Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 20

Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 2011, 4, 2948

doi:10.1093/cjres/rsq013
Advance Access publication 10 May 2010

India, China and the East Asian Miracle: a human capital


development path to high growth rates and declining
inequalities

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


Aurelie Charlesa, Giuseppe Fontanaa,b and Abhinav Srivastavac
a
Department of Economics, Leeds University Business School, University of Leeds, Leeds LS2
9JT, UK, A.Charles@lubs.leeds.ac.uk, gf@lubs.leeds.ac.uk
b
University of Sannio, Italy
c
ItalyEuropa Statistics India, Taylor and Francis Books India Pvt Ltd, 812-816 Tolstoy House,
1517 Tolstoy Marg, New Delhi 110001, India, abhinav_223@hotmail.com

Received on January 6, 2010; accepted on March 25, 2010

The High-Performing Asian Economies (HPAEs) have been unusually successful compared to
large parts of Asia (including India), Africa and Latin America at matching high growth rates
with significantly declining income inequalities. This paper looks at India and the HPAEs from
a human capital development perspective, and it seeks to explain the reasons for the possible
causes of these different patterns of growth rates and income inequalities. The paper proposes
a new Human Capital Index, and argues that the notion of fair wage is the key factor linking
human capital development to high growth rates and declining inequalities.

Keywords: Human capital, inequality, fair wage, East Asian Miracle, India, China
JEL Classifications: O10, O15, O53

Introduction Interestingly, between the middle 1960s and


middle 1990s, there was very little growth for large
The four tigers, namely Hong Kong, the
Republic of Korea, Singapore and Taiwan, to- parts of Asia, Africa and Latin America. This stark
gether with Japan, China, Indonesia, Malaysia contrast between the high growth rate plus declin-
and Thailand are well-known for the successful ing income inequalities of the HPAEs on one side,
economic performances between middle 1960s and the low growth rate plus stable (or rising) in-
and middle 1990s. Less known is that in the come inequalities for large parts of Asia, Africa and
same period, these High-Performing Asian Latin America on the other side, has created an in-
Economies (HPAEs) have been also successful teresting debate about the possible causes of these
at matching high growth rates with significantly different economic performances. Some scholars
declining income inequalities. Indeed, the com- have argued that the East Asian Miracle of
bination of high growth rates and declining HPAEs is explained by the existence of regional
income inequalities has persuaded some com- strengths involving government intervention act-
mentators to speak of an East Asian Miracle ing together (Stiglitz, 1996, 151). Yet, this view
(World Bank, 1993). fails to explain why countries like India and

The Author 2010. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Cambridge Political Economy Society. All rights reserved.
For permissions, please email: journals.permissions@oup.com
Charles, Fontana and Srivastava

Philippines did not record impressive growth rates income and the total supply of goods and services at
and declining inequalities, in spite of sharing the the expense of the entitlements of people, and the
same geographical proximity to some HPAEs. capabilities that these entitlements generate, has
Other scholars have maintained that the successful been increasingly seen as one of the most important
performance of HPAEs is explained by the adop- deficiencies of traditional measures of human wel-
tion of laissez-faire and free market policies pro- fare (Sen, 1984, 1990). On the other side, the past
moted through the Washington Consensus. Yet decades have seen a significant increase in the

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


again, the evidence is controversial. India has a large availability of statistics measuring the different eco-
and dominant public sector. But this is also the case nomic and social aspects of the welfare of a nation
for Korea and China, two successful HPAEs. More (Booysen, 2002).
generally, most HPAEs are characterized by some The Human Development Index (HDI) by the
form of State intervention.1 United Nations Development Programme (UNDP)
This paper looks at the East Asian Miracle from is since 1990 one of the most successful attempts of
a totally different perspective, that of human capital moving beyond traditional measure of well-being.
development (Fontana and Srivastava, 2009). It The HDI is a composite index that expressly aims to
argues that the latter is a major factor in explaining measure the multi-dimensional aspects of the wel-
both the high growth rates and declining income fare of a nation. It is made of three components:
inequalities experienced by HPAEs as well as the longevity, knowledge and access to resources. The
comparatively poor economic and human develop- first component is directly measured by Life Expec-
ment performance of India since middle 1960s. tancy at birth (LE). Education achievement is con-
Building on this, it then suggests that fair wages sidered a proxy measure for knowledge, and it is
are a significant cause of these different human calculated as weighted sum of Adult Literacy Rate
capital development performances, via the (ALR) (2/3) and level gross enrolment ratios (1/3).
workers-channel and the employers-channel. Finally, access to resources is represented by the
The paper is structured as follows. The next sec- real per capita GDP.
tion proposes a new Human Capital Index (HCI) in The HDI has been criticized on several grounds,
order to measure human capital in India and HPAEs. including the formal measure of access to resources
The paper moves on to argue that the notion of fair used, the sensitivity of the index to the selected
wage is a key factor linking human capital develop- fixed ranges for its longevity and knowledge com-
ment to high growth rates and declining inequalities. ponents, as well as the subjective weight assigned
This idea is then used to explain the different eco- to its components, which implies a universally ac-
nomic performances of a component of the industry ceptable human welfare function (Noorbakhsh,
sector, namely manufacturing, in China and India. 1998). These are general criticisms, which apply
Finally, the final section concludes. to several other composite indices of well-being
(Salzman, 2003). More specific criticisms refer to
the fact that the knowledge and education compo-
The construction of the Human nents of the HDI are unnecessarily restrictive. For
Capital Index instance, the knowledge achievement variable con-
In the 1980s, the dominant view was that Gross siders neither the quality nor the accessibility of the
Domestic Product (GDP) per capita was the most health system. The HCI proposed in this section is
important indicator of the welfare of a nation. How- an attempt to overcome these specific criticisms.
ever, the last two decades have witnessed a growing The HCI is comprised of three components:
theoretical and empirical literature that has chal- health achievement, education achievement and
lenged this view, and has suggested the multi- per capita GDP. It is calculated for India and three
dimensional aspects of well-being (Streeten, 1994; HPAEs, China, the Republic of Korea and Malay-
UNDP, 2003). On one side, the focus on aggregate sia; however, where data are available, indices for

30
India, China and the East Asian Miracle

components of HCI are presented for additional also the ratio of the total population having
HPAEs. All data used for constructing the HCI access to improved sanitation facilities, and being
are obtained from the World Bank (2009), World immunized against diphtheriapertussistetanus,
Development Indicators, though some data on measles, malaria and other illnesses, should be in-
Korea have been obtained from the statistics pub- cluded in the HI. However, due to inadequate data,
lished by the Ministry of Education, Seoul. Finally, this information is not considered in the construc-
Linear Scaling Technique (LST) has been used in tion of the HI.

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


order to standardize the range of raw data available
into a unit-free index between 0 and 1. The implicit 1) The Fertility Rate Index (FI) is a measure of the
assumption in the LST used is that an increase in the total FR, namely the expected number of chil-
variable corresponds to an increase in the overall dren born per woman in her child-bearing years.
welfare. Therefore, the following formula has been Most countries strive to maintain FR at the re-
used: placement level, the implicit assumption being
x  minx that FRs above replacement levels have negative
; effects on the health of the woman and her off-
maxx  minx
spring. The FR is also indicative of the status of
where min (x) and max (x) are the lowest and high- women in the society: high rates are associated
est values the variable x can attain. As a reference, with poor fertility controls, and low status of
for the highest and lowest values, corresponding women in the society. For this reason, the oppo-
statistics of Norway and Sweden (countries that site of the FI, namely (1 FI), is used when
have consistently dominated the HDI charts) and calculating the overall HI.
Yemen and Sierra-Leone and Lesotho (countries
that have performed poorly) have been considered, According to the Central Intelligence Agency
respectively. In some cases where the figures for (CIA), Hong Kong and Mali have the lowest and
these countries are not indicative, that is, in cases the highest FR in the world, namely 0.98 and 7.38,
where Norway and Sweden have not done well in respectively (CIA, 2007). Therefore, the FI is given
a particular area, or Lesotho has performed rather by the following formula:
well on some statistics, the values for other coun-
tries have been used. This is done in order to form FR  0:98
FI = :
realistic limits (i.e. from actual country evidence), 7:38  0:98
within which a variable can fluctuate.
2) LE is a conventional statistics measuring the
The Health Index potential return on investment in human capital.
The UNDP assumes the maximum and mini-
The health achievement component of the HCI is an
mum values of LE to be 85 and 25 years, re-
extensive index. It takes into account a wide range
spectively. The same limits are used in
of factors influencing not only the general health of
constructing the overall HI. Thus, the Life Ex-
individuals but also, among other things, the afford-
pectancy at birth Index (LEI) is given by the
ability and accessibility of the health system. Six
following formula:
variables are considered in the Health Index (HI) of
the HCI, namely, (i) the Fertility Rate (FR), (ii) the
LE  25
LE, (iii) the Infant Mortality Rate (IMR), (iv) the LEI = :
85  25
number of Physicians (P) per thousand of popula-
tion, (v) the number of hospital beds (Ho) per thou-
sand of population and (vi) public health 3) The IMR is another conventional statistics mea-
expenditure as a percent of GDP (PHE). Ideally, suring the level of health in a country. It denotes

31
Charles, Fontana and Srivastava

the number of deaths of infants (under the age of the Hospital beds per thousand of population
one) per thousand live births: this is a significant Index (HoI) is given by the following formula:
loss of human capital, since these infants die
before they can grow to make any meaningful Ho  0:4
contribution to the economy and society. For this HoI = :
10:8  0:4
reason, like in the case of the FR the opposite of
the IMR, namely (1 IMR), is used when

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


calculating the HI.
6) Finally, PHE is an important statistics measuring
the level of health in a country. PHE is proxy
According to the CIA (2007), the values of the
measure of the accessibility and affordability of
IMR vary from 184.44 (for Angola) to 2.30 (for
health care. According to the Human Develop-
Singapore). Thus, the Infant Mortality rate Index
ment Reports from 2000 to 2006, PHE was 8.62
(IMI) is calculated by the following formula:
for Sweden and a mere 0.5 for Nigeria (UNDP,
2006). Therefore, the Public Health Expenditure
IMR  2:30 as a percent of GDP Index (PHEI) is given by the
IMI = : following formula:
184:44  2:30
PHE  0:5
PHEI = :
8:62  0:5
4) A non-conventional statistics measuring the
level of health in a country is the number of On the basis of the above discussion, the overall
P per thousand of population. Although there HI can be calculated by taking a weighted average
is no consensus about the optimal number of of all standardised variables, namely the FI, LEI,
P (and health workers, more generally) for IMI, PI, HoI and PHEI:
a population, there is ample evidence that
P, which includes generalists and specialists, 1  FI+23LEI+231  IMI+PI+HoI+PHEI
HI= :
is positively associated with immunization 8
coverage and outreach of health care. Accord-
ing to the World Bank (2009), in 2005 P varies Two points need to be discussed before present-
from 3.1 (for Norway) to 0.2 (for the ing the results of the overall HI. First, the PHEI is
United Arab Emirates and Afghanistan). difficult to calculate: most countries do not disclose
Therefore, the number of Physicians per thou- information about the various aspects of govern-
sand of population Index (PI) is given by the ment spending. Data are particularly hard to obtain,
following formula: more so for the 1960s and 1970s. One way around
P  0:2 this difficulty is to simply drop this variable from
PI= : the index. Therefore, as a working formula, the
3:1  0:2
adjusted overall Health Index HI* is defined as
follows:
5) Another non-conventional statistics measuring
the level of health in a country is the number
of Ho per thousand of population. Like the pre-
1  FI+23LEI+231  IMI+PI+HoI
vious statistics, Ho is a proxy for the quality and HI = :
accessibility of the health care system. Accord- 7
ing to the World Bank (2009), in 2005 the
values of Ho typically vary between 10.8 (for Secondly, there is the thorny subject of the sub-
Norway) and 0.4 (for Afghanistan). Therefore, jective weights assigned to the single components

32
India, China and the East Asian Miracle

of the HI*. The PI and the HoI represent a proxy this way overtaking Malaysia by early 1980s. Over-
for the accessibility of the health system. There- all, Figure 1 shows that between 1960 and 2005
fore, the two indices taken together have a weight India, China, Singapore, Korea, Malaysia, Thailand
of two, which are the same weights assigned to the and Japan all recorded a rise in their adjusted health
LEI and the IMI. Finally, the FI gets half of the index, though India consistently underperformed
weight assigned to the other indices, because it is compared to the HPAEs analysed: in 2004, the
perceived to be the least important variables of the HI* for India is 0.50, against 0.63 for Thailand,

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


overall HI*. Sensitivity analysis performed by al- 0.77 for Singapore and 0.82 for Korea. Finally,
tering the weights assigned to each component of Appendix A, which displays the individual compo-
the HI* indicates that the results of the overall nents of the HI, confirms this conclusion. Between
adjusted health index are not drastically affected. 1960 and 2005, with the exception of the HoI
Moreover, the ordering or rank of the countries in (Table A5), India underperformed China, Singa-
HI* is indicative of how a country has performed pore, Korea, Malaysia, Thailand and Japan on all
on all components of the adjusted health index, components of the adjusted health index, namely
that is, a country receiving an overall high rank the FI (Table A1), the LEI (Table A2), the IMI
is one that has performed well on all components (Table A3) and the PI (Table A4).
of its HI*.
Figure 1 shows that the adjusted health index for The Education Index
India is the lowest of all countries under study: in The education achievement component of the HCI
1960, India recorded a HI* of 0.17, which compares is also an extensive index. It tries to capture more
poorly with the corresponding HI* of Singapore empirical evidence than conventional indices of
and Korea, namely 0.52 and 0.33, respectively. In well-being do. It includes the ALR and the School
the same year, Japan recorded a HI* of 0.72. In- Enrolment Rate (SER) as well as the pupilteacher
terestingly, Figure 1 shows that the six HPAEs and ratio (PTR) in primary education. Furthermore, in
India follow the same trend with a steep rise of the most developing countries, the number of students
adjusted health index from 1960 to 1985 followed leaving schools and colleges before finishing their
by a flat period, which remains up to today. China studies is large. Therefore, the education achieve-
experiences the steepest rise of HI* in the 1970s, in ment component of the HCI includes a proxy for

Figure 1. Adjusted Health Index.


Source: Authors calculations.

33
Charles, Fontana and Srivastava

the completion of primary education, namely, the tion. However, no all students complete their pri-
persistence of students to grade 5. Overall, six mary education. The PG5R measures the share of
variables are considered in the Education Index children enrolled in the first grade of primary school
(EI) of the HCI, namely, (i) the ALR, (ii) the who eventually reach grade 5. Therefore, the PG5R
SER, (iii) the persistence to grade 5, (iv) the is an important complementary statistics to the
agedependency ratio, (v) the PTR in primary SER. According to the World Bank (2009), in
education and (vi) public education expenditure 2004 Sweden recorded a PG5R of 99.99. In the

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


as a percentage of GDP. same year, many developing countries failed to pro-
vide data, hence the suggested minimum value for
1) The ALR is a conventional statistics measuring PG5R is zero. The Persistence to Grade 5 Index
the stock of literate individuals within the adult (PG5I) is therefore calculated by the following
population. The ALR is produced by the UNDP formula:
in order to calculate the HDI. UNDP sets the PG5R
PG5I = :
maximum and minimum values at 100 and 0, re- 100
spectively. Therefore, the Adult Literacy Index
(ALI) is calculated by the following formula:
4) Another non-conventional statistics measuring
ALR the level of health in a country is the Age-
ALI = :
100 Dependency Ratio (ADR). It measures the pro-
portion of the population in the age below 15
and over 65 years to the population between age
2) The SER is another conventional statistics for 15 and 65. ADR is thus a measure of the burden
measuring the education achievement of of those who are not working or able to work on
a country. It is calculated by expressing the those who are economically active. For this
number of students enrolled in primary education reason, the opposite of the ADR, namely
as a percentage of the population of official school (1 ADR), is used when calculating the EI.
age for that level of education. Like for the ALR, According to the World Bank (2009), in 2002
the SER is produced by the UNDP in order to ADR was 0.98 and 0.29 for Yemen and United
calculate the HDI. The UNDP sets the maximum Arab Emirates, respectively. Therefore, the Age-
and minimum values of the SER at 100 and 0, Dependency Index (ADI) is calculated by the
respectively. Importantly, the SER is capped at following formula:
one in order to avoid the risk of double counting:
many children may enrol in primary schools, only ADR  0:29
ADI = :
to drop out, and enrol back again. The School 0:98  0:29
Enrolment Index (SEI) is calculated by the fol-
lowing formula:
5) The primary school PTR is an important proxy
for the quality of education dispensed in class-
SER rooms. PTR indicates the number of pupils en-
SEI = :
100 rolled in primary school divided by the number
of primary school teachers: the lower is the PTR,
the higher is ceteris paribus the quality of the
3) A non-conventional statistics measuring the level education system. For this reason, the opposite
of health in a country is the Persistence to Grade 5 of the PTR, namely (1 PTR), is used when
Rate (PG5R). The SER described above measures calculating the EI. According to the World Bank
the number of students enrolled in primary educa- (2009), in 2004 the PTR was 10.11 and 45.24 for

34
India, China and the East Asian Miracle

Sweden and Guinea, respectively. Therefore, the this reason, ALI, SEI and PG5I have a weight of
primary school PupilTeacher Index (PTI) is cal- two. The ADI and the primary school PTI are per-
culated by the following formula: ceived to be the least important variables of the
overall EI*, and hence they get half of the weight
PTR  10:11 assigned to the previous indices. Again, sensitivity
PTI= : analysis performed by altering the weights assigned
45:24  10:11
to each component of the EI* indicates that the

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


6) Finally, Public Education Expenditure as a per- results of the overall adjusted education index are
cent of GDP (PEE) is an important statistics not drastically affected.
measuring the level of education in a country. Figure 2 shows the adjusted education index for
PHE is proxy measure of the accessibility and India, China, Korea and Malaysia. In 1991, India
affordability of education system. Again, accord- recorded an EI* of 0.58, which compares poorly
ing to the World Bank (2009), in 2004 the PEE with the corresponding EI* of Malaysia, Korea
was 7.35 and 1.56% for Sweden and United Arab and China, namely 0.85, 0.87 and 0.94, respec-
Emirates, respectively. Therefore, the Public Ed- tively. By early 2000s, all HPAEs had significant
ucation Expenditure as a percent of GDP Index improvements in their education systems. How-
(PEEI) is given by the following formula: ever, India did not eliminate its education gap: in
PEE  1:56 2003, the EI* for India is 0.71, against 0.89 for
PEEI = : Korea, 0.90 for Malaysia and 0.93 for China. Appen-
7:35  1:56
dix B confirms this conclusion: India underper-
formed Korea, Malaysia and China on the ALI
On the basis of the above discussion, the overall (Table B1), the SEI (Table B2; this is not the case
education index EI can be calculated by taking for Malaysia) and especially PG5I (Table B3). In-
a weighted average of all standardised variables, terestingly, the latter index, which measures the share
namely the ALI, the SEI, the PG5I, the ADI, the of children enrolled in the first grade of primary
primary school PTI and the PEEI: school who eventually reach grade 5, indicates a par-
23ALI+23SEI+23PG5I+1  ADI+1  PTI+PEEI
ticular weakness of the Indian education system.
EI = :
9
The Gross Domestic Product Index
Like for the overall health index, two points need The final component of the HCI is the per capita
to be discussed before presenting the results of the Gross Domestic Product Index (GDPI). It is a proxy
education index. First, since most countries do not for the standard of living in a country. Consistently
disclose information about the various aspects of with Anand and Sen (2000) and the computation of
government spending, the PEEI is difficult to cal- the income component of the UNDP HDI, the
culate. PEEI is thus dropped from the overall edu- GDPI is calculated by taking the logarithm of real
cation index. Then, the adjusted overall Education GDP per capita, adjusted for (i) different purchasing
Index HI* is defined as follows: power parity of each national currency and (ii) for
23ALI+23SEI+23PG5I+1  ADI+1  PTI
the assumption of diminishing marginal utility of
EI  = : income (see also Salzman, 2003). Therefore, the
8
GDPI is calculated by the following formula:
Secondly, different weights have been assigned logGDPper capita  log100
to components of the adjusted overall Education GDPI = :
log40; 000  log100
Index EI*: the ALI, the SEI and the PG5I are con-
sidered to be the most significant proxies of the Figure 3 shows the GDPI for India and
quality of the education system of a country. For six HPAEs, namely China, Singapore, Korea,

35
Charles, Fontana and Srivastava

Malaysia, Thailand and Japan, together with India, for the period 20002005. Despite the severe data
from 1975 to 2005. All countries are on a positive limitations, Figure 4 shows the poor performance
trend, though some countries start from very low on human capital development of India compared
level. In 1975, the GDPI for China and India is 0.29 to HPAEs. In 2000, India recorded an HCI* of 0.55,
and 0.40, respectively. This compares poorly with which then slightly increased to 0.59 in 2004. How-
the GDPI for Singapore and Japan, namely 0.69 and ever, China recorded an HCI* of 0.69 already in
0.82, respectively. By the early 2000s, the gap in 1991. Similarly, Malaysia and Korea recorded an

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


GDPIs is reduced though still significant. In 2005, HCI* of 0.75 and 0.83, respectively, in 2000.
the GDPI for India is 0.57 against 0.67 for China, Malaysia, Korea and especially China kept increas-
0.93 for Singapore and 0.93 for Japan. ing their HCI* in the early 2000s, such that the
human development gap between these countries
The Human Capital Index and India increased rather than decreased by the
The HCI is made of three equally weighted compo- middle 2000s.
nents, namely the HI, the EI and the GDPI de- Figure 4, together with Figures 13, shows that
scribed above. Furthermore, given the limited data with the possible exception of China all HPAEs
availability on both the PHE and the PEE, the ad- scored highly on all components of the HCI*,
justed health index HI* and the adjusted education namely, the adjusted health index, the adjusted ed-
index EI* are used in the construction of the HCI. ucation index and the GDPI, which translated in an
Therefore, the adjusted Human Capital Index HCI* overall high HCI*. In short, Figures 14 shows that
is given by the following formula: since 1960 HPAEs could count on an increasingly
healthy, educated and skilled workforce. This was
not the case for India. Interestingly, China and India
HI +EI +GDPI
HCI = : seem to have started from a similar position in the
3
1960s, but their human development and economic
performances drew apart in the following decades.
Figure 4 below shows the adjusted human capital The next section looks at China and India in order
index HCI* for India, China, Korea and Malaysia to understand the role of fair wages as a potential

Figure 2. Adjusted Education Index.


Source: Authors calculations.

36
India, China and the East Asian Miracle

key factor linking human capital development to rable countries in terms of population and geo-
high growth rates and declining inequalities. graphic size, and up to the 1980s, they also had
a very similar level of per capita GDP (Bosworth
and Collins, 2008). However, in the last two deca-
Linking human capital development to des, the Chinese growth rate has been much higher
high growth rates and declining than the Indian growth rate, which has led to a rising
inequalities: a fair wage hypothesis gap in the economic performance of the two coun-

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


China and India are often compared in terms of tries. In this regard, it should suffice to remember
emerging economic powers. They are two compa- that in 2008 China recorded more than double per

Figure 3. Gross Domestic Product Index.


Source: Authors calculations.

Figure 4. Adjusted Human Capital Index.


Source: Authors calculations.

37
Charles, Fontana and Srivastava

capita GDP than India. Some authors have argued todays workers will be tomorrows consumers. In
that these different economic performances are other words, increases in wages eventually lead to
explained by the late 1970s market-oriented reforms an increase in consumption, hence in aggregate de-
in China (Sen, 2008). The previous section has sug- mand, and possibly in output (Taylor, 2003). Im-
gested a different argument: human capital develop- portantly, increases in wages also give access to
ment had a significant role in explaining the different better health and education, which in turn raise
economic performances of India and China (again the quality of the workforce. In this sense, a fair

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


see, also, Sen, 2008). Since the 1960s, India per- wage for workers means an income that enables
formed poorly on all components of the HI and the them to sustain and/or improve their human capital,
EI, which translated in an overall low HCI. By con- which has a positive effect on their level of effort in
trast, in the same period, China could count on an the labour market. This is indeed the original idea
increasingly healthier, more skilled and educated behind the efficiency wages hypothesis (Yellen,
workforce (Bosworth and Collins, 2008). 1984). The hypothesis emerged in the context of
Charles (2009) has argued that the notion of fair less-developed countries and established a link be-
wage is useful for explaining the different perform- tween wages, nutrition and illnesses: poor nutrition
ances of India and China. She maintains that fair leads to low productivity and low wages, which
wages are a key factor linking human capital de- sustain deficient nutrition and lead to a vicious cir-
velopment to high growth rates and potentially de- cle of poverty and poor health (Leibenstein, 1963).
clining inequalities. The fair wage-effort hypothesis Second, there is the employers-channel: the
(Akerlof and Yellen, 1986) and fairness-related the- wage offered by employers responds to signals sent
ories (Kahneman et al., 1986) suggest that wages by workers, namely marginal increases in labour
are set above their market clearing level essentially productivity, and therefore output. In other words,
because employers have a perception as to how labour productivity depends on the fair real wage
much they should pay for a given work or level of paid by the employer. Different authors put forward
effort. In the same way, workers have a perception as different arguments as to why employers may deem
to how much effort they should provide for a given fair to set wages in excess of their market-clearing
level of wage, relative to the wage of other workers. level: they may do it in order to reduce the costs of
In other words, norms attached to the value of fair- labour turnover and attract a better pool of appli-
ness affect the remuneration for a certain type of cants (Salop, 1979), to reduce shirking by workers
work as well as the effort for a given level of wage (Shapiro and Stiglitz, 1984), to increase labour pro-
(Charles, 2010). Importantly, norms not only affects ductivity while saving on total labour costs (Carlin
remunerations and efforts but they are also affected and Soskice, 2005) or simply for moral motivations
by them: for instance, the pace of economic growth (Solow, 1979). In the context of HPAEs based on
can influence the perception of what is a fair wage, labour-intensive industries such as manufacturing,
the level at which it should be set from the point of labour productivity becomes an essential instru-
view of employers and the level of effort workers ment for economic growth.
should offer for a given wage level. Mosley (2004, 762) has argued, along similar
There are two main channels through which fair lines, in favour of the government paying a social
wages link human development to economic devel- efficiency wage premium in order to sustain the mo-
opment. First, there is the workers-channel: the mentum of accumulation against the threat of polit-
effort made by workers responds to signals sent ical disturbances. In his argument, the provision of
by employers, including marginal increases in social goods like health and education operates not
wages. An increase in wages means an increase in only between workers and employers but also at
purchasing power that could be spent on goods and a social level. It signals the commitment of a govern-
services. This is the idea behind Henry Fords high ment to a human capital-based development strategy,
wage doctrine of five dollars a day for his workers: which engender social norms conducive to efficiency

38
India, China and the East Asian Miracle

wage responses from the entire population. This so- faster rate, and by early 2000s overtakes the Indian
cial interpretation of the notion of fair wage reinfor- real wage index. Similarly, Figure 6 shows that
ces the effects of the workers-channel and the starting in the late 1980s, Chinese productivity
employers-channel described above. It also plays rose constantly for two decades. In short, between
a crucial role in the passage from import substitution late 1980s and mid-2000s, China experienced an
industrialization policies to export-oriented industri- increasing real wage and an increasing labour pro-
alization policies, which require the development of ductivity in the manufacturing sector. The situa-

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


skills and aptitudes for the development of new prod- tion in India could not be more different. Figure 5
ucts and processes in manufacturing. shows a decreasing trend of the real wage index in
In summary, fair wages link human development the Indian manufacturing sector between 1986 and
to economic development via the workers-channel 2003; while Figure 6 shows that productivity
and the employers-channel. Figures 5 and 6 below remains constant over the same period. In short,
support the view that fair wages are a key factor between mid-1980s and mid-2000s, India had to
linking human development to economic develop- cope with a decreasing real wage and a constant
ment, and hence are useful for explaining the dif- productivity in the manufacturing sector.
ferent performances of India and China. Figures 5 and 6 together support the idea that the
Figure 5 presents the real wage index in the notion of fair wage is useful for explaining the
manufacturing sector of China and India for the pe- different performances of both China and India.
riod 19802008.2 It shows that since 1980, Indian Lets start with China. First, the workers-channel:
workers in the manufacturing sector have experienced the increase in the real wages index raised the
a constant fall in the real wage index, i.e. a fall in their purchasing power of workers in the manufacturing
purchasing power. By contrast, over the same period sector, which in turn improved access to health and
manufacturing workers in China have experienced education for them and their families. The high
a constant increase in real wages (Figure C1 in Ap- value for China of the adjusted health index
pendix C shows a similar pattern for other HPAEs). (Figure 1), adjusted education index (Figure 2)
Figure 6 presents labour productivity in the and the overall HCI (Figure 4), is consistent with
manufacturing sector of China and India for the this. Importantly, the improved access to health
period 19802005. From 1980 to 1986, China and and education had then a positive effect on the
India had a similar level of productivity. However, labour productivity, and hence on the per capita
from mid-1980s onwards, their performances grew GDP (Figure 1). Second, the employers-channel:
apart: by early 2000s, a manufacturing worker in the increase in the real wages index raised labour
China was five times more productive than a similar productivity in the manufacturing sector, which
worker in India. This is consistent with Bosworth has positive effects on the per capita GDP. The
and Collins (2008, 55) who also found that China employers-channel thus reinforced the positive
has experienced a much faster rate of total labour link between real wages and per capita GDP estab-
productivity compared with India, thanks to a dou- lished by the workers-channel. Finally, there are
bling of growth in the contribution of increased important positive feedback effects from GDP to
capital per worker in China compared with India. real wages. As explained before, the remuneration
In the context of the fair wage hypothesis, the for a certain type of work as well as the effort for
relationship between real wage and labour produc- a given level of wage are affected by the pace of
tivity needs to be understood by looking at economic growth: as per capita GDP grows, the
Figures 6 and C1 simultaneously.3 Figure 5 shows perception of what is a fair wage, the level at
that the real wage index in the Chinese which it should be set and the level of effort work-
manufacturing sector rose steadily up to 1997 ers should offer change. In other words, the initial
1998, the date of the Asian financial crisis. There- increase in the real wage index in the Chinese
after, the Chinese real wage index rose at an even manufacturing sector, which was affordable as

39
Charles, Fontana and Srivastava

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


Figure 5. Real-wage Index in the manufacturing sectors of China and India.
Source: KILM (2006).
Note: The real-wage index is the nominal wages index corrected for changes in purchasing power measured by the consumer price index
in each country with the year 2000 as base 100 (KILM, 2006).

a result of an undervalued Chinese currency, trig- for per capita GDP of India compared to China
gered a virtuous circle: growing levels of health in the last couple of decades (Figure 1). Second,
and education capital and of labour productivity the employers-channel: again decreases in the real
had beneficial effects on the level of per capita wages index were not beneficial to labour produc-
GDP, which led to further increases in real wages, tivity, and this is useful for understanding why by
and hence health and education capital and labour early 2000s a manufacturing worker in India was
productivity. five times less productive than a similar worker in
Unfortunately, India seems to have been trapped China. The employers-channel thus reinforced the
in a vicious circle, where both the workers-channel negative link between real wages and per capita
and employers-channel work against further prog- GDP established by the workers-channel. Taking
ress in human capital and economic developments. together the workers-channel and the employers-
First, the workers-channel: decreases in the real channel and their feedback effects, the initial
wages index lowered the purchasing power of reduction in the real wage index in the manufactur-
workers in the manufacturing sector, which in turn ing sector seems to have had a severe negative
restrained access to better health and education for impact on human capital development and
them and their families. The low value for India of economic development in India.
the adjusted health index (Figure 1), adjusted ed-
ucation index (Figure 2) and the overall HCI Summary and conclusions
(Figure 4) is consistent with this. Importantly, This paper has examined the role of human capital
the restricted access to health and education had in explaining the high growth rates and declining
then a negative effect on the labour productivity, inequalities experienced by HPAEs between mid-
which remained almost constant for over two dec- dle 1960s and middle 1990s in comparison to the
ades between mid-1980s and mid-2000s. All this poor performance of India during the same period.
helps to explain the relatively poor performance For this purpose, a HCI has been built. HCI is made

40
India, China and the East Asian Miracle

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


Figure 6. Labour Productivity in the manufacturing sector of China and India (19802006).
Source: KILM (2006).
Note: Labour productivity is calculated GDP per person employed in the manufacturing sector in 1997 US$ (KILM, 2006).

of three components measuring the health achieve- equality in the case of South Korea and Taiwan,
ment, the education achievement and per capita GDP respectively. Similarly, Kay (2002) has recently argued
of a country. Despite data limitations, the main out- that land reforms explain the different development tra-
come of the HCI analysis is unambiguous: between jectory and performances of HPAEs and Latin-America
countries. In the case of India, the effects of land reform
middle 1960s and middle 1990s India lagged behind
are more problematic to interpret (Banerjee et al., 2002;
HPAEs on human capital development. Interest-
Besley and Burgess, 2000). Land reform received top
ingly, India and China started from a similar po- priority when India regained its independence in 1947,
sition in the 1960s, but they grew apart in terms of though its adoption and implementation was left to state
human capital and economic performances in the governments. This has led to a lot of variation in the
following decades. The paper has suggested that implementation of land reforms across Indian states and
fair wages are a significant cause of these differ- over time: the states of West Bengal and Kerala are the
ent performances. Fair wages are a key factor most notable successful examples of land reform, while
linking human capital development to economic the state of Bihar is arguably the most disappointing case
development. Fair wages through the workers- (violent tensions often arise between land owners and
channel, the employers-channel and their feed- peasants).
2
back effects help to explain why since 1960s In- The manufacturing sector made 40.23% of Chinese
dia performed poorly compared to China on all GDP in 1980 and 34.38% in 2008, while it made
components of the HI and the EI. Fair wages also 16.72% of Indian GDP in 1980 and 16.02% in 2008
(World Bank, 2009).
help to explain why in 2008 China recorded more
3
than double per capita GDP than India. The analysis here is purely descriptive since the scarcity
of data points does not allow a reliable econometric anal-
ysis to be performed.
Endnotes
1
Another controversial explanation for the East Asian
Miracle is the success of land reforms for early HPAEs. References
Amsden (1989) and Wade (1990) maintain that land Akerlof, G. A. and Yellen, J. L. (eds) (1986) Efficiency
reforms have been a key factor in enabling industrialisa- Wage Models of the Labor Market. Cambridge: Cam-
tion and, importantly, with relatively low levels of in- bridge University Press.

41
Charles, Fontana and Srivastava

Amsden, A. H. (1989) Asias Next Giant: South Korea Mosley, P. (2004) Institutions and politics in a Lewis-
and Late Industrialization. Oxford: Oxford University type growth model. The Manchester School, 72: 751
Press. 773.
Anand, S. and Sen, A. (2000) The income component of Noorbakhsh, F. (1998) The human development index:
the human development index. Journal of Human some technical issues and alternative indices. Journal
Development, 1: 83106. of International Development, 10: 589605.
Banerjee, A. V., Gertler, P. J. and Ghatak, M. (2002) Salop, S. C. (1979) A model of the natural rate of un-
Empowerment and efficiency: tenancy reform in employment. The American Economic Review, 69:

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


West Bengal. Journal of Political Economy, 110: 117125.
239280. Salzman, J. (2003) Methodological Choices Encountered
Besley, T. and Burgess, R. (2000) Land reform, poverty in the Construction of Composite Indices of Economic
reduction, and growth: evidence from India. Quarterly and Social Well-Being. Ottawa, Ontario: Center for the
Journal of Economics, 115: 389430. Study of Living Standards.
Booysen, F. (2002) An overview and evaluation of com- Sen, A. K. (1984) Resources, Values and Development.
posite indices of development. Social Indicators Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Research, 59: 115151. Sen, A. K. (1990) Development as capability expansion.
Bosworth, B. and Collins, S. M. (2008) Accounting for In K. Griffin and J. Knight (eds.). Human Development
growth: comparing China and India. Journal of Eco- and the International Development Strategy for the
nomic Perspectives, 22: 4566. 1990s. pp. 4158. London: Macmillan.
Carlin, W. and Soskice, D. (2005) Macroeconomics and Sen, A. K. (2008) Perspectives on the economic devel-
the Wage Bargain: A Modern Approach to Employ- opment of India and China. In G. Secondi (ed.). The
ment, Inflation, and the Exchange Rate. 2nd edn. Development Economics Reader, pp. 3441. London:
New York: Oxford University Press. Routledge.
Charles, A. (2009) A fair-wage approach to human cap- Shapiro, C. and Stiglitz, J. (1984) Equilibrium unemploy-
ital development in India and China. Presented at 6th ment as a worker discipline device. American Eco-
International Conference on Developments in Eco- nomic Review, 74: 433444.
nomic Theory and Policy, Bilbao, July 2009. Solow, R. M. (1979) Another possible source of wage
Charles, A. (2010) Fairness and wages in Mexicos ma- stickiness. Journal of Macroeconomics, 1: 7982.
quiladora industry: an empirical analysis of labor de- Stiglitz, J. (1996) Some lessons from the East Asian Mir-
mand and the gender wage gap. Review of Social acle. The World Bank Research Observer, 11: 151177.
Economy. (in press). Streeten, P. (1994) Human development: means and
CIA. (2007) The World Factbook 2006. Available online ends. American Economic Review Papers and
at: https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/download/ Proceedings, 84: 232237.
[Accessed 2 April 2007]. Taylor, J. E. (2003) Did Henry Ford mean to pay effi-
Fontana, G. and Srivastava, A. (2009) A human capital ciency wages? Journal of Labor Research, 24: 683
approach to inequalities: the case of the East Asian 694.
Miracle and India. Journal of Economic Issues, 43: UNDP. (2003) Human Development Report 2006.
523530. New York: Oxford University Press.
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L. and Thaler, R. (1986) Fair- UNDP. (2006) Human Development Report 2006.
ness as a constraint on profit seeking: entitlements in the New York: Oxford University Press.
market. The American Economic Review, 76: 728741. Wade, R. (1990) Governing the Market: Economic The-
Kay, C. (2002) Why East Asia overtook Latin America: ory and the Role of Government in East Asias Indus-
agrarian reform, industrialisation and development. trialization. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Third World Quarterly, 23: 10731102. World Bank. (1993) The East Asian Miracle: Economic
KILM. (2006) Key Indicators of the Labour Market. 5th Growth and Public Policy. The World Bank Research
edn. Geneva, Switzerland: International Labour Office, Reports. New York: Oxford University Press.
Bureau of Publications. World Bank. (2009) World Development Indicators,
Leibenstein, H. (1963) The theory of underemployment ESDS International. Washington, DC: University of
in densely populated backward areas. Reprinted in Manchester.
Akerlof, G. A. and Yellen, J. L. (eds) (1986). Efficiency Yellen, J. L. (1984) Efficiency wage models of unem-
Wage Models of the Labor Market, pp. 2240. ployment. American Economic Review (Papers and
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Proceedings), 74: 200205.

42
India, China and the East Asian Miracle

Appendix A: Health Index components

Table A1. Fertility Date Index (FDI)


India China Singapore Korea Malaysia Thailand Japan

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


1960 0.87 0.38 0.69 0.73 0.91 0.85 0.16
1970 0.75 0.75 0.33 0.55 0.7 0.69 0.18
1971 0.64 0.32 0.56 0.18
1972 0.72 0.61 0.32 0.49 0.65 0.62 0.18
1977 0.66 0.27 0.13 0.32 0.49 0.46 0.13
1980 0.62 0.24 0.12 0.29 0.51 0.38 0.12
1981 0.31 0.12 0.26 0.12
1982 0.59 0.21 0.11 0.22 0.51 0.32 0.12
1985 0.54 0.21 0.1 0.11 0.49 0.26 0.12
1986 0.07 0.10 0.11
1987 0.50 0.25 0.10 0.09 0.47 0.22 0.11
1990 0.44 0.17 0.14 0.09 0.44 0.19 0.09
1991 0.12 0.12 0.08
1992 0.4 0.15 0.12 0.12 0.41 0.17 0.08
1995 0.38 0.15 0.11 0.10 0.38 0.16 0.07
1997 0.14 0.10 0.09 0.35 0.15 0.06
2000 0.33 0.14 0.07 0.07 0.32 0.15 0.06
2001 0.14 0.07 0.05 0.32 0.05
2002 0.31 0.14 0.06 0.03 0.30 0.15 0.05
2003 0.30 0.14 0.04 0.03 0.29 0.15 0.05
2004 0.29 0.13 0.04 0.03 0.28 0.14 0.05

43
Charles, Fontana and Srivastava

Table A2. Life Expectancy Index (LEI)


India China Singapore Korea Malaysia Thailand Japan

1960 0.32 0.19 0.64 0.48 0.49 0.52 0.71


1967 0.38 0.58 0.69 0.54 0.57 0.57 0.77
1970 0.41 0.61 0.71 0.60 0.61 0.59 0.78
1971 0.62 0.79

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


1972 0.42 0.64 0.72 0.63 0.60 0.81
1974 0.65 0.82
1980 0.49 0.69 0.77 0.68 0.69 0.65 0.85
1981 0.69 0.86
1982 0.50 0.71 0.78 0.71 0.67 0.86
1983 0.70 0.87
1985 0.53 0.72 0.79 0.72 0.73 0.69 0.88
1986 0.88
1987 0.54 0.73 0.81 0.75 0.74 0.70 0.89
1990 0.57 0.73 0.82 0.77 0.75 0.72 0.89
1991 0.78 0.90
1992 0.58 0.73 0.83 0.76 0.73 0.90
1994 0.85 0.91
1995 0.61 0.74 0.86 0.81 0.77 0.73 0.91
1996 0.86 0.92
1997 0.62 0.74 0.87 0.82 0.78 0.73 0.92
1999 0.87 0.84 0.93
2000 0.63 0.75 0.88 0.85 0.79 0.74 0.93
2001 0.76 0.89 0.85 0.80 0.74 0.94
2002 0.64 0.76 0.89 0.86 0.80 0.74 0.94
2003 0.64 0.77 0.90 0.86 0.80 0.75 0.94
2004 0.64 0.77 0.90 0.87 0.81 0.76 0.95

44
India, China and the East Asian Miracle

Table A3. Infant Mortality Index (IML)


India China Singapore Korea Malaysia Thailand Japan

1960 0.79 0.81 0.18 0.48 0.38 0.55 0.15


1965 0.73 0.59 0.13 0.29 0.46 0.09
1970 0.68 0.45 0.09 0.22 0.24 0.39 0.06
1975 0.67 0.34 0.06 0.19 0.33 0.04

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


1980 0.61 0.26 0.05 0.07 0.16 0.23 0.03
1985 0.52 0.21 0.04 0.11 0.19 0.02
1990 0.43 0.19 0.02 0.03 0.07 0.16 0.01
1991 0.43 0.02 0.01
1992 0.42 0.01 0.01
1993 0.39 0.01 0.01
1994 0.39 0.01 0.01
1995 0.39 0.19 0.01 0.01 0.06 0.11 0.01
1996 0.38 0.01 0.01
1997 0.37 0.01 0.00
1998 0.38 0.01 0.00
1999 0.37 0.01 0.02 0.00
2000 0.36 0.17 0.01 0.01 0.05 0.09 0.00
2001 0.35 0.15 0.01 0.01 0.05 0.09 0.00
2002 0.34 0.15 0.00 0.01 0.09 0.00
2003 0.33 0.00 0.01 0.09 0.00
2004 0.32 0.13 0.00 0.01 0.04 0.08 0.00

45
Charles, Fontana and Srivastava

Table A4. Physicans per thousand Index (PI)


India China Singapore Korea Malaysia Thailand Japan

1965 0.001 0.3 0.11 0.27


1970 0.001 0.23 0.16 0.01 0.31
1975 0.001 0.26 0.16 0.01 0.31
1980 0.06 0.34 0.22 0.10 0.02 0.38

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


1981 0.02 0.36 0.23 0.10 0.02 0.38
1985 0.39 0.27 0.14 0.04 0.45
1986 0.39 0.18 0.14 0.05 0.45
1987 0.40 0.17 0.05
1988 0.07 0.44 0.31 0.17 0.06 0.003 0.48
1989 0.46 0.21 0.06 0.01
1990 0.46 0.37 0.21 0.07 0.008 0.52
1991 0.46 0.39 0.24 0.07 0.009
1992 0.01 0.46 0.39 0.27 0.07 0.01 0.52
1993 0.07 0.46 0.41 0.27 0.08 0.01
1994 0.47 0.42 0.31 0.08 0.55
1998 0.11 0.48 0.49 0.38 0.59
1999 0.51 0.39 0.38 0.17 0.03 0.59
2000 0.11 0.49 0.39 0.37 0.17 0.06 0.59
2001 0.29 0.42 0.41 0.17 0.06 0.59
2002 0.12 0.50 0.42 0.45 0.06 0.62
2003 0.13 0.42 0.48 0.06 0.62
2004 0.14 0.41

Table A5. Hospital beds per thousand Index (HoI)


India China Singapore Korea Malaysia Thailand

1960 0.005 0.38 0.09 0.32 0.03


1969 0.10
1970 0.02 0.10 0.32 0.29 0.07
1975 0.02 0.15 0.28 0.28 0.07
1980 0.03 0.17 0.34 0.12 0.11
1981 0.03 0.18 0.34 0.18
1985 0.03 0.19 0.19 0.21
1986 0.19
1987 0.03 0.2 0.19
1990 0.21 0.31 0.26 0.17 0.12
1991 0.04 0.21 0.31 0.28 0.16 0.12
1992 0.04 0.21 0.29 0.29 0.16 0.12
1993 0.21 0.31 0.32 0.16
1994 0.21 0.30 0.36 0.16
1998 0.20 0.45
1999 0.20 0.5 0.17
2000 0.04 0.20 0.26 0.55 0.14 0.17
2001 0.20 0.24 0.55 0.14
2002 0.04 0.19 0.23 0.59 0.17
2003 0.05 0.23 0.64 0.17
2004 0.05 0.17

46
India, China and the East Asian Miracle

Appendix B: Education Index components

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


Table B1. Adult Literary Index (ALI)
India China Singapore Korea Malaysia Thailand

1990 0.49 0.78 0.89 0.96 0.81


1991 0.51 0.79 0.97 0.81
1992 0.97
1997 0.98
1998 0.52 0.98
2000 0.54 0.99 0.85
2001 0.88 0.1 0.85
2002 0.56 0.88 0.1 0.86
2003 0.59 0.90 0.1 0.88
2004 0.61 0.91 0.92 0.1 0.89
2005 0.93

Table B2. School Enrolment Index (SEI)


India China Korea Malaysia

1991 0.98 1 1.05 0.95


1998 0.99 0.97 0.98
1999 0.97 0.95 1
2000 0.99 0.98 0.97
2001 0.98 1 1 0.95
2002 0.99 1 1 0.93
2003 1 1 1 0.93
2004 1 1 1
2005 1

Note: SEI capped at 1 to adjust for multiple enrolments.

Table B3. Progression to Grade 5 Index (PG5I)


India China Korea Malaysia

1991 0.56 0.86 0.99 0.97


1998 0.59 0.96
1999 0.62 0.99
2000 0.59 0.99 0.87
2001 0.61 0.86 0.99 0.87
2002 0.84 0.86 0.99 0.98
2003 0.79 0.86 0.99 0.99
2004 0.79 0.86 0.98

47
Charles, Fontana and Srivastava

Appendix C

Downloaded from http://cjres.oxfordjournals.org/ at University of Iowa Libraries/Serials Acquisitions on June 6, 2015


Figure C1. Real-wage Index in the manufacturing sector of different Asian countries (19802008).
Source: KILM (2006).
Note: The real-wage index is the nominal wages index corrected for changes in purchasing power measured by the consumer price index
in each country with the year 2000 as base 100 (KILM, 2006).

48

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi