Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 13

World Development Vol. 30, No. 1, pp.

107119, 2002
2001 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved
Printed in Great Britain
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev 0305-750X/01/$ - see front matter
PII: S0305-750X(01)00100-0

On the Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment to


Developing Countries: Is Africa Dierent?
ELIZABETH ASIEDU *
University of Kansas, Lawrence, KS, USA
Summary. This paper explores whether factors that aect Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) in
developing countries aect countries in sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) dierently. The results indicate
that: (a) a higher return on investment and better infrastructure have a positive impact on FDI to
non-SSA countries, but have no signicant impact on FDI to SSA; (b) openness to trade promotes
FDI to SSA and non-SSA countries; however, the marginal benet from increased openness is less
for SSA. These results imply that Africa is dierentsuggesting that policies that have been
successful in other regions may not be equally successful in Africa. 2001 Elsevier Science Ltd.
All rights reserved.

Key words Africa, capital ows, foreign direct investment, investment risk, developing countries

capital for investment. In addition, FDI brings


with it employment, managerial skills and
The African continent did not benet from the in- technology, and therefore it accelerates growth
creased investment ows to developing countries as and development. 3 The role of FDI as a source
a whole, in spite of the fact that the countries of the of capital has become increasingly important to
region undertook many eorts to attract invest- SSA. This stems from the fact that income
ment . . . (UNCTAD, 1995, p. iii).
levels and domestic savings in the region are
very low. As a result, external capital is needed
to supplement domestic savings in order to spur
investment and growth. Most countries in SSA,
however, do not have access to international
1. INTRODUCTION capital markets and therefore have to rely on
the other two forms of foreign nance: FDI
The past decade has witnessed a dramatic and ocial loans (e.g., loans from multilateral
increase in Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) to organizations such as the World Bank). 4 In
developing countries, with FDI increasing from addition, ocial lending to the region has
$24 billion (24% of total foreign investment) in declined substantially over the past decade
1990 to $178 billion (61% of total foreign ocial nance as a share of GNP has declined
investment) in 2000 (World Bank, 2001). This is from 6% in 1990 to 3.8% in 1998. Furthermore,
welcome news, especially for poor countries foreign aid per capita declined from an average
that do not have access to international capital of $35 over 198992 to about $28 over 199397
markets. As suggested by the above quote, (World Bank, 2000b). It is therefore imperative
however, Africa, the poorest region, did not for SSA to increase its share of FDI in order to
benet from the FDI boom despite eorts to compensate for the decline in ocial assistance.
attract FDI. 1 For example, over 198089 and
199098, FDI to sub-Saharan Africa (SSA)
grew by 59%. 2 This compares with an increase * I wish to thank Kwabena Gyimah-Brempong, James
of 5,200% for Europe and Central Asia, 942% Freeman, Ted Juhl, Donald Lien, Joseph Sicilian,
for East Asia and Pacic, 740% for South Asia, participants at the 2001 African Finance and Economics
455% for Latin America and Caribbean, and Association conference in New Orleans and two anon-
672% for all developing countries (World Bank, ymous referees for useful comments. I also wish to thank
2000a). Africa's inability to attract FDI is The University of Kansas for nancial support from the
troubling because FDI is crucial to the region. General Research Fund grant number 2301073. Final
The reason is that FDI provides the needed revision accepted: 27 August 2001.
107
108 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Unfortunately, for most countries in the region, can countries do not apply to them because the
eorts to attract FDI have been futile. circumstances dier so much. Hence, my anal-
One objective of this paper is to examine why ysis will shed light on ways via which policy
SSA has been relatively unsuccessful in makers in SSA can attract FDI.
attracting FDI. I nd the determinants of FDI The results can be summarized as follows: (i)
to developing countries and analyze whether Countries in SSA have on the average received
these variables have a dierential impact on less FDI than countries in other regions by
FDI ows to SSA. Specically, I use cross- virtue of their geographical location; (ii) Higher
sectional data on 71 developing countries to return on capital and infrastructure develop-
answer the following questions: (a) What ment promote FDI to non-SSA countries, but
factors drive FDI to developing countries? (b) have no signicant impact on FDI ows to SSA
Are these factors equally relevant for FDI to countries, ceteris paribus; (iii) Openness to
SSA? (c) Why has SSA attracted so little FDI? trade has a positive impact on FDI ows to
(d) Why has SSA been relatively unsuccessful in both SSA and non-SSA countries. However,
attracting FDI despite policy reform? Is Africa FDI to SSA is less responsive to changes in
dierent? openness than FDI to other regions. These
As regards question (a), note that, although results suggest that Africa is dierent!
there is an extensive literature on the determi- The remainder of the paper is organized as
nants of FDI to developing countries, most of follows: Section 2 presents some stylized facts
the analyses are based on a relatively small about FDI to Africa and Section 3 briey
number of countries. Furthermore, only a few reviews the empirical literature on the deter-
African countries are included in the samples. minants of FDI to developing countries.
For example, Gastanaga, Nugent, and Section 4 describes the data and the explana-
Pashamova (1998) consider 49 countries, six of tory variables. Section 5 presents the empirical
which are in SSA, while Schneider and Frey results and Section 6 discusses the results.
(1985) consider 51 countries of which 13 are in Section 7 concludes.
SSA. An exception is Edwards (1990), where 25
out of 51 countries are in SSA. My empirical
analysis employs a more comprehensive data-
setthe dataset includes 71 developing coun- 2. FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT TO
tries about half of which are in SSA (32 SSA AFRICA: STYLIZED FACTS
countries and 39 non-SSA countries). An
advantage of using a dataset that spans a large In this section, I summarize three stylized
set of countries is that it increases the degrees of facts about FDI that motivate my analysis. The
freedom and therefore enhances the credibility supporting data are presented in Tables 1 and
of the results. Furthermore, it allows me to test 2.
the extent to which the determinants of FDI
identied in previous studies explain the vari- (a) SSA has not beneted from the boom in FDI
ation in FDI for my comprehensive sample. that began in the mid-1980s
Regarding questions (b), (c) and (d), these
issues are yet to be addressed in the literature. During 198084 and 199497, the annual
Analyzing FDI ows to Africa is important average of FDI to developing countries
for several reasons. First, on the subject of increased by 1,630% while FDI to Africa
FDI, Africa remains underresearched. To the increased by 496%. As a result, Africa's share in
best of my knowledge, there is no published total FDI ows has dropped signicantly, from
empirical study on FDI that focuses exclusively 36% in 197074 to 10% in 198084 and to 3% in
on Africa. 5 This is surprising since, as pointed 199599 (Table 1). It is important to note that,
out earlier, FDI is crucial to the region. Second, although the continent as a whole has not fared
since FDI contributes to growth, it is important well in attracting FDI, some countries have
to know the factors that aect FDI ows to the been quite successful, especially in recent years.
slowest growth region, Africa. Third, to the For example, over 198993 to 199498, average
extent that FDI to SSA is driven by dierent net FDI to Tanzania, Uganda and Zimbabwe
factors, policies that have been successful in increased by 1,610%, 1,140% and 1,093%
other regions may not be equally successful in respectively. This compares to an increase of
SSA. Indeed, a number of African policy 240% for all developing countries (World Bank,
makers believe that the lessons from non-Afri- 2000a).
DETERMINANTS OF FDI 109

Table 1. Annual averages of net FDI inows to developing countries and selected regions (millions of dollars), 197099
FDI ows 197074 197579 198084 198589 199094 199599
All developing countries 2,058 5,967 8,896 15,222 25,347 153,805
East Asia & Pacic 464 1,034 2,346 5,588 26,352 60,342
Europe & Central Asia 58 65 87 341 4,469 20,784
Latin America & Caribbean 1,500 3,496 5,467 5,960 15,629 59,332
South Asia 50 71 163 350 863 3,693
Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) 741 803 866 1,337 1,847 5,170
SSA's share (%) 36 13 10 9 4 3
Source: World Bank (2000a).

Table 2. Rates of return on US FDI in Africa and selected regions, 199196


Region/sector 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996
Africa 30.6 28.4 25.8 24.6 35.3 34.2
Primary 35.4 29.1 26.1 23.9 34.2 36.9
Secondary 16 18.9 30.5 30.0 42.8 21.3
Tertiary NA 22.2 23.5 21.7 21.6 23.1
Other industries 28.4 40.8 13.5 44.1 35.0 17.4
Asia & Pacic 23.8 22.6 20.7 18.4 20.2 19.3
Latin America & Caribbean 12.1 14.3 14.9 15.3 13.1 12.8
Developing countries 15.9 17.2 16.9 16.5 15.8 15.3
All countries 11.6 10.4 11.1 11.7 13.3 12.5
Source: United Nations Center for Trade and Development (1999).

(b) FDI has become an important source of itythat attract or deter FDI. Table 3 presents
nance to SSA the eects of six variables that have been widely
used in the literature (for an extensive survey
Since 1990, FDI has outpaced (partially see Chakrabarti, 2001, and Gastanaga et al.,
substituted for) ocial lending (loans from 1998). Clearly, the results are conicting. The
multilateral organizations) in SSA. During objective of this paper is not to resolve the
199094 and 199599, net ocial ows declined conicting empirical results. 6 Instead, I exam-
by 24% whereas FDI increased by 180%. As a ine the extent to which the variables included in
consequence, FDI's share of total foreign previous studies explain the variation in FDI
investment has risen substantiallyfrom 7% for my sample and analyze whether these vari-
over 198084 to 10% over 199094 and 27% ables have a dierent impact on FDI to SSA.
over 199599 (World Bank, 2000a).

(c) The return on FDI to Africa is higher than 4. DESCRIPTION OF THE DATA AND
FDI to other regions THE VARIABLES
The average return on US investment to In determining the factors that aect FDI, it
Africa over 199196 was 30%. This compares is useful to distinguish between two types of
with 21% for Asia and Pacic, 14% for Latin FDI: market-seeking and non-market seeking.
America and 16% for all developing countries The main objective of market-seeking FDI is to
(Table 2). serve domestic markets. Here goods are
produced in the host country and sold in the
local market. As a consequence, this type of
3. A BRIEF LITERATURE REVIEW FDI is driven by domestic demand such as
large markets and high income in the host
Most of the empirical analyses on the deter- countrysuggesting that FDI in small and
minants of FDI use crosscountry regressions to poor countries is less likely to be market seek-
identify country characteristicssuch as ing. For non-market seeking FDI, goods are
market size, labor cost and political instabil- produced in the host country but sold abroad. 7
110 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 3. Eect of selected variables on FDI


Determinants of Positive Negative Insignicant
FDI
Real GDP per Schneider and Frey (1985) Edwards (1990) Loree and Guisinger (1995)
capita Tsai (1994) Jaspersen, Aylward, and Wei (2000)
Lipsey (1999) Knox (2000) Hausmann and
Fernandez-Arias (2000)
Infrastructure Wheeler and Mody (1992)
quality Kumar (1994)
Loree and Guisinger (1995)
Labor cost Wheeler and Mody (1992) Schneider and Frey (1985) Tsai (1994)
Loree and Guisinger (1995)
Lipsey (1999)
Openness Edwards (1990)
Gastanaga et al. (1998)
Hausmann and
Fernandez-Arias (2000)
Taxes and taris Loree and Guisinger (1995) Wheeler and Mody (1992)
Gastanaga et al. (1998) Lipsey (1999)
Wei (2000)
Political Schneider and Frey (1985) Loree and Guisinger (1995)
instability Edwards (1990) Jaspersen et al. (2000)
Hausmann and
Fernandez-Arias (2000)

Hence, demand factors in the host country are particularly for countries in SSA. 9 Since my
less relevant. A more pertinent factor for this analysis calls for the inclusion of many African
type of investment is the ease with which rms countries, I am unable to test the impact of
can export their products. Nevertheless, factors these important variables on FDI. Indeed, this
that increase the productivity of capital are may explain why only a few African countries
relevant for both types of FDI. were included in previous studies. Below I
As shown in Table 8 (see Appendix A), the describe the independent variables included in
countries included in the analysis are mostly the analysis.
poor and small countries. Furthermore, about
half of the countries are in SSA, and FDI to (a) Description of explanatory variables
that region is mainly in natural resources,
which is non-market seeking. This suggests that (i) Return on investment in the host country
FDI to the countries in my sample is less likely FDI will go to countries that pay a higher
to be market-seeking. This conjecture guides return on capital. But nding an appropriate
my explanation of how various variables measure for the return on investment is prob-
aect FDI. 8 All the independent variables lematic, especially for developing countries,
employed have been used in previous studies, thereby making testing this hypothesis very
with diering interpretations for some of the dicult. This is because most developing
variables. In the discussion below, I point out countries do not have well-functioning capital
these dierences and also highlight the caveats markets, and therefore it is dicult to measure
of the proxy variables used in the empirical the return on capital. To get around this
analysis. problem, I assume that the marginal product of
As is standard in the literature, the dependent capital is equal to the return on capital. This
variable is the ratio of net FDI ows to GDP. implies that investments in capital-scarce
My choice of independent variables was countries will yield a higher return. Since
constrained by data availability. For example, capital-scarce countries tend to be poor, I use
data on important factors such as real wages, the inverse of the real GDP per capita to
trade policies, and tax legislation are not measure the return on capital. This implies
readily available for most developing countries, that, all else being equal, investments in coun-
DETERMINANTS OF FDI 111

tries with a higher per capita income should tions (and therefore less openness) can have a
yield a lower return and therefore real GDP per positive impact on FDI. The reason stems from
capita should be inversely related to FDI. 10 the ``tari jumping'' hypothesis, which argues
The assumed inverse relationship between that foreign rms that seek to serve local
income per capita and the return on capital is markets may decide to set up subsidiaries in the
consistent with empirical facts. According to host country if it is dicult to import their
UNCTAD (1995), the average return on US products to the country. In contrast, multina-
FDI in developing countries over 199093 was tional rms engaged in export-oriented invest-
about 17%. This compares with 10% return on ments may prefer to locate in a more open
investment in developed countries. economy since increased imperfections that
In the literature, the relationship between accompany trade protection generally imply
real GDP per capita and FDI is far from higher transaction costs associated with
unanimous (Table 3). Edwards (1990) and exporting. As discussed previously, FDI for my
Jaspersen et al. (2000) use the inverse of income sample is less likely to be market-seeking and
per capita as proxy for the return on capital therefore I hypothesize a positive relationship
and conclude that real GDP per capita is between openness and FDI.
inversely related to FDI/GDP. In contrast, The empirical literature has generally focused
Schneider and Frey (1985) and Tsai (1994) nd on the impact of trade openness on FDI. One
a positive relationship between the two vari- would, however, expect capital account open-
ables. The argument here is that a higher GDP ness to also aect FDI. For example, restric-
per capita implies better prospects for FDI in tions on currency convertibility, such as foreign
the host country. As pointed out earlier, this exchange control laws, are likely to deter FDI.
argument is valid for market-seeking FDI. This is particularly true for market-seeking
Hence my analysis is consistent with that of FDI since such laws makes it dicult for
Edwards and Jaspersen et al. foreign rms to repatriate their prots. Unlike
trade openness, data for variables that measure
(ii) Infrastructure development capital account openness are not readily avail-
Good infrastructure increases the productiv- able. Hence, I am unable to analyze the
ity of investments and therefore stimulates FDI empirical link between current account open-
ows. As is standard in the literature, I use the ness and FDI.
number of telephones per 1,000 population to
measure infrastructure development. A good
measure of infrastructure development should (iv) Political risk
take into account both the availability and The empirical relationship between political
reliability of infrastructure. Thus the measure I instability and FDI ows is unclear (Table 3).
employ falls short since it captures only the For example, Jaspersen et al. (2000) and
availability aspect of infrastructure. Clearly, Hausmann and Fernandez-Arias (2000) nd no
infrastructure is of little use if it is not reliable. relationship between FDI ows and political
Hence, one would expect infrastructure reli- risk while Schneider and Frey (1985) nd an
ability (e.g., how often the phone lines are inverse relationship between the two variables.
down) to be more important to foreign inves- Using data on US FDI for two time periods,
tors than infrastructure availability (the Loree and Guisinger (1995) found that political
number of telephones in a country). Since data risk had a negative impact on FDI in 1982 but
on the reliability of telecommunication are not no eect in 1977. Edwards uses two indices to
available, I use telephones per 1,000 population measure political riskpolitical instability
to measure infrastructure development, albeit (which measures the probability of a change of
imperfectly. 11 government) and political violence (the sum of
the frequency of political assassinations, violent
(iii) Openness of the host country riots and politically motivated strikes). The
In the literature, the ratio of trade political instability variable was signicant but
(imports + exports) to GDP is often used as a the political violence variable was not. For my
measure of openness of an economy. 12 This analysis, I use the average of the number of
ratio is also often interpreted as a measure of assassinations and revolutions, as in Barro and
trade restrictions. The impact of openness on Lee (1993), to measure political instability. The
FDI depends on the type of investment. When sign of the estimated coecient is not deter-
investments are market-seeking, trade restric- mined a priori.
112 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

(v) Other economic variables higher than that of Asia. Table 5 also shows
I also test the signicance of other variables that the return on investment is on the average
that have been used (most of them sparsely) in higher for SSA. This is consistent with the data
previous studies. These include the ratio of provided in Table 2.
liquid liabilities to GDP as a measure of
nancial depth, the ratio of government
consumption to GDP as a measure of the size 5. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
of government, the ination rate as a measure
of the overall economic stability of the country I begin my analysis by determining the vari-
and the growth rate of GDP as a measure of the ables that are relevant in explaining the varia-
attractiveness of the host country's market. The tion in FDI/GDP for my sample. I use ordinary
hypothesis is that nancial depth, lower ina- least square (OLS) for all the estimations. The
tion, smaller government and higher growth results are reported in Table 6. Columns (1)(4)
rates foster FDI. are results from cross-section regressions,
where the variables are averaged over the 10-
(b) Description of the data year period, 198897. Column (5) reports
results for a panel regression. Here, the vari-
The data were obtained from the World ables are averaged over three subperiods: 1988
Bank's World Development Indicators. 90, 199193 and 199497.
Summary statistics of the variables are reported The results reported in Column 1 of Table 6
in Table 4. Table 5 compares FDI/GDP, the indicate that a large share of the variation in
return on investment, openness and infra- FDI rate can be explained by a small number of
structure development for SSA and non-SSA factors, namely, openness to trade, infrastruc-
countries. ture development and the return on investment.
According to Table 5, the measures of As a group, these factors account for about
infrastructure and openness are on the average 60% of the variability in FDI/GDP. Indeed, the
lower for SSA. 13 Indeed, my dataset is not an adjusted R2 is very high for a crosscountry
anomaly. According to Collier and Gunning regression. The results also show that FDI/
(1999), infrastructure is less available and less GDP increases with the degree of openness to
reliable in Africa than other regions. The international trade, infrastructure development
authors document that the number of tele- and the return on investment. 14 These results
phones per capita in SSA is one-tenth that of are consistent with previous studies.
Asia. Furthermore, the level of faults of Afri- I next include a dummy variable, AFRICA,
ca's telecommunication system is three times and test whether countries in SSA on the

Table 4. Summary statistics for the full sample (71 countries)


Variables Mean Standard deviation Minimum Maximum
100  FDI=GDP 1.754 2.222 )0.517 11.034
100  Imports Exports=GDP 69.54 48.97 17.036 360.451
logPhones per 1; 000 population 2.84 1.524 )0.211 6.078
log1=GDP per capita )7.732 0.86 )9.794 )6.106
100  Government consumption=GDP 13.042 4.118 4.21 25.434
Ination rate 145.403 549.556 0.955 3367.62
100  M2=GDP 32.228 18.369 7.31 84.045
GDP growth 3.622 2.538 )4.956 9.755
Political risk 0.22 0.32 0 1.333

Table 5. Dierences between sub-Saharan Africa and other developing countries (mean of selected variables)
Variables SSA Non-SSA
100  FDI=GDP 0.885 2.467
Openness to trade 66.995 71.628
logPhones per 1; 000 population 1.785 3.706
RETURN log1=GDP per capita )7.178 )8.189
DETERMINANTS OF FDI 113

Table 6. OLS estimation


Variable (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Intercept 4.32 6.188 6.523 13.098 12.252
(0.146)a (0.000) (0.047) (0.013) (0.002)
OPEN 100  Imports Exports=GDP 0.030 0.032 0.032 0.033 0.035
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
INFRAC logPhones per 1; 000 population 0.837 0.574 0.623 1.399 1.345
(0.002) (0.032) (0.052) (0.001) (0.000)
RETURN log1=GDP per capita 0.906 0.997 1.112 2.220 2.107
(0.056) (0.026) (0.032) (0.007) (0.007)
Africa dummy )1.342 )1.415 )1.451 )1.523
(0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.000)
GDP growth 0.004
(0.966)
100  Government consumption=GDP 0.027
(0.562)
Ination rate 0.000
(0.629)
100  M2=GDP 0.002
(0.862)
Political instability )0.022
(0.972)
OPEN  AFRICA )0.005 )0.003
(0.615) (0.742)
INFRAC  AFRICA )1.374 1.384
(0.014) (0.001)
RETURN  AFRICA )1.800 )1.611
(0.059) (0.027)
Adjusted R2 0.6043 0.6530 0.6244 0.7119 0.5706
Number of observations 71 71 68 71 211
a
P -values are in parentheses.
*
Signicance at the 0.10 level.
**
Signicance at the 0.05 level.
***
Signicance at the 0.01 level.

average receive less FDI relative to countries in tions. Furthermore, the economic variables
other regions. AFRICA equals one if a country is and the measure of political risk are not
located in SSA. The results reported in Column signicant. 15 The insignicance of the esti-
2 indicate that the Africa dummy is negative mated coecient of the political risk variable
and statistically signicant. Furthermore, the agrees with the ndings of Edwards (1990),
adjusted R2 increases noticeably, indicating the Jaspersen et al. (2000) and Hausmann and
importance of regional eect. The coecient of Fernandez-Arias (2000). Indeed, this result is
the Africa dummy is interesting because it not surprising. For example, in 1998 and 1999,
measures the average dierence in FDI/GDP Angola, a highly unstable country ranked rst
between an SSA country and a non-SSA in FDI ows among SSA countries
country with the same levels of openness, (UNCTAD, 2000). A plausible explanation is
infrastructure and return on capital. The results that FDI to Angola (which is mostly in
indicate that on the average FDI/GDP for a petroleum) is so protable that the return after
country in sub-Saharan Africa is about 1.3% adjusting for risk is quite substantial. It is
less than that of a comparable country outside interesting to note that the Africa dummy
the region. remains signicant after controlling for a wide
Using the specication in Column 2 as my range of factors. 16 This indicates that there is
basic model, I test for robustness by including an unaccounted for ``Africa eect''suggest-
economic variables (government consumption, ing that the inability of countries in sub-
the ination rate, nancial depth and growth Saharan Africa to attract FDI may be partly
rates) and a measure of political risk. The blamed on the fact that these countries are
results reported in Column 3 shows that the located in a continent that happens to have a
basic model is robust to changes in specica- bad reputation.
114 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

I next test whether the impact of openness, is therefore possible that the dierential impact
return on capital and infrastructure develop- of these variables can be explained by a
ment on FDI/GDP is the same for SSA and ``threshold eect'' and not a ``regional
non-SSA countries. To carry out the test, I eect.'' 18 I tested this hypothesis by including
interact each variable with the Africa dummy. quadratic terms for INFRAC and OPEN in the
The regression results are reported in Column regressions. The estimated coecients for the
4. Three facts stand out from Column 4. First, quadratic terms were not signicant, suggesting
all the three variables remain signicant, that there is no second-order eect (the results
suggesting that these variables are important in are not reported). Finally, I checked the
explaining FDI ows to non-SSA countries. robustness of the results by examining whether
Second, the coecients of all the interactive the results hold when panel data is used. The
terms are negative, suggesting that the marginal results reported in Column 5 indicate that the
eect of the variables on FDI/GDP is less for results are robust.
SSA countries compared to non-SSA countries.
Third, two of the coecients of the interactive
terms, AFRICA  RETURN and AFRICA  6. DISCUSSION OF RESULTS
INFRAC, are signicant.
Table 7 reports the estimated partial coe- The signicance of the Africa dummy and the
cients (with P -values in parentheses) of OPEN , dierential impact of openness, return on
RETURN and INFRAC for SSA countries and investment and infrastructure development on
non-SSA countries. 17 Table 7 shows that FDI to SSA suggests that Africa is dierent. In
INFRAC and RETURN do not have a signicant this section I summarize the empirical results
impact on FDI/GDP to SSA. The insigni- and provide explanations for each result.
cance of INFRAC follows from the fact that I
cannot reject the hypothesis (based on the F -
test) that the sum of the coecients for INFRAC (a) Result 1
and INFRAC  AFRICA (0:025 1:399 1:374)
equals zero. A similar analysis holds for Countries in SSA have on the average received
RETURN . In contrast I reject the hypothesis less FDI than countries in other regions by virtue
that the sum of the coecients for OPEN and of their geographical locationthere is a nega-
OPEN  AFRICA (0:028 0:033 0:005) is tive eect on FDI for being an African country.
equal to zero, suggesting that openness to trade The negative and signicant estimated coef-
has a signicant impact on FDI/GDP to SSA. cient of the Africa dummy suggests that there
The results also indicate that, although open- may be an adverse regional eect for SSA.
ness promotes FDI in both African and non- There are two plausible explanations for this.
African countries, the marginal benet from First, the continent is perceived as being
improved openness is somewhat less for coun- inherently risky. This perception of Africa is
tries in SSA. Specically, a 1% increase in supported by the empirical evidence of Haque,
openness leads to a 0.033% increase in FDI/ Nelson, and Mathieson (2000), who nd that
GDP for a non-SSA country. This compares commercial risk-rating agencies often rate
with a 0.028% increase for a comparable African countries as riskier than warranted by
country in SSA. the fundamentals. Second, due to lack of
As discussed earlier, the measures of open- knowledge about the countries in the continent,
ness and infrastructure development are on the investment decisions are often not guided by
average lower for countries in SSA (Table 4). It country-specic conditions but rather based on
inferences from the environment of neighboring
countries. Thus, to some extent, foreign inves-
Table 7. Partial eect of selected variables tors evaluate African countries as if the coun-
Variable SSA Non-SSA tries in the continent constitute ``one big
country.''
OPEN 0.028 0.033
(0.002) (0.000)
INFRAC 0.025 1.399 (b) Result 2
(0.642) (0.001)
RETURN 0.419 2.220 Higher return on capital promotes FDI to non-
(0.401) (0.007)
SSA countries, but has no signicant impact on
***
Signicant at the 0.01 level. FDI ows to SSA countries, ceteris paribus.
DETERMINANTS OF FDI 115

In a risky environment, higher returns may in Africa for two reasons. First, for many
not induce more investments. The reason is that years, African governments have used their
the risk-adjusted return may be lowtoo low, trade policy as a macroeconomic instrument to
so that it may deter investment. As discussed manage their balance of payments. 21 Hence
earlier, Africa is perceived as being inherently when the terms of trade deteriorated, trade
risky. One factor that seems to aggravate the restrictions were tightened, and slackened
risk environment in SSA is the uncertainty of again when the terms of trade improved.
government policy. For example, the risk of Second, a number of countries embark on
policy reversal was chosen as the most impor- reform as part of aid conditionality, where a
tant risk factor by 150 foreign investors in East donor, such as the World Bank, oers tempo-
Africa (World Bank, 1994). Not surprisingly, rary aid during reform. Once aid ends, there is
policy uncertainty has a negative impact on little incentive for the country to continue
private investment. But the risk of policy reform, and most countries do abandon
reversal has a more profound impact on FDI reform. In summary, trade reform is sustain-
than other types of investments. The reason is able only if it is consistent with macroeconomic
that FDI is partially irreversiblemuch of the equilibrium. Africa's trade reform has in the
costs associated with FDI are sunk and there- past been ad hoc and therefore not sustainable.
fore not retrievable if disinvestment occurs. 19 Foreign investors anticipate this and therefore
Thus, policy uncertainty coupled with the do not increase investments when liberalization
irreversible nature of FDI makes Africa overly occurs.
risky for FDI. In the midst of excessive policy
risk, higher returns may not be sucient to (d) Result 4
compensate for the possibility of a costly
mistake should policy be reversed. As a conse- Infrastructure development promotes FDI to
quence, we would expect foreign investment to non-SSA countries, but has no signicant impact
be less responsive to an increase in the return on FDI ows to SSA countries, ceteris paribus.
on capital. 20 This seems to be the case for Result 4 may be explained by two facts. First,
Africa. Thus investment risk, in particular the FDI to SSA tends to be natural resource based,
risk of policy reversal, may explain why higher mainly in extractive industries. For example, in
returns do not translate into increased FDI in 1993, petroleum alone accounted for about
SSA. 66% of FDI from the United States to SSA
(UNCTAD, 1995). Second, infrastructure
(c) Result 3 development, in particular, the availability of
telephones, is not very relevant for natural
Openness to trade promotes FDI to both resource-based investments. Indeed, foreign
SSA and non-SSA countries, however, the rms in extractive industries often locate in
marginal benet from increased openness is remote areas, which typically lack access to
less for SSAsuggesting that trade liberal- basic amenities such as electricity and water.
ization will generate more FDI to non-SSA For example, Nigeria, an oil exporting country,
countries than SSA countries. receives substantial amounts of FDI (e.g., in
Sub-Saharan Africa has received less FDI 1994 Nigeria ranked seventh among developing
than other regions because openness is glob- countries in receiving FDI) despite its weak
ally important for FDI and countries in SSA infrastructure. According to Collier and
are less open than countries in other regions. Gunning (1999) about 78% of rms in Nigeria
One way by which a country can increase its use private generators because electricity supply
degree of openness is by liberalizing trade. is unreliable.
Thus Result 3 suggests that, all else being
equal, trade liberalization is less eective in
promoting FDI to Africa compared to other 7. CONCLUSION
regions. A plausible explanation for the
subdued response of FDI to trade liberaliza- This paper has analyzed the determinants of
tion is that foreign investors do not perceive Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) to developing
reform as credibleliberalization moves by the countries and examined why sub-Saharan
government are perceived as transitory and Africa (SSA) has been relatively unsuccessful in
therefore subject to reversal. The risk resulting attracting FDI despite policy reform. The
from the lack of credibility of reform is higher results indicate that the factors that drive FDI
116 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

to developing countries have a dierent impact more, the full benets of trade liberalization
on FDI to SSA. Specically, infrastructure will be realized only if investors perceive reform
development and a higher return on capital as credible and not subject to reversal. As a
promote FDI to non-SSA countries. In consequence, African governments should
contrast these factors have no eect on FDI to develop mechanisms to enhance the credibility
SSA. Openness to trade promotes FDI to both of the reform process. 22 Second, policies that
SSA and non-SSA countries; however, the have been successful in other regions should
marginal benet from increased openness is less not be blindly replicated in Africa since these
for SSAsuggesting that trade liberalization policies may have a dierential impact on
will generate more FDI to non-SSA countries Africa. Finally, the results suggest that Africa is
than SSA countries. Another important nding perceived as overly risky and therefore a
is that, all else being equal, FDI is uniformly country in the region will receive less FDI by
lower in SSA. This indicates that there is an virtue of its geographical location. This
``adverse regional eect'' for SSA: a country in perception may be partly attributed to igno-
SSA will receive less FDI by virtue of its rance about countries in the continent. One
geographical location. These results suggest way to dispel this myth is for governments to
that Africa is dierent. disseminate information about their countries.
The results have three policy implications. International organizations such as the
First, to enhance FDI ows, African countries World Bank can play an important role in this
need to liberalize their trade regimes. Further- regard.

NOTES

1. All references to Africa refer to sub-Saharan Africa. A 6. Chakrabarti (2001) analyzes the robustness of the
number of African countries have liberalized their invest- various variables.
ment framework. This includes removing trade restric-
tions such as minimum export requirements and limits on
imports. See UNCTAD (1999) for a discussion of the 7. Non-market seeking FDI includes natural resource
liberation measures undertaken by some African coun- based investments and other export-oriented invest-
tries. ments such as auto assembly plants.

2. This excludes South Africa. There are no data 8. To the extent that dierent factors inuence dierent
available on FDI to South Africa for the 1980s. types of FDI, an ideal approach will be to analyze the
determinants of each type of FDI. Unfortunately,
3. See De Mello (1997) for a survey of the literature disaggregate FDI data are not available for most
on FDI and economic growth. For recent surveys on developing countries.
FDI and technology spillover to host countries, see
Pack and Saggi (1997) and Blomstrom and Kokko
9. The World Bank's World Development Indicators
(1998).
has data on wages and taxes in host countries; however,
the data are not available for most of the countries in my
4. Foreign Investment generally takes three forms: sample.
Foreign Direct Investment (FDI), Indirect Foreign
Investment (which includes commercial bank lending
and bond nance) and ocial loans. Ocial loans are 10. The inverse relationship may also reect a
loans from bilateral organizations (mainly governments perception that investment risk rises as per
of developed countries) and multilateral organizations capita GDP declines. As a consequence investors
(mainly the World Bank and IMF). may require higher returns to oset the perceived
greater risk.
5. There are a number of studies on FDI ows to other
regions. Recent regional studies include those of Stone 11. Another measure of infrastructure quality is
and Jeon (2000), who analyze FDI ows to Asia, Barrel the frequency of power outages. The data although
and Holland (2000), who focus on Central Europe, and published in World Development Indicators are
Tuman and Emmert (2000), who examine FDI ows to not available for most of the countries in my
Latin America. sample.
DETERMINANTS OF FDI 117

12. Gastanaga et al. (1998) use a dierent measure to equal to the estimated coecient of the generic term.
capture the degree of openness. They compute two The estimated coecient for SSA is equal to the sum
indices: one measures ``the degree of openness to inward of the estimated coecient of the generic term and the
FDI'' and the other measures ``the general openness to estimated coecient of the respective interaction term.
capital ows.'' For example, the estimated partial coecient of
RETURN is 2.22 for non-SSA and 0:419 2:22 1:8
for SSA.
13. See Easterly and Levine (1997) and Collier and
Gunning (1999) for a discussion on why these indicators
are lower for Africa. In contrast with my data, Rodrik 18. For example suppose it is the case that infrastruc-
(1998) nds that the degree of openness for sub-Saharan ture promotes FDI only if it exceeds a certain threshold
Africa is comparable to that of other regions. (e.g., INFRAC > b, say). Then changes in INFRAC may
not have a signicant impact on FDI to SSA since
INFRAC for SSA is too low and does not achieve the
14. I also run regressions using the LIBOR spread,
threshold, b. Here, the unresponsiveness of FDI to
dened by the domestic interest rate minus LIBOR, as a
changes in INFRAC may be attributed to SSA's weak
proxy for the return on investment. All else equal, a
infrastructure.
larger spread implies higher risk and therefore a lower
risk-adjusted return. Hence the LIBOR spread should be
inversely related to FDI. This variable was not signif- 19. For example, a multinational corporation that
icant for my sample. abandons its operation in a foreign country is less likely
to completely recover the costs associated with setting
up the foreign subsidiary.
15. I experimented with two other measures of nan-
cial depthM1/GDP and M3/GDPboth were not
signicant. I also experimented with an alternative 20. Rodrik (1991) constructs a model that links policy
measure of country risk, expropriation risk. Like the uncertainty to private investor response and shows that
political risk variable, it was not signicant. The variable even moderate amounts of policy uncertainty may
is a survey-based indicator that measures the risk of require large increases in the return on capital in order
conscation and forced nationalization of foreign enter- to induce investment.
prises. Data on expropriation risk were obtained from
the International Country Risk Guide, published by
21. This suggests that trade policy is endogenously
Political Risk Services.
determined. See Asiedu and Esfahani (2001)
for a discussion on endogenizing FDI and trade
16. Jaspersen et al. (2000) also nd that the Africa policies.
dummy persists in all their regressions.
22. See Collier and Pattillo (2000) for a discussion
17. This is how the partial coecients were on how governments can increase the credibility of
computed. The estimated coecient for non-SSA is reform.

REFERENCES

Asiedu, E., & Esfahani, H.S. (2001). The determinants Collier, P., & Gunning, J. W. (1999). Explaining African
of FDI restrictions: The case of US rms. economic performance. Journal of Economic Litera-
Mimeo. ture, 13(3), 64111.
Barro, R. J., & Lee, J.-W. (1993). International compar- Collier, P., & Pattillo, C. (2000). Investment and risk in
isons of educational attainment. Journal of Monetary Africa. New York: St Martin's Press.
Economics, 32(3), 363394. De Mello, L. R. (1997). Foreign direct investment in
Barrel, R., & Holland, D. (2000). Foreign direct developing countries and growth: A selective survey.
investment and enterprise restructuring in Central Journal of Development Studies, 34(1), 134.
Europe. Economics of Transition, 8(2), 477504. Easterly, W., & Levine, R. (1997). Africa's growth
Blomstrom, M., & Kokko, A. (1998). Multinational tragedy: Policies and ethnic divisions. Quarterly
corporations and spillovers. Journal of Economic Journal of Economics, 112(4), 12031250.
Surveys, 12(3), 247277. Edwards, S. (1990). Capital ows, foreign direct invest-
Chakrabarti, A. (2001). The determinants of foreign ment, and debtequity swaps in developing countries.
direct investment: Sensitivity analyses of cross-coun- NBER working paper no. 3497. Cambridge, MA:
try regressions. KYKLOS, 54, 89114. NBER.
118 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Gastanaga, V., Nugent, J. B., & Pashamova, B. (1998). Schneider, F., & Frey, B. S. (1985). Economic and
Host country reforms and FDI inows: How much political determinants of foreign direct investment.
dierence do they make? World Development, 26(7), World Development, 13(2), 161175.
12991314. Stone, S., & Jeon, B. N. (2000). Foreign direct
Haque, N. U., Nelson, M., & Mathieson, D. J. (2000). investment and trade in Asian-Pacic region:
Rating Africa: The economic and political content of Complementarity, distance and regional economic
risk indicators. In P. Collier, & C. Pattillo (Eds.), integration. Journal of Economic Integration, 15(3),
Investment and risk in Africa (pp. 3370). New York: 460485.
St Martin's Press. Tsai, P.-L. (1994). Determinants of foreign direct
Hausmann, R., & Fernandez-Arias, E. (2000). The new investment and its impact on economic growth.
wave of capital inows: Sea change or just another Journal of Economic Development, 19, 137163.
title? Inter-American Development Bank working Tuman, J., & Emmert, C. (2000). Foreign direct invest-
paper no. 417. ment in Latin America, 19791992. Social Science
Jaspersen, F. Z., Aylward, A. H., & Knox, A. D. Quarterly, 80(3), 539555.
(2000). The eects of risk on private investment: United Nations Center for Trade and Development
Africa compared with other developing areas. In P. (UNCTD). (1995). Foreign direct investment in
Collier, & C. Pattillo (Eds.), Investment and risk in Africa. New York: United Nations Publication.
Africa (pp. 7195). New York: St Martin's United Nations Center for Trade and Development.
Press. (1999). Foreign direct investment in Africa: Perfor-
Kumar, N. (1994). Determinants of export orientation mance and potential. New York: United Nations
of foreign production by US multinationals: An Publication.
inter-country analysis. Journal of International Busi- United Nations Center for Trade and Development.
ness, 25(1), 141156. (2000). UNCTAD press release, www.unctad.org/en/
Lipsey, R. E. (1999). The location and characteristics of press/pr2854en.htm.
US aliates in Asia. NBER working paper no. 6876. Wei, S.-J. (2000). How taxing is corruption on interna-
Loree, D. W., & Guisinger, S. (1995). Policy and non- tional investors? Review of Economics and Statistics,
policy determinants of US equity foreign direct 82(1), 111.
investment. Journal of Business Studies, 26(2), 281 Wheeler, D., & Mody, A. (1992). International invest-
299. ment location decisions: The case of US rms.
Pack, H., & Saggi, K. (1997). Inows of foreign Journal of International Economics, 33, 5776.
technology and indigenous technological develop- World Bank. (1994). Adjustment in Africa: Reforms,
ment. Review of Development Economics, 1(1), results and the road ahead. New York: Oxford
8198. University Press.
Rodrik, D. (1991). Policy uncertainty and private World Bank. (2000a). Global development nance (CD-
investment in developing countries. Journal of Devel- ROM).
opment Economics, 36(2), 229242. World Bank. (2000b). World development indicators
Rodrik, D. (1998). Trade policy and economic perfor- (CD-ROM).
mance in sub-Saharan Africa. NBER working paper World Bank. (2001). Global development nance (CD-
no. 6562. ROM).

(For Appendix A see opposite)


DETERMINANTS OF FDI 119

APPENDIX A

Table 8. Countries grouped by region


Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) Latin America & Caribbean Asia Other
Benin Argentina Bangladesh Algeria
Botswana Bolivia China Egypt
Burkina Faso Brazil India Morocco
Cameroon Chile Indonesia Papua New Guinea
Cape Verde Colombia Malaysia Tunisia
Central Africa Costa Rica Nepal
Congo Dem. Rep. Ecuador Pakistan
Congo Rep. El Salvador Philippines
C^ote d'Ivoire Grenada Singapore
Gabon Guatemala South Korea
Gambia Guyana Sri Lanka
Ghana Haiti Thailand
Guinea Honduras
Guinea Bissau Jamaica
Kenya Mexico
Madagascar Nicaragua
Malawi Panama
Mali Paraguay
Mauritania Peru
Mauritius Trinidad and Tobago
Mozambique Uruguay
Niger Venezuela
Nigeria
Senegal
Sierra Leone
South Africa
Swaziland
Tanzania
Togo
Uganda
Zambia
Zimbabwe

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi