Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 18

Profit efficiency in the European Union banking industry: a directional technology

distance function approach


Author(s): Anastasia Koutsomanoli-Filippaki, Dimitris Margaritis and Christos Staikouras
Source: Journal of Productivity Analysis, Vol. 37, No. 3 (June 2012), pp. 277-293
Published by: Springer
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/43549894
Accessed: 06-07-2016 17:46 UTC

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted
digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about
JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Springer is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of Productivity
Analysis

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293
DOI 10.1007/sl 1 123-01 1-0261-z

Profit efficiency in the European Union banking industry:


a directional technology distance function approach

Anastasia Koutsomanoli-Filippaki
Dimitris Margaritis * Christos Staikouras

Published online: 10 December 2011


Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2011

Abstract We employ the directional technology distance 1 Introduction

function approach and present estimates of profit efficiency


in the 25 European Union (EU) member states over the The European banking industry has faced numerous chal-
period 1998-2008. This method decomposes profit effi- lenges during the past decade culminated by the 2007
ciency into its technical and allocative components. We subprime and subsequent global financial crises while at
investigate potential efficiency differences across the old the same time undergoing an unprecedented wave of con-
EU region and the new EU member states, across countries solidation in response to changes in regulation and tech-
and across banks of different size. Our results indicate a nology. The implementation of European Union (EU)
significant level of profit inefficiency for the EU region, policies such as the Single Market Programme and the
which is predominantly attributed to allocative ineffi- European Monetary Union, aimed at enhancing the inte-
ciency. Our findings also suggest that banks operating in gration of banking and financial systems, have created a
the old EU region are, on average, more profit efficient than more market oriented and competitive financial sector
credit institutions in the new EU member states. Overall, throughout Europe. In particular, in relation to old EU
we observe considerable variation of efficiency scores member states (EU- 15), as a result of the Second European
across countries and different patterns in efficiency change Banking Directive and the Single European Passport, the
over time, as well as a negative relationship between bank speed of deregulation accelerated, and with the elimination
size and efficiency. or lowering of barriers the market-entry costs substantially
decreased, favoring competition and the creation of a
Keywords Profit efficiency Technical efficiency unified banking market.
Allocative efficiency European Union Data envelopment As the process of achieving full financial integration
analysis Directional distance functions among its member countries was evolving, the EU initiated
an eastward enlargement plan through the inclusion of two
JEL Classification D24 G21 G28 P34 Mediterranean countries and eight former socialist coun-
tries from Central and Eastern Europe (EU- 10). In March
1998 the EU formally launched a transition process that led
A. Koutsomanoli-Filippaki (E3)
Council of Economic Advisors, Hellenic Ministry of Finance, to the enlarged Union in May 2004. During this process,
5-7 Nikis St., Syntagma Square, 10180 Athens, Greece the new EU member states, and especially the Central and
e-mail: a.koutsomanoli@mnec.gr Eastern European (CEE) countries, have gone through a
significant economic and political transformation. In par-
D. Margaritis
The University of Auckland Business School, Auckland, ticular, a catching up process, characterized by rapid
New Zealand financial development and high economic growth, has been
e-mail: d.margaritis@auckland.ac.nz taking place. Since 1998 significant efforts were directed
C. Staikouras
towards improving the legislation related to the banking
Athens University of Business and Economics, Athens, Greece sector in the transition countries, while there have been
e-mail: cstaik@aueb.gr a series of amendments on the banking supervision

Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
278 J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293

regulative framework aiming at its harmonization with the proportionately without changing inputs or by decreasing
EU regulative system and the international standards of inputs proportionally for given outputs. Secondly, our
effective supervision. These laws increased the attractive- method allows overall bank profit efficiency to be
ness of the banking systems for foreign investment, decomposed into technical efficiency, which reflects the
strengthened prudent standards and practices in the banks' ability of a firm to obtain maximum output from minimum
operations, enhanced corporate governance and improved possible input use, and allocative efficiency, which indi-
efficiency in banking operations and supervision. cates the ability of a firm to use the inputs and outputs in
Research interest in the EU banking systems intensified optimal proportions, given their respective prices and the
following the first and the second wave of the EU production technology.
enlargement. In light of the increased competition under In order to empirically estimate the directional distance
the Single Market for financial services, the ability of EU function, we employ a non-parametric linear programming
credit institutions to compete and survive in an increasingly approach, Data Envelopment Analysis (DEA). This method
integrated European financial landscape becomes even has the advantage of constructing a data-driven techno-
more important. Moreover, the different structures and past logical frontier that requires no specification of any par-
legacies of the acceded countries and the close ownership ticular functional form or error structure. Efficiency is
ties between the EU- 15 and EU- 10 credit institutions due to measured as the distance from the frontier. As the frontier
the increasing presence of the latter in the CEE banking is data specific, there will be a new frontier for each year
industry create additional challenges in terms of real con- rather than an average across years as it is common with
vergence in a unified European banking market. The stochastic methods. A drawback of the DEA approach is
dominant role played by banks in the provision of financial that it attributes all deviations of a firm's performance from
services in the European economy makes the performance best-practice to inefficiency, as it makes no accommoda-
of the banking system crucial for economic development tion for statistical noise. We postulate a common techno-
and sound functioning of the industrial sectors, as attested logical frontier across all EU-25 banking sectors. We
by the current financial and economic crisis. Indeed, an believe this is a reasonable assumption to make in light of
improvement of banking performance indicates a better (a) the significant level of harmonization in banking and
allocation of financial resources, and therefore an increase other financial services legislation that has taken place over
of investment that favors growth. the past decade across EU Member States; (b) the reduction
This paper investigates the profit efficiency of the EU-25 of barriers to cross-border trade in EU banking services and
banking industries over the period 1998-2008. Although increase in financial integration; and (c) the close owner-
research on the efficiency of banks and other financial ship ties between EU- 15 and EU- 10 countries due to the
institutions in the US and other developed countries is increasing presence of the EU- 15 banks in the CEE
voluminous, this paper fills a gap in the literature by banking region.
departing from the traditional analysis of efficiency in a Using this methodology, we address a number of ques-
number of important ways. First, we use the directional tions regarding banking efficiency in the EU countries. Are
technology distance function approach, a generalization of bank choices of inputs and outputs consistent with profit
the more familiar Shephard (1970) input and output dis- maximization? If bank choices of inputs and outputs are
tance functions, to measure technical and profit efficiency not optimal, how much of the profit inefficiency is attrib-
by exploiting the duality between the directional distance uted to allocative or technical inefficiency? How has profit
and profit functions.1 Unlike the Shephard functions that efficiency evolved over time? Are there any differences
scale either in the input or the output direction, the direc- across the EU-25 countries? Does the size of financial

tional distance function simultaneously adjusts in the institutions matter for profit efficiency?
direction of fewer input and greater output production as The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2
much as it is technologically feasible. This entails an presents a brief review of the literature on productivity in
extremely flexible description of technology without the European banking sector. Section 3 describes the
restricting banks to optimize by either increasing outputs methodology, while Sect. 4 provides the description of the
data. Section 5 discusses the empirical results, while con-
clusions are drawn in Sect. 6.
1 DEA models based on Shephard distance functions have been used
extensively in EU banking studies (see for example, Pastor et al.
1997; Casu and Molyneux 2003; Lozano-Vivas et al. 2001, 2002;
Grigorian and Manle 2002; Casu and Girardone 2006). To our 2 Literature review
knowledge, Devaney and Weber (2002) were the first to use a
directional technology distance function approach to estimate profit
efficiency for U.S. banks and Koutsomanoli-Filippaki et al. (2009a, b) A proliferation of studies on bank efficiency and produc-
for CEE banks. tivity has emerged as a result of rapid changes in the

Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293 279

structure of the financial services industry and advances in allows firms to optimize by simultaneously adjusting inputs
financial and non-financial technologies (see Berger and and outputs, and it is a measure of technical inefficiency.
Mester 2003). A large body of literature exists on banking To define it we need to specify a directional vector,
efficiency concentrating in the US industry. Although denoted by g. This vector determines the direction in which
European research on efficiency has not matched the vol- technical efficiency is assessed. Let a directional vector be
ume of US studies, this has begun to change recently.2 represented by g = (gx, gy), where gx G R+ and gy G R+,
There are several reasons why banking efficiency has while we no longer make use of the index, k. The
attracted particular attention, as is documented by its long directional technology distance function seeks the
tradition in the literature. Efficiency measures are not only maximum simultaneous expansion of desirable outputs
success indicators, by which the performance of individual (y), and contraction of inputs (x) for the directional vector,
banks and the industry as a whole, can be evaluated, but g and provides a unifying structure, since it includes the
also influence the cost of financial intermediation and the Shephard distance functions as special cases.5
overall stability of financial markets.3
T(x,y,gx,gy) = sup{/? : (x- gx, y + gy) el}. (2)
Banking efficiency is estimated by employing either
non-parametric or parametric techniques (Berger and In this study, we use a common direction vector which is
Humphrey 1997; Alam 2001; Berger and Mester 2003). A set equal to: g = ( gXgy ) = (*,?) This directional vector
large number of studies have computed efficiency mea- implies that the amount by which a bank could increase
sures by employing DEA techniques to estimate Shephard outputs will be t (*, y, x, y) units of y and decrease inputs
(1970) type distance functions (see Berg et al. 1992). Using
by T(xi y ; x1 y) x units of x. For a bank that is technically
DEA, Sheldon (1999) finds that larger, specialized EU
efficient and is on the frontier, the value of the directional
banks are more profit efficient than smaller, diversified
distance function would be zero. On the other hand, values of
banks over the period 1993-1997. On the other hand, fol-
Drix^y, gx , gy) > 0 indicate inefficient production.
lowing the pioneering work of Aigner et al. (1977), several
One of the properties of the directional distance function
studies have estimated distance functions using parametric
is that it is dual to the profit function. In particular, profit
methods (see, for example, Cuesta and Orea 2002).
maximization requires the simultaneous adjustment of
outputs and inputs, which is also characteristic of the
directional distance function approach. Given output prices
3 Methodology
Pm R+ input prices wN G R+, and technology 7, we
We use the directional technology distance function pro- define the profit function IT (p,w) as:
posed by Chambers et al. (1996) to model the production Il (p, w) = max{#y - wx : {x, y) T} (3)
process and measure profit efficiency. We assume there are
This function is homogeneous of degree 1 in prices in
k = 1, ..., K banks which use G R+ inputs to produce
addition to being convex and continuous in positive prices.
3 1 e R+ outputs. Technology (7) for each bank is defined Profit maximization implies that:
as the set of all feasible input-output vectors:4
n (p,w) = py * - wx* >py - wx for all (. x , y) G 7 (4)
Tk = {(/,/) : X G R+,y G x can produce y}. (1)
where y* and x* are optimal input and output vectors that
The directional technology distance function completely maximize profits. Since the directional technology distance
characterizes technology (i.e. it is equivalent to 7), it function is a complete characterization of technology, we
can substitute 7 with Dr^^&cg^in expression (4) [see
2 Studies that have investigated efficiency in the European banking Fre and Grosskopf (2004) and Fare et al. (2008)]. By
industry, and particularly focus on cross-country comparisons,
include Allen and Rai (1996), Altunbas et al. (2001), Lozano-Vivas
rearranging we have:
et al. (2001, 2002), De Guevara and Maudos (2002), Maudos et al.
n {p,w) -(py-wx) R
(2002), Vander Vennet (2002), Casu and Molyneux (2003), Casu and
Girardone (2004), and Koutsomanoli-Filippaki et al. (2009a, b). Pgy + Wgx
3 According to Molyneux et al. (1996) "greater efficiency might be
expected to lead to improved financial products and services, a higher 5 The Shephard output distance function optimizes over output
volume of funds intermediated, greater and more appropriate quantities, but not inputs. Hence if the directional vector g is set at (0,
innovations, a generally more responsive financial system, and y ) then the directional (output) distance function is equal to the
improved risk-taking capabilities if efficiency profit gains are reciprocal of the Shephard output distance function minus one.
channelled into improved capital adequacy positions". Similarly, the Shephard input distance function optimizes over input
4 It is assumed that the technology satisfies the axioms listed in Fare quantities but not outputs and if we set g = ( x , 0) then the directional
and Primont (2003), among which are convexity and free or strong (input) distance function is equal to one minus the reciprocal of the
disposability of outputs and inputs. Shephard input distance function.

Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
280 J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293

On the left-hand side we have the Nerlovian measure of K

profit efficiency, while on the right-hand side is the Y. Zkykm >ym,m = 1, - , Af,
k= 1
directional distance function. If we then add an allocative
K
efficiency component, AET , to the inequality in (5), we
arrive at our decomposition of profit efficiency as a strict 'Y^ZkXvkn<x,n- 1 - 1,
k= 1
equality, that is:
K

Tl(psw) - (py - wx) -* , v , -


~~ = , gX gy) v -h AEj , (6) ^2zkek<tk
Pgy + Wgx k= 1

k
The left-hand side of (6) is equal to the difference
Zk> 0,k= = 1
between maximum profit, II (p,w), and observed profit, (py- k= 1

wx), normalized by the value of the directional vector


( pgy -h wgx).6 On the right-hand side we decompose profit where the convexity constraint Y^Zk = 1 in the LP prob-
efficiency into technical and allocative efficiency by lems above imposes a variable returns to scale (VRS)
exploiting the duality between the profit function and the technology, effectively ensuring that an inefficient bank is
directional distance functions. benchmarked against banks of a similar size. In addition,
To empirically estimate the directional distance function imposing VRS in the maximum profit model (8) implies
and the profit function, we can either use an activity that perfect competition is not assumed, and hence maxi-
analysis approach (i.e. DEA) or a parametric distance mum profits may be different than zero.
function approach. In this paper, we follow Devaney and
Weber (2002) and opt for a non-parametric method. In
particular, we solve the following linear programming (LP) 4 Data description
problem:
Our dataset consists of banks operating in the EU member
max T(x,y;xv,0,) = (7) states and are listed in the IBCA-Bankscope database, over
subject to: the period 1998-2008.7 We confine our analysis to credit
institutions that report positive equity capital yielding a
K
sample of 30,101 bank-year observations. After reviewing
S>>W + fo,
*= i the data for reporting errors and other inconsistencies, we
obtain an unbalanced panel dataset of 29,587 bank-year
observations that we use for bank efficiency analysis.8 Our
k= 1 sample is quite extensive and covers the largest credit
K
institutions in each country as defined by their balance
sheet aggregates (i.e. bank assets).9
yj Zk^k < ejc
k= 1 While there continues to be a debate about the definition

k of bank inputs and outputs, we adopt the traditional inter-


Zk> o, k = 1, = 1 mediation approach as suggested by Sealey and Lindley
k= 1

7 This database reports published financial statements from banks


where x = ( xv,e ) and xv denotes N - 1 variable inputs and
worldwide, homogenized into a global format, which are comparable
e denotes a fixed input. across countries and therefore suitable for a cross-country study.
To estimate maximum profit, we solve the following 8 For each year the respective figures for the number of banks are:
linear programming problem: 2,270 (1998); 2,414 (1999); 2,508 (2000); 2,867 (2001); 2,829 (2002);
2,851 (2003); 2,176 (2004); 3,021 (2005); 3,004 (2006); 2914 (2007);
n(p, w) = ma x(py - wxv) (8) 2733 (2008). The additions to the sample are not necessarily new
market entrants, but rather successful banks that are added to the
subject to: database over time. Exits from the sample are due primarily to either
mergers with other banks or bank failures.
9 Note that our efficiency estimates are based on unconsolidated data
and thus are bank-specific and do not take explicitly into account the
6 Note that the normalization in (6) means that this profit inefficiency way the production is organized at the conglomerate level. However,
measure is independent of units of measurement and is also well Berger et al. (2000) argue that despite the fact that it is not possible to
defined even if observed profit is zero or negative. The choice of determine the extent to which transfer pricing, shared inputs, and
normalization is not arbitrary; rather it coincides with the value of the other intra-organizational arrangements might impact efficiency
Lagrangean multiplier associated with constrained profit maximiza- assessments, most evidence suggests that this potential bias is not
tion as defined in (8) below. significant.

Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293 281

(1977), which views banks as institutions that collect Another issue in the efficiency literature is the treatment
deposits, using labor and physical capital, to transform of financial capital, which accounts for different risk
them into loans and other earning assets.10 Thus, the input preferences. If financial capital is ignored, the efficiency of
vector includes: labor (defined as total personnel expenses), banks that may be more risk averse than others and may
physical capital (approximated by the book value of fixed hold a higher level of financial capital would be mismea-
assets) and total deposits.11 The output vector includes sured, even though they are behaving optimally given their
loans (defined as total loans net of provisions) and other risk preferences.14 Apart from this, a bank's capital directly
earning assets.12 As in Berger and Bonaccorsi di Patti affects costs by providing an alternative to deposits as a
(2006) we measure input and output prices as exogenous funding source for loans (see Berger and Mester 1997). 15
market averages. The price of labor is defined as the Fare et al. (2004) found that using bank equity as a
average price for labor a bank faces in the domestic market. quasi-fixed input in the analysis of bank profit efficiency is
This is computed as a weighted average of personnel sufficient to account for both the risk-based capital
expenses (wages and benefits) to the number of employees requirements and the risk-return trade-off that bank owners
of other banks in the domestic market excluding the bank's face. Thus, we include equity capital as a quasi-fixed input
own price, where the weights are each other bank's market in estimating the directional distance function. In this case
share. Other prices are similarly calculated in weighted equity capital enters the directional distance function with a
average terms. As is common practice in banking studies directional vector value set to zero.
(see Vander Vennet 2002), the price of physical capital is Table 1 provides summary statistics of the variables
calculated as other administrative expenses to fixed used in this study for the whole EU-25, for the EU-15 and
assets,13 while the price of deposits is defined as the ratio of EU- 10 regions, and for each country over the period
interest expenses to total funds. Likewise, the price of loans 1998-2008. The sample is dominated by the small and
is expressed as interest income to total loans, while the medium sized German banks representing about half of the
price of other earning assets is defined as the ratio of non- total observations. We observe considerable variations
interest income to other earning assets (see Mertens and across regions and countries in relation to both output and
Urga 2001). input quantities and respective prices. Overall, the banking
sector in the old EU-15 region is dominated by larger
financial institutions than that of the EU- 10 area. EU-15
credit institutions have, on average, higher personnel
10 A variety of approaches have been proposed in the literature for
the definition of bank inputs and outputs; yet, there is little agreement expenses, deposits, loans and other earning assets than the
among economists as what unequivocally constitutes an acceptable EU-10 banks. On the other hand, EU-10 credit institutions
definition, mainly as a result of the nature and functions of financial face much lower input prices; command higher output
intermediaries. See Berger and Humphrey (1997) for a review of
prices and report, on average, higher profits than EU-15
studies on financial institution efficiency and the various methods
used to define inputs and outputs in financial services. banks. Nevertheless, there is considerable variation across
1 1 It was not possible to use the number of employees as a measure of these statistics even within each EU region.
labor for each bank due to incomplete data on the number of Finally, with regards to the price of loans and deposits,
employees in the BankScope database. However, we have used this we observe a higher price of loans but a lower price of
information to construct the labor price data as explained below.
deposits for EU-10 compared to EU-15 banking systems.
12 Note that recent studies (e.g. Clark and Siems 2002; Isik and
In particular, the average price of loans for EU-10 coun-
Hassan 2003; Casu and Girardone 2005) introduce off-balance-sheet
activities as an additional output, as arguably these activities may tries is 11.91 compared to an average of 9.25 for EU-15,
have an effect on bank performance measures. However, the IBCA while the average price of deposits is 3.80 for EU-
database does not provide detailed information on off-balance sheet lOcompared to 4.51 for EU-15. This indicates a higher
activity and hence the inclusion of this variable would result in a
interest margin for EU-10 countries compared to EU-15,
significant reduction of our sample. In addition, Becalli et al. (2006)
argue that the great variability in accounting practices across which is consistent with previous studies (see for example,
countries, especially with respect to the treatment of off-balance- ECB 2005). Higher net interest rate margins in EU-10
sheet activities, may introduce a remarkable sample bias if off- reflect the relative strength of net interest income in the
balance-sheet data are used in cross country studies.
13 As pointed out by an anonymous referee, caution needs to be
exercised with the use of the physical capital input in banking, as the 14 (Hughes and Moon 1995) and Hughes et al. (1996) tested and
value of fixed assets included in bank balance sheets may be rejected the assumption of risk neutrality for banks. And risk taking
underestimated when physical resources are leased and not owned. behavior is more than likely to have increased as more intense
These variations in the ownership-leasing mix coupled with differ- competition in the enlarged EU market put a big squeeze on bank
ences in accounting practices for fixed assets across countries will profit margins.
also have some effect on price measures defined in relation to fixed 15 German banks as well as banks from Luxembourg are more thinly
assets. This may in part explain the significant variation in the price of capitalized holding on average about half of the equity needed to
capital across countries observed in Table 1. support their assets compared to other EU banks.

Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
282 J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293

mooio^Ht^^voocsoor^invooN X o o r-
NOioesooNOio^-oo^ineses^r- ON NO o
r> -M *
OO *
- < -H r.
- < - < T"
w
- I O wN
T" N
o -

Tf OO vO CS O
ocN-H^^-NDONinrsNDONCNioor-'^-vD'^-ooTj-mTj-r^mNDr-ooio^ , ^ N rjvq
r^Ovpr^oocNjcno-Hfnoqo<r|pvo*OTtcscvOiOfno-HVON-CS , o oo es o m
oj u-j en oo es in es' n t- so rt cn Tf ^ en r' h * co o h oo iri *"H

r- i oo r*- 00 ON
ovovo*OTt^HONr^O"cn<s>oci^Hp-ooTi-Tt^H-HONor-cM<SooN os no es on
Oencsoocnr^NOONinvor^cnTf NOTf'-jeseNoejioppcsoor^Tf Tf NO __ r' en en en od
r-1 or-iooo^N^ h Hyf5inNPP0H0^^v0K^hH0fn Pu es
OU r- 1

eSTfONO^*-HeNOOOCS*niOCSr^CS^HCSeNCScnNOOOlOeSONOOTfNO CD h ^ 2 >t
eSO'CSr-OOONNOO'^HTf^HOOcnONOOTfONOONOOTf^ONOOONOO CD ^ '-H on es ^ no
> Tf no Tf en e hiohn' hnhioo^omh vin TtoTdrjH > es o no -< <n

oooTtcoNomoooooO'-HmooaNOOoor-^j-oooNOONcNO'^-Nr-r-- as o as oo ^
^ oNqr-NOONco*or"ppooooqoo<soqoor-ONOO-HONcnor-ooN ^ as ^ o as g ^ oo ^ 4
> en r-' o o 0 on vd ci p-" 00 r*-" es vo en on r*-" d -<' u-i Tf 00 es" no no ^h" -h' 00 rs o
> r- r-'- iio^nr-'- 'ONr-HNomoo^i-oo r ^ t- on ^ r- es no ^ ^ ^ 00 (n rs 00 ri

en^HesONONoinr-Tj-ONr-NO^HNOONOcnenT-r-cnTi-escncncnoo
^ en -hoo p 00 00 es p -os r^.-<vo r^_ est-^oq t no en on p en ^tO Tfvo r-; - 1 ^ o en m
> s vo no '- no 00 no on es no O ^h' on en ^ '- r-' r-' o uS r--' on en en ^-' p no o r-; o
|>io no '-i en es no -h en es no r-> '- 1 en es no ^ 0 *- > s (S en en h o
> .- 1 00 *- es

inp- NOONOONOooenr- OenenenTt oor- ^ppioio^- inpOin


HH^HO^OO^rioO^t H^^^oilONlOHVO^HONHOOVO >.
3 no- iNOenoo-HeneSNOenioNONooiooo-HNor-csr-ONONONONOoo C? >. es ^ h m o
a h oo o N es m id N o m t h a* 10 't h o o in m 10 *o (N m N *-h -3 es ^ es
W -h en '-h en en f-T in 1-T -h r-n" -h cn es" cy o es Tf PQ
no-hes Tf Tf
-h en o i-

oo-HoqoNr-H'qespvqppesoqooTnr;penNqr^ONt^NqoNi>Ti-^
enh o'ori ^0'Tdoiod^HHoenaHio'o^HOhO o t!- -1 es m
enr^^eN^H<NNOior--<N'- 't--Nor-Tf<NO<- 'eNcneN^cs<NenesoNt~- o " t!- , -1 es ;J m _J
Ttr-r--HTt^j-cnr->oooTtNDOOenONNOeno-H-HTtiooeno^H(N 5 ^ ^ 00 1
r r-Hvomr--H(NeseneSen sooo^nNO^Tfior-^H^HCso^es ^ rg cn on on 00
r-1 - 1 - i es es on es >- < es *-<
io 00

pr^Tj-^Hinoor-iOOOi-HOopesooeni-joooNor^oor^r^OesooooTf
o en Tf o r-" c> Tf r*" Tf no Tf en o vo no -< o r*" r- en 00 i-h o od r**' en -h 00 es o
NOOOONr^mOOOOOO'^ONON'- iCNONNOTtNOioeSeSr-HOx-mONeSlONO u- nn 'j-i nn r
no^ es Tf on <N en on n p^ Tf 00 no^ *-h rt on 00^ vo^ on Tf vo^ no^ 00^ Tf on !J u- nn ^ 'j-i nn r
C 00 es" on es" Tf .-<" en en es" es" Tf" vo" en en on *-<" es" 00" es" es" en es" en" es" on" 00 ^ o t o'
?* 1- en es es en 1- 1 <<t ^ es) en *- 1 ^ ^ ^ ^

no Tf r no Tf p; o Tf Tf os r*^ n on 00 o *n vo r-> o Tf io es Tf Tf es
Ttiniooo^^NO-csiooooo^iooocsesoooor^^r^uSenNOen o on --in en
ooNOooioO'ooooenenNOiOi- iON>OTfTfTfcniocncnoooor^Tfcnoo in Tf o ^ r-
cs^ vq ^ en ^ r-; 00^ on es^ no^ *n on p en en on en *-h ^ in in ON n r- in 00 o on in
G es" ^h" en es" en" no en" 10" es" m" es" Tf" o" on ^h" es" es" 00" es" m" cn" Tf" Tf" es" es" 00" en O <o on r- no
?< es r- en en es r- es en -h X ^ vo on

esoNespONvqr^ooioocTfcnioppenvqoO'-jcnr-cnppespeSNq ^ _
lovooocnoor-'^iooNOOioioNoes' Ttnoor^Nooioes^HNO^-cncnNi) -, ^ LT- ^ ~- _
cninesr-'^-ooooioeN'- lenTf'- iNO-^-r-eNcnenr-ONcncs^i-NOO^^ on 00 on en 00
es es no - i - t- vo es o es en ^ 1- 1 es en tj- Ksesescnooes
X

pNopNO^O^-enpoooNOoenioenr^NOiooppooiovooopNor^ 5 vi H S O
ohiohiohTtThesooden^t^ ^ ^eNio^ooes X ^ rn ^ 00 ^
eSTto^Ttr-^r-enNoeSTtes^HOOvoesooONOvooNcnr-Hiovo ^
h es *o en ^ es o es es es es^ten

oo
X ^h"
o
o
^ h h 00 en T
00
O o es* i- h" o no
ON ^ Tj-oopesio^HONor-^ooesr^TtTi-poTi-pioesiopio^peSNO ^ en no o ^ es
ON o 00 00 o r*>* Tt 00 00 o -H* T Tt en r-' r-' o 00 no Tj-" uS 00 ^ 00 ^
v- - ieneneSenONOenenO>0'- ONOONen Tj-ONTtr^ocsenenONi- es
CU r-H^H00 -H es ^HTfso^HOO en ^ en m es
C fl
o

to ccc

H
C/3
c
cd
c
cd
c
co
c
cd
ccd
cco
c cO
c c
co
c
co
c
co
c
co
c
co
c
co
S
co
Q S 2
^OQQQ.aQQQQ^QQQQQiO

E

s
00 a S

2
A
^'S-i
Zi Zi < D.
< 2-s D.
(D (D C
igloC rz
03<U>^NOt.S2tbk3^3c3 o rz S
S I oo c
Il cJi
Ji<
^^^-2DJC
oI'll DJC
X X~~
o.t3
H U<pquuqwu,;OOKJ

Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293 283

"d-
m ON 00 m
^ m O IO CS en
Tf onO o
NO o
Oon
- O
! ^
^ O
c "G
vi
_
CS *
CS_
^ O
J~
O ~
io *
NO TfrH
fl
. -o
U
-2 SS
C/2

0 CS en C U eC ^
U u M ^
h .C
S X "2
_( u E
oo(NOoom<Nr^ON^^oo^j-m^^t^OQ*oONioONNO ^ S 8
^-r-r^p no no oq en r-NO o >o ^tr-eN <n en o o r-. o ^ en te .^ ^
es ^'lo^' "3- ^^no-^^cno^' no cSNOcnNOcn on lovorn g Sh u ^
01 ^ cu.^h-S
. ^ .22 o

r-i^HooiomooomTj-'- 'Ooo^-H- iT^-T^-voioiO'- 'OOOO-H S 05 *o & 1 S 1 05 1 *o &


-< - o on vq noo cn oo r- r-; i-; io - p no t; es o on oq en cn > e .y
1 m'ooh^K r!H^ioowori'HK^o'rMioo'fn -2 > o * 5
O . ,-H ,-H ,-H ,-H

C/3 'i ,
U W Q
__ ONiNr-r-mcnvoiocNr-ON-^-mNONor-io^H^HOr-r^c ci e o
g __ oqp^iop^piooN^popNqpor-iocMoqOT;<N x~.se e o
<o o en Tj-' i- en -h T '^h Tf -J -h* en t- -h en H t-" i- c g o
S5-85
S ^ -S o
o^teNiTj-cONTtor^oooooesot^^^NONooNoooNNo u o .SP
tj- .-< no es en es no en en vq p es oq no en es on r-^ no *C ^ o C O
es oo en on no oo io no es r-' on io r-'^' io en no es
> * f OOrH^rH^rHlOrHT ONenOO^H^CSNOCSP^CS teW
> * f OOrH^rH^rHlOrHT ONenOO^H^CSNOCSP^CS - f3 teW
ooenTj-ooovovONOOOcsONt^*ocsenenooNOTtor- 'S ^ - to
3 Z- 'I .a
_ csooovoNONOOTtioioNor^iooo^en^HpO^HCSr^cs jg - c3 u
_ >> NOooOOOOOTtlONOOr^T-CSOOOOocSCSOtONO O.H
> NO CN Tj- ^ CS Tt NO IO NO- 'CS- 'NO- < 2 c t?
Dh *13 .53
c T3 J: ,

g
. ooiooNOoooOOTj-OTtooTfenoN'-HpOr^oopNor^en w c 2 -2
.ts ^ es r-' oo no r' no r-' es es io vo r-' no en r-' "3- io o r-' w u E u e
3 csr-csNONOTj-ONoooNO^HenT-r-or-TfcsoTt'-H-HTt u o > *C ^
.y.y
n* i- "Tten^j-NOONTf-
^ ^ * "i-HCScnoenenocSTfNOenr^Tfo
****** * h h au Y a^
^ cL y
t3 y
W en r- -H ^-h Tt *-< en oo cn es m w a
mwa2^^
^ .sp
g'oxS
en vo r--_ O - On es on oq i- ; en en es vo on Tt io r-H in on to Tt -g ft w
en en on r^" es" oo on iri cn r-' o cn io en en r^" -g S M o M
NONOTtHON^ooHvocsenent^enenr--cscsr-oocSONCS <- -e >" c
oo o en on o -H p^ p^ en no on r* cd en oo^ no^ cn o^ en p^ -5 <- "5 ,0 c
-, io ri h ci n-" r-" *-<" ^ *o" rfr" es" cn ^h" no" t oo h en' ^ t3 'i
r^^ en
^ on S
es ^ "O
en es ^ en
D en ^
u g-O
g ^
w <U
f2 o
>< w S
tj-cn r--oq io no r*;co tj-^-oo on on io io on esoo o p o u O.o ^
no r-" oo t-" o es* oo no no oo Tt io Tf en ^ <o oo * h
OcNoenONOoio^^eNenenenON^ooenooenoioooio d -g 3 Q.
P. ^ ^ ^ ^ on 00 no 10^ r- 10 T o en tn c 7;
^lo^H
d ^ es" en
-H o" -H
r-" ^ ^Tt
^ es"es
en 10"
en^ on
no" no"
es00"
<Nes" 10"
2 X Tt" ^
r^"o^ en
-a^ oOO
^ S -a
'S 2 s
5 c ^
52 O* 0
ON r^i co r-; oa so ^ oqpONoqooTtNqpoqioONCSen iScgo
^NioHHOOdHyoo^o!^ (s'einirioeioo^ ^ -o
*- enesoen0NeS'-H0Nr--eneSN00N0eSeNTN0enenen0N B< u O
uo cn on en Tt p^ en 00^ cn no^ oo^ no^ 00 oo^ en in N h 3 X c
^-h" es" 00" en" 10" 00" -<" es" -T en" o" io" on" io h v yo en' ^ v io 0 S S
en vo ^ ^ ^ - h ^ h ^ N ^ en
^ ^ 3 ? J)
6 3, &
.S o1o ^
^
pOioiotNes^enr-'-r^NOoopNOio-Henr-^ioNor^ "J -
'-ioooiooooNOeneSTenenioioes^itenOenT^- X ^ P S
enoo^oooeSTi-OTi-^enencNooesoooioONOooT}- ^C'SCM
es r- on es cn en o noon io es 10 ' ^ ^ - c3

es X r- on - es cn en o - noon - io es 10 |t|jf ' . ^ . ^ ^ - ^oes .. .. ^^-S


o c3
-S
o -S c
m" X -c ^ .2
cn ^- no r- NO Tj- oo en 00 en ^h on 0 ^t r^- io eN o p cN '-h -g ^ #op ^ d
ao^cnNor-'eN^NO^OoooNOocnoooooocnr-'No
looesoo^NOooescseSTtoo^ioeSNOoor^oioesc^ON S>*o_S
1- r^- 00 -"-es 1- no m 10 o 10 ^ ^

X 1- r^- 00 -"-es 1- no m 10 o -* 10 ^ siglo << a,a,S .00


S o
ri t g
oenrHrH^Mio^ioh^^Men^hO^in^iomM rtc'c^o
.- o N oo on ^ ^ 10 vo ^ es' o' t o' ^ 00 h ^ o -h" h Tt c g S
^ envOT-r-iOTi-ioeSTesen^vor^ONenTtioNONONOioio es g c
g en no ' es es 00 es no 00 tj- ^ w q S
^ - S w W S.s| q "OP3 W2
"O 2
P3 > I ! 's i
i i i i S i i i i - -i - i
Qil c ^ r" R. c
TD
D
3 - P o
Sst^.2
G

G
O
O 8
G _ _ ^ s, -
T3 -S5 _ -S _ c % 2
0) h rjTD^C c <D lOOlO "S-."CJ3
IS e
3'S'S
S g -- 35
-- > >
> > *S
^ *SO
-o
i iO ii i i ^
H 3 OO^ S
U cu
CuSoo
-200ogo
o.o.^00
W5 5
WDWD
Wp
h agg csc g
o

Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
284 J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293

"new" Member States compared to the "old" Member "old" and "new" EU Member States could be the result of
States. Moreover, we observe that the standard deviation of a less competitive market structure in the EU-10 countries,
both the price of loans and the price of deposits is larger in which is likely to allow banks to price the cost of inefficient
the case of EU- 10 banking systems, suggesting substantial operation into interest rates thereby extracting oligopolistic
cross-country variations across new EU Member States rents16 (see also Holo and Nagy 2006; Kosak and Zajc
(see also, ECB 2005, 2010). 2009). Our findings also indicate that allocative ineffi-
ciency tends to be a much larger source of potential profit
loss than technical inefficiency in both regions. In partic-
ular, the average technical efficiency score for the EU- 15
5 Empirical results banks for the whole period under investigation is estimated
at 0.15, while the average allocative component is 3.5
5.1 Profit efficiency estimates times higher standing at 0.52. Similarly, for the EU-10
region, average technical efficiency is estimated at 0.23,
Table 2 reports estimates of average profit efficiency and while the allocative efficiency estimate is 1.16. Hence,
its decomposition for the sample of banks from the EU- 15 overall profit inefficiency in the EU- 15 and EU-10 banking
and the EU-10 regions, over the period 1998-2008. The industries may be attributed, to a much greater extent, to
difference between optimal and actual profits is equal to the choosing the incorrect input-output mix rather than to the
gain in profit realized by removing technical inefficiency underutilization or wasting of resources.
(i.e. the gain in revenue from any potential output increase Regarding the evolution of profit efficiency and its
and the decline in costs from any potential reduction in components over time (see Figs. 1, 2, 3), we observe that
input use) and the gain realized by removing allocative profit inefficiency in the EU-10 region has generally
inefficiency (i.e. using an optimal input/output mix). deviated from the EU- 15 trend, and aside from a short lived
Table 2 also reports the number of banks on the efficient improvement in 2006/2007, this gap has generally widened
frontier for each year examined, i.e. banks that have zero since 2003. More specifically, technical inefficiency in the
technical inefficiency. We find that on average about 3 EU region decreased from 1998 to 2002, with efficiency
percent of the banks have been on the efficiency frontier improvements being more pronounced for EU- 15 banks.
over the period 1998-2008. For EU-10 countries, these improvements are likely to
Technical efficiency is estimated using a directional reflect the effects of an intensifying banking reform process
vector equal to the mean values of outputs and (variable) and increasing level of competition due to entry of foreign
inputs in each year and a value of zero for the fixed input; investors, as a result of low government entry barriers,
that is we set the directional vector, g = (jtv,0,;y). For particularly in nations that reduced their state bank
example, for year 1998 we have g - (jci,J2,J3, 2,^1,^2) = ownership.17
(54.7, 69.0, 3888.1, 0, 2571.7, 2166.7). Thus, given that This period was characterized by unprecedented level of
the directional distance function gives the expansion in consolidation through mergers and acquisitions aimed at
outputs and contraction in inputs multiplied by the direc- reaping profitability, reducing cost inefficiency, increasing
tional vector and since >i998e/-i5 = (x,y,z;gX9gy) = 0.7, market power, and exploiting scale and scope economies.
if the average EU- 15 bank were to operate technically However, these gains were short-lived and completely
efficiently in 1998, it could expand loans by 0.233 x reversed post 2002 as an increasing gap emerged between
2,571.7 = 599.2 (m); expand other earning assets by EU-10 and EU- 15 credit institutions. According to the
0.2337 x 2,166.7 = 504.8 (m), while spending 0.2337 x European Central Bank (ECB 2003), the improved per-
54.7 = 12.7 (m) less on labor, using 0.2337 x 69 = 16.1 formance of EU- 15 banks at the time was associated with
(m) less physical capital and 0.2337 x 3,888.1 = 905.9 the introduction of organizational changes (e.g. outsourc-
(m) less deposits. When we add the allocative component ing); the centralization of information technology and
of inefficiency, for the average EU- 15 bank to earn maxi- back-office activities, and the establishment of unified
mum profits outputs and inputs have to be reallocated and platforms, aiming at reducing cost, standardizing operating
lost profits as a proportion of the normalized value of the and information procedures and exploiting specialization
directional vector, p x y -h w x x, is 0.7. according to the customer segment.
Table 2 shows that the average profit efficiency score
for the EU- 15 and EU-10 regions is estimated at 0.66 and 16 This is consistent with the higher interest margin observed in EU-
10 countries compared to EU- 15 banking systems as discussed above.
1.39, respectively, for the period 1998-2008. This suggests
17 Through an intense process of restructuring and growth in the
that, on average, banks in the 'old' EU regime outperform
enlarged market, EU-10 banks adopted strategies aimed at improving
credit institutions in the new EU member states in terms of
efficiency, expanding output and increasing the range of services
profit efficiency. The efficiency gap observed between offered (Goddard et al. 2001).

Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293 285

S "3
__
__ w o in N
oo S S-i S S Ba "fi
<n on N. oo on 1 *5 a
V N ^ h i i oo ^ es o in 5 ^ u o a
Ch
< 35 <N - < rn in C> i g n N ^ (S ^ H 5 4 ^ s
On O t O ^ m ^-3 O O ^ 5g fi J2
u c
o *o c3

5 Pas 1*1 Pas


oo22
oo ^HSooo^iTto^ oo^ 0'
oo ^ <n r ^ ri r^ r-Hen 5 jm
o vo o' jo
>? .. 2
<&& o o
g r-^O<NV0(N^ ^ H (N (S fn ON On H -2 h
CS O N O Ci O ^ i- (S N O < h n h Sc -S
'3 G

11*
^ (S "( oo oo s, vo
s . 1 1
3* m pn m O *n ^ c fi
^ p: "<fr lO CS <N i-h <n S vo 00 VO 00 ^ CS y O O
o ^ ^ ^ ^ t ! iri es vq es > on <n -h ooe
es o ^ o t o t ^ ^ o t d ^

lU
S <
sO8 h? h
> ?
h ^(V)
O aO
S n(NS S^ "O S (S(S
n "O > ^> OO$ fN
fN 5
^ U22 -o
I U i33
CS ^tO^Tj- CSNOtcSCNCS ^ CC C
O Z P
fige;
en o
So

On -a ooo 0
0
W-. Tf io es [n es 3- - m rn io es K. oo 'S . g ..
W-.
S h g(N
es h
io (y)
m [nintxon
Os ^es Tt
- in'ojojo
io N
<N>o es
oo fs
es Qh.
fi
hh..
es d ^ d t d t en ^H^ot^H^r^ S .2
o S K
It*
*n -a ^ 00 *n S S I ^
i io m (N h io N o o (S 5 oo fri h Sog
H io ^ ^ o On es 5 ^ H fri 'o ^ S'pfi
t es ies
o-^oto^^t o-^oto^^t
N io CS m H (N Oy io h CS io O ^ N 4 ^ o V o^'
^' O On vo
(S es 5t
^ tX t oo ^
H ^ fri n
'o ^ ^ h n 00 S'pfi
fio fifiSS Sog fio
O Q.

li
s s |
ggnono
M S(N
(N !hh fr)
^ fr) m
mS o
S o^5
ri on
ones es
XS^^ ^<n
<n oo
OnOn S^ SSS Iu
es ^ t ^ oo o^ototo "gfi'S
X
2g
S
ONON pQ
t? 8>
8
M #vi Tt 0' es oo es t' ^ ^ tv. m oo vo oj'5 ^
#vi g ON^cnovoor^ en vo oo ^ vo en J ^ g
O g ^ ^ h in (N ^ es oo (N o io ^ ^
"O
es ^ t ^ m -h ^ t - * *- ^ t . -
2 <X g <
ti ^ -
0

t .2 g . 3
g 's
Tt 5 (N h ^ ^ m o' h m > c o >
en o 55
o
om opop
gm Tt Onoh Qft)
^o ^vQesoo
Tt^omvhesonMrn
es >^ nOo.pC
On h<G<G
> ^
1 es o N o t t ^ ^ o t -i t m o t?
m
I
|i^
i

g "<fr <L
G J

ON w -2 o
i
> ^ 4 !0 On O N 00 lo On fn oo C^, -H p e o ^
cn in vo > o 4 rH<^
in^ !0 o
On enrH<^
on O N. oo ^ Nen
^ P 00 ooo
lo ^ io ^
'I es On
P^ fn
^ oo'I
oo^oo
on C^,
v -H Ttvtfi p,
p, p e o"a
es N 6 t o t r-H- ^ d t d t "*t v tt-i ^ a ^
0
tt-i . t> a ^

1 -p-a ?H
II
2 I
0

w -. it in o o *o oo - > * > ~Oft,g>


-. S 4 (N in N oo n o) ^-Noo^cs^o > > ec
g ND N -H Tt n O O ^ ^ ^ 00 00 H ec ^DSti
1 - o ^ o t o ^ *o ^ o t o t en 13 g u
> g fi u
0
gal 85
8 5 J.T3
ON a >H y
a
oo
ON r- a fi S >H "| y
opcncNr-oOf ^voesjnoNO S *a
"S3
oo hS CN
5 o *o
es m
JNJN
5 #5o'Nvri-hm(n N,
en ot' oo 5 oo
r- 5 h on
fi efi ti
e g*9ti &g

1 *- ^ t t m ^-^dtdtcn g | ? o
Hi 5
0


c*

1 Ci s i e i!!| u o -a
1
i Ci e u o -a

D i _,_,r r<2H5<2
UQh Ci555E? r 5 <r.oJsESi
ZWO-i u o -a
H 5 < ZHtiti.0

Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
286 J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293

Swedish banks at 0.404, 0.408 and 0.464, respectively.


Latvian banks are on average the most profit efficient
among EU-10 banks with an average score of 0.501. 18
Greek banks with an average efficiency score of 3.001 and
Finish banks at 2.656 yield the highest average estimates
of profit inefficiency in the EU sample, closely followed
by Irish (2.648), Portuguese (2.395), Spanish (2.303) and
Hungarian banks (2.183).
Following a suggestion by an anonymous referee, we
have also computed ratios of actual to optimal (profit
maximizing) input use and output production to assess in
more detail banks' allocative efficiency performance. Our

Fig. 1 Profit Efficiency (EU- 15 vs. EU- 10)


estimates show that the majority of EU- 15 banks tend to
over utilize labor. This is particularly evident in the case of
banks in Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Greece,
Luxembourg, Netherlands and Poland. On the other hand,
there is no evidence of labor overuse for the majority of
banks in EU-10 countries. In particular, we find that the
bulk of banks in Estonia and Latvia tend to underutilize
labor. We also find that most EU-25 banks tend to over

utilize physical capital. The main exceptions are banks in


Denmark, Ireland, Italy and Sweden. Moreover, our results
indicate that on average banks in all EU-25 countries
overuse deposits. With regards to output mix, we find that
banks in Belgium, Czech Republic, Latvia, Luxembourg,
Malta and Slovakia appear to under-produce loans relative
to other earning assets, while the bulk of banks in the
Fig. 2 Technical Efficiency (EU- 15 vs. EU- 10)
remaining EU countries appear to over-produce loans rel-
ative to other earning assets.
Regarding the evolution of efficiency scores, profit
efficiency displays diverging patterns across the EU
countries over the period 1998-2008. Profit efficiency
appears to be on the decline for the majority of EU member
states during that period. More specifically, the largest
declines are estimated for Hungary, followed by France,
Slovakia, Ireland and Poland and are almost entirely due to
a sharp increase in allocative inefficiency. While Hungar-
ian banks were not directly exposed to the toxic US sub-
prime market, they suffered immensely during the
2007/2008 global financial crisis as a result of foreign-
Fig. 3 Allocative Efficiency (EU- 15 vs. EU- 10)
currency exposures but also as a result of a very weak
domestic economy characterized by large external and
government deficits. On the other hand, our results indicate
Table 3 presents more detailed information on the profit that Sweden exhibits the highest improvement in terms of
efficiency for each EU banking sector. Overall, we observe profit efficiency over time. This may in part reflect the
considerable variation of efficiency scores across countries considerable effort that went into strengthening the coun-
and different patterns in efficiency change over time. These try's banking system at the aftermath of a major banking
differences may in part be explained by interest rate dif- crisis in the early 1990s.
ferentials between countries as well as changes in the
general level of interest rates overtime. 18 These countries, with the exception of Germany, also exhibit the
largest dispersion in profit efficiency scores as measured by the
German banks appear, on average, to be the most profit
coefficient of variation over the sample period 1998-2008. In
efficient, with an average efficiency score of 0.333 over particular, according to our estimates, Latvia has experienced a
the sample period, followed by Austrian, Danish and substantial drop in profit efficiency post 2005.

Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293 287

Table 3 Decomposition of profit efficiency by country

Country 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 98-08

Austria TI 0.187 0.110 0.147 0.158 0.145 0.122 0.110 0.089 0.097 0.092 0.066 0.111
0.382 0.296 0.444 0.538 0.481 0.423 0.296 0.142 0.299 0.321 0.193 0.360
AI 0.168 0.254 0.162 0.244 0.401 0.337 0.271 0.335 0.286 0.197 0.493 0.293
0.849 0.623 0.247 0.333 0.964 0.515 0.886 0.621 0.720 0.361 1.066 0.702
Til 0.354 0.365 0.309 0.402 0.546 0.459 0.381 0.424 0.383 0.289 0.558 0.404
0.933 0.763 0.666 0.794 1.397 0.868 1.170 0.731 0.983 0.651 1.219 0.956

Belgium TI 0.294 0.409 0.322 0.162 0.080 0.294 0.170 0.182 0.094 0.113 0.119 0.180
0.213 0.752 0.808 0.440 0.128 1.005 0.152 0.171 0.170 0.174 0.153 0.539
AI 0.660 0.752 0.481 0.688 0.678 0.446 0.219 0.712 1.128 0.736 2.098 0.711
0.630 1.375 0.437 1.493 0.560 0.684 0.399 1.564 2.015 0.664 2.185 1.213
n' 0.954 1.161 0.803 0.850 0.758 0.740 0.389 0.894 1.223 0.849 2.217 0.891
0.792 2.095 1.171 1.628 0.635 1.632 0.467 1.589 2.015 0.724 2.189 1.478

Cyprus TI 0.405 0.235 0.235 0.233 0.242 0.296 0.295 0.345 0.336 0.450 0.347 0.307
0.624 0.396 0.380 0.444 0.454 0.492 0.557 0.709 0.718 0.783 0.696 0.563
AI 0.742 0.743 0.900 0.641 1.156 0.867 0.785 0.897 0.859 1.067 1.568 0.916
0.935 1.034 1.052 0.777 1.773 0.973 1.242 1.191 1.232 1.695 2.458 1.315
ni 1.148 0.977 1.135 0.874 1.398 1.163 1.080 1.243 1.195 1.517 1.915 1.223
1.528 1.360 1.405 1.167 2.221 1.414 1.795 1.895 1.932 2.402 3.147 1.827

Czech Rep TI 0.629 0.313 0.297 0.319 0.291 0.266 0.341 0.464 0.439 0.415 0.260 0.319
1.023 0.492 0.506 0.579 0.466 0.501 0.509 0.596 0.801 0.726 0.354 0.596
AI 1.053 0.982 1.121 1.191 1.163 0.759 1.439 1.603 2.299 1.223 2.545 1.426
1.121 1.087 0.916 0.810 1.978 1.223 2.413 1.859 2.195 1.028 2.516 1.723
n' 1.682 1.295 1.418 1.510 1.454 1.025 1.780 2.067 2.738 1.638 2.805 1.745
1.731 1.417 1.341 1.284 2.410 1.655 2.911 2.407 2.937 1.721 2.793 2.167
Denmark TI 0.213 0.114 0.092 0.084 0.097 0.074 0.052 0.075 0.085 0.113 0.080 0.099
0.616 0.317 0.272 0.232 0.312 0.178 0.135 0.169 0.171 0.276 0.160 0.292
AI 0.486 0.421 0.262 0.216 0.320 0.268 0.208 0.182 0.289 0.290 0.465 0.309
0.946 0.706 0.274 0.250 0.604 0.290 0.386 0.313 0.711 0.926 1.030 0.648
Til 0.699 0.535 0.354 0.300 0.417 0.342 0.260 0.257 0.374 0.403 0.544 0.408
1.419 1.006 0.468 0.447 0.805 0.440 0.444 0.380 0.747 1.135 1.067 0.834
Estonia TI 0.183 0.099 0.080 0.124 0.140 0.162 0.158 0.279 0.268 0.286 0.034 0.173
0.196 0.118 0.116 0.198 0.218 0.248 0.251 0.477 0.498 0.551 0.039 0.303
AI 1.770 0.967 1.207 1.397 2.025 0.740 1.116 0.516 1.031 2.236 1.382 1.308
1.812 1.388 1.518 1.712 2.952 1.127 1.949 0.453 1.404 3.110 2.166 1.803
Jl 1.953 1.067 1.286 1.521 2.166 0.902 1.274 0.795 1.300 2.522 1.415 1.463
2.005 1.500 1.629 1.903 3.169 1.374 2.199 0.912 1.441 3.638 2.204 2.006
Finland TI 2.332 0.945 0.300 0.656 0.265 0.668 0.405 0.531 0.489 0.779 0.870 0.769
3.232 1.320 0.000 0.970 0.151 0.961 0.508 0.523 0.492 1.007 1.325 1.099
AI 1.814 2.507 1.868 0.453 1.109 1.637 1.533 3.066 2.292 2.328 2.476 1.887
1.171 2.298 0.000 3.132 0.427 2.237 1.843 3.050 2.740 2.928 1.873 2.112
ni 4.146 3.452 2.168 1.109 1.374 2.305 1.939 3.597 2.781 3.107 3.346 2.656
4.404 3.618 0.000 2.245 0.578 3.198 2.351 3.572 3.232 3.934 2.932 2.743
France TI 0.424 0.412 0.367 0.339 0.310 0.346 0.281 0.434 0.517 0.488 0.425 0.391
0.558 0.619 0.492 0.446 0.372 0.427 0.313 0.548 0.800 0.689 0.440 0.536
AI 0.572 0.352 0.496 0.739 1.119 0.980 1.533 1.805 1.316 1.385 2.595 1.127
0.799 1.857 0.902 0.887 1.215 1.306 1.663 1.947 1.727 1.352 1.628 1.545
ni 0.995 0.763 0.862 1.078 1.429 1.326 1.814 2.239 1.834 1.873 3.020 1.519
1.060 1.725 1.253 1.187 1.456 1.494 1.856 2.300 2.040 1.747 1.919 1.769

Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
288 J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293

Table 3 continued

Country 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 98-08

Germany TI 0.148 0.098 0.085 0.089 0.100 0.109 0.115 0.099 0.098 0.077 0.065 0.097
0.234 0.162 0.145 0.149 0.174 0.211 0.200 0.187 0.215 0.149 0.137 0.182

AI 0.242 0.202 0.119 0.110 0.182 0.178 0.252 0.341 0.262 0.271 0.389 0.236
0.386 0.310 0.227 0.218 0.499 0.511 0.589 0.490 0.504 0.543 0.690 0.486

ni 0.389 0.300 0.203 0.198 0.282 0.287 0.368 0.440 0.359 0.348 0.454 0.333

0.547 0.417 0.333 0.328 0.624 0.609 0.728 0.642 0.663 0.621 0.798 0.603

Greece TI 1.821 0.506 0.812 1.048 0.579 0.883 0.784 0.888 0.511 0.759 0.412 0.773

1.302 0.714 0.939 1.110 0.928 1.099 1.342 1.099 0.677 0.965 0.441 0.995

AI 1.856 4.242 2.772 2.278 2.180 1.938 1.997 1.660 3.597 0.709 1.814 2.234

1.514 3.198 1.646 2.182 2.542 1.315 2.512 1.755 2.379 0.926 1.090 2.119

ni 3.676 4.748 3.584 3.326 2.759 2.822 2.781 2.549 4.109 1.469 2.226 3.007
2.384 3.459 2.181 2.427 3.418 2.212 3.379 2.765 2.895 1.317 1.448 2.652

Hungary TI 0.439 0.201 0.223 0.218 0.229 0.296 0.420 0.524 0.412 0.416 0.475 0.338
0.622 0.277 0.244 0.260 0.282 0.336 0.364 0.545 0.306 0.293 0.271 0.360

AI 0.913 0.767 1.195 1.373 1.471 1.606 2.153 2.367 4.221 1.399 3.191 1.846

0.594 0.561 0.776 0.826 1.629 1.160 1.486 1.980 3.677 1.043 1.643 1.841

ni 1.352 0.968 1.418 1.591 1.700 1.902 2.573 2.891 4.634 1.815 3.666 2.183

0.927 0.758 0.948 1.011 1.902 1.452 1.836 2.513 3.877 1.309 1.894 2.086

Ireland TI 0.165 0.692 0.091 0.170 0.668 0.803 0.312 0.659 0.696 0.730 1.057 0.562

0.178 1.411 0.118 0.234 1.481 1.633 0.566 1.140 1.275 1.045 0.629 1.137

AI 2.351 2.522 2.151 2.600 2.508 2.783 0.637 0.003 2.019 2.943 4.275 2.086

0.798 1.569 1.384 1.909 2.198 1.492 0.516 2.492 1.668 2.880 2.245 2.179

ni 2.517 3.214 2.243 2.770 3.176 3.587 0.949 0.662 2.715 3.673 5.332 2.648
0.754 2.793 1.357 1.997 3.179 2.863 1.039 2.748 2.286 3.114 2.872 2.747

Italy TI 0.223 0.096 0.080 0.086 0.058 0.076 0.235 0.111 0.082 0.079 0.051 0.094
0.633 0.296 0.249 0.260 0.149 0.207 0.305 0.354 0.246 0.245 0.149 0.302
AI 0.572 0.623 0.593 0.630 0.706 0.761 1.624 0.615 0.853 0.285 0.595 0.642

0.777 0.805 0.929 1.020 1.238 1.165 1.741 0.801 1.283 0.930 1.111 1.062

ni 0.795 0.719 0.673 0.716 0.764 0.836 1.859 0.726 0.935 0.364 0.646 0.736
1.203 1.043 1.139 1.210 1.367 1.334 1.969 1.095 1.421 1.127 1.235 1.259

Latvia TI 0.024 0.013 0.021 0.030 0.037 0.040 0.060 0.075 0.084 0.074 0.074 0.051
0.051 0.018 0.028 0.038 0.049 0.055 0.077 0.104 0.097 0.093 0.072 0.072

AI 0.229 0.201 0.208 0.371 0.232 0.198 0.332 0.470 1.486 0.319 0.809 0.451

0.227 0.219 0.290 0.371 0.280 0.247 0.359 0.284 1.766 0.484 1.234 0.797

ni 0.254 0.215 0.228 0.401 0.269 0.237 0.392 0.545 1.570 0.393 0.883 0.501
0.273 0.235 0.317 0.407 0.327 0.300 0.435 0.379 1.857 0.552 1.275 0.846

Lithuania TI 0.104 0.046 0.041 0.042 0.056 0.077 0.111 0.167 0.138 0.149 0.140 0.098

0.119 0.065 0.058 0.064 0.070 0.097 0.117 0.173 0.144 0.151 0.132 0.117

AI 0.445 0.883 0.645 0.655 0.456 0.444 0.545 0.955 2.968 0.667 1.592 0.949

0.356 0.957 0.799 0.763 0.625 0.543 0.606 0.713 2.881 0.746 1.619 1.364
ni 0.548 0.929 0.686 0.696 0.513 0.521 0.656 1.122 3.106 0.816 1.732 1.047
0.447 1.022 0.853 0.826 0.692 0.637 0.718 0.880 2.995 0.841 1.729 1.441

Luxembourg TI 0.188 0.155 0.165 0.204 0.226 0.193 0.182 0.204 0.216 0.294 0.268 0.203
0.432 0.344 0.390 0.440 0.479 0.398 0.412 0.496 0.458 0.565 0.558 0.442

AI 2.081 1.094 0.825 1.115 1.727 1.211 1.672 2.033 2.333 1.984 2.841 1.609

2.466 1.676 1.095 1.305 2.424 1.885 2.468 1.971 2.278 1.865 2.738 2.069

ni 2.269 1.249 0.990 1.319 1.953 1.405 1.855 2.236 2.549 2.279 3.108 1.812
2.660 1.863 1.321 1.572 2.693 2.110 2.633 2.259 2.585 2.280 3.013 2.308

Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293 289

Table 3 continued

Country 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 98-08

Malta TI 0.238 0.203 0.164 0.177 0.174 0.154 0.160 0.176 0.188 0.139 0.136 0.171
0.249 0.209 0.202 0.217 0.211 0.206 0.212 0.238 0.220 0.184 0.156 0.192

AI 0.776 0.671 0.851 0.871 0.873 0.804 0.903 1.252 1.334 0.649 1.274 0.938

0.627 0.626 0.662 0.653 0.692 0.674 0.761 0.763 1.319 0.366 1.100 0.748

7cl 1.014 0.874 1.015 1.048 1.047 0.957 1.063 1.428 1.522 0.788 1.411 1.108

0.870 0.835 0.775 0.794 0.856 0.833 0.938 0.973 1.526 0.537 1.246 0.895

Country 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 98-08

Netherlands TI 0.567 0.457 0.405 0.503 0.288 0.317 0.258 0.491 0.323 0.158 0.227 0.366
1.240 0.776 0.803 0.885 0.518 0.747 0.565 0.965 0.635 0.162 0.295 0.745

AI 0.914 1.842 1.302 1.145 2.421 1.833 1.187 0.852 1.476 0.572 2.001 1.457
0.706 2.284 1.714 1.491 2.833 2.668 1.758 3.106 2.123 0.518 1.537 2.113

ni 1.481 2.298 1.707 1.647 2.710 2.150 1.444 1.343 1.799 0.730 2.228 1.825

1.647 2.690 2.097 2.158 3.066 2.740 1.991 2.626 2.357 0.579 1.697 2.312

Poland TI 0.582 0.294 0.329 0.421 0.201 0.288 0.324 0.342 0.385 0.507 0.327 0.363
1.011 0.464 0.458 0.581 0.243 0.437 0.343 0.357 0.361 0.530 0.301 0.519

AI 0.808 1.163 1.187 1.500 1.647 0.975 1.837 1.376 2.167 1.717 2.821 1.498

0.796 0.998 1.026 1.259 1.945 1.276 2.348 1.343 1.928 1.487 2.201 1.579

Tel 1.391 1.457 1.516 1.921 1.848 1.263 2.161 1.718 2.552 2.223 3.148 1.860

1.270 1.261 1.361 1.615 2.083 1.596 2.673 1.652 2.140 1.959 2.450 1.846

Portugal TI 0.987 0.427 0.689 0.918 0.212 0.380 0.689 0.262 0.360 0.349 0.298 0.522
1.617 0.666 1.190 1.422 0.245 0.551 1.409 0.246 0.334 0.286 0.262 0.940

AI 1.863 2.283 1.959 1.958 1.761 2.133 1.272 1.497 3.194 0.534 1.761 1.873
1.321 2.095 1.418 1.612 1.239 1.631 0.645 0.809 1.584 0.480 1.541 1.481
ni 2.850 2.710 2.648 2.876 1.973 2.513 1.962 1.758 3.554 0.883 2.060 2.395

2.715 2.474 2.553 2.979 1.436 2.122 1.550 0.931 1.771 0.744 1.784 2.132

Slovakia TI 0.113 0.119 0.133 0.148 0.147 0.151 0.201 0.196 0.215 0.198 0.252 0.176
0.118 0.187 0.171 0.179 0.191 0.190 0.242 0.251 0.277 0.218 0.226 0.210

AI 0.332 0.179 0.421 1.097 0.813 0.657 1.161 1.384 1.307 0.756 2.647 1.049

0.181 0.248 0.442 0.772 0.887 0.578 1.228 1.087 1.270 0.388 1.947 1.138

tcI 0.446 0.298 0.554 1.246 0.961 0.808 1.362 1.580 1.522 0.954 2.899 1.225
0.117 0.435 0.608 0.934 1.067 0.742 1.461 1.312 1.524 0.562 2.148 1.304

Slovenia TI 0.334 0.126 0.060 0.131 0.139 0.130 0.159 0.173 0.174 0.102 0.131 0.144
0.457 0.185 0.041 0.212 0.216 0.176 0.194 0.253 0.255 0.087 0.159 0.211

AI 1.306 1.102 0.770 0.914 0.903 0.820 1.098 0.872 2.291 0.389 1.372 1.073

0.706 0.820 0.551 0.656 1.173 0.734 1.234 0.520 1.972 0.343 1.476 1.135

Til 1.640 1.228 0.830 1.046 1.042 0.950 1.257 1.045 2.465 0.491 1.503 1.217
1.088 0.979 0.585 0.832 1.382 0.877 1.415 0.703 2.169 0.396 1.626 1.284

Spain TI 0.917 0.519 0.478 0.523 0.394 0.525 0.542 0.509 0.352 0.577 0.260 0.492
1.034 0.601 0.563 0.661 0.430 0.609 0.523 0.790 0.485 0.628 0.346 0.646

AI 1.563 1.813 1.585 1.384 2.249 2.278 2.515 1.260 2.399 1.571 1.698 1.811

0.968 1.129 1.170 1.701 1.926 1.564 1.851 1.286 2.345 1.916 2.088 1.753

7cl 2.480 2.332 2.064 1.907 2.643 2.803 3.057 1.769 2.750 2.148 1.958 2.303

1.586 1.538 1.609 1.882 2.300 2.020 2.215 1.961 2.760 2.379 2.398 2.153

Sweden TI 0.999 0.128 0.655 0.104 0.094 0.077 0.071 0.069 0.063 0.035 0.015 0.084
1.302 0.217 1.172 0.462 0.436 0.373 0.449 0.268 0.231 0.109 0.017 0.384

AI 2.260 1.967 1.446 0.283 0.556 0.371 0.167 0.381 0.347 0.326 0.133 0.379

1.887 1.938 1.304 0.611 1.643 0.901 0.486 1.272 1.232 1.247 0.141 1.124

Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
290 J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293

Table 3 continued

Country 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 98-08

n' 3.260 2.095 2.101 0.387 0.650 0.448 0.238 0.450 0.410 0.362 0.147 0.464

2.442 1.970 1.631 0.874 1.913 1.071 0.930 1.511 1.451 1.328 0.155 1.349

UK TI 0.413 0.494 0.437 0.378 0.340 0.241 0.291 0.365 0.333 0.254 0.190 0.334

0.611 0.773 0.736 0.530 0.534 0.474 0.650 0.687 0.694 0.570 0.446 0.615

AI 1.732 1.953 1.902 1.717 2.025 0.917 0.793 1.233 1.221 0.843 1.160 1.372

1.437 1.607 1.568 1.287 2.435 1.221 1.434 1.321 1.428 1.307 1.369 1.571

ni 2.145 2.447 2.339 2.095 2.365 1.158 1.084 1.599 1.555 1.097 1.350 1.706

1.610 2.116 1.917 1.588 2.850 1.360 1.962 1.905 1.998 1.606 1.706 1.961

The table reports means and SD (in italics) of profit efficiency over time for each EU-25 country and its decomposition into technical and
allocative efficiency. TI denotes technical efficiency, measured by the value of the directional distance function; nl denotes profit efficiency; AI
denotes allocative efficiency

Overall, we find different patterns in efficiency change percent of total observations, while most banks are clas-
over time in the EU banking markets. These diverging sified as small (50 percent).
trends may reflect the legacy of different banking regula- Table 4 presents the average profit efficiency scores
tions and the different structures of the financial systems over time for credit institutions of different size categories.
across the member states but also the fragility of the dif- Overall, we observe a negative relationship between size
ferent banking systems to domestic and international eco- and efficiency. Our results indicate that small banks appear
nomic developments. Our results offer no clear indication to be the most profit efficient and also the most technical
supporting the view that an enlarged EU market for efficient, followed by medium-sized banks. This superior
financial services has given rise to far more robust banking performance by the small banks is evident throughout the
structures. In part, the problem may be that many of these entire period under investigation. A possible explanation is
banking systems continue to be fragmented or lack effec- that small banks, which operate mostly in local (niche)
tive supervision. But it may also be the case that a rapid markets and have access to 4 soft' information about local
rise in cross border exposures has made these systems more conditions, engage in relationship banking and exercise
fragile to adverse external and internal shocks. The severity some monopoly power, which allows them to earn more
of the recent financial and economic crisis is largely profit.19 The large efficiency differentials we find between
associated with the combined effects of excessive risk- large banks and smaller banks are of notable relevance to
taking and bad lending decisions of banks facing a squeeze the current regulatory policy debate on bank size.
on profits as regulatory barriers were lifted and competition
became more intense.
6 Conclusion

5.2 Profit efficiency estimates by bank size


This paper investigates the profit efficiency of the Euro-
Although EU banks have similar organizational structure pean Union banking industry, using a non-parametric
and objectives, they vary significantly in size. Thus, as a directional technology distance function approach, over the
next step, we examine whether or not there is a relationship period 1998-2008. During this period, a number of sig-
between size and inefficiency levels. This issue is of direct nificant events took place, among them the most notable
relevance in the current environment as regulators in many being the EU enlargement with 10 new member states and
countries seem to have an increasing aversion towards very the 2007/2008 subprime and global financial crises. These
large banks mainly due the systemic risks they may pres-
ent. We divide banks into three subgroups according to the 19 Following an anonymous referee's suggestion and given that our
sample is dominated by small and medium sized German banks, we
size of their balance sheet aggregates: large (with assets
recalculated average profit inefficiency for banks of different size-
more than 10,000 million), medium (with total assets classes excluding German banks from our sample in order to assess
between 500 million and 10,000 million) and small (with whether the over-performance of small banks is due to the institu-
assets less than 500 million). The large bank sample is tional/regulatory structure of Germany and not because of their small
size. Overall, our conclusions remain valid and average inefficiency
relatively small to ensure that only truly large banks are
estimates for small and medium-sized banks remain broadly
included and represents about 6 percent of total observa- unchanged. Nevertheless, when excluding German banks, average
tions. On the other hand, medium-sized banks represent 44 profit inefficiency for large banks increases.

Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293 291

Table 4 Decomposition of Profit Efficiency by bank size

1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 98-08

Small (<500 mil.euros) TI 0.039 0.020 0.017 0.017 0.018 0.019 0.023 0.018 0.017 0.014 0.011 0.019
0.030 0.015 0.013 0.013 0.013 0.014 0.015 0.014 0.013 0.010 0.008 0.016

AI 0.154 0.150 0.104 0.111 0.117 0.120 0.082 0.211 0.119 0.066 0.098 0.123

0.195 0.170 0.136 0.145 0.138 0.158 0.071 0.102 0.138 0.055 0.082 0.139

ni 0.193 0.170 0.120 0.128 0.135 0.139 0.105 0.230 0.136 0.080 0.109 0.142
0.204 0.172 0.138 0.147 0.141 0.159 0.076 0.106 0.141 0.061 0.085 0.143

Medium (500 <... < 10, 000 mil. euros) TI 0.325 0.202 0.172 0.177 0.177 0.178 0.176 0.182 0.161 0.134 0.104 0.177
0.351 0.200 0.177 0.179 0.174 0.174 0.161 0.178 0.155 0.131 0.102 0.190

AI 0.770 0.658 0.556 0.610 0.760 0.656 0.633 0.736 0.893 0.468 0.819 0.689

0.803 0.725 0.724 0.767 1.084 0.838 0.881 0.704 1.152 0.421 0.858 0.847

ni 1.095 0.860 0.727 0.787 0.937 0.834 0.809 0.918 1.053 0.602 0.924 0.866
0.996 0.830 0.805 0.859 1.188 0.925 0.984 0.828 1.231 0.512 0.934 0.947

Large (>10,000 mil. euros) TI 1.957 1.217 1.135 1.188 1.042 1.106 1.017 1.263 1.071 0.958 0.698 1.108
1.389 1.025 0.910 0.962 0.931 1.041 0.935 0.972 0.962 0.829 0.549 0.977

AI 1.816 2.680 2.296 2.169 4.309 3.169 3.439 3.200 3.673 2.789 4.267 3.130

3.434 3.065 1.787 2.267 2.423 2.252 2.920 2.583 2.535 2.238 1.691 2.550

ni 3.773 3.897 3.432 3.356 5.352 4.274 4.456 4.463 4.743 3.748 4.965 4.238

3.640 3.066 2.154 2.491 2.714 2.431 3.124 2.870 2.698 2.466 1.869 2.709

The table reports means and SD (in italics) of profit efficiency over time for banks of different size classes and its decomposition into technical
and allocative efficiency. TI denotes technical efficiency, measured by the value of the directional distance; nl denotes profit efficiency; AI
denotes allocative efficiency

developments have raised questions about competitiveness, the intense restructuring process that was in place during
bank size, ownership type and structure and the fragility of that period and the increasing presence of foreign investors
credit institutions to global financial and domestic eco- that enhanced competitive pressures. However, our find-
nomic conditions, and have brought the issue of bank ings indicate that there is overall a negative trend in profit
efficiency at the forefront. Profit efficiency is inextricably efficiency over the period 1998-2008 and this is more
linked with the ability of banks to absorb bad debts and pronounced for EU- 10 credit institutions.
hence with the ability of banking systems to withstand Regarding the issue of whether there are differences in
systemic shocks. This is a particularly sensitive issue in the bank profit efficiency across the EU countries, our findings
EU context. European rather than U.S. banks were the first indicate considerable variation and different patterns in
to be struck by the 2007 subprime crisis. And the European efficiency scores across banks and banking systems. Our
Central Bank, not the US Fed, was the first central bank to results offer no clear indication that an enlarged EU market
come to the rescue of banks through large scale emergency for financial services has brought about robust beneficial
lending. While European banks funding needs at present changes in most banking systems. We find that the gap
far exceed those of any other banking system, rating between the old and new Europe has widened rather than
agencies have placed sovereign debt of some EU member shrunk and this is in spite of some signs of profit efficiency
states close to junk status. convergence in 2001-2003 and the technical efficiency
We address a number of issues related to bank perfor- gains EU- 10 banks made in 1998-2002.
mance in the EU countries. Regarding the question of We also investigated whether the size of financial
whether bank choices of inputs and outputs are consistent institutions has an effect on profit efficiency. Our results
with profit maximization, our results show significant profit show a negative relationship between size and efficiency,
inefficiency. This is mainly attributed to allocative ineffi- as small banks appear to be the most profit efficient credit
ciency, that is choosing the incorrect input-output mix institutions, while large banks are the most inefficient. This
rather than to the underutilization or wasting of resources. is an interesting finding in view of the current policy debate
EU- 15 banks appear, on average, to outperform their EU- regarding bank size.
10 counterparts. We associate profit efficiency improve- Overall, in light of increasing global financial pressures,
ments for the new EU member states in 1998-2002 with EU banks will need to further improve their performance in

Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
292 J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293

order to respond to new challenges lying ahead and to Devaney M, Weber WL (2002) Small-business lending and profit
efficiency in commercial banking. J Finan Serv Res 22(3):
survive in a highly competitive global environment. While 225-246
a rationalization of the industry is currently under way and European Central Bank (2003) Structural analysis of the EU banking
authorities are tightening the regulatory regime, the out- sector: year 2002. (ECB, November)
look for the EU economies is still uncertain and this European Central Bank (2005) Banking structures in the new EU
member states. (ECB, January)
imposes further strains on the quality of the banks' loan
European Central Bank (2010) Report on EU banking structure.
portfolios. (ECB, September)
Fre R, Grosskopf S (2004) New directions: efficiency and produc-
tivity. Kluwer Academic, Boston/London/Dordrecht
Fre R, Primont D (2003) Luenberger productivity indicators:
References
aggregation across firms. J Product Anal 20:425-435
Fre R, Grosskopf S, Weber W (2004) The effect of risk-based capital
Aigner D, Lovell C, Schmidt P (1977) Formulation and estimation of requirements on profit efficiency in banking. Appi Econ
stochastic frontier production function models. J Econom 36:1731-1743
6:21-37 Fre R, Grosskopf S, Margaritis D (2008) Efficiency and productivity:
Alam IMS (2001) A non-parametric approach for assessing productiv- Malmquist and more. In: Fried HO, Lovell CAK, Schmidt SS
ity dynamics of large banks. J Money Credit Bank 33:121-139 (eds) The measurement of productive efficiency and productivity
Allen L, Rai A (1996) Operational efficiency in banking: an growth. Oxford University Press, New York
international comparison. J Bank Financ 20:655-672 Goddard J, Molyneux P, Wilson J (2001) European banking:
Altunbas Y, Gardener EPM, Molyneux P, Moore B (2001) Efficiency efficiency, technology and growth. John Wiley & Sons LTD,
in European banking. Eur Econ Rev 45(10): 1931-1955 West Sussex, England
Becalli E, Casu B, Girardone C (2006) Efficiency and stock Grigorian D, Manle V (2002) Determinants of commercial bank
performance in European banking. J Bus Financ Account performance in transition: an application of data envelopment
33:245-262 analysis. The World Bank, Working Paper, No. 2850
Berg S, Forsund F, Jansen E (1992) Technical efficiency of Holo D, Nagy M (2006) Bank efficiency in the Enlarged European
Norwegian banks: the nonparametric approach to efficiency Union. MNB working papers 2006/3
measurement. J Product Anal 2:127-142 Hughes J, Moon C (1995) Measuring bank efficiency when managers
Berger A, Bonaccorsi di Patti E (2006) Capital structure and firm trade return for reduced risk. Working Paper (Department of
performance: a new approach to testing agency theory and an Economics, Rutgers University)
application to the banking industry. J Bank Financ 30:1065-1 102 Hughes JP, Lang W, Mester LJ, Moon C (1996) Efficient banking
Berger A, Humphrey D (1997) Efficiency of financial institutions: under interstate branching. J Money Credit Bank 28:1045-1071
international survey and direction of future research. Eur J Oper Isik I, Hassan MK (2003) Financial deregulation and total factor
Res 98:175-212 productivity change: an empirical study of Turkish commercial
Berger A, Mester L (1997) Inside the black box: what explains banks. J Bank Financ 27:1455-1485
differences in the efficiencies of financial institutions? J Bank Kosak, M, Zajc P (2009) The East-West efficiency gap in European
Financ 21(7):895-947 Banking. In: Morten et al. (eds) Competition and profitability in
Berger A, Mester L (2003) Explaining the dramatic changes in european financial services-strategic, systemic and policy issues.
performance of US banks: technological change, deregulation, Routledge
and dynamic changes in competition. J Financ Intermed Koutsomanoli-Filippaki A, Margaritis D, Staikouras C (2009a)
12:57-95 Efficiency and productivity growth in the banking indus-
Berger AN, De Young R, Genay H, Udell GF (2000) Globalization of try of Central and Eastern Europe. J Bank Financ 33:
financial institutions: evidence from cross-border banking per- 557-567
formance. In: Litan RE, Santomero A (eds) Brookings-Wharton Koutsomanoli-Filippaki A, Margaritis D, Staikouras C (2009b) Profit
papers on financial services No. 3 efficiency in the banking industry of Central and Eastern Europe:
Casu B, Girardone C (2004) Large banks' efficiency in the single A directional technology distance function approach. Manage
European market. Serv Ind J 24(6): 129- 142 Financ 35(3):276-296
Casu B, Girardone C (2005) An analysis of the relevance of off- Lozano- Vi vas A, Pastor JT, Hasan I (2001) European bank perfor-
balance sheet items in explaining productivity change in mance beyond country borders: what really matters? Eur Financ
European banking. Appi Financ Econ 15:1053-1061 Rev 5:141-165
Casu B, Girardone C (2006) Bank competition, concentration and Lozano-Vivas A, Pastor JT, Pastor JM (2002) An efficiency
efficiency in the Single European banking market. Manch Sch comparison of European banking systems operating under
74:441-468 different environmental conditions. J Product Anal 18:59-77
Casu B, Molyneux P (2003) A comparative study of efficiency in Maudos J, Pastor JM, Perez F, Quesada J (2002) Cost and profit
European banking. Appi Econ 35(1 7): 1865- 1876 efficiency in European banks. J Int Financ Mark Inst Money
Chambers R, Chung YH, Fre R (1996) Benefit and distance 12:33-58
functions. J Econ Theory 70:407-419 Mertens A, Urga G (2001) Efficiency, scale and scope economies in
Clark JA, Siems TF (2002) X-efficiency in banking: looking beyond the Ukrainian banking sector in 1998. Emerg Mark Rev
the balance sheet. J Money Credit Bank 34:987-1013 2:292-308
Cuesta RA, Orea L (2002) Mergers and technical efficiency in Molyneux P, Altunbas Y, Gardener E (1996) Efficiency in European
Spanish saving banks: a stochastic distance function approach. banking. Wiley, Chichester
J Bank Financ 26:2231-2247 Pastor JT, Lozano-Vivas A, Pastor JM (1997). Efficiency of European
De Guevara JF, Maudos J (2002) Inequalities in the efficiency of the banking systems: a correction by environmental variables.
banking sectors of the European Union. Appi Econ Lett Working Paper WP-EC 97-12. Instituto Valenciano de Investi-
9:541-544 gaciones Econmicas, S. A

) Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
J Prod Anal (2012) 37:277-293 293

Sealey C, Lindley J (1977) Inputs, outputs and a theory of production Shephard RW (1970) Theory of cost and production functions.
and cost of depository financial institutions. J Financ Princeton University Press, Princeton
32:1251-1266 Vander Vennet R (2002) Cost and profit efficiency of financial
Sheldon G (1999) Costs, competitiveness and the changing structure conglomerates and universal banks in Europe. J Money Credit
of European banking. Fondation Banque de France pour la Bank 34(l):254-282
Recherche Working Paper, France

Springer

This content downloaded from 197.255.68.201 on Wed, 06 Jul 2016 17:46:25 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi