Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 72

Consumption and Savings Decisions:

A Two-Period Setting

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis

Universidad Auton
oma de Madrid

Fall 2012

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 1 / 68


1 Summary

2 Credit markets
Budget constraints
Preferences
The optimization problem
Comparative statics
Change in x
Interest rate changes
The elasticity of intertemporal substitution

3 Extensions
The Life Cycle Hypothesis

4 Equilibrium with Many Agents


Credit Market Equilibrium
A Numerical Example
Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 2 / 68
Outline

In the first lecture we studied labor-leisure decisions in a static


environment.
In this lecture we study consumption and savings decisions in a
two-period setting. The original model was developed by Irving Fisher.
We consider a pure exchange economy. Agents receive a known
endowment of goods in both periods.
I Alternatively, we can think of an economy with inelastic labor supply.
The final good is perishable, but agents can borrow and lend on a
perfectly competitive credit market.
There is still no money in the economy. No financial intermediation
by banks either. Bonds are the only financial instrument.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 2 / 68


Savings motives

Why do people save?


1 Consumption smoothing - agents dislike fluctuations in consumption
spending.
2 Precautionary motives fear of unemployment etc.
3 Retirement
4 Purchase of real estate or durable consumption goods.
For the moment we focus on 1. Saving for retirement is treated at the end
of the course, while precautionary savings is left for later.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 3 / 68


Bonds

A bond is a piece of paper with a promise of a future payment of a


certain amount of goods to the holder of the bond.
Bonds are issued by borrowers and handed over to lenders.
All bonds are supposed to expire in one period.
We denote the (real) interest rate by R.
A loan of 1 unit of the final good in period t implies a repayment of
1 + R units of the final good in period t + 1.
We assume complete information. All loans are repaid.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 4 / 68


Notation

Let bt denote the bond holdings of a household in period t

I Positive values bt > 0 imply that the household is a lender.


I On the contrary, when bt < 0 the household is a borrower.

The household that buys bt bonds in t will receive (1 + Rt )bt in


period t + 1.

Since the credit market only operates between the first and second
period we drop the time index on R.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 5 / 68


Budget constraints

In general terms, the one-period budget constraint of a household can


be written as
ct + bt = yt + (1 + R )bt 1
When bt 1 > 0, the resources of the household exceed the value of
income
yt + (1 + R )bt 1 > yt
By contrast, when bt 1 < 0, the household has to devote part of this
periods resources to pay back the loan plus interest

yt + (1 + R )bt 1 < yt

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 6 / 68


Individual vs. Aggregate Saving

Before we analyze the savings and consumption decisions of Robinson


Crusoe, one important remark about the value of aggregate savings.

With credit markets the consumption of an individual household no


longer needs to coincide with her income (ct 6= yt ).
Nonetheless, in any equilibrium of a closed economy aggregate
savings must satisfy Bt = bt = 0. Why is this the case?
Consequently, aggregating the individual budget constraints
ct + bt = yt + (1 + R )bt 1 we obtain:

Ct = Yt
Some households spend more than their income, and others less. But
on the aggregate level consumption equals income.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 7 / 68


Robinson Crusoe in a Two-period Setting

In the rest of this theme, we analyze the case of an economy that lasts for
two periods.
We start by analyzing the decisions of a single agent:

I Robinson receives an endowment (or fixed income) of y1 units in the


first and y2 units in the second period.
I Robinson takes the interest rate as given and needs to choose his
consumption and savings in both periods.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 8 / 68


One-period budget constraints

Robinson faces the following pair of one-period budget constraints:

c1 + b1 = y1 ,
c2 + b2 = y2 + (1 + R )b1 .

Robinsons savings in the second period are necessarily equal to zero


He would like to borrow an infinite amount, but there are no
lenders! Hence,

c 2 = y 2 + ( 1 + R ) b1

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 9 / 68


The inter-temporal budget constraint
The two budget constraints can be consolidated into a single lifetime
budget constraint.

In a first step, we solve for b1 :

b1 = y1 c1 ,

Inserting this expression into the right-hand side of the budget constraint
for period 2, we obtain

c2 = y2 + (1 + R )(y1 c1 ).

Dividing both sides by (1 + R ) yields the following expression:


c2 y2
c1 + = y1 + .
| {z 1 + R} | {z 1 + R}
Present Value of Lifetime Consumption Present Value of Lifetime Income

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 10 / 68


Intertemporal budget constraint
In the sequel we denote the present value of lifetime income (or total
resources) by x:
y2
x = y1 +
1+R
The agent can freely distribute the consumption of these resources
over the two periods
c2
c1 + = x.
1+R
Note that 1+1R is the opportunity cost (in terms of period 1
consumption) of one unit of consumption in period 2.

Similarly, (1 + R )x is the el future value of the agents resources and

(1 + R )c1 + c2 = (1 + R )x = (1 + R )y1 + y2

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 11 / 68


The inter-temporal budget constraint

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 12 / 68


Preferences

The lifetime budget constraint defines the choice set (budget set) of the
agent. To complete the description of his problem, we need to define his
preferences over consumption in both periods.
Well use the following standard specification of time-separable
preferences:
U (c1 , c2 ) = u (c1 ) + u (c2 ),
The same function u (.) defines utility in both periods, but the utility
from future consumption is discounted at rate 1.
1
The discount factor is commonly expressed as = 1+ , where
represents the rate of time preference.
Finally, u 0 (.) = u (.)/ct > 0 and u 00 (.) = u 0 (.)/ct < 0

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 13 / 68


Inter-temporal marginal rate of rate of substitution (IMRS)

The indifference curves in this two-period setting are pairs of current and
future consumption that offer the same level of utility u 0 :

U (c1 , c2 ) = u (c1 ) + u (c2 ) = u 0

Along the indifference curve

u 0 (c1 )dc1 + u 0 (c2 )dc2 = 0


And the IMRS is defined as:

dc2 u 0 ( c1 )
= 0
dc1 u (c2 )

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 14 / 68


Example

Throughout the course we will often use the example of logarithmic


preferences (log-utility):

u (c1 , c2 ) = log(c1 ) + log(c2 ).


These preferences satisfy our set of assumptions and often yield simple
close-form solutions.

u (c1 , c2 ) 1 2 u (c1 , c2 ) 1
= ; 2
= 2
c1 c1 c1 c1

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 15 / 68


Exercise I

a. Derive the expression for the IRMS in the case of logarithmic


preferences:
U (c1 , c2 ) = log(c1 ) + log(c2 )
b. How does the value of the IMRS change if we raise the value of c1 ?
What is the explanation?
c. Calculate the value of the IRMS for the case in which c1 = c2 .
d. Repeat c for the general case U (c1 , c2 ) = u (c1 ) + u (c2 ).

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 16 / 68


Answers
a. The total derivative is given by

1
dc1 + dc2 = 0.
c1 c2
Hence,
dc2 c2
=
dc1 c1
b. An increase in c1 causes a fall in the value of the IMRS. Marginal
utility from consumption in the first period is decreasing in c1 . Hence,
an agent who consumes a large quantity of goods in the first period
and few goods in the second period, will be willing to sacrifice one
unit of first-period consumption in return for a small amount of
additional consumption in the second period.
c. 1/
d. Idem
Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 17 / 68
Indifference curves

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 18 / 68


The Optimization Problem of an Agent

In compact form the optimization problem can be written as

max[u (c1 ) + u (c2 )] (1)


c1 ,c2

subject to
c2
+ c1 = x. (2)
1+R
Like before there are two solution methods. Here we use the
substitution method. Given that

c2 = (x c1 )(1 + R ),

we can rewrite the maximand as

max[u (c1 ) + u ((x c1 )(1 + R ))] (3)


c1

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 19 / 68


The solution
The FOC associated with our optimization problem

max[u (c1 ) + u ((x c1 )(1 + R ))]


c1

is given by:

u 0 (c1 ) + u 0 ((x c1 )(1 + R ))(1)(1 + R ) = 0.


| {z }
c2

Or alternatively,
u 0 (c1 ) = u 0 (c2 ) (1 + R )
| {z } | {z }
MC MB

u 0 ( c1 )
= 1 + R.
u 0 (c2 )
| {z }
IMRS

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 20 / 68


Graphical representation of solution

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 21 / 68


Consumption Euler equation

The optimality condition known as the Consumption Euler equation

u 0 ( c1 )
= (1 + R )
u 0 (c2 )

is nothing else than the intertemporal variant of a well-known result in


consumption theory.

IMRS = price ratio of consumption in both periods

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 22 / 68


Optimal profile of consumption

According to the Euler equation

u 0 (c1 ) = (1 + R )u 0 (c2 )
there are two opposing forces that affect the inter-temporal choices of the
agent
The stronger the degree of time preference the lower is , the
less attractive is c2 ;
The higher is the interest rate, the more attractive it is to save.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 23 / 68


Perfect consumption smoothing

When (1 + R ) = 1, the Euler eqn. reduces to:

u 0 (c1 ) = u 0 (c2 ).

Given the strict concavity of u (.), this implies c1 = c2 .

Intuition: Recall that = 1/(1 + ). Hence, the necessary condition for


perfect consumption smoothing can be written as:
1+R
(1 + R ) = = 1,
1+

which is only satisfied if


R = .

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 24 / 68


Rising of falling consumption profiles

Using the same line of argument, one can easily demonstrate that the
consumption Euler eqn
u 0 ( c1 )
= (1 + R )
u 0 (c2 )
implies the following three results

(1 + R ) < 1 = c1 > c2
(1 + R ) = 1 = c1 = c2
(1 + R ) > 1 = c1 < c2

The above conditions play a central role in any dynamic macro model with
endogenous consumption choices.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 25 / 68


Log utility
Suppose that the agents preferences satisfy

u (c1 ) + u (c2 ) = log(c1 ) + log(c2 ).

In this case, we can write the maximand as

max[log(c1 ) + log((x c1 )(1 + R ))]


c1

and the associated FOC is:


1 1
+ (1)(1 + R ) = 0
c1 c2

1 1
= (1 + R ) = c2 = (1 + R )c1
c1 c2
c2
= (1 + R ).
c1

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 26 / 68


Log Utility

In this particular case, it is straightforward to obtain closed-form solutions


for the optimal consumption levels. Substituting c2 = (1 + R )c1 into the
lifetime budget constraint we get:

c1 (1 + R )
c1 + = x,
1+R
And so,
x
(1 + )c1 = x = c1 = .
1+

c2 = c1 ( 1 + R ) =
x (1 + R ).
1+
 
x 1 y2
b1 = y1 c1 = y1 = y1
1+ 1+ 1+R

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 27 / 68


Lagrange method

Lets return to our original problem

max[u (c1 ) + u (c2 )] (4)


c1 ,c2

subject to
c2
+ c1 = x. (5)
1+R
The Lagrangian associated with the above maximization problem can
be written as:
c2
L(c1 , c2 , ) = u (c1 ) + u (c2 ) + [x c1 ]
1+R

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 28 / 68


Solution
c2
L(c1 , c2 , ) = u (c1 ) + u (c2 ) + [x c1 ]
1+R
The FOCs are given by:

L(c1 , c2 , )
= u 0 ( c1 ) = 0
c1
L(c1 , c2 , ) 1
= u 0 (c2 ) + ( )=0
c2 1+R
L(c1 , c2 , ) c2
=x c1 = 0
1+R

Using the fact that = u 0 (c1 ), we obtain the same solution as


before:
u 0 (c1 ) = u 0 (c2 ) (1 + R )
| {z } | {z }
MC MB

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 29 / 68


Comparative statics

Our next objective is to determine the response of the optimal solutions to


changes in x and R.

Lets start with the case of an increase in x:


A rise in x represents a pure income effect that leads to an increase in
current and future consumption;
The effect on borrowing or lending depends on the timing of the rise
in income;
Transitory and permanent changes produce different effects;

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 30 / 68


Income effects

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 31 / 68


Example log utility

Suppose the agents preferences are given by:

U (c1 , c2 ) = log (c1 ) + log (c2 )

Previously, we have shown that the optimal consumption choices


satisfy:
x x (1 + R )
c1 = and c2 = .
1+ 1+
Hence,

c1 1 c (1 + R )
= => 0 and 2 = => 0
x 1+ x 1+

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 32 / 68


The borrowing/lending position
The changes in (c1 , c2 ) depend solely on the size of x. By contrast, the
changes in b1 depend critically on the timing of the income changes.
To be more specific, with logarithmic utility,
y2
y1 1+
b1 = R
.
1+

and so
b1 b1 1
= => 0 y = =< 0.
y1 1+ y2 (1 + )(1 + R )

After an increase in y1 the agent chooses a higher b1 . That is, lenders


will lend more, while borrowers will borrow less. Similarly, after an
increase in y2 the agents reduce the value of b1 .

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 33 / 68


Interest rate changes

An increase in the interest rate provokes both an income and a


substitution effect:

substitution effect: The higher interest rate lowers the cost of


consumption in the second period and makes saving more attractive.
Income effect: For given values of b1 , the rise in R reduces the
feasible consumption levels for borrowers while it raises the wealth of
lenders. The former need to pay higher interest payments, while the
latter receive higher interest payments.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 34 / 68


Higher interest rates
First-period borrowers

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 35 / 68


Higher interest rates
First-period lenders

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 36 / 68


The sum of income and substitution effects
The combined effect of a higher interest rate on the consumption levels
depends on the sign of b1 .

First-period lenders (b1 > 0)


Income effect: c1 > 0 & c2 > 0
Subst. effect: c1 < 0 & c2 > 0
Combined effect: c1 0 & c2 > 0
c1 > 0 if the income effect dominates the substitution effect.

First-period borrowers (b1 < 0) :


Income effect: c1 < 0 & c2 < 0
Subst. effect: c1 < 0 & c2 > 0
Combined effect: c1 < 0 & c2 0
c2 < 0 if income effect dominates the substitution effect.
Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 37 / 68
Disentangling income and substitution effects
First-period borrowers

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 38 / 68


Disentangling income and substitution effects
First-period lenders

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 39 / 68


Example log utility
With logarithmic preferences, the savings rate does NOT depend on the
interest rate, because the income and substitution effect cancel out against
each other.
Recall that
x x (1 + R )
c1 = and c2 = .
1+ 1+
y2
with x = y1 + 1+R .

Hence, the savings rate c1 /x = 1


1+ does not depend on R. But,

c1 1 y2
= <0
R 1 + (1 + R )2
c2
= y1 > 0
R 1+

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 40 / 68


Exercise II

Agents A and B have identical preferences over current and future


consumption:

Ui = ln (c1,i ) + ln (c2,i ) con i = A, B


but they have different endowment patterns as (y1,A , y2,A ) = (1, 0) y
(y1,B , y2,B ) = (0, 1), respectively.

and c and calculate the exact values of


a. Derive the solution for c1,i 2,i
these variables for the case in which R = 0.
b. Analyze the effects of an increase in R.
c. Who benefits from the higher interest rate?

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 41 / 68


The elasticity of intertemporal substitution
Economists measure the willingness of agents to substitute future for
current consumption with the elasticity of intertemporal substitution.

ln (ct +1 /ct )
EIS =
ln ( u 0 (ct +1 )/u 0 (ct )
Computation
1 Derive the expression for the Intertemporal Marginal Rate of
Substitution (IMRS)
2 Calculate the elasticity of the IMRS with respect to the ratio
(ct +1 /ct ).
3 The EIS is the inverse.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 42 / 68


The elasticity of intertemporal substitution
Economists measure the willingness of agents to substitute future for
current consumption with the elasticity of intertemporal substitution.

ln (ct +1 /ct )
EIS =
ln ( u 0 (ct +1 )/u 0 (ct )
Computation
1 Derive the expression for the Intertemporal Marginal Rate of
Substitution (IMRS)
2 Calculate the elasticity of the IMRS with respect to the ratio
(ct +1 /ct ).
3 The EIS is the inverse.
The EIS is important because it measures the elasticity of the optimal
consumption path to changes in the interest rate.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 42 / 68


Example: Log Utility

For the case of logarithmic preferences U = log (c1 ) + log (c2 ) we have:

dc2 c2
IMRS = =
dc1 c1
The elasticity of the IMRS w.r.t. c2 /c1 is given by
   
c2 c2
c 1 c1 1
c2   = ( ) = 1
( c1 ) c2
c
1

The EIS is the inverse of this number and so is 1.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 43 / 68


Interest-rate sensitivity of consumption growth

The EIS is of interest because it measures the elasticity of the optimal


consumption growth with respect to the interest rate.
Given that IMRS = (1 + R ) we have:
 
c2
d c1
  
c2

c2

c1 d c1 1+R
  = . c2
d (1+R ) d (1 + R )
1+R c1

The above statistic can be matched to the observed elasticity in data on


consumption.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 44 / 68


Log utility

With logarithmic preferences, the growth rate of consumption reduces to:


x (1+R )
c2
 
1+
= = (1 + R )
c1 x
1+

Hence, the elasticity of intertemporal substitution is equal to

(1 + R ) 1 + R
. =1
(1 + R ) (1 + R )

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 45 / 68


Summary

Due to concave utility, the agents prefer relatively smooth consumption


levels.

Borrowing and lending allows the agents to achieve smooth consumption


levels. Indeed, when (1 + R ) = 1, the agents choose a constant
consumption level.

Equilibrium consumption levels depend on the value of x. Compensating


changes in y1 and y2 that leave x unchanged lead to changes in savings,
but they do not alter the optimal consumption levels.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 46 / 68


Credit constraints

According to most empirical studies, consumption is more sensitive to


fluctuations in current income than suggested by Fishers model (Excess
sensitivity of consumption).

One candidate explanation is the existence of credit constraints. The


most extreme form of credit constraints analyzed in the literature assumes

bt 0 t

Binding credit constraints force agents to lower their consumption in


periods with relatively low income, leading to a positive correlation
between consumption and current income.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 47 / 68


Exercise III

Consider an agent with standard time-separable preferences


U (c1 , c2 ) = u (c1 ) + u (c2 ). The agent has a fixed income of 0.5 units of
the final good in the first period of life and 1.5 units in the second period.
Suppose for simplicity that = 1 and R = 0.
a. Calculate the agents optimal consumption decisions in the absence of
credit constraints.
b. Derive the agents consumption choice when agents cannot borrow,
i.e. b1 0.
c. Repeat a for an agent with an income of 1.5 units in the first and 0.5
units in the second period.
c. Return to a but now suppose that the agent lives during many
periods. How could the agent avoid having to reduce consumption in
bad periods?

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 48 / 68


N periods / Uncertainty
In real life, agents live for many agents and future income is uncertain. In
these circumstances, agents need to solve
N
max E0
{ct ,bt }
t u (ct )
t =0

subject to:
ct + bt = yt + (1 + Rt )bt 1
Let t denote the Lagrange multiplier associated with the period-t budget
constraint. Case I: Without uncertainty and with Rt = R, the FOCs:

t u 0 ( ct ) = t
0 = t + (1 + R )t +1 =
u (ct ) = (1 + Rt )u 0 (ct +1 )
0

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 49 / 68


Generalizing lifetime budget constraints

Consider the following sequence of budget constraints

c0 + b0 = y0
c1 + b1 = y1 + (1 + R )b0
.
.
cN + bN = yN + (1 + R )bN 1

Solving forwards, we obtain:


N N
yt ct
bN = (1 + R )t (1 + R )t
t =0 t =0

When life ends in N, bN = 0 and we obtain the standard expression.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 50 / 68


Uncertain 2-period income
To illustrate the effects of uncertainty, lets consider a case in which
N = 2 and income in the second period is uncertain. With pl = 0.5 the
agent receives low income y2l and with complementary probability
ph = 1 pl = 0.5 he receives income y2h > y2l . Formally,

maxu (c1 ) + [0.5u (c2l ) + 0.5u (c2h )]


c1 ,b1

s.t. c1 + b1 = y1
c2i = y2i + (1 + R )b1

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 51 / 68


Uncertain 2-period income
To illustrate the effects of uncertainty, lets consider a case in which
N = 2 and income in the second period is uncertain. With pl = 0.5 the
agent receives low income y2l and with complementary probability
ph = 1 pl = 0.5 he receives income y2h > y2l . Formally,

maxu (c1 ) + [0.5u (c2l ) + 0.5u (c2h )]


c1 ,b1

s.t. c1 + b1 = y1
c2i = y2i + (1 + R )b1

F.O.C:

u 0 (c1 ) = (1 + R )[0.5u 0 (c2l ) + 0.5u 0 (c2h )]


= (1 + R )E1 u 0 (y2i + (1 + R )b1 )
< (1 + R )u 0 (E (y2i + (1 + R )b1 ))

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 51 / 68


Uncertain 2-period income
To illustrate the effects of uncertainty, lets consider a case in which
N = 2 and income in the second period is uncertain. With pl = 0.5 the
agent receives low income y2l and with complementary probability
ph = 1 pl = 0.5 he receives income y2h > y2l . Formally,

maxu (c1 + [0.5u (c2l ) + 0.5u (c2h )]


c1 ,b1

s.t. c1 + b1 = y1
c2i = y2i + (1 + R )b1

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 52 / 68


Uncertain 2-period income
To illustrate the effects of uncertainty, lets consider a case in which
N = 2 and income in the second period is uncertain. With pl = 0.5 the
agent receives low income y2l and with complementary probability
ph = 1 pl = 0.5 he receives income y2h > y2l . Formally,

maxu (c1 + [0.5u (c2l ) + 0.5u (c2h )]


c1 ,b1

s.t. c1 + b1 = y1
c2i = y2i + (1 + R )b1

Consumption Euler equation:


 0 
u ( c1
E1 = 1+R
u 0 (c2i )

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 52 / 68


Life Cycle Hypothesis

Nobel prize winner Franco Modigliani considered an extension of the


basic model of Fisher to analyze decisions along the life cycle.
The basic insight: income varies in an almost deterministic manner
along the life cycle and agents use the credit market to insulate
consumption from these movements in income.
Agents typically borrow when they are young (education, housing),
save during prime age and dissave during retirement.
At different stages of their life, agents or households therefore act at
different sides of the credit market.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 53 / 68


The Life Cycle Hypothesis

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 54 / 68


The Life Cycle Hypothesis

When the agents have unrestricted access to credit markets,


consumption decisions no longer depend on income in a given period
but on the PV of lifetime income.
Let y denote average income along the lifecycle and suppose
= 1 and (1 + R ) = 1.
Savings tend to be negative in periods in which yt < y .
Savings tend to be positive in periods in which yt > y .
These optimal savings decisions allow agents to maintain a constant
(or smooth) consumption level although income changes.
Implication:
Consumption depends primarily on y and hence x. The marginal
propensity of consumption from changes in y is near to 1. By
contrast, transitory changes in yt have little effect on consumption.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 55 / 68


Permanent income hypothesis

The life-cycle model of Modigliani focuses on deterministic changes along


the lifecycle. However, during ones lifetime income also suffers transitory
and largely unpredictable changes in income.

Friedman formalizes this idea by supposing that income in any given


period is the sum of a permanent and a transitory component

yt = y + t

Suppose t is i.i.d. with E t = 0. In that case its clear that ct should


hardly respond to the realizations of t . By contrast, changes in y should
lead to changes in ct of similar size.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 56 / 68


Random Walk Hypothesis

Bob Hall reconsidered the results of the permanent income hypothesis


(PIH) assuming that agents have rational expectations agents make
efficient use of all the available information.

Main prediction: If the PIH holds and agents have rational expectations
then consumption changes should be unpredictable. That is, consumption
follows a random walk and Et ct +1 = ct .

In ordinary words: Agents only revise their consumption decisions if they


receive new information that forces them to revise their expectations. This
is intrinsically unpredictable.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 57 / 68


Ejercicio III

Lucas vive durante dos periodos y su renta disponible en ambos periodos


es y1 1 y y2 2 , donde t es un impuesto de cuantia fija en el perodo
t. Suponga que Lucas tiene las siguientes preferencias:

U (c1 , c2 ) = log(c1 ) + log(c2 )


Suponga que el gobierno reduce el valor de 1 en 1 unidad pero al mismo
momento aumenta el impuesto en el segundo perodo con (1 + R )
unidades.
a. Analice como afectan los cambios en los impuestos al valor actual de
los recursos totales de Lucas.
b. Como afectan los cambias a las decisiones de consumo y ahorro de
Lucas?

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 58 / 68


Equilibrium with Many Agents

To end this second theme, we now proceed with an analysis of equilibrium


consumption and savings decisions in an economy with many agents.
Here we analyze the case of heterogenous agents with different
degrees of impatience;
In the exercises well consider the alternative case in which agents
have identical preferences but different income sequences.
In the latter case we are able to generate competitive equilibria in which
all agents end up with a constant consumption level during their lifetime.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 59 / 68


Setup
Suppose the economy is populated by a large number of agents. All
agents have a constant income stream y1 = y2 = y . Hence,
y
x =y+ .
1+R
There are two types of agents with different preferences. Ni agents of
type i with preferences

log(c1 ) + i log(c2 ),

and Nj agents of type j with preferences

log(c1 ) + j log(c2 ),

where i < j . In other words, the type-i agents are less patient that
their type-j counterparts.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 60 / 68


Individual problem
Recall that the individual optimization problem of type-i agents can be
written as:

max[u (c1i ) + i u ((x c1i )(1 + R ))]


c1i
Similarly, the Consumption Euler eqn. is:
c2i = c1i i (1 + R ).
Solutions:
x
c1i =
1 + i
(1 + R )x
c2i =
1 + i
x
b1i = y c1i = y
1 + i
i y 1+y R
= .
1 + i
Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 61 / 68
Credit Market Equilibrium

In any equilibrium, the interest rate adjusts to ensure that the credit
market clears. Formally,
Ni b1i + Nj b1j = 0
Or equivalently,
Ni b1i = Nj b1j
| {z } |{z}
Creditdemand Creditsupply

Substituting the solutions for b1i and b1j in the market clearing condition
yields:
i y 1+y R j y 1+y R
Ni + Nj =0
1 + i 1 + j
Given the values for (y , i , j , Ni , Nj ) this equation can be solved for R.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 62 / 68


A Numerical Example

Suppose that y = 1, i = 0.8 and j = 0.9, Ni = 20, and Nj = 80.

Accordingly, the market clearing condition can be written as:

i y 1+y R j y 1+y R
Ni + Nj = 0,
1 + i 1 + j

0.8 1+1R 0.9 1+1R


20 + 80 = 0,
1 + 0.8 1 + 0.9
So,
0.8 1+1R 1
0.9
20 = 80 1+R
1.8 1.9

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 63 / 68


Solution
0.8 1+1R 1
0.9
20 = 80 1+R
1.8 1.9
1.9(20) 80(1.8)
(0.8)20(1.9) = (80)0.9(1.8),
1+R 1+R

38 144
30.4 = 129.6.
1+R 1+R

144 38
30.4 + 129.6 = +
1+R 1+R

182 182
160 = = 1 + R = = 1 + R = 1.1375
1+R 160
Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 64 / 68
Equilibrium consumption and savings decisions
Given R, it is straightforward to calculate the solutions for b1i and b1j :

i y 1+y R 0.8 1+1R


b1i = =
1 + i 1.8
0.8 160
182 0.8 0.879
= = = 0.0439.
1.8 1.8

j y 1+y R 0.9 1+1R


b1j = =
1 + j 1.9
0.9 160
182 0.9 0.879
= = = 0.011.
1.9 1.9
Note also that

Ni b1i + Nj b1j = (20)(0.0439) + (80)(0.011) = 0.

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 65 / 68


Equilibrium Consumption and Savings Decisions
Besides
y 1
x =y+ = 1+ = 1.8791.
1+R 1 + 0.1375
Hence,
x 1.8791
c1i = = = 1.0439 > y1 = 1.
1 + i 1.8
Obviously, it must be true that

c1i + b1i = y1
1.0439 0.0439 = 1.

Finally,
i x (1 + R )
c2i =
1 + i
0.8(1.8791)(1 + 0.1375)
= = 0.94999 < y2 = 1.
1 + 0.8
Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 66 / 68
Equilibrium consumption and savings decisions

Equivalently, for type-j agents:


x 1.8791
c1j = = = 0.989 < y1 = 1.
1 + j 1.9

c1j + b1j = y1 ,
0.989 + 0.011 = 1

j x (1 + R )
c2j =
1 + j
0.9(1.8791)(1 + 0.1375)
= = 1.0125 > y2 = 1.
1 + 0.9

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 67 / 68


Summary

In this second part we have analyzed the competitive equilibrium in


an economy of two periods;
All agents maximize their lifetime utility and can borrow or lend the
desired amount at the equilibrium interest rate;
All individuals enjoy a constant level of income. Nonetheless, in
equilibrium
The impatient agents (type i) choose to borrow against their future
income;
The impatient agents (type j) choose to lend part of their first-period
resources;
In the exercises you are invited to solve an example in which agents
use the credit market to smooth their consumption;

Dynamic Macroeconomic Analysis (UAM) Consumption and Savings Fall 2012 68 / 68

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi