Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 19

Financial Crisis

China and the Financial Crisis


Stimulating and Understanding Household Consumption

Growth in Chinas economy has become too dependent on investment and David Janoff Bulman
exports, and it has been argued that the current model for economic growth
Johns Hopkins School of
is unsustainable. This article argues that China should promote the house- Advanced International Studies
hold consumption share and that, in the wake of the financial crisis, strong
adjustments are needed to enable consumption to grow faster than the GDP.
There are many possible measures the government can take, including fis-
cal and macro policies, price and tax measures, and financial reforms. Due
to Chinas current high growth and low income, there is large potential for
comsumption growth.

Consumption to repeat the obvious is the sole ing the household consumption share of GDP.
end and object of all economic activity. Despite being outpaced by investment, Chinese
John Maynard Keynes consumption has grown at one of the fastest
paces in the world. From 2000 to 2007, Chinas
To boost domestic demand is a long-term strategic household consumption nearly doubled in real
policy for Chinas economic growth and the way for terms. However, over this period real GDP grew
us to tackle the financial crisis and stave off external by a whopping 153%.3 With a decreasing share
risks. of GDP, lagging consumption (or, rather, surging
Wn Jibo investment) contributes to global imbalances, in-
efficient domestic growth, and concerns of envi-
Introduction ronmental sustainability. Consumption promo-

I n recent years, Chinas economy has become


increasingly investment-led. The consump-
tion share of the Gross Domestic Product (GDP)
tion is therefore important for reducing growth
volatility, enabling households to share in gains
from growth more fully, and balancing interna-
has declined on an almost annual basis since the tional relationships and trade. The current global
beginning of the reform period in 1978, falling economic crisis provides a potential opportunity
below 50% in 2007 and 2008 after having ex- to move towards a consumption-led growth path.
ceeded 67% of GDP in 1981.1 Consumptions As Paul Romer presciently said in 2004, A crisis
share of annual GDP growth has also contracted, is a terrible thing to waste. China has rebounded
falling from almost 80% of growth at the begin- quickly from the crisis, and overheating may now
ning of reform to less than 40% between 2003 be a greater concern than recession. This paper
and 2006 (in 2007, the share edged slightly will demonstrate that household consumption
above 40% again). In this decline, household has held up well over the past year but that more
consumption has led the way; government con- dramatic adjustments will be necessary to enable
sumption as a share of GDP has stayed relatively consumption to grow faster than GDP for any
constant between 13-16% of GDP, while house- extended period. These adjustments will have to
hold consumption fell from a share of over 50% focus both on increasing household income and
in the early 1980s to only 35.3% in 2008.2 on decreasing household saving rates.
Dependence on investment- and export-led
growth will not be sustainable moving forward, Crisis strikes
and it is essential that China rebalance by increas- The global financial crisis hit China hard,

Summer 2010 20
David Janoff Bulman

but consumption has remained strong due to a household consumption growth. They include
combination of proactive government responses government purchases and are collected by
as well as advantageous preconditions. Chinas provincial-level statistics offices from reporting
economy began to slow at the end of 2007, well enterprises and farmer surveys.6 For valuable
before the Lehman collapse. The subsequent comparative purposes, it is useful to look at NBS
global recession made matters worse, triggering household consumption data that is compiled
a trade contraction and resulting in a negative quarterly from direct household surveys. This
contribution of net exports to Chinas GDP data excludes government purchases as well as
growth so far in 2009. Nevertheless, Chinas construction materials (which are included in
economy has already rebounded. Having bot- retail sales if they are purchased by individuals),
tomed out in the first quarter of this year, GDP counting them as investment instead.7 There-
expanded 7.7% year-on-year (YOY) in the first fore, when housing purchases are high, as they
nine months of 2009. According to Chinas Na- are now, retail sales are likely to exceed house-
tional Bureau of Statistics (NBS)4, consump- hold survey-based consumption data. On the
tion contributed 4.0 percentage points of this other hand, retail sales do not include spending
growth, investment contributed 7.3 percentage on many services, so there is a chance of under-
points, and net exports had a negative contribu- estimation. Historically, the two statistics have
tion. This consumption contribution (52%) is closely tracked one another, as seen in chart 4
large compared to its 40% level in recent years, below. That said, in crisis, government spending
implying that the recovery has not been entirely has increased, as have fears of inventory explo-
investment-led. About two-thirds of this con- sions and hoarding, all of which could potential-
sumption growth was from households, with ly drive up retail sales without actually boosting
one-third from the government. Indeed, Chinas household consumption.
household consumption growth has proved very The household survey data also demon-
resilient during the downturn as a result of low strates resilient, albeit not as rapid, consumption
leverage and high savings, government direct and growth. Through the first half of 2009, year-on-
indirect stimulus measures, a rapid expansion of year rural per capita consumption grew by 8.1%
consumer credit, and sustained growth in house- in real terms while urban per capita consump-
hold income and employment. tion grew by 11.2%. Growth continued in the
There are many indications that Chinese third quarter: rural per capita consumption was
consumption has continued to grow despite the up 9.2% while urban per capita consumption
global recession. As one indicator, retail sales was up 10.5% (again in real terms). While slow-
have been remarkably resilient. Having lagged er than retail sales growth, these growth figures
GDP growth through 2007, nominal retail sales were still well above real GDP growth, as seen in
outpaced GDP over 2008 and have continued chart 5 below. Resiliency is also reflected in con-
to outpace GDP so far in 2009. While headline sumer confidence indices. Consumer confidence
numbers on nominal retail sales seem to indicate began to fall as early as December 2007, bot-
a sharp decline from the end of 2008 through the toming out in March 2009 before beginning to
first half of 2009, much of this apparent decline rise again.8 According to CLSAs own consumer
was actually a result of high retail price inflation confidence index, the share of families who be-
in the first half (H1) of 2008 and a decline into lieved their income would decline over the next
retail price deflation in H1 2009.5 In real terms, six months peaked at 38% in December 2008
Chinese retail sales barely hiccuped in the first before falling steadily to 16% by May 2009.9
quarter of 2009 before resuming an extremely Clearly, consumption growth has remained
rapid pace of growth, as seen in chart 3. strong, surprising many analysts.
Retail sales are a questionable proxy for Several factors have enabled this consumer

21 Greater China
Financial Crisis

spending resilience. Perhaps most importantly, changed nationally to boost consumption. Be-
Chinese consumers were in a strong position yond rural areas, many policies were established
coming into the crisis: income growth was ro- to promote consumption throughout the coun-
bust, debt was low, and household savings were try in particularly, policies to promote car and
high, providing a solid cushion. These precon- housing sales. With regard to housing, the gov-
ditions were extremely important, and are not ernment exempted the stamp tax and land value-
new in Chinas case; previous business cycles in added tax on individual housing purchases, low-
China have led to high volatility in GDP and ered the minimum mortgage rate, and lowered
GDP proxies (including the Purchasing Man- the minimum down payment to 20% of the
agers Index, electricity production, etc.), but houses value (from 30% previously). Vehicle tax-
retail sales and household income growth have es for low-emissions vehicles were lowered, and
remained relatively steady in these cases as well. a cash for clunkers program was established to
For instance, in 1999, as net exports shrank in provide CNY 5,000-15,000 for old automobile
the wake of the Asian Financial Crisis, consump- trade-ins. The efficacy of these measures is clear,
tion accounted for over 88% of GDP growth.10 with much of the growth in retail sales led by
However, preconditions are not the entire story. housing-related items and automobiles. In the
A strong government response, a rapid increase in first three quarters, furniture sales jumped 34%
consumer credit, and policies promoting income YOY, building and decoration materials jumped
and employment growth have enabled Chinese 30.2%, and automobile sales jumped 44.5%.15
consumers to continue to expand their spending In addition, many government efforts have
behavior even as the economy has slowed down. been made to increase the breadth of the social
The government response to domestic con- safety net. A trial rural old-age insurance pro-
traction and international recession has been gram has been established in 10% of Chinas
swift and aggressive. While investment has been counties, covering 90 million people. The gov-
the predominant focus of stimulus, there is some ernment is spending CNY 12 billion to increase
truth to Premier Wen Jiabaos assertion that teacher salaries16, and has allocated CNY 43 bil-
Chinas stimulus package focuses on expanding lion to provide health insurance for retirees of
domestic demand and is aimed at driving eco- closed or bankrupt SOEs. In April, a health care
nomic growth through both consumption and reform package was announced that will involve
investment11. The stimulus package and addi- CNY 850 billion through 2011. Two-thirds will
tional government spending have come in many be spent on patients and one-third on hospi-
forms. In rural areas, the government has moved tals.17 Outside of these new programs, the 2009
to boost consumption, both directly and indi- budget for education, medical and health care,
rectly. The minimum purchasing price of grains social security, employment, government-sub-
was raised by 15%.12, 13, 14 Farmer subsidies were sidized housing and other programs related to
increased, resulting in a transfer of about CNY peoples well-being will be 29.4% higher than
[RMB] 123 billion. Subsidies amounting to in 2008.18 As part of the CNY 4 trillion stimulus
CNY 40 billion were given to rural households package, there is a CNY 40 billion allocation for
for purchases of home appliances, agricultural medical services, culture, and education, as well
machinery, automobiles and motorcycles. This as a CNY 280 billion allocation for affordable
included a CNY 20 billion, 13% subsidy to pur- housing.19 All of these programs to boost social
chase home appliances in rural areas and a bring welfare should increase consumption both by
automobiles to the countryside program which increasing current expenditure on the relevant
was meant to contribute CNY 5 billion between items (i.e. health care, education) and by de-
March and September. creasing precautionary savings.
Regulatory and tax policies have also been These government measures add up, and in

Summer 2010 22
David Janoff Bulman

combination amount to hundreds of billions of calculates that a 15% drop in exports implies a
CNY directed at increasing consumption. If one 2.3% increase in unemployment in 2009 (equal
assumes that household consumption increases to 17.5 million jobs). This squares well with re-
10% in 2009 (reasonable given the above figures ports of job losses of 20 million in Q4 2008 and
through Q3), this would mean an increase of Q1 2009. However, employment growth picked
CNY 1.1 trillion clearly, much of the increase up again and turned positive in the first half of
could potentially be accounted for by govern- the year through August, eight million new
ment measures. This policy response is in stark jobs had been created.24 Moreover, job losses
contrast to the one taken during and after the in the first half of the year were concentrated
Asian Financial Crisis, when state-owned enter- among migrants who contribute a small share to
prise (SOE) restructuring led to rapid growth consumption growth.
but also reduced job security, income growth, Much has been made of the explosion in
and the public provision of health, education, Chinese bank lending in 2009. Not enough
and housing, all of which led to a decreasing has been made of the explosion in bank lend-
share of consumption in GDP.20 ing to individuals. Consumer lending has in-
The government investment stimulus has creased dramatically.25 In December 2007, with
also had positive effects on income and employ- the housing boom, consumer loans accounted
ment growth: as long as income growth and em- for over 80% of the increase in total net lend-
ployment growth are resilient, one should expect ing by Chinese banks. The vast majority of this
consumption growth to remain strong as well. was mortgage lending. Consumer loans then
The CNY 4 trillion investment stimulus pack- declined as the government tightened monetary
age has done much to reignite Chinese growth. policy at the end of 2007 and beginning of 2008.
While it is investment-focused and in the long In March 2009, consumer loans again began to
run may promote further imbalance, in the short grow rapidly and by July accounted for over 50%
run it has and will continue to create jobs and of new net lending, reaching over CNY 200 bil-
boost incomes, thus helping keep consumption lion in net new monthly loans over the summer
resilient. Coming into the crisis, per capita in- months, as shown in chart 7 below.26 The mas-
come growth was growing rapidly. Chan esti- sive growth in consumption loans squares with
mates that nominal growth in per capita urban the increased purchases of autos and housing-
and rural incomes far outpaced GDP in 2008.21 related purchases. Growth was not confined to
This trend continued in 2009. Through the first mortgages: through September, banks in China
three quarters, real urban income had grown at had issued 175 million new credit cards, 33.3%
10.5% and real rural income had grown at 9.2% more than during the same period in 2008.27
(compared to GDP growth of 7.7%). Transfer Rapidly growing consumer credit can of course
income was up 16% for urban households and be dangerous, and there are indications that
31.4% for rural households, indicating the pro- consumer lending has begun to overheat.28 De-
active government response. Beyond govern- spite these concerns, consumer lending growth
ment measures, including a CNY 370 billion al- has been important for sustaining high Chinese
location for rural infrastructure and programs to household consumption this year.
boost rural income22, part of the reason for this
resilience is that wage growth is more highly cor- Understanding the relative decline
related with services than industry, and Chinas in household consumption
service industries have been far less affected than Chinese household consumption has proved
manufacturing and heavy industry during the resilient over the past year, outpacing GDP
crisis. Another part of income resilience is that growth. Does this signal a new trajectory in
employment has been relatively strong. Sun23 Chinas growth pattern? Has the household con-

23 Greater China
Financial Crisis

sumption share of GDP reached its nadir? Or had stayed at its 2000 level of 64.1% of GDP for
will things return to the way they were before as the past eight years, household consumption as
China shrugs off the lingering effects of the cri- a share of GDP at the end of 2008 would have
sis? To adequately confront these questions, it is been 39.7%. If, on the other hand, the savings
necessary to understand why Chinas household rate had remained at its 2000 level of 27.5% over
consumption has declined as a share of GDP. the past eight years while household income fol-
First, to state the obvious, the household con- lowed its actual trend, household consumption
sumption share of GDP declines because con- as a share of GDP would be 41.3%. Instead the
sumption growth is outpaced by GDP growth. ratio fell to 35.3%. These hypothetical cases are
Chinas household consumption constituted a shown in chart 10 below. The conclusion is clear:
mere 35.3% of GDP in 2008. Real private con- both elements explain part of the truth.
sumption growth has tracked real GDP growth
fairly consistently over the past 30 years, as seen Determinants of lower household disposable
in chart 8 below. Chinas low proportion of pri- income to GDP ratio
vate consumption is a result of sharp declines in The household disposable income share of
1989-1994 and 2001-2008. The more recent GDP in China has fallen sharply in recent years
decline is particularly shocking, especially from as corporate profits have risen rapidly without
2001 to 2006. It is therefore important to look a commensurate rise in employment or wages.
for elements of Chinas economy that changed in This is not a long-term phenomenon: the house-
this period. hold income share of GDP grew for the first five
Household consumption growth can be years after reform in 1979, rising from 54% to
outpaced by GDP either because consum- 64% before plateauing and then beginning to
ers save a larger portion of their disposable in- decline in 2000. Most explanations for the de-
come or because the economy grows faster than clining income share of GDP focus on structural
does household disposable income. Identifying issues particularly a shift towards an excessive
whether declining disposable income or rising focus on investment as well as increasing pro-
savings rates are responsible for the overall re- ductivity and profitability. Industry, and particu-
duction in household consumption is important larly heavy industry, is capital- rather than labor-
for determining appropriate policy responses. intensive, leading to relatively slow employment
Too often, there is a tendency to assert that it growth. Additionally, as China has a large sur-
is one of these factors and not the other, when plus of rural under-employed labor, wage pres-
in reality the answer seems to be that both fac- sures have remained low, preventing wage in-
tors are involved. Household savings as a pro- creases from keeping pace with profits. Beyond
portion of disposable income demonstrated no structural issues, Chinas repressed financial
clear pattern from 1992 to 2004, fluctuating system has prevented households from directly
around 30%.29 Since 2000, however, household reaping the rewards of high corporate profitabil-
saving rates grew rapidly, rising from 27.5% to ity, thus suppressing a major potential non-wage
37.9% in 2007. Household disposable income source of income. Back-of-the-envelope calcula-
as a share of GDP exhibits a similar trend. This tions below indicate that of the 8.6 percentage
ratio hovered around 65% from 1992 to 1999 point decline in the income share of GDP from
and then fell sharply from 2000 to 2006 (from 1998 to 2007, about 6 percentage points appear
64.1% to 57.3%). Given these patterns, it fol- to be a result of the declining wage share of GDP
lows that the household consumption share of while the rest is attributable to relatively lower
GDP also saw its sharpest decline since 2000 interest income.
(falling from 46.4% to 35.3% by 2008). Look- In the past ten years, Chinese firms have be-
ing at some counterfactuals, if disposable income come remarkably profitable. Since 1998, profits

Summer 2010 24
David Janoff Bulman

as a share of GDP have climbed from 1.7% to bor and minimal rights for migrants have helped
over 10% in 2008, likely as a result of productiv- to keep wage costs low. According to calculations
ity gains arising from SOE restructuring in the based on flow of funds data, the wage share of
late 1990s as well as greater access to internation- GDP reached 53.7% in 1999 before falling to
al markets enabled by WTO accession in 2001.30 47.6% by 2007.36 Based on these numbers, the
Direct and indirect government subsidies have employment and related wage decrease explain
also enabled this transformation. Current value- 6.1 percentage points of the 8.6 percentage point
added tax policies create distortions by subsidiz- decrease in the household income share of GDP
ing and stimulating manufacturing relative to from 1998 to 2007.
consumption.31 Lending interest rates have been The consequences of relatively slow wage
artificially held down by deposit interest rate and employment growth are compounded by
caps, under-pricing the true cost of capital. Ad- Chinese households reliance on wages finan-
ditionally, government savings increased dramat- cial investments yield little return and account
ically after the 1994 fiscal reforms, and much of for only a small portion of income. In the last
this saving was used to finance investment rather five years of data (2003-2007), the wage com-
than current spending.32 Government capital in- pensation share of disposable income has aver-
jections to SOEs are a large source of free capital aged over 83%, while government transfers have
for these firms (free in the sense that dividend made up an additional 10%. Less than 6% of
payments to the government only began to be household disposable income came from inter-
collected in 2008).33 est and dividend payments.37 Household interest
Yet while profits have soared, growth in em- and dividend income declined as a proportion
ployment and wages has, in relative terms, stag- of GDP from 5.5% in 1994 to 2.4% by 2005
nated. In the decade from 1998 to 2008, while despite growth in household saving deposits as a
profits rose at a compound annual growth rate share of GDP, as seen in chart 12 below. Includ-
(CAGR) of 35.6%, employment grew at only ing the other category that likely includes sales
3.6% (referring to the same NBS industry sam- of financial assets (i.e. stocks), financial income
ple as above). He and Kuijs34 calculate that, from amounted to 7.1% in 2007 (the latest year with
1993 to 2005, around 85% of industry growth flow of fund data). To put this in comparison,
came from increased labor productivity rather in Korea, this share is over 30%; in Japan it is
than new employment. Urban employment over 20%.38 This low share of financial income
growth slowed from 5.4% per year during 1978- is mainly a result of deposit interest rate caps
1993 to less than 3% during 1993-2005. This is these caps increase the profitability of industry
not surprising given the capital-intensive nature by lowering the cost of capital, while at the same
of the rapidly growing industries: steel and other time decreasing potential household income.
investment goods employ fewer workers than The declining share of interest income was ex-
light industries and especially the service sector.35 acerbated by the 1999 introduction of a 20%
The service sector share of GDP has fallen in the tax on interest income.39 Consequently, the real
past eight years after rising rapidly through the return on financial assets in China is only 0.5%,
first two decades of reform, while industry has compared to 1.8% in Korea and 3.1% in the
reached its largest share of GDP in Chinese his- US.40 Declining interest income appears to ex-
tory (48.6% in 2008). plain several percentage points of the relative de-
As employment has declined in relative cline in household disposable income. If interest
terms, wages have also decreased (again, in rela- income had grown in line with savings deposits
tive terms): in other words, low employment from 1998 onwards, it would have accounted for
growth has not been offset by higher wages for 4.8% of GDP by 2006 (instead of just 2.8%).41
those already employed. Surplus agricultural la-

25 Greater China
Financial Crisis

Determinants of high household savings under-sample richer households that have a high-
Not only are Chinese households receiving a er opportunity cost of being surveyed. In China,
smaller share of GDP as disposable income, but as the top quintile has increased saving rates the
as a result of a confluence of factors, including most and now accounts for over half of all sav-
demographic change, rapid income growth, con- ings, this under-sampling would drive down the
strained consumer credit markets, and the lack micro saving rates estimates.49 Moreover, gray
of a social safety net, households are also con- and black markets are large in China, and much
suming a smaller portion of this income. Chi- illegal expenditure and income may not be re-
nese high household savings are a key contribu- ported. Chart 13 below shows the discrepancy
tor to the extremely high national savings that in China between micro and macro estimations.
have arguably led to global imbalances.42, 43, 44, 45 Flow of funds data indicate that saving rates fluc-
While Chinese saving rates rose for much of the tuated around 30% until 2000, when they began
early part of the reform period, they were largely to rise steeply, while household survey estimates
steady over the course of the 1990s and actu- indicate a steadily rising urban savings rate and
ally reached their 1992-2007 low in 2001 (at a rural savings rate that has declined since 1998.
27.0%). High Chinese saving rates have long The aggregate household survey data suggests a
been a topic for analysis. One popular theory larger and more gradual increase in the house-
relates to cultural values. While it is impossi- hold savings rate. For the reasons noted above,
ble to conclusively discount the cultural values except where noted, the subsequent analysis fo-
hypothesis, little evidence exists. The Chinese cuses on the macro flow of funds data.
themselves had average household saving ratios
under 5% until the 1980s.46 High saving rates Precautionary savings
in Korea and Japan fell dramatically as the coun- Perhaps the most frequently cited argument
tries developed, and both share similar Confu- for Chinas high savings are that households
cian ethics. While cultural values may, all other undertake precautionary savings to offset the
things being equal, result in higher savings rates, disappearance of a government-provided social
development and policy changes seem to easily safety net; there is some validity to this argu-
overcome these cultural barriers. Other theories ment, but it cannot explain the entire increase
hold up much better, including the effects of in household savings. Market-driven structural
demographic change, precautionary saving due reforms have decreased government involvement
to an insufficient social safety net, and undevel- in the safety net, with potentially unintended
oped consumer credit markets. In reality, there is consequences. Pension reform in the mid-to-late
no single silver bullet that could lower Chinese 1990s increased personal saving for retirement,
saving; rather, many factors contribute, with while SOE restructuring stunted employment
the most important factor perhaps simply being growth and lowered health coverage. There is
time and further growth in per capita income. no doubt that the government share of pension
To discuss saving behavior it is necessary to and health coverage has declined.50 For instance,
calculate savings; unfortunately, this presents private household health spending rose from
more difficulties than one might hope. Macro 1.5% in 1990 to 7.0% in 2008.51 Feng, He, and
(flow of funds) and micro (household survey) Sato52 find that in China, pension reform in the
estimates do not always match. This is a prob- mid-to-late 1990s boosted the savings rate by
lem globally, although perhaps especially so in 6.3 percentage points for those aged 25-29 and
China.47 One problem is that individuals tend 2.8 percentage points for those aged 50-59. This
to systematically under-report income in survey- follows from their finding that pension wealth,
based methods.48 Additionally, non-response is a defined as the present value of expected future
large problem, and survey methods are likely to pension payouts, declined between 29% and

Summer 2010 26
David Janoff Bulman

54%, depending on age and gender, as the pen- exactly what shifted around 2000 to lead to a
sion system was restructured. In Taiwan, Chou, spike; saving rates have increased dramatically
Liu, and Hammitt53 find that the introduction in the past five years as the government has im-
of public coverage through National Health In- proved social welfare systems. Also, as Anderson
surance in the 1990s reduced household saving notes58, considering its low per capita income,
rates by 8.6-13.7 percentage points on average. China does very well in terms of pension cover-
Also lumped into precautionary savings age and publicly funded schools. There is clearly
could potentially be thrown saving for education something to these arguments. However, there
and housing. While not necessarily precaution- are many potential explanations. On the one
ary, housing and education services were previ- hand, saving for housing purchases is a new phe-
ously provided by the government the privati- nomenon. Additionally, saving is a luxury, and
zation of these important markets has likely had Chinas household income in the 1990s may not
as large an effect on rising saving rates as any oth- have been sufficient to allow optimal savings
er factor. Education and recreation spending as a levels for health, retirement, and education. This
percentage of total urban per capita household is supported by the data although the govern-
expenditure rose from 5.3% in 1990 to 12.3% ment safety net has again expanded in recent
in 2008.54 There are two student loan financing years, the share of private spending on health
schemes currently in place, but they are still only and education has continued to increase.
at a small scale.55 If, as McKinseys China Ur-
ban Consumer Savings Behavior Survey finds, Demographics
97% of urban parents expect their children to Demographic shifts also help to explain
go to college, this saving would vastly outpace Chinas high household saving. Globally, many
the future expenditure on education for those econometric models have relied on demograph-
students who actually do end up attending col- ics to explain saving rates, with perhaps the most
lege. According to McKinseys survey, education famous and widely used being the Modigliani59
was the top reason that people saved, with 60% life-cycle hypothesis (LCH). The LCH predicts
of households in the survey claiming to save for that saving rates increase with a rising proportion
education.56 Given that the average annual cost of the working-age population in combination
of university education is nearly 50% of aver- with long-term per capita growth trends. Given
age household disposable income, these savings a sharp decline in fertility, largely due to the one-
must be high. child policy, Chinas dependency ratio has de-
With regard to home purchases, housing clined dramatically over the past 30 years, from
market privatization in the late 1990s created an 70% of the working-age population in 1979 to
incentive to save for better housing. Increased less than 40% in 2008.60 Having fewer depen-
spending on housing is clearly evident. Accord- dents to support should decrease current expen-
ing to flow of funds data, household gross fixed diture and increase savings. Using data through
asset investment rose from 10% of income in 2000, Modigliani and Cao argue that this de-
the mid 1990s to over 16% by 2003 the vast mographic shift, along with high sustained per
majority of this fixed asset investment is likely capita income growth, explain the entire increase
for housing purchases. Chamon and Prasad57 in savings. The chart below shows the perfor-
calculate that housing-related motives could ac- mance of the LCH as it relates to China, using
count for three percentage points of the increase Modigliani and Cao data through 2000 and then
in household savings rates. bringing forward their methodology through
Precautionary savings likely explain much of 2008 using NBS data.61 Clearly, the LCH does
the increase in Chinas saving rates. A problem a good job at explaining the growth in savings
that many have noted is that they fail to explain rates through the beginning of the reform pe-

27 Greater China
Financial Crisis

riod; however, it fares less well in recent years.62 for the elderly, but it is also likely that demo-
Aside from shifts in age structure, other graphics are not the whole story behind rising
demographic arguments focus on rising sex im- saving rates.
balances and increasingly unequal income dis-
tribution. In China, the per capita income gap Financial repression
between rural and urban areas increased from Financial repression, particularly con-
2.8 to 3.3 times between 2000 and 2008, with strained consumer credit markets and the lack
inequality also increasing within rural and ur- of investment opportunities, also contribute to
ban areas. The propensity to consume for poorer high household saving. Low levels of household
households and households in rural areas is high- debt constrain consumer spending. Household
er than for richer households and households debt to disposable income in China is 30%,
in urban areas, as seen in chart 15 below. This while in Japan, Korea, and the US this level is
implies that redistributive policies could have a over 120%.65 As a share of GDP, consumer
large effect on national household saving rates. credit stands at only 13% in China, compared
At the extreme, assuming unchanged propensi- to 70% in Korea and 48% in Malaysia.66 Clearly,
ties to consume, a hypothetical reallocation of compared to its neighbors, Chinas low level of
CNY 100 from a top quintile rural household to household borrowing serves as a constraint on
a bottom quintile rural household would induce consumption. The problem with this explanation
additional consumption of CNY 39.3. In urban for high savings is that financial liberalization has
areas, the same top-to-bottom quintile realloca- increased in recent years as the saving rate has
tion of CNY 100 would result in additional con- climbed. Lending to households, particularly for
sumption of CNY 16.63 Wei and Zhang64 recent- mortgages, has grown dramatically. Credit cards
ly proposed a novel hypothesis: Chinas growing outstanding have grown from 3 million in 2003
sex imbalance has led families with sons to boost to 130 million by 2008.67 However, there is not a
their savings in order to make their sons more at- culture of debt. As of the end of Q3 2009, credit
tractive as grooms. They argue that this competi- card debt accounted for 4.4% of total consumer
tive saving behavior accounts for 50% of the in- debt and in 2008 credit cards accounted for 15%
crease in household saving rates. This analysis re- of retail sales, yet the amount of overdue debt is
lies on the high correlation between regions with still small (despite growing during the crisis, as
high sex imbalances and high saving rates, so an discussed above). This indicates that credit cards
alternative explanation for their results could be seem to be used more as a convenient method
that parents value education more for male chil- of payment or as a status symbol, rather than as
dren or that males are the buyers of houses and a means of increasing current income/consump-
thus have to save for these future purchases (in tion. Despite rapid increases in debt, most hous-
other words, an interaction between sex imbal- es are still paid for in cash and there are high
ances and precautionary saving behavior). restrictions on loan-to-value ratios and mortgage
Similar to the precautionary savings rebut- interest rates. Additionally, in a recent survey,
tals, it is not clear what trend changed with re- 58% of banks saw accessing/using credit bureaus
gard to demographics in the past eight years. and historical data as a major challenge, indicat-
Post-reform trends (increasing inequality, lower ing one reason for a continued unwillingness to
dependency ratio, sex imbalance, urbanization) issue cards.68 This lack of a debt culture is not set
continued, but seemingly without any structural in stone: in Korea, household debt exploded in
break or increased rate of change in recent years. the past decade, and savings rates declined dra-
It is of course possible that some inflection point matically.69
was reached in terms of coming-of-age of one- Interest rate caps and a dearth of other in-
child-policy children or higher life expectancy vestment opportunities may also contribute to

Summer 2010 28
David Janoff Bulman

higher savings rates. Many studies have found bors; doing so provides some optimism that Chi-
that in time-series data, saving rates are nega- nas high saving and low consumption may be
tively correlated with net financial worth.70 The temporary phenomena associated with a low per
wealth effect generated by sustained improve- capita income development path. Chinas savings
ments in alternative investment opportunities rates and disposable income share of GDP are
could lead to greater consumption in China. low in a global comparison. As seen in charts 16
China now has the second-largest stock market and 17 below, Chinas household savings rate is
in the world by market capitalization, having much higher and its household income/GDP
surpassed Japan in July 2009. Invested value in ratio much lower than in other nations; the
the free float on the stock market grew by over combination of the two leads to Chinas unprec-
CNY 8 trillion in 2006 and 2007, with much of edentedly low household consumption share of
this investment made by Chinese savers. Howev- the GDP.76
er, to date the stock market has perhaps been too Looking at the historical development of
volatile to contribute to increased perceptions of other countries sheds light on Chinas experi-
individual wealth sustained gains and confi- ence. It is common for the consumption share
dence could have large effects on consumption. of GDP to undergo a U-shaped trajectory dur-
While many economists argue that lower deposit ing the development process. In theory, at a low
rates should drive down savings/deposits, the level of income, household marginal propensity
reverse argument may be closer to the truth in to consume is high as families need to meet daily
China: if saving for a specific future outlay (e.g. expenditure levels; at a certain level of income
house, education), then lower interest rates that they are able to start saving to balance out cur-
stunt income growth require higher savings.71, 72 rent and future consumption; at an even higher
Raising (or eliminating) deposit interest rate caps level of income, they have saved sufficiently and
could therefore boost consumption. have great enough wealth through property and
Other factors also contribute to high sav- financial investment to refocus income on cur-
ings. In particular, supply side issues should not rent consumption. This has played out globally.
be ignored. There is a lack of retail infrastruc- In the United States, the consumption share of
ture in third-tier inland cities as well as rural GDP fell through the first half of the 20th cen-
areas.73 A 2007 study by the China Consumers tury and then began to rise in the 1950s. Sav-
Association found that 30-60% of rural house- ings rates in the teens then disappeared over the
holds were unsatisfied with infrastructure for course of the 1980s and 1990s. Japan provides a
consumption (availability of retail outlets, trans- more similar story to China. From 1955 to 1970,
portation, etc.).74 The service industry is also un- Japans investment share of GDP rose from 20%
derdeveloped and many services are unavailable. to 35% while household consumption decreased
According to estimates by Wang and Zhang,75 from 60% to 48%.77 The trend reversed in 1970,
services represent only 26% of total personal with the household consumption share of GDP
consumption, compared to 57% in Japan and again rising to 60%. Notably, Japans household
Korea and 56% in Taiwan. Some of these ser- saving rate peaked at 19% in 1976 before falling
vices may come with time, including legal and rapidly to less than 2% by 2006.78
financial services. Like Japan, the similarities with China are
striking in other East Asian nations that have
China in comparison also experienced investment-led growth accom-
Given the difficulties in pinpointing the ex- panied by a falling share of household consump-
act causes behind high saving rates, it is valuable tion in GDP during their early stages of develop-
to look at the development experience of other ment. These countries all eventually shifted their
nations, particularly Chinas East Asian neigh- growth patterns, providing more optimism for

29 Greater China
Financial Crisis

a shift than the above analysis of savings rates cies and imbalances in the economy. The need
would indicate. South Korea and Taiwan provide to rebalance has not been denied by the Chinese
particularly interesting and relevant examples, government. As early as December 2004, dur-
given cultural, geographic, and historical simi- ing the Central Economic Work Conference, the
larities, as well as the recent time frame in which government acknowledged that Chinas current
they reached a high state of development. Tai- growth model was not sustainable. The financial
wans household saving rate declined gradually crisis has added a sense of urgency to the need
over the past 20 years, from over 30% in 1992 to for rebalancing/restructuring. Prior to the crisis,
just over 20% in 2008.79 In South Korea, from China had already moved forward on several
1970 to 1988, the household consumption share fronts, including increased expenditure on the
of GDP fell from 75.0% to 50.7% between social safety net, eliminating the agriculture tax
1970 and 1988 it has since climbed back to on farm income, raising the cut-off for income
55%. The household savings rate increased dur- tax exemption, initiating dividend collection
ing the early stages of development, peaking at from large SOEs, and building a new socialist
25% in 1988, the same year that household con- countryside.84 More steps would be beneficial.
sumption reached its lowest share of GDP. The Macro and fiscal policies, in particular low-
household savings rate then rapidly fell, and by ering government explicit and implicit subsidies
2003 was just over 2%.80 for industry and expanding the social safety net,
Similar trends have been seen in other coun- should remain a high priority. This paper has
tries, as chart 18 below demonstrates. Apart from focused predominantly on household consump-
East Asian countries, the U-shaped household- tion. However, government consumption and
consumption-to-GDP development path has in particular government non-investment could
also been witnessed in South Africa and Mexico help China rebalance. The large volume of Chi-
(and likely many other countries as well). The nese government savings that is transferred to
chart shows the decline in the household con- lower-level governments and industry for invest-
sumption ratio for 25 years prior to reaching a ment comes at the expense of household con-
low and then beginning to rise (or at least flatten sumption. Increased government expenditure on
out).81 It is very interesting to note that in the pe- social welfare and redistributive measures would
riod in which household consumption again be- have multiple benefits by reducing government
gan to grow, per capita incomes in these countries investment/savings, effectively increasing house-
were very similar. Using constant international hold income, and lowering the need for pre-
(2005) dollars, per capita GDP at purchasing- cautionary savings. In a related vein, rural land
power parity (PPP) in the reversal years were: reform, oft-discussed, could have very beneficial
Japan (US$11,060), Korea (US$9,977), Malay- wealth effects in Chinas countryside. Service sec-
sia (US$9,651), Taiwan (US$9,400), South Af- tor development can take a long time, but would
rica (US$8,597), and Mexico (US$10,059).82 In have very beneficial effects on both household
2008, by this metric, China reached US$5,510. income, for reasons discussed above, as well as
This implies that China may still have some consumption, because it would provide better
growing left to do before reaching its own inflec- infrastructure for spending. Household registra-
tion point. tion (hku, ) reform could increase urban-
ization through the elimination of constraints
Conclusions83 on internal mobility while also increasing urban
While the global comparison hints that time migrant wages through enhanced workplace le-
alone might give Chinese consumers their day in gitimacy and bargaining power. Education re-
the sun, many policy measures could spur this form through better public funding for universi-
process while beneficially easing other inefficien- ties would diminish a major need for household

Summer 2010 30
David Janoff Bulman

savings. my will move back to an investment-led growth


Price and tax measures are also important. pattern. In the end, a reduction in investment
Progressive and redistributive policies can have will be a necessary component in any rebalanc-
a large effect by targeting money at those with ing. Many methods of decreasing investment
high propensities to consume. The government will naturally increase consumption, meaning
could again raise the cutoff for income taxes and that lower investment will not necessarily lead
could enlarge the share of pension and welfare to lower GDP growth than China has become
payments to the household sector. A higher min- used to.
imum wage could be set, and VAT policies could With its current combination of low income
be amended to stop subsidizing industry. and high growth, Chinas consumption growth
Financial reforms would also help. Consum- potential is huge. McKinsey argues that with the
ers should have more options for investment, right policies, the household consumption share
and a removal of interest rate caps would increase of GDP could rise from its current share of 36%
household interest income while also leading to to as high as 50% by 2025.86 That would bring
better pricing of the cost of capital, ostensibly China more in line with the consumption shares
lowering this implicit subsidy to investment. of its East Asian neighbors (although still below
More consumer loans, particularly for education, their current levels and far below Western or Or-
would help expand current consumption. Addi- ganisation for Economic Co-operation and De-
tionally, further liberalization would help ensure velopment levels). However, quick calculations
that capital flowed efficiently firms would have show that this shift will not be easy. To bring
more leeway to hire staff and increase employ- household consumption as a share of GDP above
ment.85 50% by 2025, assuming annual GDP growth of
This is a brief, and far from exhaustive, list of 8%, China would have to increase the house-
steps that China could take to increase the con- hold disposable income share of GDP by almost
sumption share of GDP. While many of these one percentage point annually and decrease the
policies have been rhetorically supported by the household saving rate by almost one percentage
government, actual reforms have been slower in point annually. This would require that income
coming about. The response to the crisis, as de- grow at 9-9.5% annually and consumption grow
scribed above, has been extremely proactive, but at 10-10.5% annually a formidable challenge,
measures do not appear sustainable; increasing to say the least. In other words, even assuming
consumer subsidies and providing tax breaks are significant rebalancing, it will take a long time
very useful at stimulating demand in the short for China to become a true consumption-driven
term, but as China removes these government economy.
measures in 2010, it seems likely that the econo-

31 Greater China
Financial Crisis

Summer 2010 32
David Janoff Bulman

33 Greater China
Financial Crisis

Summer 2010 34
David Janoff Bulman

Endnotes
1 Unless otherwise noted, data on the Chinese economy is from Chinas National Statistical Yearbook, compiled by the National Bureau of Statistics (NBS):
National Bureau of Statistics of China, China Statistical Yearbook, various years (1992-2009) (Beijing: China Statistics Press).
2 Consequently, there has been an increase in the overall government share of consumption, from a post-reform low of 20% in 1988 to over 27% in 2008.
3 To put this growth differential in perspective: if household consumption as a share of GDP had stayed constant over the last two decades (instead of falling
by 15.8 percentage points), personal consumption would have been 45% greater than it was at the end of 2008, assuming that GDP growth followed its
actual trajectory. (If, instead, the additional consumption added to GDP while government consumption, investment, and net exports stayed the same,
yielding the same proportion would have resulted in 92% greater household consumption and the GDP being CNY 10 trillion higher than it is today.)
4 NBS.
5 The retail price index is produced monthly by the NBS and differs from the more commonly used Consumer Price Index CPI, although the numbers tend
to be similar.
6 Albert Keidel, Chinas GDP Expenditure Accounts, China Economic Review, 12 (2001), pp. 355-367.
7 Andy Rothman, Chinese Consumption: True or False, CLSA: Asia-Pacific Markets, Sinology, China Macro Strategy.
8 NBS, 2009.
9 Rothman.
10 Jonathan Garner, The Rise of the Chinese Consumer: Theory and Evidence (Hoboken, NJ: Wiley, c. 2005). Similar to the situation in 2009, one-third of this

35 Greater China
Financial Crisis

contribution was from government consumption.


11 Wen Jiabao, Speech at 2009 Summer Davos in Dalian, September 11, 2009. <http://www.fmprc.gov.cn/eng/zxxx/t583527.htm>.
12 Mingchun Sun, Consumption Outlook | China, Nomura International (HK) Limited, May 20, 2009.
13 Ligang Liu, Impact of the Global Financial Crisis on China: Empirical Evidence and Policy Implications, China & World Economy, vol. 17, no. 6 (2009),
pp. 1-23.
14 These data are compiled from government speeches: Sun, Consumption Outlook | China and Liu. The values represent government intentions it is unclear
how much of the proposed expenditure has actually taken place.
15 NBS, 2009.
16 Sun, Consumption Outlook | China.
17 Liu.
18 Wen.
19 Qing Wang and Steven Zhang Chinas Under-Consumption Over-Stated, Morgan Stanley Global Economic Forum, September 15, 2009.
20 Mingchun Sun, China: Unscathed through the Global Financial Tsunami, China & World Economy, vol. 17, no. 6 (2009).
21 Anthony Chan, Asian Weekly Economic Insights, Alliance Bernstein Global Economic Research, March 6, 2009.
22 Wang and Zhang.
23 Sun, China: Unscathed through the Global Financial Tsunami, pp. 24-42.
24 Peoples Daily, China creates 7.57 mln new jobs in first eight months, October 30, 2009. <http://english.people.com.cn/90001/90776/90884/6799501.html>.
25 Peoples Bank of China, Quarterly Statistical Bulletin (Beijing). The loan data is from the Peoples Bank of China (PBOC) website. Consumer loans are
defined as consumption loans under the loans to residents category.
26 Net new lending is defined as the monthly difference in the value of outstanding loans.
27 Xinhua News Agency, Chinas credit card debt continues to expand: central bank, November 30, 2009, <http://news.xinhuanet.com/english/2009-11/30/
content_12565483.htm>.
28 Credit card debt 6 months overdue rose 126.5% YOY in the first three quarters to CNY 7.4 billion, accounting for 3.4% of total outstanding credit card
debt. This prompted the PBOC to set quotas for credit card sales and prohibit card issuance to people younger than 18. However, the overdue rate is still
low compared to the United States, and with a small volume of total outstanding credit card debt, poses no apparent systemic problem for the banking
system (Xinhua News Agency, 2009).
29 Household savings rates are calculated from the NBS flow of funds, which is only available from 1992-2007. The differences between this data and
calculations based on household survey data are discussed below.
30 This is calculated from NBS industry statistics. These statistics include only those firms above a designated size. While this means that a number of
smaller firms are not included in the sample, the sample is still large and fairly representative, covering over 400,000 enterprises and representing 88 million
employees in 2008.
31 Jianwu He and Louis Kuijs, Rebalancing Chinas Economy Modeling a Policy Package, World Bank Research Paper no. 7, September 2007.
32 He and Kuijs.
33 Nicholas Lardy, Chinas Consumption Driven Growth Path, Conference on Chinas Agricultural Trade: Issues and Prospects, July 2007. According to Lardy,
government capital transfers accounted for 8% of all fixed investment in 2003.
34 He and Kuijs.
35 Lardy.
36 Jahangir Aziz and Li Cui, Explaining Chinas Low Consumption: The Neglected Role of Household Income, IMF Working Paper WP/07/181, July 2007. Aziz
and Cui find that the wage share fell from 67% of GNP in the mid 1980s to a 2005 level of 56%. It is not clear where they got their data from.
37 This was calculated based on flow of funds data, so information is not available yet for 2008.
38 Aziz and Cui.
39 Lardy.
40 Jonathan Woetzel, Janamitra Devan, Richard Dobbs, Adam Eichner, Stefano Negri, and Micah Rowland, If Youve Got It, Spend It: Unleashing the Chinese
Consumer, McKinsey Global Institute, August 2009.
41 Interest income data is unavailable for 2008. 2006 is used because of the one-time decline in household saving in 2007, likely due to explosive stock
market investment. (Having grown by CNY 2.1 trillion in 2006, savings deposits grew by only CNY 1.1 trillion in 2007. As the market crashed in 2008,
individuals shifted rapidly out of the stock market and back into savings deposits, which grew by CNY 4.5 trillion.)
42 Xinhua He and Yongfu Cao, Understanding High Saving Rate in China, China & World Economy, vol. 15, no. 1 (2007), pp. 1-13.
43 Tamim Bayoumi, Hui Tong, and Shang-Jin Wei, The Chinese Corporate Savings Puzzle: A Firm-level Cross-country Perspective, NBER Working Papers 16432,
National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
44 IMF, Awash with Cash: Why are Corporate Savings So High?, World Economic Outlook, April 2006, ch. IV, pp. 135-159.
45 Chinas Corporate Savings is Not a Key Driver for Its Current Account Surplus: A Cross-country Firm-level Comparative Perspective, IMF Working Paper,
Preliminary Draft, October 2009. Many recent articles have asserted that high Chinese household saving is not as much of a problem as high corporate
saving. In 2008, 19 percentage points of Chinas national saving rate of 55% of GDP were contributed by households while 25 percentage points were
contributed by the corporate sector. The remaining 11 percentage points were contributed by the government. Household saving previously represented a
much higher portion of savings. As He and Cao note, the share of household saving in national saving was as high as 52.3% in 1992 (it was 35% in 2008).
The government and corporate shares have both grown to offset this decline. However, Chinas corporate saving patterns are more in line with global trends
than its household savings patterns. Corporations throughout the world have witnessed higher undistributed profits over the past two decades. In the US,
according to Department of Commerce Bureau of Economic Analysis data, gross government saving has been negative since 2001 and household saving
has been close to zero gross corporate savings, on the other hand, have consistently stayed above 10% of GDP for over three decades and contributed over
100% of gross national savings from 2005-2008. As Bayoumi, Tong, and Wei show, from 2001 to 2005, Chinas corporate savings over GDP increased 2.7
percentage points, lower than in Japan (4 percentage points), Korea (3 percentage points) and the UK (3.6 percentage points). In general, the world has
seen a rapid increase in corporate savings in the past decade. As the International Monetary Fund (IMF) writes: In stark contrast to the secular decline
in household saving, corporate saving in the G-7 countries has increased strongly over the last decade, and now accounts for about 70% of total private
(household plus corporate) saving, compared to 50% in the early 1990s. Consequently, many countries have gross corporate saving rates that do not
differ dramatically from China (Bayoumi, Tong, and Wei). Therefore, even though corporate savings in China have grown as a share of overall savings, the
anomaly remains the high share of household (and government) savings.
46 Modigliani and Cao.
47 Chamon and Prasad.
48 United Nations, System of National Accounts 2008.
49 Chamon and Prasad.
50 This is the case if one assumes that health and pension coverage through SOEs is a form of government, rather than private, coverage. The privatization of

Summer 2010 36
David Janoff Bulman

SOEs in the 1990s eliminated pension and health coverage for tens of millions of Chinese employees.
51 NBS, 2009.
52 Jin Feng, Lixin He, and Hiroshi Sato, Public Pension and Household Saving: Evidence from China, BOFIT Discussion Papers, 2/2009.
53 Shin-Yi Chou, Jin-Tan Liu, and James Hammitt, National Health Insurance and Precautionary Saving: Evidence from Taiwan, Journal of Public Economics,
87 (2003), pp. 1873-1894.
54 NBS, 2009.
55 Woetzel et al.
56 The survey only represents urban areas, and the sample size was only 783 people.
57 Marcos Chamon and Eswar S. Prasad, Why are Saving Rates of Urban Households in China Rising?, IZA Discussion Paper no. 3191.
58 Jonathan Anderson, The Myth of Chinese Savings, Far Eastern Economic Review, November 2009.
59 Franco Modigliani and Shi Larry Cao, The Chinese Saving Puzzle and the Life-Cycle Hypothesis, Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 42, no. 1 (Mar. 2004),
pp. 145-170.
60 World Bank, World Development Statistics. This data is taken from the World Banks World Development Indicators database.
61 It should be noted that the actual savings rate used by Modigliani and Cao (and carried forward through the 2008 data to maintain continuity) is based on
a proxy calculation for aggregate household savings that uses savings deposits, government bonds, and fixed asset investment growth. This proxy matches the
flow of funds data well through the 1990s, but begins to fall apart over the past 10 years.
62 Charles Yuji Horioka and Junmin Wan, The Determinants of Household Saving in China: A Dynamic Panel Analysis of Provincial Data, Federal Reserve Bank
of San Francisco Working Paper Series, January 2007. The LCH is not without its detractors. Horioka and Wan utilize provincial variation and find that the
lagged saving rate, income growth, and the real interest rate have determined Chinas saving rate and that age structure and dependency ratios have had no
significant effect. By this logic, inertia is the most important factor in Chinas high saving rate, implying that these high rates could persist for a long time
(unless growth slows markedly, in which case the savings rate will rise). Perhaps more condemningly, Chamon and Prasad find a U-shaped pattern of savings
over the life-cycle, with young and old households saving most, while the LCH predicts higher saving for middle-aged people.
63 This calculation was inspired by a similar exercise conducted by Chi Hung Kwan at the Research Institute for Economy, Trade and Industry on his China in
Transition blog: <http://www.rieti.go.jp/en/china/09062901.html>.
64 Shang-Jin Wei and Xiaobo Zhang, The Competitive Saving Motive: Evidence from Rising Sex Ratios and Savings Rates in China, NBER Working Paper Series,
15093, June 2009.
65 Sun, China: Unscathed through the Global Financial Tsunami.
66 Woetzel et al.
67 Woetzel et al.
68 Xinhua News Agency, 2009.
69 Kyuil Chung, Household debt, the savings rate and monetary policy: the Korean experience (2009), BIS Papers chapters, in: Bank for International Settlements
(ed.), Household debt: implications for monetary policy and financial stability, vol. 46, pp. 83-94.
70 Alain de Serres and Florian Pelgrin, The Decline in Private Saving Rates in the 1990s in OECD Countries: How Much Can Be Explained by Non-Wealth
Determinants, OECD Economic Studies, no. 36, 2003/1.
71 In this framework, inflation could also counter-intuitively boost savings rather than current consumption, as in a low-debt society inflation reduces
household wealth. Indeed, in the life-cycle regression framework for China discussed above, the coefficient on inflation is positive, implying greater savings
when inflation is high.
72 The empirical evidence on the relationship between deposit rates and saving is inconclusive. Evidence in favor of the latter hypothesis would be those
analyses that find a negative coefficient on deposit rates. Norman Loayza, Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel, and Luis Servn, in their 2000 survey of saving in
developing countries (What Drives Private Saving Across the World?, The Review of Economics and Statistics, MIT Press, vol. 82(2), pp. 165-181), find an
ambiguous relationship between interest rates and saving one study in their sample found a positive relationship, one found a negative relationship, and
four found no significant relationship.
73 Woetzel et al.
74 Sun, Consumption Outlook | China.
75 Wang and Zhang.
76 Economist Intelligence Unit, Country Database. The Economist Intelligence Unit data for the real disposable income share of GDP seems to underestimate
this parameter by 10-15%. However, given the consistently low estimates, it is probably safe to assume that a similar calculation is being used across
countries. As the chart only intends to provide a comparison, the data therefore remains useful.
77 Liu.
78 David Campbell and Wako Watanabe, Will the Future Japanese and US Personal Saving Rates be Relatively Equivalent?, September 2009, <http://w4.stern.
nyu.edu/emplibrary/NYU,_Working_Paper_N-009.pdf>.
79 Taiwan National Statistics, 2009.
80 Bank of Korea ECOS, 2009.
81 The data, drawn from the World Banks World Development Indicators, only goes back to 1960 for countries whose relevant development periods extend
before 1960, data is therefore missing.
82 These GDP per capita values are all constant 2005 international dollars. With the exception of Taiwan, the data were taken from the World Banks World
Development Indicators database. Taiwans data was taken from the IMF World Economic Outlook the value is equal to the current price GDP (PPP) per
capita (US$7,159.38) multiplied by the inverse of the GDP deflator index (76.125).
83 Other resources used for this research: Vincent Chan, Embracing Chinas Consumption Boom, Credit Suisse (Hong Kong) Limited, March 2008. Economist
Magazine, The Hamster-Wheel: The More China Spends, the More it Saves, A Special Report on the World Economy, October 3, 2009, pp. 9-10.
84 The new socialist countryside policy was initiated in 2006 as a means to boost farmer incomes and rural economic development through a program of
rural investment, agricultural subsidies, and improved basic social services.
85 For instance, Aziz and Cui find, using World Bank Enterprise Survey data, that firms in China that list access to finance as a major constraint also have lower
employment growth, implying that greater credit access could have positive effects on employment.
86 Woetzel et al.

37 Greater China
Financial Crisis

David Janoff Bulman


David Janoff Bulman is a second-year MA candidate in International Economics with concentrations in China
Studies and Quantitative Economic Methods and Theory at the Johns Hopkins School of Advanced International
Studies. He received his BA in Economics from Columbia University. His current research is focused on the
Chinese economy and China-US economic relations, with a special interest in Chinese macroeconomic develop-
ments related to domestic rebalancing, as well as international prospects for the renminbi. He has worked previ-
ously as a consultant in China for two years.

Summer 2010 38

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi