Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 7

Energy Policy 47 (2012) 8793

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Energy Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol

Financing off-grid sustainable energy access for the poor


Yannick Glemarec 
United Nations Development Programme, New York, United States

a r t i c l e i n f o abstract

Article history: This paper examines the role of public instruments in promoting private nance to achieve off-grid
Received 22 December 2011 sustainable energy access. Renewable energy technologies are increasingly becoming the cheapest
Accepted 14 March 2012 solutions for off-grid energy access. The dramatic uptake of mobile phones in developing countries
Available online 30 March 2012
shows how quickly decentralized services can develop on a commercial basis under the right
Keywords: conditions, and raises the prospect that private nance could also drive decentralized energy access
Energy policy for the poor. Indeed, there are already a number of instances of clean energy solutions such as solar
Market barriers portable lights, household biogas units or solar home systems that have managed to scale-up through
Finance leveraging private nance. However, the experience gained from rst-generation market development
projects show that, in almost all cases, signicant public resources have been necessary to increase the
affordability of clean energy technologies, provide access to nancing for the poor, and remove non-
economic barriers. Such public interventions may be funded by international public nance, domestic
budgets and carbon nance. Despite mounting scal constraints facing governments worldwide, the
emergence of new sources of climate nance and the political momentum in support of energy subsidy
reforms, as well as new programming modalities, offer opportunities to leverage additional resources to
achieve universal energy access by 2030.
& 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction Deichmann et al., 2010). The rapid uptake of mobile phones


shows how quickly decentralized services can develop on a
As a consequence of the global economic and nancial crises, commercial basis in developing countries under the right condi-
the outlook for additional ofcial development assistance (ODA) tions. It is clear that in a time of overall challenges for traditional
is rather dim in the coming years. At the same time, a recent development assistance, the private sectors role in achieving
study (Hudson Institute, 2011) estimates that private ows of sustainable energy access is emerging as a critical question for
capital from OECD countries to developing countries amounted to public policy makers and development practitioners. This paper
USD 455 billion in 2009.1 attempts to respond to this question by examining the results
This is more than a fourfold increase since 2002. As a of the rst generation of publicly funded market-driven pro-
comparison, ODA in 2009 was estimated at USD 120 billion. In grammes for clean energy access which have been implemented
this context, many development organizations, both bilateral and worldwide. It draws on reports and interviews of project man-
multilateral, are increasingly prioritizing their efforts to engage agers from multilateral agencies who have been supporting this
the private sector in order to look at new and innovative forms of rst generation of market-driven projects as well as the online
investments, nance and partnerships to catalyze and drive library of mitigation evaluations of the Climate Change evaluators
development.2 Community of Practice hosted by the Evaluation Ofce of the
Off-grid renewable energy technologies both at the indivi- Global Environment Facility.3 This analysis is augmented by a
dual systems level, such as solar home systems, and at the review of the peer-reviewed literature.
mini-grid level servicing 50100 households are increasingly Section 2 of this paper summarizes the recent history of
becoming the cheapest solutions for sustainable energy access in decentralized telecommunication services in developing coun-
a range of locations (REN21, 2011; UNEP, 2012; Szabo et al., 2011; tries and discusses possible lessons for off-grid renewable energy
technologies. Section 3 analyzes the key barriers to a rapid
commercialization of off-grid renewable energy technologies
 Tel.: 1 212 906 5143; fax: 1 212 906 6998. and suitable public market creation initiatives. Section 4 reviews
E-mail address: Yannick.glemarec@undp.org
1
$228 billion were private investments, $174 billion remittances and $53
3
billion were philanthropic ows. The climate change Evaluators Community of Practice has collected a library
2
See 2010 Donor Statement as an example of this increased emphasis: http:// of almost 500 evaluations on project, programme and policy and portfolio level,
www.enterprise-development.org/download.aspx?id=1645 including for decentralized renewable energy access.

0301-4215/$ - see front matter & 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2012.03.032
88 Y. Glemarec / Energy Policy 47 (2012) 8793

the options for funding of public instruments to support market Economist, 2009). They are strong anecdotal evidences that access
creation for universal energy access. to telecommunication services in developing countries can unlock
entrepreneurship, promote economic development, lead to
greater political empowerment, and provide tax revenues for
2. The growth of the mobile industry and its relevance for governments (Roller and Waverman, 2001; The Economist, 2009).
clean energy access The growth of the mobile phone industry offers several lessons
for the rapid commercialization of new technologies. With the
The International Energy Agency (IEA) estimates that in 2009 right regulatory environment and business models, the poor have
USD 9.1 billion was invested globally in extending access to the capacity and the willingness to fully or partially pay for
modern energy services4 and that annual investment must services that provide clear, immediate and substantial benets.
increase ve-fold to USD 48 billion a year to provide universal Similarly, the private sector has the capacity and appetite to
modern energy access by 2030 (IEA, 2011). Although the sum invest in new service delivery mechanisms provided that there is
estimated by IEA to achieve universal energy access is only commercially viable unmet demand.
equivalent to about 3% of global energy expenditure, the difculty Decentralized clean energy markets display some character-
of mobilizing such an amount from public resources should not istics similar to mobile telephony markets. Low-income house-
be under-estimated. Energy access programmes will need to holds and micro-enterprises can gain several direct economic
compete with other priority programmes for scarce domestic benets by adopting clean energy systems, including: (i) reduced
and international public resources. Development practitioners energy expenses; (ii) reductions in household expenses, particu-
will need to build a business case for public resource allocation larly for health care (reduced respiratory problems, etc.); (iii)
for universal energy access and use these scare resources in a increased net incomes; and (iv) savings in time and effort (UNDP,
catalytic manner to leverage complementary private nance. 2012; Sovacool et al., 2011; Clemens et al., 2010). Maybe not
The rapid diffusion of technologies such as mobile phones to surprisingly in views of these benets, some clean energy markets
low-income consumers demonstrates the potential of innovative in developing countries are experiencing double-digit growth
commercial models to provide universal access for basic services. rates. Solar home systems (SHS) in Africa have grown by 13% a
From 1960 to 2000, telephone landlines grew so slowly in sub- year over the past decade and conservative assumptions suggest
Saharan Africa that coverage was limited to 1.4 lines per 100 that the African market for off-grid renewable lighting could
inhabitants in 2000 (Deichmann et al., 2010). In the past, industry experience 4050% annual sales growth during the next decade
watchers believed there was little opportunity for mobile tech- (IFC, 2010).
nology to remedy this situation in markets where the majority of Despite these instances of impressive growth, the number of
people live at or below subsistence-level income. The upfront cost people without access to electricity in sub-Saharan Africa is
of a handset was thought to be an insurmountable barrier for the expected to increase by 10%, from 585 million in 2009 to 645
billions of individuals living on just a few dollars per day. Yet, million in 2030 under a business-as-usual scenario, as the rate of
emerging markets have become the primary growth opportunity connections will not be able to keep pace with population growth.
for the telecommunications industry and, with the right business Globally, over 1 billion people will remain without access to
models, mobile phones are today accessible to some of the electricity by 2030.
worlds poorest. While establishing new markets in mobile communications
As of October 2011 (ITU, 2011), there were 5.9 billion mobile and clean energy technologies share some characteristics, they
subscribers worldwide. The majority of these subscribers were have also some fundamental differences. Mobile telephony has
located in developing countries, where the subscriber penetration relatively low physical infrastructure requirements, and can reach
was estimated at 79% of the total population. Given that entire remote areas in a more cost-effective fashion than decentralized
villages in poor and/or rural communities will often share one or clean energy technologies. Mobile phones simplicity of use has
two cell phones, it is also estimated that 8090% of people in also been a major factor in its adoption all over the world (UNDP,
some poor countries have at least minimal access to a cell phone 2012). In contrast, clean energy development and access face a
(Zuckerman, 2009). Furthermore, close to 80 million mobile large number of inter-connected information, institutional, beha-
subscribers, most of them in developing countries, have no access vioral, technical and nancial barriers.
to the electrical gridand yet use a mobile phone (UNDP, 2012). Based on a meta-evaluation of independent evaluations of
The dramatic uptake of mobile phones in developing countries World Bank, UNDP and UNEP market creation/transformation
can be credited to the emergence of two main technology projects for clean energy development co-nanced by the Global
standards and to several innovative business models. Pre-paid Environment Facility (GEF), Woerlen (2011) found that sustain-
platforms were developed, allowing customers to purchase air- able market development involves four main groups of stake-
time at a price as low as USD 0.25 per minute, share airtime and holders: users of the technology, the supply chain (e.g. local
even buy airtime on credit. Handset prices were slashed, with the manufacturers, assemblers, shops and maintenance technicians),
introduction of ultra low-cost handsets, bringing prices to as low policy makers and nanciers. Each of these groups typically
as USD 15 per unit in line with the capacity for upfront payment encounters a number of barriers that prevent them from using
of poor households (Proparco, 2009). Another vital factor has been or supporting the sustainable energy technology. Woerlen (2011)
the liberalization of telecoms markets and the issuing of licenses also identied 20 key investment barriers across the four types of
to rival operators. Mobile telephony is intrinsically more amen- stakeholders (Table 1).
able to competition than xed-line, and the uptake of mobile This means that none of these stakeholders alone can trans-
telephony was particularly striking in competitive markets while form a market. The support of a single one of the stakeholder
it stagnated in the few remaining countries where mobile tele- groups is a necessary but not sufcient condition for scaling up a
communication remains a government-run monopoly (The given technology. Financial de-risking instruments (partial loan
guarantees, political risk insurance, etc.) aimed at encouraging
4
private investment will have little impact in the absence of strong
For its analysis, IEA denes modern energy access as a household having
reliable and affordable access to clean cooking facilities, a rst connection to
consumer demand, local technical capacity and supportive reg-
electricity and then an increasing level of electricity consumption over time to ulatory instruments. The severity of these different barriers will
reach the regional average. vary with location, technologies and consumer groups, and a
Y. Glemarec / Energy Policy 47 (2012) 8793 89

Table 1 is expected to continue rising in the coming decade. Oil price


Key barriers to market creation for sustainable energy development. volatility is also expected to increase. Poor households commonly
Source: Adapted from Woerlen (2011).
devote around 60% of their income to food (McKinsey & Company,
Barriers Consumers/ Policy Local Supply chain and 2011). A doubling of the oil price could therefore wipe out the
users makers nanciers infrastructure remaining income available to be spent on other goods and
services.
Lack of X X X In contrast, the cost of clean energy technologies is rapidly
affordability
Lack of access X X
falling and they are increasingly becoming the cheapest and most
Lack of expertise X X X X sustainable solutions in levelized terms for energy access to the
Lack of X X poor in numerous off-grid situations. Rapid technological innova-
motivation tion in basic solar technologies and a scale-up of commercializa-
Awareness X X X X
tion efforts by entrepreneurs is driving a substantial decrease in
Lack of business X X
model the manufactured price of clean energy technologies and will
Lack of cost X X X further increase their competitiveness against fossil-fuel based
effectiveness sources of electricity in the coming years. Large-scale (on-grid)
solar power capacity could become available at around USD 1 per
watt by 2020, down from more than USD 8 per watt in 2007 and
unique mix of information, regulatory and economic policies will USD 4 watt in 2010 (McKinsey & Company, 2011).
be required to remove them in each situation (Glemarec, 2011). However, as low-income consumers do not have the luxury to
Most studies looking at off-grid renewable energy barriers tend to reason in terms of levelized cost of energy; upfront costs are likely
emphasize economic and technical barriers but ignore or down- to remain the major bottleneck to achieve universal clean energy
play end-user values and behaviour (Sovacool et al., 2011). access. Governments can take four decisive actions to lower
Thus, a key challenge for policy makers aiming to leverage upfront costs: (i) reduce balance of system (BOS) costs; (ii)
private nance to catalyze and drive off-grid clean energy access eliminate taxes and tariffs on clean energy devices; (iii) reduce
is to identify the public policy levers required to remove the subsidies on fossil fuels and subsidize part of the upfront and
specic investment barriers for a given technology in each operation costs; and (iv) promote entrepreneurship and income-
location. generating activities by the new end-users of these energy
services.
On average, component costs amount to roughly 50% of the
3. Policy levers for off-grid sustainable energy market cost of the nal clean energy device, with the balance of system
development (BOS) accounting for the remaining 50%.7 Opportunities for near-
term reductions of more than 50% in BOS by simply scaling up
Public policies to spur new business models and accelerate the and implementing best practices have been reported in some
commercialization of clean energy technologies will need to markets (Bony et al., 2010). Many of these soft cost reductions in
address these barriers in an integrated manner. Based on the BOS can be implemented via smart policies that encourage
experience of the rst generation of market-driven programmes standardization of equipment and eliminate inefciencies in
(UNDP, 2011, 2012), work will be needed on at least three fronts5: business practices, as well as development of local supply of
technical and managerial expertise.
 increasing affordability of clean energy access technologies for Initiatives to reduce taxes and tariffs on solar goods can also be
the poor; part of the solution set. A straightforward policy option is to lower
 increasing access to nancing for the poor; and or abolish taxes and duties on a clearly-dened subset of clean
 removing non-economic barriers. energy products. These tax breaks on energy systems could be
coupled with favorable tax policies on equipment targeted to
specic commercial use of energy. For example, it could entail
reducing tariffs on welding machines for a small microenterprise
3.1. Increasing affordability of clean energy access technologies using electricity for welding. The negative impact on the govern-
ment budget can be offset by commensurably reducing subsidies/
The failure of governments to achieve signicant electrica- increasing taxes and levies on fossil-fuel generators. This policy
tion in many countries has seen the growth of decentralized offers the added advantage of further eroding the upfront cost
energy solutions based mostly on fossil fuel such as diesel-fuelled advantage that kerosene has on clean energy generators today.
micro-grids and liqueed petroleum gas. It is estimated that poor We will come back to the issue of fossil fuel subsidies in the last
households in Africa face recurring expenditures on fuels ranging section of this article.
between 10% and 25% of their monthly household budgets.6 The Beyond reductions in assembly costs and policies on taxes and
price of kerosene has tripled in Africa during the last decade and tariffs, there can be a strong case for temporary subsidies to meet
part of the initial costs of achieving energy access. Output-based
5
For the sake of brevity, this generic description of public policies to remove subsidy programmes aimed at partially covering the purchasing
market barriers refers to both individual/household-based systems and mini-grids costs of clean energy systems have proven highly effective in
(servicing 50100 households). However, substantial differences exist between scaling up competitive clean energy solutions. Under the Biogas
these two types of off-grid system. Mini-grids are often more cost effective on a
Support Programme in Nepal, for example, a subsidy of about 30%
US$/kWh basis than individual systems. They also present slightly different risk
proles and face a broader range of non-investment barriers than stand-alone was available for covering 30% of plant costs, while 20% could be
systems, such as the need for collective management, billing and payment contributed by the user in-kind (e.g. labour or locally available
arrangements, etc.
6
80% of the population lives on $2.5/day or less in sub-Saharan Africa. The
7
typical household consumption is 13 kWh/day for users already connected In the case of a Solar Home System (SHS), the BOS represents everything
(Szabo et al., 2011), with average fossil fuel-based electricity prices of 18 US cent except the module itself: mounting and racking components; inverters; wiring;
per kWh (Liebreich, 2011). However, in some cases the inhabitants of rural areas installation labor; nancing and contractual costs; and in some mature markets,
already pay a much higher amount for diesel electricity (Szabo et al., 2011). permitting and interconnection.
90 Y. Glemarec / Energy Policy 47 (2012) 8793

construction materials). The remaining 50% was supplied through longer maturities might be required. Another key reason why
cash contributions from users (UNDP, 2011). MFIs have yet to embrace this new business opportunity is that
Last, but arguably most importantly, the promotion of com- they are poorly equipped to appraise clean energy loans for the
mercial use of energy can enormously enhance rural development poor. The rst set of experiences with clean energy loans has
benets and increase the long-term affordability of energy ser- shown higher default rates than with traditional micronance
vices by new end-users. A recent UNDP/AEPC evaluation (Legros (UNCDF/UNDP, 2011). Much of this arose from technology failure
et al., 2011) of the impacts of mini-hydropower systems installed (the cheapest RE products on the markets were often cheaply
by Nepals Rural Energy Development Programme found that the made) and the understandable reluctance of clients to pay for
direct benets attributable to electricity access amount to about faulty systems or their incapacity to reimburse loans in the
USD 150 per year per household. The study estimates that absence of the expected energy savings/increase income.
initiating a productive activity using newly available electricity
can produce an additional USD 912 for a household. Similar 3.3. Removing non-economic barriers
impacts of promotion of productive uses of energy have been
reported in other locations (Yadoo and Cruickshank, 2012). While the price and payment terms are important factors,
A clear conclusion is that skills enhancement to support the experience shows that even well designed nancing schemes will
development of income-generating activities should be a key not be enough to promote widespread adoption of clean energy
component of off-grid renewable energy programmes to increase systems. A number of complementary informational, institu-
their affordability and adoption rate, and their impact on tional, regulatory, and behavioral instruments will be required
economic growth (UNDP, 2012; Gurung et al., 2011; Yadoo and to remove non-economic hurdles. Four instruments seem applic-
Cruickshank, 2012). able in most situations: (i) clear policy statements and targets; (ii)
consumer education and community participation; (iii) standar-
3.2. Increasing access to nancing for the poor dization of equipment; and (iv) research and development.
A UNDP review of 17 initiatives on energy access for the poor
While the options described above can reduce the life-cycle in the Asia-Pacic region concluded that those that were able to
costs of decentralized energy systems, upfront cost will continue achieve a signicant expansion benetted from a strong commit-
to be an issue for the poorest energy consumers. About 2.7 billion ment from their national governmentsa commitment reected
people lack access to basic nancial services (United Nations in policy documents and supported by budgetary allocations
Secretary Generals Special Advocate for Inclusive Finance for (UNDP, 2011). Conversely, an uncertain policy environment can
Development, 2011). A similar number rely on solid fuels to meet present a bottleneck to expansion. In Sri Lanka, a project to
their basic needs (IEA, UNDP and UNIDO, 2010). This is not a commercialize solar home systems (SHS) faces challenges as a
coincidence. Given their high upfront cost, clean energy technol- result of the governments stated policy to extend the national
ogies can be an expensive proposition for most poor households grid to at least 95% of the population by 2015 (UNDP, 2011).
in the world. For example, a household biogas digester (approxi- Although the policy itself is laudable, many un-electried villages
mately USD 300700) can account for more than a full-year of are now uninterested in implementing off-grid schemes and
income for the poor. investing in SHSs because of the expectation of grid electrication
Even with a capital subsidy of 30%, the upfront costs of a in the near future. The risk of arrival of grid electricity within the
residential biogas digester can still exceed by an order of repayment period can also prove a major deterrent for both
magnitude the upfront payment capacity of poor households. nanciers and technology providers to enter the market.
Access to nancing adapted to the cash ow proles of poor Uncertainty about whether nancial support from government
households will therefore be a key enabler for scaling up clean for specic clean energy opportunities will continue can also
energy markets. Five principal market driven models exist to result in investors being reluctant to invest or demanding higher
provide upfront costs: (i) dealer/supplier credit-based sales; (ii) returns to compensate for this risk. A recent survey of investors
consumer credit through commercial banks; (iii) consumer credit (UNEP, 2012) found that the most powerful incentive mechanism
through micronance institutions (MFIs); (iv) fee-for-service for renewable energy deployment in developing countries was
models where the equipment remains the property of the service the establishment of clear national targets for renewable energy.
provider; and (v) public sector-operated revolving fund credit Given the crucial importance of promoting productive uses of
schemes. energy by new end-users, these national energy access strategies
The choice of the most suitable model to provide upfront and targets should be embedded into national development
nance will depend on the maturity of the banking sector and the strategies. In addition, experience shows that establishing institu-
socio-economic conditions of the targeted beneciaries. In loca- tions dedicated to energy services for the poor can facilitate the
tions where the private sector is non-existent, government-led implementation of these strategies and targets (UNDP, 2011). For
models such as public sector-operated revolving fund credit example, the Alternative Energy Centre in Nepal, the Renewable
schemes might be the preferred option. In countries with mature Energy Authority in Kenya and the Energy Regulatory Commis-
micronance markets, consumer credit through MFIs could be the sion in Bangladesh are dedicated to the effective realization of
most appropriate solution in the near future (UNCDF/UNDP, national energy access targets.
2011). MFIs are focused on expanding nancial outreach to the Besides the existence of a clear national policy, the experience
poor, and therefore have unrivalled knowledge of, relationships of the rst generation of market-driven projects for energy access
with and access to low-income consumers. Coupled with grant highlights the importance of raising awareness, developing the
subsidies when applicable, the size of MFI loans is theoretically skills and closely involving prospective customers. In the conclu-
appropriate for all but the most expensive clean energy systems sion of a review of mini-hydropower development in Nepal,
for the poor. Sovacool et al. (2010) commented: Spreading social awareness,
Despite this apparent match between MFIs and clean energy promoting community ownership, molding efcacious regulations,
services, the availability of energy product loans remains rela- minimizing corruption, addressing poverty, improving institutional
tively limited (IFC, 2010; IEA, 2011). One reason is that MFIs capacity, these are the enduring challenges, and until they are
typically use short maturities (of 612 months). The better meet targeted with the same rigour that engineers seek to design a dam,
the cash ow proles of the poor, new credit modalities with the hydropower potential of Nepal will remain just that. To create
Y. Glemarec / Energy Policy 47 (2012) 8793 91

sustainable energy markets, national and local government bodies models have not lessened the need for signicant and sustained
and civil society organizations will need to directly intervene to investment in market creation for rural energy access.
create demand through awareness-building, training, demonstra-
tions and piloting. 4.2. Possible additional sources of public nance for energy access
Quality control will also play a critical role in the adoption of
clean energy devices by communities. Sub-standard performance Even with a strong focus on market development and public
will cause a general decline in demand for clean energy systems private partnerships to catalyze private investment, the issue of
and, as discussed earlier, discourage nance institutions from nancing for universal energy access ultimately boils down to
entering the clean energy market because of the high risk of loan how to increase public and alternative nancial resources in order
defaults. To address this, public policies can assist in reducing to meet initial capacity development and market creation costs.
technological risks by establishing some standards and regulating This section summarizes the various options under three main
the quality of the devices produced and marketed. Supplier buy- categories: (i) international public nance for development and
back or maintenance guarantees for large systems (e.g. efcient climate change; (ii) domestic budget contributions; and (iii)
stoves for institutions) can also reduce the risk of technological carbon nance.
failure. However, such guarantees are of limited availability and For the rst source, international public nance, the share of
can be costly. development assistance to the energy sector declined from over
Research and development grants may be required to cover USD 15 billion (in 2009 US dollars) in 1980 to approximately USD
the costs of research, product design and market-testing of clean 7 billion at the end of the 1990s, before slightly increasing back to
energy devices that are suited to the unique household energy USD 9.1 billion in 2009. Furthermore, less development nance
usages of each location. Communities in which people prefer to seems to be channeled into the energy sectors of the countries
squat for cooking, for example, will require different modern cook with the lowest levels of energy access (Gualberti et al., 2012).
stove designs than communities in which people cook standing While development nance would not be enough to provide the
up, or cook indoor versus outdoor. In cold localities, combining annual investment of USD 48 billion required to achieve universal
cooking and heating systems will accelerate adoption of efcient modern energy access by 2030 (IEA, 2011), a reprioritization of
stoves. the energy sector in development assistance to the levels of 1980
and a better targeting of countries with the lowest levels of
energy access would go a long way to meet this goal.
4. Raising funds for energy access Despite present scal constraints, climate change nance is
expected to grow signicantly in the coming decade and comple-
4.1. The role of public nance for energy access ment development nance for energy access. The UNFCCC Copen-
hagen Accord (December 2009) and Cancun Agreement
The rst generation of projects has shown that achieving (December 2010) have committed developed countries to jointly
universal access to clean energy is possible through innovative mobilizing USD 100 billion per year by 2020 to support climate
publicprivate partnerships, but that signicant investment in change mitigation and adaptation activities in developing coun-
capacity development and market creation policies are initially tries. The funds for these activities are expected to come from
required to provide energy access to the poor. Public funds can public and private, bilateral, multilateral, and alternative sources
represent a signicant portion of the overall costs of decentralized of nance.
energy access investments, especially in the initial stages. For the past 20 years, the Global Environment Facility (GEF)
In a study of two rst-generation projects for micro-hydro- has been a major nancing source for market creation projects for
power and improved cooking stoves in Nepal, UNDP (2012) found clean energy access. In December 2010, at the sixteenth session of
that funding from public sources played a very dominant role the Conference of the Parties (COP 16) to the UNFCCC in Cancun,
early on (well over 90%), much of which was dedicated to the decision was made to establish a new global climate fund, the
investment in common capacity development goods such as Green Climate Fund (GCF). The governing instrument of the fund
research and development, planning, policies and regulations, was approved at COP 17 in Durban in December 2011. The GCF is
and community mobilization (56% of total programme costs for expected to support a number of innovative programming
the micro-hydropower programme over the period 19962006; mechanisms, such as NAMAs and sector-wide approaches. By
68% for the improved cooking stoves programme). The share of enabling governments to aggregate a large number of small-scale
public nance gradually declined to about 50% at a later stage and energy access projects within a single umbrella initiative, GCF-
is expected to make up less than 40% in the future. supported sector-wide approaches could prove critical to scaling
The 2011 World Energy Outlook (IEA, 2011) reaches similar up energy access efforts.
conclusions on the importance of public funding for nancing The UN Secretary General has launched the Sustainable
energy access for all. To provide the USD 48 billion per year Energy for All initiative which aims to scale up several multi-
needed for universal access, IEA estimates that around USD 18 lateral and bilateral programmes for energy access for the poor.
billion per year is needed from multilateral and bilateral devel- The International Energy and Climate Partnership Energy
opment sources, USD 15 billion per year from domestic budgets in known as Energy which was launched in Oslo in October
developing countries and USD 15 billion from the broad range of 2011 is part of these efforts and could lay the groundwork for
actors that form the private sector. developing such future initiatives under the GCF. Energy is built
These ndings are consistent with the development of rural on the premise of utilizing sector-wide approaches together with
electrication programmes in industrial countries. According to a performance-based payments in order to facilitate increased
Congressional report on the history of rural electrication in the access to energy and increased energy efciency. Its overall
USA (Department of Agriculture, 1982), the US Rural Electrica- objective is to develop commercially viable renewable energy
tion Department, which was established in 1935, took over 30 and energy efciency business models to catalyze private nance
years until the late 1960searly 1970s to reach the stage where it for universal energy access.
had developed sufcient nancial strength to obtain a portion of Energy will follow a three-step approach to country engage-
their capital needs from private sources. Technological advances, ment: Phase 1 will support strategic planning activities, including
energy market liberalization and the emergence of new business nalizing low-carbon and energy sector strategies; Phase 2 will
92 Y. Glemarec / Energy Policy 47 (2012) 8793

focus on encouraging technological innovation, creating a con- increase or improve energy access for households had so far been
ducive investment environment, piloting new nancing modal- registered and 15 were at the validation stage (UNEP Risoe
ities and leveraging market expansion; and Phase 3 will provide pipeline analysis and database).
payments and incentives against veried results in expanding Nevertheless, new potential carbon nance programming
access to new users and communities. This three-phase approach modalities under the CDM, such as Programmes of Activities
fully acknowledges the importance of readiness and market (PoAs) and standardized baselines for sector-wide application,
creation to catalyze private nance for affordable, adequate and are opening new avenues for carbon nance-supported energy
sustainable energy access for the poor. access investment. The recent November 2011 decisions by the
The second source of public funds for sustainable energy CDM Executive Board to develop standardized baselines will
access may come from direct budget contributions in developing enable projects included in a positive CDM project list of a
countries. Irrespective of their commitment to universal energy developing country (e.g. certain cooking stove technologies, solar
access, governments in developing countries will be hard pressed PV, mini-hydro, etc.) to be considered automatically additional,
to increase by several multiples their current contribution in this substantially reducing the upfront transaction costs of CDM
area, which would likely be required to provide universal energy projects. The creation of PoAs, which aggregate multiple small/
access by 2030. Besides energy access, developing countries have micro-scale projects under one policy or programmatic umbrella,
enormous challenges in the areas of education, health, social should help reduce the individual transaction costs for energy
services, food and human security, basic infrastructure, and access initiatives. As of January 2012, 58 PoAs had already been
disaster risk management. designed to increase or improve energy access for households (3
Subsidy reforms hold the promise of freeing up resources for registered and 55 at the validation stage).
energy access in many developing countries. Such reforms focus This seems to indicate that PoAs are meeting expectations in
on reducing, eliminating or redesigning subsidies that promote terms of reduced transaction costs for small and micro scale
inefcient and often harmful use of resources in a number of activities, and have become an appropriate modality for a number
economic sectors, including energy, agriculture, sheries, forests of universal energy projects that were not realised under the
and water. Conventional energy subsidies are the single most project-based CDM modality. PoAs could also be used as a starting
important barrier to the growth of clean energy technologies point to scale up clean energy access efforts as Nationally
today. The IEA estimates global fossil fuel subsidies at USD 312 Appropriate Mitigation Actions (NAMAs), opening new nancing
billion in 2009, compared to only USD 57 million for clean energy opportunities under the UNFCCC framework. An analysis con-
(IEA, 2011). The phase-out of the most detrimental subsidies and ducted by South Pole shows that a number of existing PoAs could,
their reinvestment in clean energy initiatives could signicantly integrated with a strong policy component, potentially be scaled
contribute to meeting the additional investment costs for uni- up to NAMAs (South Pole, 2011). Such NAMAs would combine
versal energy access. carbon nance with public resources for policy development to
Although a large body of literature (OECD, 2005, 2010; catalyze private nance for clean energy access. However, no
Bredenkamp and Pattillo, 2010; Laan, 2010) shows that subsidies clear consensus has been reached yet on the exact nature of
mostly benet the wealthy, indiscriminately removing them can NAMAs under the UNFCCC negotiation process. Furthermore,
hurt the poor. Efforts such as those of the Islamic Republic of Iran large programmes/sectoral approaches might remain at odds with
to remove extremely high energy subsidies (USD 40 billion to USD the need to customize clean energy devices, such as improved
100 billion a year, relative to oil prices) without disproportionally cooking stoves, for meeting the needs of a heterogeneous clientele
affecting the poor illustrate possible approaches to address the (Simon et al., 2010).
social concerns of removing subsidies (Glemarec, 2011). Besides transaction costs, another critical issue with the CDM
The third source of public funds for sustainable energy access is its uneven regional distribution to date. According to the UNEP
is carbon nance, which despite the current uncertainty regarding Risoes January 2012 pipeline data, China and India will account
the long-term future of the Kyoto Protocol, is likely to play an for 70% of the emission reductions under the CDM by December
increasingly important role in nancing the transition to a low- 2012). A key challenge to leverage new carbon nance for
emission society. The report from the UN Secretary Generals High universal energy access will be to ensure that the shift from
Level Advisory Panel on Climate Change Financing (UN AGF, 2010) project-based approaches to scaled-up approaches such as pro-
recommends that carbon markets should be further strengthened grammatic CDM does not worsen the existing imbalance with
and estimates that, globally, the carbon offset market could lead respect to regional access to climate nance.
to USD 120150 billion per year of investment in low-emission Dedicated programme development facilities will be required
technologies by 2020. to assist project proponents in under-represented markets in
The potential of carbon nance for universal energy access is accessing carbon nance as well as to develop sector-wide
signicant. For example, improved cooking stoves save 5070% on approaches for energy access, combining domestic and interna-
fuel compared to traditional stoves (Brinkmann and Klingshirn, tional, public and private, grant and non-grant instruments. A key
2005; Gibbons et al., 2009; Limmeechokchaia and Chawana, lesson from the experiences with the CDM and vertical funds such
2006). In places where non-renewable biomass or fossil fuel as the Global Fund against AIDS, Tuberculosis and Malaria
(e.g. coal in South Africa) is used for cooking, improved stoves (GFATM) is the need to ensure adequate capacity development
can signicantly reduce CO2 emissions (1 tonne of CO2 per year, from the onset to enable countries access to these resources (Bird
according to a conservative GIZ estimate). In such cases, carbon et al., 2011).
nance could constitute an additional source of revenue for
improved cooking stove products, and be used as a substitute to
public subsidies to lower the retail price to below the cost of 5. Conclusion
production.
Unfortunately, the need to comply with rigid CDM rules on Given the limited availability of public nance, it is essential to
project baselines and additionality, validation, registration, mon- catalyze private nance for clean energy access. Furthermore, the
itoring and verication can make the transaction costs of CDM private sector not only provides additional nancial ows but
projects prohibitively expensive for small-scale energy access often possesses key skills and knowledge required to scale-up off-
projects. As of January 2012, only 18 CDM projects designed to grid clean energy. The rapid uptake of mobile phones highlights
Y. Glemarec / Energy Policy 47 (2012) 8793 93

the transformational role that the private sector can play to International Finance Corporation, 2010. Solar Lighting for the Base of the
provide decentralized services on a commercial basis in develop- PyramidOverview of an Emerging Market. Washington, DC, USA.
Laan, Tara, 2010. Gaining Traction: The Importance of Transparency in Accelerat-
ing countries. However, there are fundamental differences ing the Reform of Fossil-Fuel Subsidies. Untold Billions: Fossil-fuel Subsidies,
between decentralized clean energy and mobile telephone mar- Their Impacts and the Path to Reform. International Institute for Sustainable
kets. Developing a new clean energy market involves considerable Development, Geneva.
uncertainty and large nancial outlays for research, development Legros, Gwenaelle, Rijal, Kamal, Seyedi, Bahareh, 2011. Decentralized Energy
Access and the MDGs. UNDP/AEPC, New York, USA.
of policy and regulations, education of consumers, and promotion Liebreich, Michael, 2011. Pre-COP African Minsterial-Dinner Key Note Speech.
of new income generating activities to increase the affordability Bloomberg New Energy Finance, New York, USA.
of energy services and promote economic developmentall of Limmeechokchaia, Bundit, Chawana, Saichit, 2006. Sustainable energy develop-
ment strategies in the rural Thailand: the case of the improved cooking stove
them market-building common goods, measures for which
and the small biogas digester. Renewable Energy Reviews 11 (5), 818837.
private nance is scarce. Grant-based support for these functions McKinsey & Company, 2011. Resource Revolution: Meeting the Worlds Energy.
will be necessary. Materials, Food and Water Needs. USA.
Lessons gained from rst generation market development Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, 2005. Environmental
Fiscal Reform for Poverty Reduction. OECD Guidelines and Reference Series.
projects in Africa and Asia show that these capacity development Paris.
and market-building activities account for a signicant portion of Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, 2010. Taxation, Inno-
the overall costs of clean energy access programmes, especially in vation and the Environment. Paris, France.
Proparco, 2009. What are the economic and social impacts of the mobile phone
the initial stages. Despite mounting scal constraints facing
sector in developing countries? Proparco Magazine. November 2009, Issue 4,
governments worldwide, the emergence of new programming Paris, France.
modalities and strong momentum in support of subsidy reforms REN21, 2011. Renewables 2011 Global Status Report. REN21 Secretariat, Paris,
offers opportunities to leverage signicant public resources from France.
Roller, Lars-Hendrik, Waverman, Leornard, 2001. Telecommunications Infrastruc-
international public nance, domestic budgets and carbon nance ture and Economic Development: A Simultaneous Approach. The American
to achieve universal energy access by 2030. Economic Review, USA, September 2001.
South Pole/KfW/BMU, 2011. How to Develop a NAMA by Scaling Up Ongoing
Programmatic CDM Activities on the Road from PoAs to NAMAs. Frankfurt,
References
Germany.
Simon, Gregory, Bumpus, Adam G., Mann, Philip, 2010. WinWin Scenarios at the
Bird, Neil, Billett, Simon, Colon, Cristina, 2011. Direct Access to Climate Finance: Climate Development Interface: Challenges and Opportunities for Cookstove
Experiences and Lessons Learned. Discussion Paper. ODI/UNDP, New York, Replacement Programs through Carbon Finance. University of Colorado,
USA. Denver.
Bony Lionel, Doig Stephen, Hart Chris, Maurer Eric, Newman Sam, 2010. Achieving The Economist, 2009. How a Luxury Item became a Tool of Global Development.
Low Cost Solar PV: Industry Workshop Recommendations for Near Term Special Report: Telecoms in Emerging Markets. London, UK, September 2009.
Balance of System Cost Reductions. RMI, USA. Sovacool, Benjamin K., Dhakal, Saroj, Gippner, Olivia, Bambawale, Malavika Jain,
Bredenkamp, Hugh, Pattillo, Catherine A., 2010. Financing the Response to Climate 2010. Halting hydro: a review of the socio-technical barriers to hydroelectric
Change. IMF Staff Position Note No. 2010/06. International Monetary Fund. power plants in Nepal. Energy Policy, Elsevier, UK.
Brinkmann, Verena, Klingshirn, Agnes, 2005. Stove Producers Assess their Impact: Sovacool, Benjamin K., DAgostino, Anthony L., Bambawale, Malavika Jain, 2011.
Methodology and Results of a ProBEC Participatory Impact Assessment. The socio-technical barriers to Solar Home Systems (SHS) in Papua New
Programme for Biomass Energy Conservation, GTZ, Pretoria, South Africa. Guinea: choosing pigs, prostitutes, and poker chips over panels. Energy Policy,
Clemens, Elisabeth, et al., 2010. Capacity Development for Scaling Up Decentra- Elsevier, UK.
lized Energy Access Programmes: Lessons from Nepal on its Role, Costs, and Szabo, S., Bodis, K., Huld, T., Moner-Girona, M., 2011. Energy Solutions in Rural
Financing. UNDP, New York, USA. Africa: Mapping Electrication Costs of Distributed Solar and Diesel genera-
Department of Agriculture, 1982. A Brief History of the Rural Electric and tion versus grid extension, Environmental Research Letters. IOP Publishing,
Telephone Programs. Washington, DC, USA.
UK.
Deichmann, Uwe, Meisner, Craig, Murray, Siobhan, Wheeler, David, 2010. The
UNEP, 2012. Financing Renewable Energy in Developing CountriesDrivers and
Economics of Renewable Energy Expansion in Rural Sub-Saharan Africa. Policy
Barriers for Private Sector Finance in Sub-Saharan Africa. UNEP FI, Paris,
Research Working Paper 5193. World Bank, Washington, DC, USA.
France.
Glemarec, Yannick, 2011. Catalyzing Climate Finance. UNDP, New York, USA.
UNDP, 2011. Towards an Energy Plus Approach for the Poor: A Review of Good
Gibbons, Drew, Sai, Nii Sai, Vuong, Bao, 2009. Improved Cookstoves Project: Scale
Practices and Lessons Learnt from Asia and the Pacic. UNDP, New York, USA.
up to Northern Ghana & Ghana School Feeding Program: Biogas Installation
UNDP, 2012. Mobile Technologies and Empowerment: Enhancing Human Devel-
Update. University California Berkeley, Berkeley.
Gualberti, Giorgio, Bazilian, Morgan, Haites, Erik, de Graca Cravalho, Maria, 2012. opment through Participation and Innovation. UNDP, New York, USA.
Development Finance for Universal Access, FEEM, Nota di Lavora, Lisbon, United Nations Secretary Generals Special Advocate for Inclusive Finance for
Portugal. Development, 2011. Annual Report to the Secretary-General, September 2011.
Gurung, Anup, Amal Kumar, Ghimeray, Sedky, H.A. Hassan, 2011. The Prospects of Woerlen, Christine, 2011. Meta-Evaluation of Climate Mitigation Evaluations. GEF
Renewable Energy Technologies for Rural Electrication: A Review from Evaluation Ofce, Washington, DC, USA.
Nepal. Energy Policy. Elsevier, UK. Yadoo, Annabel, Cruickshank, Heather, 2012. The role for low carbon electrica-
Hudson Institute, 2011. Centre for Global Prosperity: The Index of Global tion technologies in poverty reduction and climate change strategies: a focus
Philanthropy and Remittances. New York, USA. on renewable energy mini-grids with case studies in Nepal, Peru and Kenya,
International Energy Agency, 2011. Energy for All: Financing Access for the Energy Policy. Elsevier, UK.
PoorExcerpt of the World Energy Outlook 2011. IEA, Paris, France. Zuckerman, Ethan, 2009. Web 2.0 tools for development: simple tools for smart
International Energy Agency, 2010. United Nations Development Programme and people. In: Ashley, Holly, Kenton, Nicole, Milligan, Angela (Eds.), Change at
UNIDO: World Energy Outlook. IEA, Paris, France. Hand: Web 2.0 for Development. Participatory Learning and Action No. 59
ITU, 2011. The World in 2011: ICT Facts and Figures. Geneva, Switzerland. (June), pp. 8794.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi