparison of Two Models of Component Experiential Aspects of Consumption: Consumers Fanta-
Conceptualization," Journal of Applied Psychology, 60 sies, Feelings, and Fun," Journal of Consumer Research,
(June), 381-385. 9 (September), 132-140.
Bone, Paula Fitzgerald (1995), "Word-of-Mouth Effects on Huber, Joel and John McCann (1982), "The Impact of Inferen-
Short-Term and Long-Term Product Judgments," Journal tial Beliefs on Product Evaluations," Journal of Marketing
of Business Research, 32 (March), 213-223. Research, 19 (August), 324-333.
Boor, Myron (1990), "Reliability of Ratings by Professional Jaccard, James and Gregory Wood (1988), "The Effects of
Movie Critics," Psychological Reports, 67 (August), Incomplete Information on the Formation of Attitudes to-
243-257. ward Behavioral Alternatives," Journal of Personality and
Brannick, Michael T. and Joan P. Brannick (1989), "Nonlinear Social Psychology, 54 (April), 580-591.
and Noncompensatory Performance Evaluation," Organi- Jacoby, Jacob and Leon B. Kaplan (1972), "The Components
zational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 44, 97- of Perceived Risk," in M. Venkatesan, ed., Proceedings
122. of the Third Annual Conference of the Association for Con-
Broniarczyk, Susan M. and Joseph W. Alba (1994), "Influence sumer Research, College Park, MD: Association for Con-
of Prior Beliefs, Frequency Cues, and Magnitude Cues sumer Research.
on Consumers' Perceptions of Comparative Price Data," Kahn, Barbara E. and Robert J. Meyer (1991), "Consumer
Journal of Consumer Research, 21 (September), 219- Multiattribute Judgments under Attribute Uncertainty,"
235. Journal of Consumer Research, 17 (March), 508-522.
INTEGRATING OPINIONS 51

- - - and William T. Ross, Jr. (1993), "An Experimental Rogers, Everett M. ( 1976), , 'New Product Adoption and Diffu-
Look and How People Combine Forecasts," working pa- sion," Journal of Consumer Research, 2 (March), 290-
per, Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania. 201.
Kahneman, Daniel and Amos Tversky (1979), "Prospect The- Roselius, T. (1971), "Consumer Rankings of Risk Reduction
ory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk," Econometrica, Methods," Journal of Marketing, 35, 56-61.
47 (March), 263-291. Ross, William T., Jr. and Elizabeth H. Creyer (1992), "Making
King, Charles W. and John O. Summers (1970), "Overlap in Inferences about Missing Information: The Effects of Miss-
Opinion Leadership across Consumer Product Catego- ing Information," Journal of Consumer Research, 19
ries," Journal of Marketing Research, 7 (February), 43- (June), 14-25.
50. Shannon, Claude E. and Warren Weaver (1949), The Mathe-
Levin, Irwin P., Richard D. Johnson, and Stephen V. Faraone matical Theory of Communication, Urbana: University of
(1984), "Information Integration in Price-Quality Trade- Illinois Press.
offs: The Effect of Missing Information," Memory and Shugan, Steven M. (1980), "Cost of Thinking," Journal of
Cognition, 12 (January), 96-102. Consumer Research, 7 (September), 99-111.
- - - , Richard D. Johnson, Craig P. Russo, and Patricia Del- Tversky, Amos and Daniel Kahneman (1991), "Loss Aversion
din ( 1985), "Framing Effects in Judgment Tasks Varying in Riskless Choice: A Reference-Dependent Model,"
Amounts of Information," Organizational Behavior and Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104 (4),1039-1061.
Human Decision Processes, 36, 362-377. Walker, Chip (1995), "Word of Mouth," American Demo-
Meyer, Robert J. (1981), "A Model of Multiattribute Judg- graphics, 17 (July), 38-44.
ments under Attribute Uncertainty and Informational Con- Wall Street Journal (1994), "A 'Thumbs Up' Pulls in the
straint," Journal of Consumer Research, 8 (November),
Audience," March 25, B1.
428-441.
Muthukrishnan, A. V. (1995), "Decision Ambiguity and In- West, Patricia M. (1996), "Predicting Preferences: An Exami-
cumbent Brand Advantage," Journal of Consumer Re- nation of Agent Learning," Journal of Consumer Re-
search, 22 (June), 98-109. search, 23 (June), 68-80.
Payne, John W., James R. Bettman, and Eric R. Johnson - - - , Christina L. Brown, and Stephen J. Hoch (1996),
(1993), The Adaptive Decision Maker, New York: Cam- "Consumption Vocabulary and Preference Formation,"
bridge University Press. Journal of Consumer Research, 23 (September), 120-
- - - , Dan J. Laughhunn, and Roy Crum (1980), "Transla- 135.
tion of Gambles and Aspiration Level Effects on Risky Winkler, Robert L. (1989), "Combining Forecasts: A Philo-
Choice Behavior," Management Science, 26 (10), 1039- sophical Basis and Some Current Issues," International
1060. Journal of Forecasting, 5, 605-609.
- - - , Dan J. Laughhunn, and Roy Crum (1981), "Further Wyatt, Robert O. and David P. Badger (1990), "Effects of
Tests of Aspiration Level Effects in Risky Choice Behav- Information and Evaluation in Film Criticism," Journal-
ior," Management Science, 27 (8), 953-958. ism Quarterly, 67 (Summer), 359-368.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi