Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 3

conomies of scale and scope

Oct 20th 2008 | Online extra

Economies of scale

Economies of scale are factors that cause the average cost of producing something to fall as the volume
of its output increases. Hence it might cost $3,000 to produce 100 copies of a magazine but only $4,000
to produce 1,000 copies. The average cost in this case has fallen from $30 to $4 a copy because the main
elements of cost in producing a magazine (editorial and design) are unrelated to the number of
magazines produced.

Economies of scale were the main drivers of corporate gigantism in the 20th century. They were
fundamental to Henry Ford's revolutionary assembly line, and they continue to be the spur to many
mergers and acquisitions today.

There are two types of economies of scale:

Related items

Economics focus: Bold strokesOct 16th 2008

Idea: Hierarchy of needsOct 13th 2008

Idea: Theories X and YOct 6th 2008

Idea: OutsourcingSep 29th 2008

Internal. These are cost savings that accrue to a firm regardless of the industry, market or environment
in which it operates.

External. These are economies that benefit a firm because of the way in which its industry is
organised.

Internal economies of scale arise in a number of areas. For example, it is easier for large firms to carry
the overheads of sophisticated research and development (R&D). In the pharmaceuticals industry R&D
is crucial. Yet the cost of discovering the next blockbuster drug is enormous and increasing. Several of
the mergers between pharmaceuticals companies in recent years have been driven by the companies'
desire to spread their R&D expenditure across a greater volume of sales.

Economies of scale, however, have a dark side, called diseconomies of scale. The larger an organisation
becomes in order to reap economies of scale, the more complex it has to be to manage and run such
scale. This complexity incurs a cost, and eventually this cost may come to outweigh the savings gained
from greater scale. In other words, economies of scale cannot be gleaned for ever.

Frederick Herzberg, a distinguished professor of management, suggested a reason why companies


should not aim blindly for economies of scale:

Numbers numb our feelings for what is being counted and lead to adoration of the economies of scale.
Passion is in feeling the quality of experience, not in trying to measure it.

T. Boone Pickens, a geologist turned oil magnate turned corporate raider, wrote about diseconomies of
scale in his 1987 autobiography:

It's unusual to find a large corporation that's efficient. I know about economies of scale and all the other
advantages that are supposed to come with size. But when you get an inside look, it's easy to see how
inefficient big business really is. Most corporate bureaucracies have more people than they have work.

Economies of scope

First cousins to economies of scale are economies of scope, factors that make it cheaper to produce a
range of products together than to produce each one of them on its own. Such economies can come
from businesses sharing centralised functions, such as finance or marketing. Or they can come from
interrelationships elsewhere in the business process, such as cross-selling one product alongside
another, or using the outputs of one business as the inputs of another.

Just as the theory of economies of scale has been the underpinning for all sorts of corporate behaviour,
from mass production to mergers and acquisitions, so the idea of economies of scope has been the
underpinning for other sorts of corporate behaviour, particularly diversification.

The desire to garner economies of scope was the driving force behind the vast international
conglomerates built up in the 1970s and 1980s, including BTR and Hanson in the UK and ITT in the
United States. The logic behind these amalgamations lay mostly in the scope for the companies to
leverage their financial skills across a diversified range of industries.

A number of conglomerates put together in the 1990s relied on cross-selling, thus reaping economies of
scope by using the same people and systems to market many different products. The combination of
Travelers Group and Citicorp in 1998, for instance, was based on the logic of selling the financial
products of the one by using the sales teams of the other.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi