Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 13

PARTICIPANTS VALUES AND INCENTIVE PLANS

Regina F. Bento and Lourdes F. White

Incentive plans are designed to motivate participants to pursue what is valued by an or-
ganization. This article discusses how values may influence the design of incentive plans
and the success of their implementation. In situations where the incentive plan fits par-
ticipants values, the authors predict a process of mutual reinforcement. When values
and incentives collide, they propose two possible yet conflicting outcomes: the carrot
effect and the snubbed carrot effect. They conclude by addressing the implications of
fit and misfit for research and practice. 1998 John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

Introduction sessment and implications of the convergence


(fit) or divergence (misfit) of these signals.
Organizations use incentive compensation Practitioners, especially those involved in the
plans to define whom, what, and how they will design and implementation of new incentive
financially reward or punish. Incentive plans plans, have long been aware of the importance
therefore serve as contracts that signal to em- of reward systems in communicating corpo-
ployees participating in the plan the actions rate values (Esquibel, Ning & Sugg, 1990;
and results that are expected from them. Kanin-Lovers, 1987; White, 1985). One of the
Plan participants, however, are also ex- key challenges they currently face is the de-
posed to another set of signals about what is velopment of incentive plans that are consis-
good and bad, acceptable and unacceptable, tent with the organizational context, including
desirable and undesirable in their work envi- cultural, strategic, and financial objectives
ronment. This other set of signals comes from (White & Fife, 1993).
the value system of plan participants. In this Practitioners calls for research in this area In spite of the
context, a value can be viewed as a type of be- have not yet been systematically pursued. In popularity of
lief, centrally located within ones total belief spite of the popularity of the concepts of cul- the concepts of
system, about how one ought or ought not to tural values and of incentive plans, there is cultural values
behave, or about some end-state of existence only limited research that even relates one to and of incentive
plans, there is
worth or not worth attaining (Rokeach, 1972, the other (e.g., Kerr & Slocum, 1987; Lawler,
only limited
p. 124). 1990; OReilly, 1989). A comprehensive study research that
The two sets of signals may point in the by the National Research Council (1991) even relates one
same or to different directions with significant warned that too little attention is paid to the to the other.
implications for the success or failure of in- effects of organizational context, including
centive plans. The existing literature, unfortu- employee values, on the results of incentive
nately, has not adequately addressed the as- plans. Milkovich and Newman (1993) also

Human Resource Management, Spring 1998, Vol. 37, No. 1, Pp. 4759
1998 John Wiley & Sons, Inc. CCC 0090-4848/98/010047-13
48 HUMAN RESOURCE MANAGEMENT, Spring 1998

concluded that unfortunately, little research Values and Incentive Plans


has been done directly on the relationship be-
tween pay systems and the culture and values A value is an enduring belief that a specific
of an organization (p. 18). mode of conduct or end-state of existence is
This article contributes in two significant personally or socially preferable to an opposite
ways to the understanding of participants re- or converse mode of conduct or end-state of ex-
actions to incentive plans. First, it explores the istence (Rokeach, 1973, p. 5). These prefer-
value-driven nature of preferences for different ences are best revealed in practice by the
features of incentive plans. Second, and more trade-offs people make between various ways
importantly, it explores the consequences of fit of behaving in specific situations (Rousseau,
and misfit between the values embedded in in- 1995, p. 50). In this section we explore how
centive plans and those held by plan partici- some basic enduring beliefs and preferences
pants. We argue that the presence or lack of fit about modes of conduct, trade-offs, and in-
between the two sets of values may have a vi- tended outcomes are translated, consciously or
tal effect on the practical results achieved by unconsciously, into different features of
those plans and on the level of the participants incentive plans. Using three sets of dualities
satisfaction with the reward system. equality versus inequality, certainty versus un-
In examining situations of fit, we go certainty, and cooperation versus competi-
beyond the point of plan implementation, tionwe provide examples of how values affect
extending our analysis to discuss the dynam- preferences for certain incentive plan features
ics of mutual reinforcement between partic- over others. Later, we discuss how plan features
ipants values and plan incentives in the interact with the values of plan participants to
period following plan adoption. When explor- influence their reactions to the plan.
ing the effects of misfit, the human resource A duality is an issue that cannot easily be
(HR) professionals and researchers are resolved, because contradictory aspects of the
warned about possible exceptions to previous issue are inevitably present and are simulta-
assumptions in the literature (e.g., Kerr & neously desirable and undesirable (Martin,
Slocum, 1987; Lei, Slocum, & Slater, 1990) Feldman, Hatch, & Sitkin, 1983, p. 447); it
that the incentives provided by the pay plan contains, therefore, two opposing truths.
will send signals strong enough to bring about Dualities are particularly helpful in the study
a change in valuesthe proverbial carrot ef- of incentive plan design, since such design re-
fect. In practice, values may prove too re- quires many choices involving opposing alter-
silient to be so easily changed. We argue here natives that can be justified on the basis of op-
that human resource professionals and re- posing values.
searchers need to be aware that, when pay Our selection of three dualities is not
plan and values collide, the values held by plan meant to imply that they contain the only val-
participants may be more powerful than the ues that should be considered in assessing fit.
incentive plan in determining their decisions. Their selection was based on the fact that they
In other words, plan participants may stick have received considerable attention in the lit-
to their values and the behaviors supported erature on cultural values, particularly as they
by those values, shunning the incentives pro- influence workplace behavior (Hofstede,
vided by the plan. We call this outcome the 1984; Martin, 1992; Schein, 1992). These
snubbed carrot effect. values have also been highlighted in the man-
In the next section, we provide examples agement accounting literature where they
of how values may be reflected in particular have been related to preferences for certain
aspects of incentive plans. This is followed by characteristics of control systems (e.g., Birn-
a series of propositions regarding how fit and berg & Snodgrass, 1988; Chow, Kato &
misfit between participants values and incen- Shields, 1994; Ueno & Wu, 1993).
tive plans can affect the outcomes of plan im- It is not our purpose to engage in a theo-
plementation, as well as participants satisfac- retical discussion of all possible values that are
tion with the plan. Finally, we discuss the important for an exhaustive assessment of fit.
implications of these ideas for research and We are simply using the three value dualities
practice. to exemplify how the choice of incentive plan
Participants Values and Incentive Plans 49

features may, consciously or unconsciously, would be justified, and hierarchical dif-


reflect value preferences rather than self-evi- ferences would not need to be reinforced
dent truths. through the pay system. Salary levels and
bonus formulas would relate only loosely to
hierarchical position; instead, they would
Equality Versus Inequality be based on objectives negotiated through par-
ticipative goal-setting (Shields & Young, 1993)
Some deeply ingrained values affect expecta- and decentralized plan decision making. The
tions about the normal spread of perfor- range of pay differentials would depend on the Equality and
inequality values
mance potential in the workplace, in terms of spread in the achievement of targets such as
underlie many
the magnitude, source, and consequences of expense control, inventory management, choices made
differences in employee skills and abilities. product quality, productivity, and employee during the design
These values may fall on either side of the morale. of incentive
equality versus inequality duality. The equal- It is possible, therefore, for incentive plans.
ity side emphasizes similarities over differ- plans based on equality beliefs to yield small
ences. People are believed to be intrinsically or large pay differentials. Under equality be-
similar in their performance potential: If they liefs, HR professionals would not take small
exert the same level of effort, and benefit from pay differentials as a sign that the plan did not
equal opportunities for training and experi- work. If target setting, performance appraisal,
ence, they can be expected to reach roughly and allocation of rewards proceeded according
the same high levels of performance. The in- to plan, HR specialists would welcome the
equality side stresses differences. People are narrow differentials in performance and pay as
perceived as having a wide range of stable dif- a sign that the plan was able to motivate par-
ferences in their abilities and skills, which fol- ticipants across the board. In situations where
low a normal curve distribution; those differ- the plan produced large pay differentials, re-
ences are expected to remain even after flecting large spreads in actual achievement,
employees are exposed to various opportuni- equality beliefs would lead HR professionals
ties for learning and skill acquisition, leading to consider the need for changes in other ar-
to large spreads in performance. eas that affect performance, such as training,
Equality and inequality values underlie selection, improved communications, and job
many choices made during the design of in- design.
centive plans. As shown in Table I, this duali- In contrast, assumptions of inequality
ty affects several issues in plan design and im- would justify high power distances. Hier-
plementation. archies would be perceived as the rightful
For example, equality beliefs would lead institutionalization of significant and stable
hierarchies to be seen as mere administrative differences among people, with the most wor-
conveniences (Hofstede, 1984), based on lev- thy at the top. Plan design and goal-
els of experience and training rather than in- setting would thus be centralized in the hands
herently significant differences in skills and of an elite group of experts and top manage-
potential. Consequently, low power distances ment; salaries, bonus formulas, and other in-

TABLE I Equality Versus Inequality Values and Incentive Plans.

Incentive Plan Issue Equality Inequality

Plan decision making and Low power distances, High power distances,
implementation participative goal-setting, centralized decisions by
decentralized decisions elite group
Link between pay and Loosely linked Closely linked
hierarchical levels
Desirable range of pay Small performance differentials Large performance spreads lead
diversity lead to small pay differentials to large pay differentials
50 HUMAN RESOURCE MANAGEMENT, Spring 1998

centives would closely reflect and reinforce Table II illustrates some of the influences
ones position in the pecking order of the or- that the certainty versus uncertainty duality
ganization. Large pay differentials would be may exert on incentive plan design and imple-
the expected result of naturally large spreads mentation.
in performance (Whittlesey & Maurer, 1993). Certainty values imply that plan partici-
Under inequality beliefs, if the plan resulted pants should be able to predict (with reason-
in small pay differentials, HR professionals able accuracy) how their actions will lead to
would see this as a failure to capture existing desired rewards. In terms of HR practice,
differences in performance, possibly due to these values would indicate the need for in-
problems in the target setting and perfor- centive plans to provide clear guidelines re-
mance appraisal processes. garding, for example, how base pay will vary
over time (such as objective rules about pay
variation linked to merit, length of tenure in
Certainty Versus Uncertainty position, and promotions) and how incentive
pay will be calculated as a function of perfor-
Certainty values The second duality has to do with the optimal mance (e.g., formula-based bonuses). Base
imply that plan variability of the environment in which people salary would represent a relatively large per-
participants
should be able to operate (Hofstede, 1984), and reflects core centage of total pay (Chow, Merchant, and
predict (with beliefs about the relationships between indi- Wu, 1993); cost of living adjustments would
reasonable viduals and organizations (Schein, 1992). For be provided on a regular basis; and bonuses
accuracy) how those who believe in the certainty side of this would be linked to achievable budget targets
their actions will duality, a higher degree of predictability in the in order to increase management commitment
lead to desired
rewards.
transactions between organizations and their and decrease control costs (Merchant, 1990).
employees is expected to foster productivity, HR professionals would assume that relative-
efficiency, and stability. For example, certain- ly small rewards linked to highly achievable
ty values would support strategies that pre- targets are more motivating than potentially
serve predictability and mutual trust even in large bonuses for reaching stretch targets.
the face of current trends toward downsizing Under certainty values, organizations
and cost reduction (Cameron, 1994; Mishra & would be expected to shield employees from
Mishra, 1994). environmental uncertainty (Milliken, 1987),
For those on the uncertainty side of the following the classic controllability princi-
duality, unpredictability is perceived as neces- plei.e., that employees should not be held
sary for keeping employees on their toes, accountable for factors outside their control
challenging them to strive, innovate, take (Solomons, 1965). This principle, which is ex-
risks, and exercise their curiosity and creativi- tensively discussed in the management con-
ty. Rightsizing is expected to lead not only to trol literature (e.g., Demski, 1976; Merchant,
workforce reduction and cost cutting but also 1989), implies that HR professionals should
to increased productivity and motivation on make sure that the incentive plan includes
the part of the remaining employees. provisions to remove the effect of uncontrol-

TABLE II Certainty Versus Uncertainty Values and Incentive Plans.

Incentive Plan Issue Certainty Uncertainty

Degree of objectivity in High (objective rules, Low (subjective process)


determining total pay formula-based bonuses)
Percentage of total Low (mostly base pay) High (significant variable
pay at risk pay, stock bonuses)
Standard tightness Achievable budget targets Tight challenging standards
Accounting for Extensive use of No specific provisions for
uncontrollable factors in controllability filters controllability filters
performance evaluation
Participants Values and Incentive Plans 51

lable factors when evaluating performance Cooperation Versus Competition


(Chow, Merchant, & Wu, 1993; Young & Sel-
to, 1993). Uncontrollable factors may include This third duality refers to preferences for
Cooperative
the following: scheduling problems caused by one of two modes of interaction among orga-
values support
other organizational units; actions taken by nizational members. Such preferences are incentive plans
competitors, suppliers, or regulators; changes based on beliefs about which mode of interac- that reward
in the economy or consumer behavior; acts of tion is more conducive to the achievement of participants who
nature, and so on (Chow, Shields, & Wu, overall organizational goals (Deutsch, 1949; subordinate their
1994; Merchant, 1987, 1989). Tjosvold, 1984). One side of the duality would particular
interests to the
Adjustments for uncontrollable factors regard cooperation as the best way to channel collective good;
may be implemented in practice by the use of individual effort into collective purpose and cooperation
controllability filters (Demski, 1976; Mer- action. The other would believe that organiza- also prizes
chant, 1989). One common filter is the use of tional goals are more likely to be achieved harmonious
relative performance measures and bench- through competition among self-interested in- vertical and
horizontal
marking (Janakiraman, Lambert & Larkee, dividuals or teams, all of them putting out interpersonal
1992; Maher, 1987). This filter allows the their best effort to become the winner. relationships.
comparison with the performance of peers, Table III shows some main areas of impact
inside or outside the organization, who sup- of the cooperation versus competition duality
posedly have had to cope with the same un- on incentive plan design and implementation.
controllable factors. Another typical controlla- Cooperative values support incentive
bility filter consists of the application of plans that reward participants who subordi-
revised scenarios, in which flexible budgets nate their particular interests to the collective
are used to recalculate performance variances good; cooperation also prizes harmonious ver-
in light of what actually happened (Horngren, tical and horizontal interpersonal relation-
Foster, & Datar, 1994). ships. Valuing cooperation entails two key
In contrast, the uncertainty side of the practical HR implications. First, cooperative
duality would lead to incentive plans with an values justify the use of absolute measures of
opposite set of features. Innovation, risk- performance, which compare results against
taking, and motivation would be increased by pre-established goals. Second, cooperative
attaching significantly high rewards to end re- values lead to the avoidance of direct compar-
sults, letting plan participants figure out on isons among individuals or among groups. As
their own how to accomplish those results and Kohn (1992) characterizes it, cooperation is
cope with uncontrollable factors, and holding an arrangement that is not merely noncom-
them accountable for achieving plan targets. petitive but requires us to work together to
HR professionals would not focus on protect- achieve our goals (p. 6). Therefore, rewards
ing plan participants from environmental un- may be distributed, for example, through some
certainty; rather, the key issue would be to form of profit sharing, and calculated primar-
offer incentives large enough to make it worth- ily on the basis of the results achieved by the
while for employees to be successful in coping whole corporation. Individual and group per-
with such uncertainty. Lured by the promise formance may still be evaluated separately, but
of substantial rewards, participants would do not used to compare one individual or one
their best to anticipate and creatively respond group against another.
to changes in the environment. In order to preserve reasonably smooth in-
Accordingly, uncertainty values would jus- terpersonal relationships under cooperative
tify plan features such as the following: larger values, the evaluation process should provide
percentages of pay at risk; rewards in the form face-saving procedures, thus avoiding em-
of stock, rather than cash; performance tar- barrassment, jealousy, resentment, and other
gets set at very challenging levels and linked to threats to a cooperative spirit. In this context,
the prospect of commensurably large rewards the role of the evaluator is primarily that of a
(Simons, 1988; Chow, Shields & Wu, 1993); mentor, and the emphasis in the evaluation
and no special provisions for the use of con- feedback is on encouraging the profession-
trollability filters in performance appraisal al development of plan participants. As de-
and allocation of rewards. scribed by Kunda (1992), cooperative beliefs
52 HUMAN RESOURCE MANAGEMENT, Spring 1998

TABLE III Cooperation Versus Competition Values and Incentive Plans.

Incentive Plan Issue Cooperative Competitive

Performance measures Absolute measures Relative measures, ranking, and forced


performance spreads
Evaluation process Avoidance of interpersonal and Structural competition; encouragement
intergroup comparisons, to of winlose comparisons, zero-sum
preserve smooth relationships tournament models
Role of evaluator Evaluator as a mentor, emphasis Evaluator as a judge, emphasis on
on professional development, identifying winners and losers
and face-saving procedures

require that even those who are evaluated as Cultural Fit and Misfit of Incentive Plans
failures should be able to preserve their self-
esteem and loyalty, as well as the respect of The values embedded in incentive plans and
their peers. those held by plan participants may converge
On the other hand, when competitive be- (Fit scenario) or diverge (Misfit scenario).
liefs prevail, plan participants are expected to
strive not only to do their own best, but also to
outperform their peers. This is consistent with Fit Scenario
performance appraisals that use ranking and
forced spreads (relative performance mea- We propose that a dynamic process happens in
sures), creating zero-sum tournament models the Fit scenario. When the plan is first imple-
(Nalbantian, 1987): when one person or team mented, participants perceive it as rewarding
wins, another has to lose. The unit of per- behaviors that are congruent with their own
formance measurement may be either the in- value system. This initial fit will set in motion
dividual or the group; the distinctive feature is a process through which plan and partici-
that structural competition (Kohn, 1992) is pants values will reinforce each other over
used to enable comparisons within and across time.
groups. Consider, for example, that the duality in
Competitive values lead to laurels and vis- question refers to inequality versus equality.
ible recognitions for the winners, while the Lets assume, further, that the incentive plan
losers are challenged to strive harder to be- is driven by equality values and contains fea-
come themselves winners next time around. tures intended to foster participation, low
Thus incentives may be viewed as either power distances, decentralized decisions, and
reward or punishment. The role of the evalu- loose links between pay and hierarchical lev-
ator is to serve as a judge, handing out assess- els. If plan participants also hold equality val-
ments of success and failure. Under competi- ues, the implementation of such a plan will set
tive beliefs, more emphasis tends to be placed in motion a reinforcement process, through
on formal communication and coordination in which the egalitarian values of participants
both goal-setting (e.g., during budget prepara- will, after a while, become even stronger. In
tion) and evaluation processes, to ensure that turn, the egalitarian values held by partici-
conflicting goals will not hinder the achieve- pants will themselves support the kinds of be-
ment of overall organizational goals (Ueno & haviors and outcomes targeted by the plan, in-
Wu, 1993). If the competitively pursued tar- creasing the likelihood that the plan will reach
gets are well formulated, they should serve as its intended effects or even surpass them.
Adam Smiths (1937) invisible hand, guiding HR specialists and others involved in plan
the efforts of individuals and teams so that the implementation may find that the plans abili-
aggregate performance of the organization ty to influence participants behavior goes well
ends up being higher than if they had tried to beyond what could be reasonably expected
cooperate. from the extrinsic rewards being offered. Par-
Participants Values and Incentive Plans 53

ticipants will be so naturally inclined to re- itarian values shared by plan participants, two
spond to the plan that even small incentives effects are possible.
may lead to what would otherwise be seen as The first possible effect is that the plan
disproportionately large effects. This will, in will result in a change in values. Based on the
turn, bolster the perception that the plan is literature on learning (Bandura, 1977; Skin-
based on the right beliefs, thereby accentu- ner, 1971), motivation (Vroom, 1964), and
ating the equality features of the plan, as it is agency theories (Demski & Feltham, 1978),
formally and informally implemented over we can predict that the incentives will lead
successive cycles of evaluations and rewards. participants to change their values about the
A similar process may happen in regard significance and desirability of hierarchical
to other dualities relevant to incentive plans differences and privileges. They may take ac-
(certainty versus uncertainty, cooperation ver- tions and strive for results that will enable
sus competition, or other sets of values), as them to enjoy the increases in pay, status, and
summarized in the following propositions: perks promised in the plan (Kerr & Slocum,
1987; Lei, Slocum, & Slater, 1990). This car-
Proposition (1): In scenarios of fit between
rot effect may, over time, weaken the initially
plan and participants values, one will rein-
egalitarian values of plan participants and
force the other.
eventually lead them toward inegalitarian
Proposition (1a): The behaviors and be-
values.
liefs in the value system of plan partic-
ipants that are rewarded and valued by From the perspective of the HR specialist,
the incentive plan will increase in fre- this change in values and consequent solu-
quency and intensity over time. En- tion to misfit problems may be achieved
couraged by the plan, participants be- through any of the three main mechanisms for
liefs will lean even more strongly transmission of cultural values (Harrison &
toward their favored side of a given du- Carroll, 1991): the selection of future em-
ality. ployees whose values best fit the plan as-
The literature
Proposition (1b): The values of plan sumptions, the use of vigorous socialization, on values has
participants will reinforce the intended and the turnover of those who leave the or- consistently
effects of the incentive plan on those ganization voluntarily or through attrition emphasized the
behaviors and beliefs which are (Chatman, 1991). In such cases, the plan will permanent
deemed desirable by both the partici- achieve its intended results. nature of values
(in contrast with
pants and the incentive plan. Support- The carrot effect is consistent with the attitudes), as well
ed by the values held by plan partici- view, so popular in the 1980s, that cultures as their stability
pants, the incentive plan will be more and the values embedded in them can be con- and resilience
likely to attain, or surpass, its intended sciously designed and manipulated by man- to short-term,
results. agers for the sake of improving organizational limited change
Proposition (2): The stronger the fit be- efforts.
performance (Barley & Kunda, 1992, p. 383).
tween plan and participants values, the According to this view, it is managements re-
higher will be the satisfaction of plan par- sponsibility to design, shape, and change the
ticipants with the pay system.
organizations cultural values (Peters & Wa-
terman, 1982).
On the other hand, another effect may
Misfit Scenario happen. The literature on values has consis-
tently emphasized the permanent nature of
Misfit scenarios are those in which plan val- values (in contrast with attitudes), as well as
ues collide with the shared beliefs of plan par- their stability and resilience to short-term,
ticipants. These situations can be created ei- limited change efforts (e.g., England, 1967;
ther inadvertently or by design, in an attempt Rokeach, 1973; Schein, 1992). In practice,
to use the incentive plan to change the partic- HR specialists are well aware of numerous
ipants values. Predicting the ensuing results cases of organizations that attempted to
is less straightforward here than in the fit change their values by adopting new incentive
scenario. For example, when a plan based on systems, only to find out that plan participants
inequality beliefs is superimposed on the egal- simply ended up manipulating the system to
54 HUMAN RESOURCE MANAGEMENT, Spring 1998

make it conform to their own old preferred The snubbed carrot effect may thus ex-
ways of behaving (e.g., Ehrenfeld, 1992). plain some of the situations in which incentive
In some instances, participants may de- plans do not seem to work, become dysfunc-
cide to adopt behaviors that are actually op- tional, or are discarded. It is interesting to
posite to what is intended by the incentive note that this effect may happen regardless of
plan. Lawler (1971), for example, provides ev- how rational the incentive plan may seem.
idence that factory workers dissatisfied with For example, Ansari and Bell (1991), in their
an incentive plan designed to increase pro- study of the effects of cultural values on ac-
ductivity responded by intentionally restrict- counting control systems (including formal
ing output. Even though there have been and informal incentives), concluded that the
several studies that documented such unin- acceptance of a control system rests, there-
tended reactions to incentive plans, they have fore, not on how rational it is, but on how well
not explicitly linked those reactions to the val- it reflects the value system of its participants
ues held by plan participants (George, Brief & and the belief system within which it operates
Webster, 1991). (p. 24).
We argue that the incentives provided by a One important implication of the snubbed
new incentive plan may not be strong enough carrot effect for HR specialists is that the like-
One important to go against the grain of plan participants lihood of successful plan implementation may
implication on deeply held shared beliefs, values, and assump- not depend on how good, carefully designed,
the snubbed
carrot effect for tions. The incentives may be shunned, in what or apparently rational a plan may be. If a plan
HR specialists we call here the snubbed carrot effect. goes against deeply held participants values, it
is that the Plan participants may simply try to distort may face subtle or overt challenges through-
likelihood of and subvert the implementation of the incen- out its implementation. The HR specialist
successful plan tive plan. Instead of being lured by the should be prepared to anticipate, detect, and
implemation may
not depend on
promised rewards into changing their own be- react to those challenges.
how good, haviors and values, they re-shape the prac- The carrot and snubbed carrot effects may
carefully tice of the plan, in formal or informal ways, to arise from misfit along any duality relevant to
designed, or align it with their values. incentive plans, as captured in the following
apparently For example, if the participants hold propositions:
rational a plan
strong egalitarian beliefs, but the plan sharply
may be.
reinforces differences in pay, status, and Proposition (3): In scenarios of misfit be-
perks, participants may manipulate plan im- tween plan and participants values, the
plementation so as to reduce those differ- conflicting signals sent by each will set in
ences. This manipulation may affect various motion a change in either of the following
aspects of the performance evaluation and re- directions:
ward process, sending warning signals to the Proposition (3a): If the incentives pro-
HR specialist that plan implementation is not vided by the plan are strong enough to
override the influence of participants
proceeding as originally intended. Partici-
values, the plan will prevail. Some plan
pants, for instance, may counteract the in-
participants will adjust their behaviors
egalitarian effects of the plan by inflating per-
and beliefs to reap the promised re-
formance ratings across the board, or even
wards; others, who cannot be swayed by
circumvent the effects of forced-ranking per- the incentives, will leave the organiza-
formance evaluations by creating informal ro- tion; and the plan will help attract and
tation systems, where they take turns as top per- retain other people whose values match
formers (Bento & Ferreira, 1992). In practice, its own. Over time, the incentive plan
the carrots in the plan are not enough to lure will move the values held by partici-
participants away from their deep-seated val- pants toward the plans favored side of
ues. Instead, participants may not only snub each of the dualities (the carrot effect).
the carrots, but actually pull the plan closer Proposition (3b): If the incentives are
and closer to their own views over several cycles not enough to induce plan participants
of evaluations and rewards until the plan, as im- to move away from the behaviors and
plemented, fits their values . . . or breaks down. beliefs ingrained in their value system,
Participants Values and Incentive Plans 55

participants values will prevail. Plan It proposes that there are many crucial features
participants will disregard or subvert of incentive plans which are not self-evident
the incentives provided by the plan, but reflect value-driven choices; exemplify how
thereby weakening or reversing its certain underlying values are translated into
intended results (the snubbed carrot specific plan features; offer HR specialists the
effect). language of dualities to articulate and com-
Proposition (4): As long as there is misfit be- pare the values of plan participants with the val-
tween plan and participants values, plan ues embedded in incentive plans; and explore
participants will be dissatisfied with the pay the possible consequences of fit and misfit be-
system. tween those two sets of values.
Proposition (4a): Under the carrot ef-
In situations of fit, we predict that partic-
fect, dissatisfaction will continue until
ipants values will leverage the effects of plan
a change in participants values brings
incentives, leading to more than proportional
about a new fit with the incentive plan.
Proposition (4b): Under the snubbed
effects. In other words, seemingly modest in-
carrot effect, dissatisfaction will con- centives might be sufficient to yield large re-
tinue until the enactment of the plan is sults in desired behaviors and satisfaction with
(formally or informally) altered enough the plan. In situations of misfit, we warn HR
to fit the values of plan participants. specialists of possible trouble. Plan incentives
may be able to override the influence of op-
posing participants values (the carrot effect),
Conclusion but this may take longer and require more re-
sources than expected. Worse yet, partici-
In the 1970s and 1980s, an ever increasing pants values may be strong enough to lead
number of organizations jumped onto the them to shun plan incentives, in what we call
bandwagon of paying for performance, despite the snubbed carrot effect: They may manipu-
conflicting evidence about the influence of in- late plan implementation, in overt or subtle
centive plans on individual or firm perfor- ways, so that in practice the plan is either
mance (Guzzo, Jette, & Katzell, 1985). In the forced to adapt to their values or is abandoned
1990s, the jury is still out in regard to the abil- altogether.
ity of incentive plans to deliver their intended Furthermore, when an incentive plan is
results in the short or long term (Kohn, 1993). intentionally designed to bring about a change
This article proposes that these mixed results in participants values, we argue that HR spe-
can be explained at least in part by the fact that cialists should be prepared to face significant
incentive plans are not implemented in a vac- dissatisfaction with the plan. This dissatisfac-
uum. We argue that the effects of plan incen- tion will last until the misfit is resolved, either
tives depend on their interaction with another by an eventual change in participants values
strong set of forces: the enduring values of (in response to the carrot effect) or by formal
plan participants. or informal changes in the plan (due to the
The notion that fit matters has an intu- snubbed carrot effect).
itive appeal. One might wonder, therefore, Given all these predictions, what can HR
why incentive plans are so often implemented, professionals do? First, we recommend that,
in practice, without explicit consideration of starting in the earliest design stages, they de-
how they might reinforce or collide with pre- vote particular attention to the degree of fit be-
existing values of participants. This is not so tween participants values and the various fea-
surprising, however, if one realizes that there tures incorporated in the incentive plan. This
is very little in the literature to help HR spe- will require efforts to identify the values of
cialists with some very practical issues: what participants and to unearth the values under-
types of fit matter, how to assess fit, what to lying incentive plan issues. The dualities ex-
expect as a consequence of different degrees amined in this article should help guide those
and types of fit. efforts by providing both a vocabulary and
This article is an initial step in the long some key dimensions for comparing the two
journey toward the answers to these questions. sets of values.
56 HUMAN RESOURCE MANAGEMENT, Spring 1998

Second, when allocating resources to im- fore organizations can effectively act as value-
plement the incentive plan, HR professionals socializing agents (Rokeach, 1973).
should take into consideration the level of fit Further empirical research is now need-
or misfit that has been incorporated into the ed to explore the complex relationships be-
plan. In a fit scenario, resources (financial and tween values and incentive compensation. In
otherwise) might be saved through a careful the discussion of fit and misfit scenarios, we
evaluation of the leverage expected from the attempted to indicate the expected general di-
strength of pre-existing participants values. In rection of shifts in participants and plan val-
contrast, if plan designers decide to use the ues over time. The current state of theory de-
plan to change those values, they should be velopment in this area does not allow us to
prepared to invest additional resources to pay make more specific predictions regarding
for the successful resolution of this intention- magnitude of change; the time required for
al misfit. When participants values push them different effects to take place; the factors that
in one direction, and the carrots in the incen- explain when and why misfit will lead to ei-
tive plan try to pull them in a different one, ther the carrot or snubbed carrot effects; or
this tug of war will require substantial rein- how, exactly, the dissatisfaction caused by
forcements in order for the plan to prevail. misfit will set in motion the forces that ulti-
This means that the incentives will have to be mately reestablish fit through either of those
commensurate to the level of misfit and will effects.
likely have to be sustained over several cycles Particular effort should be made in future
of evaluations and rewards. The carrot effect studies to identify other variables that may
takes time and demands an ongoing commit- moderate the relationships proposed in this
ment on the part of the organization. In the article. For example, the effects of fit and mis-
meantime, given the predicted dissatisfaction fit may be influenced by the following vari-
of plan participants, further resources must be ables:
invested to handle the potentially high costs of
voluntary and involuntary turnover, as well as 1. individual characteristics that affect
the costs of continuously monitoring plan im- identification with organizational val-
plementation in order to detect and respond to ues (e.g., age, gender, risk preferences,
the warning signals of plan mutation due to level of education, experience, hierar-
the snubbed carrot effect. chical level, and tenure), or ability to
Third, HR professionals should note that voice opposition, subvert the plan, or
the importance of values implies that the suc- leave the organization if dissatisfied
Third, HR cess of plan implementation may be signifi- with the plan;
professionals cantly influenced by education and socializa- 2. organizational factors such as size,
should note that tion efforts. Even when there is a good fit stage in organizational life cycle, tech-
the importance
between the values underlying the plan and nology, and linkage between plan and
of values implies
that the success the values of plan participants, this fit may not other human resources and value
of plan be self-evident. Throughout plan implementa- change initiatives (Harrison & Carroll,
implementation tion, HR professionals should make a special 1991); the extent to which the incen-
may be effort to communicate how the plan features tive plan is congruent with organiza-
significantly celebrate the values of participants and how tional strategy, structure, and process
influenced by
education and the plan promotes the goals that are dear to (Lawler, 1990); the existence of similar
socialization them. In situations of misfit, HR professionals plans inside or outside the organiza-
efforts. should invest heavily in education and social- tion; strength of incentives provided by
ization efforts. In a war of values, financial the plan; the strength of the values
weapons must be combined with more in- shared by plan participants (Gordon &
depth, far-reaching social and psychological DiTomaso, 1992); the degree of cul-
instruments for sustainable learning of new tural homogeneity within the organiza-
values and behaviors. This type of learning is tion (Martin, 1992; Sackmann, 1992);
obviously not easy and requires a deeper un- and similarity to industry or occupa-
derstanding of the process of value change be- tional values;
Participants Values and Incentive Plans 57

3. environmental conditions such as the Awareness of the intended and unintend-


effect of the economic climate on ones ed effects of fit and misfit should advance both
ability to control results; job market the theory and practice of incentive plan de-
conditions; societal values; and indus- sign and implementation. Organizations invest
try-related risks (Gordon, 1991). enormous resources (financial and otherwise)
in trying to promote organizational change
This type of research has substantial prac- through new incentive plans. Understanding
tical relevance, particularly for organizations the dynamics of fit and misfit between incen-
undergoing mergers or acquisitions, facing in- tives and values should increase the likelihood
creasing work force diversity, and operating in that these resources will indeed lead to the in-
different countries or industries. tended results.

Regina Bento is Associate Professor of Management at the Merrick School of Business,


University of Baltimore. She received a Ph.D. in management from the Massachusetts In-
stitute of Technology (1990) and an M.D. degree, with a specialization in psychiatry, from
the Federal University of Rio de Janeiro, Brazil (1977). Her research has focused on the
behavioral determinants and consequences of various types of organizational change, par-
ticularly in the areas of reward systems and information technology. Her work has appeared
in numerous publications, including books and journals such as Journal of Managerial Psy-
chology, Information and Management, and others.

Lourdes F. White is Assistant Professor of Accounting at the University of Baltimore.


Prior to that, she was in the faculty of the University of Southern California. She holds a
doctorate in business from Harvard University and an M.S. in management from the Fed-
eral University of Rio de Janeiro. She has published research in incentive compensation,
performance measurement, budgeting and field research methods, including several works
by the Harvard Business School Press. Prior to her doctoral studies, she worked at the con-
trollers office of the City of Rio de Janeiro.

REFERENCES

Ansari, S., & Bell, J. (1991). Symbolism, collectivism and ratio- Chow, C., Kato, Y., & Shields, M. (1994). National culture and
nality in organisational control. Accounting, Auditing and Ac- the preference for management controls: An exploratory
countability Journal, 4(2), 427. study of the firm-labor market interface. Accounting, Organi-
Bandura, A. (1977). Social learning theory. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: zations and Society, 19(45), 381400.
Prentice-Hall. Chow, C., Merchant, K., & Wu, A. (1993). Measurement, evalu-
Barley, S., & Kunda, G. (1992). Design and devotion: Surges of ation and reward of profit center managers: A cross-cultural
rational and normative ideologies of control in managerial field study. Working paper, University of Southern California,
discourse. Administrative Science Quarterly, 37, 363399. Los Angeles, CA.
Bento, R., & Ferreira, L. (1992). Incentive pay and organiza- Chow, C., Shields, M., & Wu, A. (1993). National culture and
tional culture. In W. Bruns, Jr. (Ed.), Performance measure- the transfer of management control systems across national
ment, evaluation and incentives (pp. 157180). Boston: Har- boundaries. Paper presented at a research seminar at the Uni-
vard Business School Press. versity of Pittsburgh, PA.
Birnberg, J., & Snodgrass, C. (1988). Culture and control: A field Chow, C., Shields, M., & Wu, A. (1994). The role of national cul-
study. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 13(5), ture in the cross-border transfer of accounting controls. Paper
447464. presented at the Accounting, Behavior and Organizations
Cameron, K. (1994). Investigating organizational downsizing: Conference, San Antonio, TX.
Fundamental issues. Human Resource Management, 33(2): Demski, J. (1976). Uncertainty and evaluation based on con-
183188. trollable performance. Journal of Accounting Research, 14
Chatman, J. (1991). Matching people and organizations: Selec- (Autumn), 230245.
tion and socialization in public accounting firms. Adminis- Demski, J., & Feltham, G. (1978). Economic incentives in bud-
trative Science Quarterly, 31, 459. getary control systems. The Accounting Review, 53, 336359.
58 HUMAN RESOURCE MANAGEMENT, Spring 1998

Deutsch, M. (1949). An experimental study of the effects of co- Merchant, K. (1987). How and why firms disregard the control-
operation and competition upon group process. Human Re- lability principle. In W. Bruns, Jr., & R. Kaplan (Eds.),
lations, 2, 199231. Accounting and management: Field study perspectives
Ehrenfeld, T. (1992). The case of the unpopular pay plan. Har- (pp. 316338). Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.
vard Business Review (JanuaryFebruary), 1423. Merchant, K. (1989). Rewarding results: Motivating profit center
England, G. (1967). Personal value systems of American man- managers. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.
agers. Academy of Management Journal (March), 5368. Merchant, K. (1990). How challenging should profit budget tar-
Esquibel, O., Ning, J., & Sugg, J. (1990). New salary system sup- gets be? Management Accounting (November), 4648.
ports changing culture. HR Magazine, 35(10), 43. Milkovich, G., & Newman, J. (1993). Compensation. Home-
George, J., Brief, A., & Webster, J. (1991). Organizationally wood, IL: BPI/Irwin.
intended and unintended coping: The case of an incentive Milliken, F. (1987). Three types of uncertainty about the envi-
compensation plan. Journal of Occupational Psychology, 64, ronment: State, effect, and response uncertainty. Academy of
193205. Management Review, 12, 133143.
Gordon, G. (1991). Industry determinants of organizational cul- Mishra, A., & Mishra, K. (1994). The role of mutual trust in ef-
ture. Academy of Management Review, 16(2), 396415. fective downsizing strategies. Human Resource Management,
Gordon, G., & DiTomaso, N. (1992). Predicting corporate per- 33(2), 261276.
formance from organizational culture. Journal of Manage- Nalbantian, H. (1987). Incentive compensation in perspective.
ment Studies, 29(6), 783798. In H. Nalbantian (Ed.), Incentives, cooperation and risk shar-
Guzzo, R., Jette, R., & Katzell, R. (1985). The effects of psycho- ing: Economic and psychological perspectives on employment
logically-based intervention programs on worker productivity: contracts (pp. 343). Totowa, NJ: Rowman & Littlefield.
A meta-analysis. Personnel Psychology, 38, 275. National Research Council (1991). Pay for performance: Evalu-
Harrison, J., & Carroll, G. (1991). Keeping the faith: A model of ating performance appraisal and merit pay. Washington, DC:
cultural transmission in formal organizations. Administrative National Academy Press.
Science Quarterly, 36, 552582. OReilly, C. (1989). Corporations, culture and commitment: Mo-
Hofstede, G. (1984). Cultures consequences: International dif- tivational and social control in organizations. California Man-
ferences in work-related values. Beverly Hills: Sage. agement Review, 31(4), 925.
Horngren, C., Foster, G., & Datar, S. (1994). Cost accounting: A Peters, T., & Waterman, R. (1982). In search of excellence. New
managerial emphasis. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall. York: Harper and Row.
Janakiraman, S., Lambert, R., & Larcker, D. (1992). An empiri- Rokeach, M. (1972). Beliefs, attitudes and values. San Francis-
cal investigation of the relative performance evaluation hy- co: Jossey-Bass.
pothesis. Journal of Accounting Research (Spring), 5369. Rokeach, M. (1973). The nature of human values. New York: Free
Kanin-Lovers, J. (1987). How salary management communi- Press.
cates corporate values. Journal of Compensation and Benefits, Rousseau, D. (1995). Psychological contracts in organizations.
(JulyAugust), 4245. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Kerr, J., & Slocum, J. (1987). Managing corporate culture Sackmann, S. (1992). Culture and subcultures: An analysis of
through reward systems. Academy of Management Executive, organizational knowledge. Administrative Science Quarterly,
1(2), 99108. 37, 140161.
Kohn, A. (1992). No contest: The case against competition. New Schein, E. (1992). Organizational Culture and Leadership. San
York: Houghton Mifflin. Francisco: Jossey-Bass.
Kohn, A. (1993). Why incentive plans cannot work. Harvard Shields, M., & Young, S. (1993). Antecedents and consequences
Business Review (SeptemberOctober), 5463. of participative budgeting: Evidence on the effects of asym-
Kunda, G. (1992). Engineering culture: Control and commitment metrical information. Journal of Management Accounting Re-
in a high-tech corporation. Philadelphia: Temple University search, 5, 265280.
Press. Simons, R. (1988). Analysis of the organizational characteristics
Lawler, E. (1971). Pay and organizational effectiveness: A psycho- related to tight budget goals. Contemporary Accounting Re-
logical view. New York: McGraw-Hill. search, 5(1), 267283.
Lawler, E. (1990). Strategic pay: Aligning organizational strate- Skinner, B. (1971). Contingencies of reinforcement. East Nor-
gies and pay systems. San Francisco: Sage. walk, CT: Appleton-Century-Crofts.
Lei, D., Slocum, J., & Slater, R. (1990). Global strategy and re- Smith, A. (1937). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the
ward systems: The key roles of management development and Wealth of Nations. New York: Modern Library (originally pub-
corporate culture. Organizational Dynamics, 19(2), 2741. lished in 1776).
Maher, M. (1987). The use of relative performance evaluation in Solomons, D. (1965). Divisional performance: Measurement and
organizations. In W. Bruns, Jr., & R. Kaplan (Eds.), Account- control. Homewood, IL: Dow Jones-Irwin.
ing and management: Field study perspectives (pp. 295315). Tjosvold, D. (1984). Cooperation theory and organizations. Hu-
Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press. man Relations, 37(9), 743767.
Martin, J. (1992). Cultures in organizations. Three perspectives. Ueno, S., & Wu, F. (1993). The comparative influence of culture
New York: Oxford University Press. on budget control practices in the United States and Japan.
Martin, J., Feldman, M., Hatch, M., & Sitkin, S. (1983). The The International Journal of Accounting, 28, 1739.
uniqueness paradox in organizational stories. Administrative Vroom, V. (1964). Work and Motivation. New York: Wiley.
Science Quarterly, 32, 438453. White, P. (1985). The psychology of pay: The relationship
Participants Values and Incentive Plans 59

between management cultures and remuneration systems. Whittlesey, F., & Maurer, C. (1993). Ten common compensation
Benefits & Compensation International (September), 23 mistakes. Compensation and Benefits Review, 25(4), 44.
27. Young, S., & Selto, F. (1993). Explaining cross-sectional work-
White, W., & Fife, R. (1993). New challenges for executive com- group performance differences in a JIT facility: A critical ap-
pensation in the 1990s. Compensation and Benefits Review, praisal of a field-based study. Journal of Management Ac-
25(1), 27. counting Research, 5, 300326.

ENDNOTE
1. Financial support from the Harvard Business School Division
of Research is gratefully acknowledged.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi