Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 97

See

discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/248512662

Enhancing urban planning using simplified


models: SIMPLAN for Ahmedabad, India

Article in Progress in Planning April 2010


DOI: 10.1016/j.progress.2009.11.001

CITATIONS READS

27 223

1 author:

Bhargav Adhvaryu
Center for Environmental Planning and Technology University
20 PUBLICATIONS 53 CITATIONS

SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

SOLUTIONS View project

Mapping public transport accessibility levels (PTAL) View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Bhargav Adhvaryu on 19 May 2015.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file. All in-text references underlined in blue are added to the original document
and are linked to publications on ResearchGate, letting you access and read them immediately.
Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207
www.elsevier.com/locate/pplann

Enhancing urban planning using simplified models:


SIMPLAN for Ahmedabad, India
Bhargav Adhvaryu
Department of Architecture and Churchill College, University of Cambridge, United Kingdom

Abstract
Urban planners are faced with the decision of what planning policy to pursue in order to achieve the best possible future. Many
cities in developed nations use comprehensive models that simulate various aspects of the urban system, capable of predicting
implications of a given set of policy inputs, to assist the planning process. However, in developing countries, demographic and
socioeconomic data with appropriate spatial disaggregation are difficult to obtain. This constrains the development of such
comprehensive urban models to support planning decisions. In the absence of models, the plan-making process usually inclines
towards a more intuitive approach.
Using simplified urban models adapted to the data constraints, this paper explores the prospects of enhancing
planning in developing countries, with the aim of shifting the plan-making process from being purely intuitive towards
being more scientific. The SIMPLAN (SIMplified PLANning) modelling suite has been developed for the case study city of
Ahmedabad, India (the calibration per se is not discussed) to test alternative urban planning policies (combinations for land
use and transport) for the year 2021. Model outputs are evaluated for key economic, environmental and social indicators. It
should be noted that such a research study, in the context of developing countries, represents a first generation of studies/
models, owing to the simplicity of the model structure and its accompanying limitations and data availability constraints. The
modelling framework developed in this study has a visually driven user interface. This makes the model easy to understand,
operate and update. Due to this attribute, it allows local planning authorities to carry out testing of several alternative planning
policies themselves, without having the need to outsource modelling work to private consulting firms, usually at much higher
cost.
Key model outputs indicate that dispersing cities proves to be economically beneficial to society as a whole. Compact
development may prove to be better in terms of environmental and social aspects, but it may be possible to tackle the undesirable
effects of dispersal by appropriate combinations of planning and management measures. The modelling outputs informed the wider
debate on compact vs. dispersed urban forms. It was shown that neither of these diametrically opposite forms provide an outright
winwin solution. They are likely to perform differently in different economies and sociocultural contexts. Therefore, it would
appear that each city needs to test out the pros and cons of such alterative urban planning policies before pursing a plan for the future.
Learning from such modelling exercises, cities can prepare their own tailor-made policy that best satisfies their objectives, making
the planning process more rigorous and transparent.
# 2010 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Urban planning; Urban modelling; Land usetransport interaction (LUTI) modelling; Urban form; Compact city; Dispersed city;
Developing countries; Ahmedabad; India

E-mail address: ba247@yahoo.com.

0305-9006/$ see front matter # 2010 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.progress.2009.11.001
114 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Contents

1. Paper outline . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115


2. Context of developing countries. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115
2.1. Urban development and planning . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115
2.2. Overview of urbanisation: India, Gujarat and Ahmedabad . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117
2.3. Background of planning in the Indian context . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119
2.4. The need and relevance of this study . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121
3. General introduction of the case study city of Ahmedabad . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 122
3.1. Location, topography and climate. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 122
3.2. History . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 123
3.3. Demographics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 123
3.4. Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 123
4. Introduction to modelling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124
4.1. Definition and types of models. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124
4.1.1. Descriptive models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124
4.1.2. Explanatory models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124
4.1.3. Predictive models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124
4.2. Descriptive conceptual models of spatial organisation of land uses. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124
4.2.1. Concentric zone theory (1925) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125
4.2.2. Sector theory (1939) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125
4.2.3. Multiple-nuclei theory (1945) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126
4.2.4. Application to Ahmedabad . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126
4.3. Explanatory analytical models of location and land use . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 128
4.3.1. Isolated state (1826) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 128
4.3.2. Industrial location theory (1909) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 130
4.3.3. Central place theory (1933) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131
4.3.4. Urban bid-rent theory (1964) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 134
4.4. Introduction to LUTI models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 137
4.4.1. The land usetransport relationship. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 137
4.4.2. The Lowry model. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 138
4.4.3. The MEPLAN model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 139
4.4.4. The TRANUS model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140
4.4.5. The DELTA model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141
4.4.6. A brief discussion on LUTI models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 142
5. SIMPLAN model: a brief introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 142
6. Development of alternative policies for the future . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 146
6.1. Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 146
6.2. Key modelling inputs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 147
6.3. Trend policy 2021 (TR21) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 149
6.3.1. TR21 land use inputs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 149
6.3.2. TR21 transport inputs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 152
6.4. Compaction policy 2021 (CC21) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153
6.4.1. CC21 land use inputs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153
6.4.2. CC21 transport inputs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153
6.5. Dispersal policy 2021 (DS21) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
6.5.1. DS21 land use inputs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
6.5.2. DS21 transport inputs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 157
7. Summary of modelling outputs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 157
7.1. Land use outputs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 157
7.2. Transport outputs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 158
8. Sensitivity analysis. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 162
8.1. Variation in dwellings and employment allocation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 162
8.2. Variation in income . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 164
9. Assessment of alternative planning policies. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 164
9.1. Economic assessment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 115

9.1.1. Housing and work travel costs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165


9.1.2. Consumer and producer surplus in housing rent . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 167
9.1.3. Consumer surplus in transport . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 171
9.1.4. Estimates of costs. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 172
9.1.5. Summary of benefits and costs. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173
9.2. Environmental assessment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 174
9.2.1. Resources: new land required for residential use . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 174
9.2.2. Emissions: vehicular CO2 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 175
9.3. Social aspects . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 176
9.3.1. Mix of socioeconomic groups . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 177
9.3.2. Social equity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 179
9.3.3. Accessibility . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 181
9.4. Sensitivity analysis: assessment summary of other alternatives. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 183
9.5. A discussion on assessment matrix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 186
9.6. Conclusions on assessment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 187
10. Feedback . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 187
10.1. Background . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 187
10.1.1. Summary of key feedback and responses . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 188
10.2. SIMPLAN application to DP making . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 189
10.3. SIMPLAN simplifications and its application limitations. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 190
11. Conclusions. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 191
11.1. On alternative urban forms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 191
11.2. On the model structure and operationality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 193
11.3. On the context of developing countries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 194
11.4. Summary of key research findings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 194
11.5. Suggestions for further research . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 194
11.6. A final note . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 198
Acknowledgements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 198
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 203

1. Paper outline developed in this study was presented to local authority


planners and decision makers in Ahmedabad. Their
This paper begins by looking at urban development feedback is provided, along with the applications for
and planning in the context of developing countries and enhancing plan making. Suggestions for further
how it differs from developed countries. An overview of research as presented, followed by overall conclusions.
urbanisation is presented, followed by the background All sections in the paper are based on the authors
of planning in the Indian context. Following from this, doctoral work (Adhvaryu, 2009).
the necessity of the study is established. A general
introduction to the case study city of Ahmedabad is 2. Context of developing countries
presented. Since this recommends the use of models to
assist planning, a general introduction to models is 2.1. Urban development and planning
presented, followed by an introduction to land use
transport interaction (LUTI) models. A brief introduc- Urbanisation and urban growth (or development) are
tion to a simplified modelling suite called SIMPLAN often considered synonymous. However, there is an
(SIMplified PLANning) is provided. However, its important distinction. Urbanisation refers to the
calibration is a separate topic and is being considered relative concentration of people living in urban areas
for a shorter paper, and it is therefore not discussed here. (in a region) compared to the total population. For
Alternative urban planning policies for a future year example, in 2001 the total population in India was 1.029
(2021) are then discussed and tested using SIMPLAN. billion, of which 0.286 billion lived in urban areas, i.e.
A summary of modelling outputs is presented, followed 28% urbanisation. Urban growth refers to the absolute
by an assessment of alternative urban planning policies, increase in the physical size and population of an urban
including a section on sensitivity testing. The approach area (Potter, 1992). Urban growth is thus the combined
116 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

effect of net urban migration, natural increase, and what is new and different in developing countries is that
geographical expansion of an urban area. In this sense, its magnitude has been significant, owing to dramatic
urban migration may be associated with urbanisation. growth and population increase since the 1950s
Thus, urban growth and urbanisation are linked, i.e. (Jacquemin, 1999). One of the key problems generally
urbanisation is one of the three major components of identified as being different in developing countries is
urban growth (Jacquemin, 1999). the lack of sufficient absorptive capacity of the urban
Jacquemin (1999) argues that there is a difference economy in relation to the increase in the number of
between the urban growth process in the western world potential job seekers. The emergence of the informal
and in developing countries, which could be attributed sector in developing countries could be attributed to the
mainly to the difference in the demand and supply of mismatch between the number of potential job seekers
urban labour, and the overall population growth. In the and the number of formal jobs in the economy.
western world, urbanisation was a direct product of the There are two contrasting ways of looking at this.
gradual process (over a century) of industrialisation and One school of thought argues that since urban growth
economic development. On the other hand, in devel- produces undesirable side-effects and raises questions
oping countries, urbanisation is only partly the result of about the absorptive capacity of urban areas, strategies
industrialisation and economic growth. In addition, it is should be geared towards agricultural self-reliance,
taking place over a much shorter period, making the rural new town development, zero urban growth, and
pace of growth comparatively rapid. Other key even deurbanisation (Jacquemin, 1999). Others argue
contributing factors to urbanisation are the unfillable that, in essence, cities exist because of their ability to
expectations of rural people migrating to cities to escape offer competitive advantage for industrial production
poverty, and the lack of opportunities. The recent World and economies of scale associated with increasing
development report 2009 (World Bank, 2008) confirms urban size. For example, Alonso (1968) argues that
that the absolute numbers of people being added to the there are good grounds for believing in increasing
urban population of todays developing countries are returns to urban size. Therefore, they conclude that,
much larger, even compared to the recently industria- despite the disadvantages of urban growth, it is
lised nations such as the Republic of Korea, Taiwan and preferable to have it, from both an economic and a
China. social development perspective. Herbert (1979), in the
Beier (1976) argues that the rapid growth of urban context of urban development in the Third World,
population in developing countries is most likely to be emphasises that individuals find cities attractive for
accommodated by expanding existing urban areas many reasons, such as greater employment and
rather than by creating new settlements. This can be education opportunities and a wider range of amenities
supported by looking at more recent data. For example, and opportunities for social interaction than that found
the concentration of population in cities over one in rural areas. The World Bank (2008) argues that
million in developing countries rose from 18% to 28% denser concentrations of economic activity (i.e., cities)
from 1950 to 2005, and the population in these cities increase choice and opportunity, ensuring greater
increased at a staggering rate of 4.7% per annum market potential for the exchange of goods, services,
(calculated from United Nations, 2006). This clearly information and factors of production. This author also
shows that one million plus cities are where most of the subscribes to the view that since cities or urban
urban growth is taking place. Gilbert and Gugler (1992) agglomerations offer several economic and social
conclude that most Third World countries have been advantages, instead of preventing them from growing
transformed from rural to urban societies in two or three further, the emphasis should be on how to create well-
decades, with larger cities even doubling in size every planned cities and how to manage and absorb new
15 yearsa phenomenon fuelled by changes in the growth in a sustainable manner.
countryside, high rates of fertility, falling death rates, Increasing the absorptive capacity of urban areas
and rapid city-ward migration. must be tackled at two levels: urban planning policy
The rapid growth of urban areas in developing (i.e., city level) and national development policy
counties has brought serious problems, such as over- (Cohen, 1976). Of course, planning is only one of
crowding, poor housing conditions, inadequate social, the ways to address this issue and, obviously, what could
urban and transport infrastructure services, environ- be achieved in the longer run by urban planning policies
mental degradation, and unemployment and poverty. is tied up with the broader aspects of regional and
These problems are not new to the developed world national economic development policies. As Todaro
they were and still are facing these problems. However, (1979) argues, rather than devising ways to better
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 117

accommodate the growing population, government It is clear from the above discussion that the
policy needs to focus on economic opportunity, by scholarly literature on urbanisation and urban devel-
stressing a realistic combination of rural development opment in developing countries acknowledges that
and dispersed urbanisation strategy. urban planning policy can indeed play an important role
At the level of a city, on absorptive capacity, Beier in addressing the problems arising due to rapid
(1976) maintains that land for settling the new people urbanisation. It is beyond the scope of this paper to
would be crucial, wherein land use zoning regulations look into the broader aspects of national economic
tend to play a key role. It has been observed that without development policies that can effectively be used to
control of land and its uses, existing patterns would address the urbanisation issue. Nonetheless, what is
perpetuate, to the extent of threatening the political and within the scope of this paper is to look at urban policy
social stability of the city. Thus, it is important to have measures that could be interwoven into the city
land use zoning regulations that accommodate the needs planning process. For example, United Nations
of the poor, rather than excluding them and further (1970) indicate that the sharpest and most complex
aggravating the problem. On transportation, Beier (1976) conflicts arise in towns and cities lacking comprehen-
argues that journeys to work become longer as the city sive development plans that can harmonise the various
grows and the costs of these journeys become prohibitive demands on space, relate land development to transport,
for the very poor, who cannot afford to locate near to provide public facilities (or at least ensure there is space
where the jobs are, thus placing them at a locational for them), and integrate the man-made and natural
disadvantage and excluding them from the labour market. environments. Rivkin (1976) argues that developing
Of course, solutions have to be catered to individual cities, nations should be encouraged to develop their own
but it is clear that developing countries cannot afford to urban research institutions and to direct the analytical
follow spatial patterns and capital-intensive mass and data-gathering activities of university faculties
transport facilities (e.g., subways) like developed towards building a better understanding of the social,
countries. Jobs and residential locations will have to be economic and physical characteristics of urban areas.
contiguous and the appropriate pattern may well be cities He further argues that there are practically no empirical
with multiple centres. For example, Shanghai, China, materials extant that assess the effectiveness of different
ever since the first Metropolitan Plan in 1927, was approaches or techniques of land control in developing
planned as a metropolitan city with only one centre, with countries. There is little material on identifying the
industry and housing closely located, often in inner-city results of a process and comparing those results with
areas. However, the monocentric city became impractical initial (planning) objectives. There is nothing, save
with population growth in Shanghai, and the Shanghai impressionistic assessment, to provide guidance for a
Metropolitan Government has increasingly sought to set country or community preparing to establish new, or
up alternative commercial and industrial districts and revise old, measures.
residential towns and suburbs (Abelson, 2000).
In the context of mid- or intermediate-sized cities 2.2. Overview of urbanisation: India, Gujarat and
(say, population ranging from one to 10 million) in Ahmedabad
developing countries, Rivkin (1976) argues that these
cities have peculiar characteristics such as: (a) rapid Over the past three decades or so, the rate of
population growth, (b) presence of growing industrial urbanisation in India has been much higher than that in
processing activities, (c) increasing modernisation (e.g., the UK or the US, and second only to China (see Fig. 1).
automobiles, multi-storeyed buildings and supermar- Table 1 gives the total and urban population in India
kets), and (d) threat to environmental ambience. It is from 1901 to 2001 (and projections up to 2016). The
these characteristics that jolt the traditional land use annual growth rate of the total population in India in the
patterns and physical form and hence require land use last five decades up to 2001 has been 2.1%. Even more
control. He goes on to argue that the problems faced by dramatic has been the grown in urban population, which
such cities, namely inadequate open space, uncoordi- in this period is around 3.1% per annum. The level of
nated utilities provision, resolving competition amongst urbanisation in India has been consistently rising and is
land uses, land speculation, traffic congestion, undesir- expected to continue thus (second only to China). The
able densities, and so on, must be tackled at the level of rate of urbanisation compared to developed countries
the city itself. Solutions to such problems cannot be may seem low, but the absolute numbers of people
afterthoughts or subsidiary concerns within a national/ living in urban areas in India is rather staggering. For
regional planning framework. example, the 286.1 million people living in urban areas
118 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Fig. 1. Percentage of urban population.

in India in 2001 is even higher than the total population and 20% to 3%, respectively, while the decline for
of the US in 2000 (US Census Bureau, 2001), which Class VI cities was the steepest from 6% to 0.3%. This
was 281.4 million. clearly shows the importance of larger cities and their
The other interesting phenomenon is the growth growth potential.
differential of different cities in India. Urban areas in Urbanisation trends in Gujarat State (see Fig. 2) are
India are divided into six classes (see Table 2). In comparable to India. For example, the annual growth
1901, 26% of the urban population was living in rate of the total population in Gujarat in the last four
Class I cities, which grew to around 68% in 2001, decades up to 2001 has been 2.3% (as against 2.1% in
whereas for Classes II and III it has remained fairly India) and the annual grown rate of the urban population
constant (in the range of 10% to 11% and 12% to 16%, during the same period has been 3.2% (as against 3.3%
respectively). For Classes IV and V, the proportion of in India). However, in terms of the level of urbanisation,
urban population had declined from around 21% to 7% Gujarat stands much higher than India. From 1961 to

Table 1
Urbanisation trends in India 19012001.
Year Total population Urban population % Urban population
Millions Annual growth rate (%) Millions Annual growth rate (%)
1901 238.4 25.9 10.8
1911 252.1 0.56 25.9 0.04 10.3
1921 251.3 0.03 28.1 0.80 11.2
1931 279.0 1.05 33.5 1.77 12.0
1941 318.7 1.34 44.2 2.81 13.9
1951 361.1 1.26 62.4 3.52 17.3
1961 439.2 1.98 78.9 2.37 18.0
1971 548.2 2.24 109.1 3.29 19.9
1981 683.3 2.23 159.5 3.87 23.3
1991 846.3 2.16 217.6 3.16 25.7
2001 1,028.7 1.96 286.1 2.75 27.8
2006 1,094.1 0.63 332.1 1.53 30.0
2011 1,178.9 0.75 377.1 1.28 32.0
2016 1,263.5 0.70 425.4 1.21 34.0
Data source: Census (1991) for 19011991; Census (2001b) for 2001; Census (2001c) for 20062016 projections (shown in italics).
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 119

Table 2
Distribution of urban population in Indian cities.
Year Class of city
I II III IV V VI Total (%)
100,000 plus 50,00099,999 20,00049,999 10,00019,999 5,0009,999 Below 5,000
population (%) population (%) population (%) population (%) population (%) population (%)
1901 26.0 11.3 15.6 20.8 20.1 6.1 100
1951 44.6 10.0 15.7 13.6 13.0 3.1 100
1961 51.4 11.2 16.9 12.8 6.9 0.8 100
1971 57.3 10.9 16.0 10.9 4.5 0.4 100
1981 60.6 11.6 14.3 9.5 3.6 0.3 100
1991 65.3 10.9 13.2 7.8 2.6 0.1 100
2001 68.3 9.6 12.4 6.9 2.6 0.3 100
Data source: Compiled from Gurumukhi (n.d.) and Jacquemin (1999).

2001, the percentage of urban population grew from only the population of the Ahmedabad Municipal
25.8% to 37.4% as against 18.0% to 27.8% in India. Corporation (area 191 km2), it rose from 2.88 million
Gujarat is undoubtedly one of the most rapidly in 1991 to 3.52 million in 2001, at an annual rate of 2%. In
urbanising states in India. terms of population, the Ahmedabad urban agglomera-
Gujarat has 25 districts, of which Ahmedabad District tion ranks seventh in India, and Ahmedabad Municipal
(area of 8087 km2) has the highest population (5.81 Corporation ranks sixth. The pace of growth of the
million in 2001). The annual growth rate of total Ahmedabad urban agglomeration is staggering and
population for Ahmedabad District from 1961 to 2001 typifies a rapidly growing urban area in India.
was 2.7% and the annual growth rate for urban population
was 3.2%. Urbanisation in Ahmedabad District stood at 2.3. Background of planning in the Indian context
65.9% in 1961, which rose to 80.1% in 2001. The
population in the Ahmedabad urban agglomeration (an In general, the goals of planning human settlements
area of about 600 km2, covering the main city and are well established. Broadly speaking, these are
peripheral areas) rose from 3.31 million in 1991 to 4.69 protecting the environment and achieving economic
million in 2001 (at an annual rate of 3.5%). Considering efficiency and social equity. In order to assess whether a

Fig. 2. Location of Ahmedabad.


120 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

plan would be able to achieve its desired goals, it is average of conversion factor method, compound
necessary to forecast the implications of a proposed interest method, and Binomial expansion method for
plan. In the context of an urban area, at the very least, estimating population by zones over a 20-year period.
this would entail having an idea of the spatial Further to this, based on a rather arbitrary choice of
distribution of population and employment and its threshold densities for various sub-regions, land
interaction for the horizon year in question. requirements for residential use are calculated, followed
Planning in the context of mid-sized Indian cities is by formulating land use proposals.
generally driven by a development plan (DP). The DP One of the key regulations that controls the intensity of
sets out the course of development for the next 10 years, development, the floor space index (FSI, which is the
in accordance with the town planning act prevailing in ration of total built-up area to plot area, also known as
the state, and has a specific set of objectives. On the land floor area ration (FAR) in some countries), is almost
use side, the DP generally prescribes broad-brush uniform across the city (or in some cases it may have two
maps for land use zoning, in which uses like residential, grades). Regardless of whether the land is centrally
commercial, industrial, etc. are specified. In addition, located and/or has high transport accessibility or is
development control regulations are also specified, located at the periphery of the city, the intensity of
relating to plot coverage (or margins) and the height and development permissible is nearly the same. It seems
bulk of buildings. On the transport side, road-widening rather difficult to achieve the objective of, for example,
proposals (if any) are formulated and the future city- compact development with a blanket-type FSI regula-
level road network is specified, along with the tentative tion. In addition, the problem with this is that it does not
alignment of roads and their total widths (rights of way). respond to the demands of the real estate market. In other
Other aspects of DP include specifying augmentations words, stipulating uniform low densities across the city is
to the underground infrastructure, such as water supply, likely to create land scarcity and force unauthorised
sewerage and drainage, and specifying civic amenities. development on the periphery and on marginal lands
Special interest areas such as environmental and that are unsafe, such as hillsides, flood-prone valley
heritage conservation and tourism development may floors, river banks, etc. (Byahut & Parikh, 2006).
also be incorporated in the DP if relevant. This author believes that there is also a further
The next level of planning after the DP generally has problem that could be identified with the current
two approaches to managing new growth in urban areas. In method, which is lack of clarity as to how the final land
the first approach, planning authorities acquire agricul- use plan is arrived at. Seminal textbooks in planning
tural and undeveloped land by buying from the owners at dating back over four decades or so prescribe that a
prevailing agricultural land prices in large quantities, and planning exercise has several steps between decision to
re-plan them in an appropriate mannercalled the land plan and goal formulation to production of the final
acquisition method. In the second approach, called the plan. For example (see Fig. 3(a) and (b)) both emphasise
land readjustment and pooling method, instead of that a final plan should be generated from assessing a set
acquiring land from owners, land is brought together by of alternative plans, which are tested using some form of
pooling it from a group of owners and then the area is quantitative techniques. To date, this approach con-
planned by readjusting and reshaping the land parcels so tinues to be emphasised. For example, Healey (2007),
as to provide regular shapes to original plots and to use a studying conceptual development and the practical
portion of the land for roads, civic infrastructure and implications of spatial strategies in European cities, and
public amenities. The key advantages of the second using the example of the Cambridge sub-region,
method are that the original owners are not displaced and, emphasises the role of development of options for
more importantly, the increment in land value accrues to future growth in spatial planning and strategy formula-
the owners whenever the land is sold and developed for tion (example from Cambridge Futures, 1999) and
urban use, unlike the first method. In addition, since the Webster (2010), in the context of accessible urban form,
role of the government is more that of a facilitator, it is less emphasises that if such accessibility within a master
likely to be prone to corrupt practices, compared to the plan could be priced, its designers could more readily
land acquisition method (Ballaney, 2008). maximise the value of the plan and weigh objectively
Returning to the method of DP making, it uses between alternative designs. With regard to the Indian
models for forecasting population and the future DP-making practice, there does not seem to be any
population becomes the key basis for formulating explicit mention of alternative plans or policies and how
proposals in the DP. For example, the Draft Develop- these are assessed in order to arrive at the final plan. In
ment Plans for Ahmedabad (AUDA, 1988, 1997) use an addition, as Byahut and Parikh (2006) point out, there
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 121

Fig. 3. Scientific approach to planning.


Source: (a) Chapin (1965, Figure 36, p. 458); (b) Chadwick (1971, Figure 12.1, p. 279).

are problems in the content of the Ahmedabad microeconomic framework, have been propounded.
Development Plan itself, which are only regulatory in Using these theories as building blocks, many models
nature and do not translate into projects, and therefore for simulating urban development have been developed
many of the intentions of these plans remain unrealised. in the developed world. Such models essentially
In general, it seems that there does not appear to be a simulate where urban land uses would tend to locate
consistent theoretical and analytical framework within over space as a function of transport accessibility (or
which planning decisions are being made. Rather, they costs), a set of user preferences, and development
appear to be piecemeal and ad hoc in nature, without constraints. Further to this, land usetransport interac-
proper justification. In other words, the decisions appear tion models have also been developed, which actively
to be generally driven by political interests and seem to consider the feedback from transport to land use and
reflect a map of influences from pressure groups of vice versa.
various sorts. Exploring urban and regional policy Some LUTI models available commercially are also
issues in developing countries, Chatterjee (1983) argues used to test policy alternatives (i.e., alternative future
that the practical consequences of the lack of interaction scenarios, such as compact development or dispersed
between the political and scientific communities have development or major transport improvement projects,
been particularly severe in developing countries. She or combinations thereof) by governments in developed
asserts that the gap between the two has increased rather countries. Alternative scenarios of supply of housing
than decreased over the years. and employment, land and transport are fed as inputs to
a LUTI model. Based on the behavioural assumptions of
2.4. The need and relevance of this study how households and firms locate, a LUTI model
simulates the likely distribution of land uses for a future
Over the last four to five decades or so, many theories year and produces transport outputs for all origins and
of how land use is organised over space, embedded in a destinations, such as modal split, average trip costs, trip
122 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

lengths, passenger-kilometre travelled, and network framework for assessing planning policy alternatives,
flows and congestion. Since all outputs are quantified, which could then be compared with the current
they can be systematically evaluated against economic, approach. A clear understanding of the implications
environmental and social indicators, leading to an of alternative plans to the policy makers is crucial.
overall assessment of the alternatives, which are used to While developing a model for Cape Town, Molai and
support the plan-making and policy-formulation pro- Vanderschuren (2003) argue that there is a pressing
cess. need for models, particularly for developing countries,
However, developing a full-fledged LUTI model to that answer what if questions about land use and
support planning decisions in the context of developing transport systems and address important policy con-
countries is generally reported to have been constrained cerns of relevance to both planners and the public. In the
by the non-availability of spatially disaggregated land Indian context, a possible application could be
use data. Furthermore, no visible attempt is being made developing a modelling framework for plan making
to collect relevant land use and transport data in this and policy formulation that can answer the what if
regard (Srinivasan, 2005). Chatterjee and Nijkamp questions, similar to the one developed in this study,
(1983) have argued that while models and techniques which also helps inform the debate on alternative urban
for urban and regional analysis have been fruitfully used forms.
to fit quantitative data to urban social, political, Lastly, it is important for researchers to interact
economic, and geographic theories in the advanced closely with practitioners to obtain feedback on the
economies, they have much less applicability in potential applicability and usability of new approaches
developing countries. They maintain that the key that are likely to affect the practice of plan making. To
reasons for this are: (a) huge quantity of data required this end, a series of meetings and presentations to
for validating models; (b) type and quality of data; and government planners and decision makers were con-
(c) prohibitive data collection costs. The results of ducted in the case study city to obtain their feedback.
applications of models for planning purposes in In a nutshell, this study attempts to demonstrate how
developing countries have been generally mediocre. a theoretically consistent analytical framework can be
This is not to say that such constraints should be a developed with due regard to both data and resource
deterrent to developing models and analytical techni- constraints and used to assist in plan making, thereby
ques for planning in developing countries. As Echeni- enhancing current practice, serving as a reasonable
que (1983) points out, in cases of no or limited justification to support the need and relevance for such a
availability of data, simple and robust models could be study.
built, followed by collecting essential data for them.
Molai and Vanderschuren (2003), based on their 3. General introduction of the case study city of
experience of developing a (land usetransport) model Ahmedabad
for Cape Town, South Africa, argue that models from
developed countries are not likely to be adopted (to 3.1. Location, topography and climate
developing countries) in their present form, due to
different socioeconomic and environmental contexts. Ahmedabad is located at 23.03N 72.58E on the
The key is thus to ascertain the degree of simplicity and banks of Sabarmati river in the state of Gujarat in
adaptability required for the development and applica- western India (see Fig. 2). The city is divided by the
tion of models. To this end, in this study a simplified river into two physically distinct eastern and western
urban modelling framework has been developed for the regions. The old city (also known as the walled city) is
case study city of Ahmedabad. The scope of this on the eastern bank of the river and is predominantly
framework is informed by the literature review of characterised by row houses (sharing common walls,
prevailing academic wisdom and practical knowledge also known as terraced houses) along the streets.
and its applicability to the case study city. Ahmedabad is 53.0 m above the mean sea level, with a
Current research efforts in the Indian context need to relatively flat topographythe range between highest
focus on deepening the understanding of the nature of and lowest point being 4.27 m. Ahmedabad is in a hot
urban development and the impact of current policies on and arid region, with summer highs of around 44 8C
it, both from a spatial and socioeconomic perspective. and winter low of around 7 8C. The average rainfall,
Hence, some form of quantitative planning framework based on the past 46 years of data (19612006), is
needs to be developed which entails (a) use of simple 791 mm, with an average of 38 rain days per year
and robust descriptive and predictive models, and (b) a (AMC, 2007).
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 123

3.2. History activities. Following independence and the partition of


India in 1947, the city was scarred by intense
Archaeological evidence suggests that the area communal violence that broke out between Hindus
around Ahmedabad has been inhabited since the 11th and Muslims. Unfortunately, to date this tension still
century, when it was known as Ashaval or Ashapalli. At exists in the city and occasionally erupts in the form of
that time, Karandev I, the Solanki ruler of Anhilwara violence and rioting.
(modern Patan, which is the capital city of Patan In 1960, the Indian state of Bombay was split into
District, is north of Ahmedabad District), waged a two statesMaharashtra and Gujarat. Ahmedabad was
successful war against the Bhil king of Ashaval and selected to be the first capital of Gujarat. The capital
established a city called Karnavati, located at the was shifted from Ahmedabad to Gandhinagar in 1971,
present area of Maninagar, close to the Sabarmati river. which was a new, planned city, set to rival the Le
Solanki rule lasted until the 13th century, when Gujarat Corbusier-planned Chandighar city in Punjab State,
came under the control of the Vaghela dynasty of North India. Today, Ahmedabad is very diverse in terms
Dholka (in the southern part of Ahmedabad District) of its built form. The walled city has most of the older
and Karnavati was conquered by the Sultanate of Delhi. and heritage buildings, with great examples of beautiful
In 1411, the rule of Sultan Ahmed Shah of the Islamic architecture. New and modern buildings occupy
Muzaffarid dynasty (which ruled Gujarat from 1391 to most of the western part of the city, with buildings
1583) was established, which is how the city got its designed by noted architects like Le Corbusier, Charles
current name (the word abad means founded or Correa, and Louis Kahn.
populated). In 1487, Mahmud Begada, the grandson of
Ahmed Shah, fortified the city with an outer wall 10 km 3.3. Demographics
(six miles) in circumference. The area enclosed within it
is what is now known as the walled city. The Muzaffarid According to the 2001 census, the area under
dynastys rule in Ahmedabad ended in 1573, when Ahmedabad Municipal Corporation had a population of
Gujarat was conquered by the Mughal emperor Akbar. 3.5 million and the population of the Ahmedabad urban
During the Mughal reign, Ahmedabad became one of agglomeration area was 4.5 million. Ahmedabad has a
the empires thriving centres of trade, mainly in textiles, literacy rate of nearly 80% (88% males and 71%
which were exported as far as Europe. Ahmedabad females), which is the highest in Gujarat. It is estimated
remained the provincial headquarter of the Mughals that around 440,000 people live in slums within the city.
until 1758, when the Mughals surrendered the city to the The sex ratio (i.e., females to 1000 males) in 2001 was
Marathas. The Marathas form an Indo-Aryan group of 885 (AMC, 2007).
Hindu warriors hailing mostly from the present-day
state of Maharashtra (south of Gujarat), who created the 3.4. Economy
expansive Maratha Empire, covering a major part of
India (north and central regions), in the late 17th and In the 19th century, the textile and garments industry
18th centuries. During the Maratha governance, the city received strong capital investment, with the first textile
lost some of its past glory and was at the centre of mill being established in 1861. By 1905, there were
contention between two Maratha clansthe Peshwa of about 33 textile mills in the city, which soon came to be
Poona (also written as Pune, a city in Maharashtra about known as the Manchester of the east. However, by the
120 km south-east of Mumbai) and the Gaekwad of 1980s the textile mills had closed down, which marked
Baroda (a city in Gujarat about 100 km south-east of the end of an era of the industrys dominance in the
Ahmedabad). The British East India Company took economy of Ahmedabad.
over the city in 1818 as part of the British conquest of A sectoral shift was observed in Gujarat after
India. A military cantonment was established in 1824 liberalisation of the economy in the early 1990s. A rapid
and a municipal government in 1858. growth of chemical and pharmaceutical industries was
Indias movement of independence (from British observed in that decade. The tertiary sector, which
rule) developed strong roots in Ahmedabad when includes business and commerce, transportation and
Mahatma Gandhi established two ashrams (the communication, construction, and other services, has
Kochrab Ashram near Paldi and the Satyagraha grown rapidly in the decade up to 2001 (with about 64%
Ashram, now known as the Sabarmati Ashram) on of the jobs). This trend is continuing, with a rise in the
the banks of Sabarmati river during 19151917. Both information technology industry in Ahmedabad. A
these Ashrams became centres of intense nationalist survey in 2002 on the super nine Indian destinations
124 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

for IT-enabled services ranked Ahmedabad fifth among 4.1.2. Explanatory models
the top nine most competitive cities in the country. Explanatory models go a bit further than descriptive
models. In other words, they attempt to explain why it
4. Introduction to modelling is what it is. In this sense, these models could be termed
behavioural models (as against descriptive models,
4.1. Definition and types of models which describe the end-state of a system rather than
the process responsible for italso sometimes known
The word model is extensively used in both arts and as end-state models). Explanatory models try to
sciences. It has several meanings that vary, depending explain the phenomenon by transforming conceptual
on the context in which it is being used. Models can understanding to mathematical symbology. Their aim is
range from physical objects to mathematical equations. to offer explanations as to why the phenomenon being
Regardless of the nature of the model and the context, it modelled is happening, by studying behavioural aspects
would appear that the commonality in meaning is of the comments of a system under question (e.g., those
abstraction of reality, with the aim of either better discussed in Section 4.3).
understanding a real system or being able to predict its
behaviour. 4.1.3. Predictive models
Echenique (1972), Torrens (2000) and DfT (2005) Predictive models are similar to explanatory models
provide detailed descriptions of various types of model. in terms of having an explicit mathematical structure,
Based on these, this author has categorised models into but they enable the testing of ideas by allowing
three main categories: descriptive, explanatory and predictions to be made. It is obvious they build on
predictive, discussed in the following sections. explanatory models and have active feedback loops for
various elements of the system being modelled. In this
4.1.1. Descriptive models sense, they are simulations of a system and output
Descriptive models aim to describe real-life situa- effects given a set of stimuli (or course of action). These
tions by abstracting their key elements, leading to the can further be classified into two sub-categories. First
understanding of what it is. Torrens (2000) describes are conditional models (Echenique, 1972), wherein
these as basic models and categorises them into three cause and effect are modelled, i.e., if x occurs y must
sub-categories. First are scaled or iconic models, which follow (also termed as what if models). Second are
are scaled-down versions of reality, usually without any optimising models (DfT, 2005), which optimise urban
functional or predictive capacity. Essentially, they systems rather than predict their behaviour. Examples of
differ from reality only in size (e.g., architectural optimising-type LUTI models include TOPAZ (first
models of buildings). Second are analogue models, in developed in 1970 in Australia by J.F. Brotchie, R.
which size is transformed, but so are some of the Sharpe, and J.R. Roy) and SALOC (first developed in
properties of the thing that is being modelled (e.g., 1973 in Sweden by L.L. Lundqvist), see Webster and
maps, in which size is reduced, as with the scale model, Paulley (1990). Such models are intended as tools,
but also some of the features of real elements are which can find an optimum design, as against
symbolised). Third are conceptual models, generally conditional models, which respond to a design input
attempting to express how we think a system works. by the user. Optimising models may be informative for
Usually, conceptual models are schematic representa- research and long-term planning, but in general they
tions or diagrams of a real-life system, using boxes and require a substantial model development effort, in order
arrows showing interrelationships between its various to link them to the practical planning problems of
elements or highlighting key elements (e.g., schematic individual cities or regions (DfT, 2005). Good examples
diagrams of a carbon cycle or a plant cell). If of predictive models are the land usetransport
appropriate, the word model in the context of interaction models, discussed in Section 4.4.
conceptual models could be used interchangeably with
theory. Some key conceptual urban models are 4.2. Descriptive conceptual models of spatial
described in Section 4.2. Often, descriptive models organisation of land uses
have a mathematical structure, in which case they could
be termed descriptive analytical models (e.g., density Essentially, there are three main models or theories,
gradients (Clark, 1951), dispersion index (Bertaud, often referred to as human ecological theories, which
2001), and concentration/de-concentration measure have been advanced to offer generic descriptions of how
(SCATTER, 2005)). urban land uses organise over space. These are the
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 125

invasion and succession. As the city grew and


developed over time, the CBD would exert pressure on
the zone immediately surrounding it (i.e., the zone of
transition). Outward expansion of the CBD would
invade nearby residential neighbourhoods, causing
them to move outward. The process was thought to
continue, with each successive neighbourhood moving
further from the CBD. Burgess suggested that inner-city
housing was largely occupied by immigrants and
households of low socioeconomic status. As the city
grew and the CBD expanded outward, lower status
residents moved to adjacent neighbourhoods, and more
affluent residents moved further from the CBD. A
noteworthy feature of this theory was that it observed a
positive correlation between income status and place of
residence, i.e., the more affluent households were
observed to live at greater distances from the CBD.

4.2.2. Sector theory (1939)


Fig. 4. Concentric zone theory.
Homer Hoyt in 1939 proposed the sector theory,
Source: Burgess (1925). primarily developed to describe the structure of
residential areas, by modifying the concentric zone
concentric zone theory, the sector theory, and the theory. Based on his study of rent patterns in 25 widely
multiple-nuclei theory, which are discussed in the distributed American cities, Hoyt concluded that land
following sections. The reviews of these theories are uses tended to conform to a pattern of sectors rather than
drawn from Chapin (1965), Carter (1995), Harvey concentric circles, i.e., a city expands essentially along
(1996), and Torrens (2000), unless mentioned other- transport routes (railways and highways) in wedge-
wise. shaped sectors emanating from the CBD (see Fig. 5),
rather than in concentric circles.
4.2.1. Concentric zone theory (1925) The higher the accessibility of land, the higher would
In 1925, Ernest W. Burgess put forward the theory of be its rent. This meant that most of the commercial
concentric zones (Burgess, 1925). Burgess theorised functions would remain in the CBD, but some
that urban land use organises itself in concentric rings manufacturing functions would develop in wedges
around the central business district (CBD) (see Fig. 4), along the transport routes. Low-income households
with each ring having a different land use. This theory would locate near the factories/manufacturing sector,
was developed based on observations of the city of while middle- and high-income households would tend
Chicago from the 1980s to the early 20th century. to locate away from the factories. Hoyt observed that,
The CBD (Zone I) forms the core of the city because it over time, high-income classes expanded outward from
is the most accessible area and has shopping, offices, the CBD along faster transport routes. In general, he
hotels and restaurants, theatres, banks, etc. Encircling the
CDB is an area in transition, which is being invaded by
business and light manufacturing (Zone II). Zone III is
inhabited by workers in industries who have escaped
from the area of deterioration (Zone II) but who desire to
live within easy access of their work. Beyond this are
residential areas (Zone IV) of high-class apartment
buildings or of exclusive restricted districts of single-
family dwellings. Still further, out beyond the city limits,
is the commuters zone (Zone V)suburban areas or
satellite citieswithin a 3060 min ride of the CBD.
The process of change in the spatial patterns of
residential areas was described as a process of Fig. 5. Sector theory.
126 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

The innovative thing about this theory was that it


recognised the fact that many cities tend to be
polycentric, and hence the traditional monocentric
models (e.g., concentric zone and sector theories) did
not explain the urban land use pattern in most large
cities. In addition, it goes further than the monocentric
models in recognising the fact that, apart from transport
accessibility, there are other factors that affect the
spatial distribution of urban land uses, such as
topography, special accessibility, and historical influ-
ences. It should be noted that the multiple-nuclei theory,
Fig. 6. Multiple-nuclei theory. unlike the previous two theories (which described
changes in the basic arrangement of land use patterns),
describes the land use pattern at a particular point in
concluded that, rather than purely the distance from the time.
CBD, the accessibility of land was also an important
determinant of rent and hence land use. Hoyt, in a way, 4.2.4. Application to Ahmedabad
further enhanced the distance from the centre element Carter (1995) argues that the key criticism of the
of Burgess, by adding the directional element. Unlike concentric zone theory is that it lacks universality and
Burgess, Hoyt acknowledged that the distribution of may have been applicable to the American city of the
land uses has a strong relationship with transport 1920s. This author thinks that the concentric zone
accessibility. In addition, Hoyts hypothesis allows for a theory is too simplistic and too limited in historical and
more irregular pattern of development, implying that cultural application to lead to an understanding of land
different parts of a city grow at different rates. use patterns of contemporary cities in developing
countries. As can be seen from Fig. 7, there is no
4.2.3. Multiple-nuclei theory (1945) indication of formation of concentric zones in
Harris and Ullman (1945) proposed the multiple- Ahmedabad, as suggested.
nuclei theory, in which they theorised that many towns On the other hand, as suggested by the sector theory,
and nearly all large cities did not grow simply around a the formation of wedges (or sectors) along transport
single CBD, but were, rather, formed by the progressive routes is abstractly evident for industrial areas (see
integration of a number of separate centres (or nuclei). Fig. 7). Since commercial development is allowed along
Although they recognised that the CBD was a major roads 18.0 m or higher (see Fig. 8), strong formation of
centre of commerce, they suggested that cells or clusters commercial sectors is not evident, except for some
of specialised activities (such as sectors 2, 6 and 7 in major concentrations in western Ahmedabad (Ashram
Fig. 6) would develop according to specific require- Road on the western riverbank and CG Road, which is
ments, different rent-paying abilities, and their agglom- about one kilometre west of Ashram Road commercial
erative tendencies. At the centre is the CBD, with light area). In recent times, another major commercial sector
manufacturing and wholesaling located along transport has developed in western Ahmedabad, beyond the AMC
routes. Heavy industry was thought to locate near the boundary (called SG Highway, see Fig. 15).
outer edge of the city, perhaps surrounded by lower- Residential use is spread all across the city, with
income households, and suburbs of commuters and high-income households generally concentrated in the
smaller service centres would occupy the urban western parts (not distinguished on the map)an
periphery. observation consistent with sector theorys view on
Harris and Ullman identified four factors responsible residential location. This author believes that, as
for the emergence of sub-centres, as follows: (a) suggested by the sector theorythat distribution of
interdependency amongst activities and the need to be land uses has a strong relationship with transport
in close proximity; (b) natural clustering tendency, accessibilityit is quite plausible that this relationship
which is mutually profitable (e.g., retail centres, exists in cities in developing countries. Although sector
medical centres, etc.); (c) incompatibility of functions theorys application to Ahmedabad is fairly moderate, a
and special area (land) requirements; and (d) high land comprehensive study of a large number of cities in
costs (or rents), which impacted the process of developing countries needs to be undertaken, in order to
nucleation. generalise its applicability to such cities.
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 127

Fig. 7. Land use map of AMC area.

As noted before, although the sector theory provides multiple-nuclei theory, as against the concentric zones
a useful way of describing the evolution of patterns of and sector theories, is that major cities tend to have
urban spatial structure, its ability to explain the land use multiple centresthis is rather true in the case of
organisation of larger present-day cities, especially in Ahmedabad. In fact, jobs are scattered all over the city,
developing countries, appears to be limited. This is with higher concentrations in the CDB, and other
because, although such urban areas have traditionally commercial areas forming sub-centres (see Fig. 15).
had a centre, over the past few decades they have The general disadvantage of the conceptual models
exhibited a tendency towards a multiplicity of sub- discussed in this section is that they do not have an
centres, like most metropolitan areas in the West. In this explicit mathematical structure, and lack the beha-
sense, the multiple-nuclei theory appears to be the only vioural explanation of their constituent elements.
theoretical model that recognises this aspect of present- Therefore, they cannot be applied to cities for analysing
day larger cities. The key deviation predicted by the the evolution of their spatial structure in order to
128 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

4.3.1. Isolated state (1826)


Johann Heinrich von Thunen in 1826 made the first
attempt to show the interlinkages between space and
economic activity. He developed a model that demon-
strated how production cost and the cost of transporting
production to the market affects agricultural land use
(i.e., cropping pattern) in a region. Von Thunen assumes
an isolated agricultural region at the centre of which is a
single town. This town is the only market for the
agricultural produce. The soil is capable of cultivation
and has the same fertility throughout the region. The town
supplies the rural area with all the manufactured products
and in turn obtains all its provisions from the surrounding
countryside. The key questions the theory tries to answer
are: what pattern of cultivation will take place, given the
above assumptions? And, how will the farming system be
affected by its distance from the town?

4.3.1.1. Concept of land rent. Von Thunen introduced


the concept of land rent, which was defined as the
portion of the farm revenue that is left after deduction of
the interest on the value of buildings, timber, fences and
Fig. 8. All roads with commercial development allowed. other valuable objects separable from land, i.e., the
portion that is attributable to the land itself. Thus, land
provide a useful quantitative basis. To this end, as rent is the surplus left after deduction of production
mentioned before, descriptive analytical models, such costs (i.e., sowing, cultivation, harvesting, administra-
as density gradients (Clark, 1951), dispersion index tion, transport, interest on buildings, etc.). Land rent (or
(Bertaud, 2001), and concentration/de-concentration surplus) for a particular crop being grown at a particular
measure (SCATTER, 2005) could be used. These location can be mathematically expressed as shown in
models essentially use time-series population data by Eq. (1).
spatial units of analysis (e.g., zones or census wards),
S q p  c  kt (1)
creating quantitative measure of the change in spatial
structure. The spatial structure of Ahmedabad has been where S is the land rent (or surplus) per unit of land; q is
analysed using these three measures in a forthcoming the yield of crop per unit of land; p is the price of crop
paper by this author and hence is not repeated here. fetched at the market per unit of weight; c is the
production cost per unit of weight; k is the transport
4.3. Explanatory analytical models of location and cost per unit of weight per unit of distance; t is the
land use distance from the town (or market).
If we take a hypothetical example of three crops, A,
In Section 4.2, we looked at some key theories that B and C, each of these crops will have such an equation
provided a generic picture of the effects of economic of their own (see Fig. 9), which will be different based
forces in shaping the spatial structure of cities. Urban on their yield and the price they fetch in the market. It
economists have tried to present a more detailed can be seen that from the town/market to tA, crop A will
account of the effect of economic forces on location of be grown, as it fetches more land rent than any other
specific land uses in the context of a land market, crop. From tA to tB, crop B offers highest land rent, and
attempting to explain the phenomenon. The works of hence it will be grown in this ring. Lastly, from tB
four authors, namely von Thunen (1826), Weber (1909), onwards, crop C will be grown similarly. It should be
Christaller (1933), and Alonso (1964) are discussed in noted that if two crops have the same yield, then the one
the following sections, as their contributions could be with the lower transport cost will be grown further away
considered unprecedented, setting a sound foundation from the town, and if the production costs of two crops
for the development of more comprehensive models are the same, then the one with the lower yield will be
over the years (such as the ones discussed in Section 4.4. grown further away from the town.
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 129

The second ring will have forestry, i.e., it will be


engaged in growing fuel wood.
The third, the fourth and the fifth rings will have
various types of grains grown using the crop alternation
system, the improved system, and the three-field
system, respectively.
The sixth ring will be used for stock farming,
breweries, etc., since no grain will be grown, as the land
rent here becomes zero.
In summary, since farmers would try to maximise
profit (which is essentially the market price minus the
production and transport costs), the most productive
activities (e.g., vegetables, milk, etc.) or activities
Fig. 9. Land rent for various crops. having high transport costs (e.g., firewood) would locate
near the market. The agricultural land use model thus
4.3.1.2. Pattern of cropping for the isolated state. - generated is shown in Fig. 10(a), while (b) illustrates the
Based on the actual data collected by von Thunen for a effect of change in grain price on the sizes of the rings.
period of five years for Tellow town in Germany, and
using the principle developed above, he calculates the 4.3.1.3. Comments. Von Thunens theory establishes
distances of the different rings around the town that will that land values will be highest at the centre of the town
grow the various types of crops as discussed below. and will decrease towards the periphery. Also, the
The first ring from the town (or the market) will have density or intensity of an activity will be higher near the
crops that are perishable in nature (i.e., those that cannot centre and will decrease towards the periphery. This
survive long journeys). Examples are cauliflower, results in the most favourable land use pattern around an
strawberries, lettuce, etc. Milk will also be produced isolated town, in the form of different economic
in this ring. It should be noted that no land would ever lie activities locating in concentric rings. Using the
fallow in this ring. It is profitable to get manure from the introduction of highways and railways as an example
town for these crops. However, as distance from the town to signify the effect of improvements in transport, von
increases, a point is reached when the transport costs of Thunen shows that the limits of the isolated state are
fetching the manure from the town are more than the cost extended markedly, concluding that transport improve-
of producing manure in the farm. This point marks the ments have a vast effect on the welfare of a nation.
end of the first ring and the beginning of the second. Although von Thunens model is for only agricultural

Fig. 10. Agricultural land use pattern and effect of grain price.
130 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

land, it can also be extended to urban land uses, as


shown by William Alonso (discussed in Section 4.3.4).
Comments on its application to Ahmedabad are
discussed in the same section, owing to the conceptual
similarities of von Thunens and Alonsos models.

4.3.2. Industrial location theory (1909)


Alfred Weber in 1909 explored the theoretical
aspects of location of a specific type of economic
activity, i.e., industries. He defined location factors as
those forces that operate as economic causes of
Fig. 11. Location of an industry in the location figure.
location. In other words, these factors can be seen as
an advantage gained by locating an economic activity at
a particular place rather than elsewhere. are of the pure type (the one that imparts its total
weight into the product), the weight to be transported
4.3.2.1. Classification of location factors. Factors that from the place of production to the place of
could be held responsible for location could be consumption is one ton. Weber here uses an analogy
categorised into two types: general factors, which are from mechanics, in that the weights to be transported
those that apply to each and every industry, regardless of are treated as weights hanging down from the three
their size or what they are manufacturing (e.g., cost of corners of the location figure (the actual mechanical
transport, cost of labour, and rent) and special factors, device used is known as a Varigons frame). These
which are those that apply to only this or that type of weights represent the force with which the corner of the
industry. They may be attributed to some peculiar location figures will pull (or attract) the location
technical requirement of an industry (e.g., perishability towards them in order to minimise transport costs. Thus,
of materials, climatic requirements, specific inputs the point at which the weights stabilise mathematically
requirements, such as fresh water, etc.). represents the location, P, where production will take
All location factors, whether general or special, may place.
be classified further, based on the influence they Labour and agglomeration factors: Having had the
exercise, and distribute the industries regionally and location fixed based on least transport cost, the second
agglomerate (or deglomerate) industries within the factor, i.e., labour cost, is then introduced. In doing so,
regional distribution. To distribute industries regionally the deviation caused by introducing this factor is
means to direct industries towards places that are examined to ascertain their combined effect. Finally,
geographically determined and given, thus creating a agglomerative factors are considered, to arrive at the
fundamental framework of industrial locations. To final deviation. Such a method allows an elegant and
agglomerate means to contract industry at certain points simple analysis of the factors of location and how they
within the regional framework. Of course, a third set of would work when acting together.
location factors may also be thought to exist: natural
and technical factors, on the one hand, and social and 4.3.2.3. Comments. Webers theory helps us under-
cultural factors, on the other. stand how transport costs influence the location of an
industry. Based on the location of raw material deposits
4.3.2.2. Orientation of industry. Transport factors: and the place of consumption of a finished product, the
Weber analysed the location factors by first looking optimum location of an industry can be easily found
at transport costs as the only influencing factor in the such that the overall transport costs are minimal. This
location of an industry. In other words, it is possible to orientation may be attracted to other places, either by
find an optimum location with regard to transport costs, cheaper availability of labour or cheaper production
to which an industry will be attracted. This forms the costs, due to agglomeration of industries.
basic network of industrial orientation created by the In general, this theory explains how industries locate
first location factor, i.e., transport costs. This could be and move to different regions (or even countries) with
explained by a simple example. Let M1 and M2 (see changes in availability of raw material and labour and in
Fig. 11) be raw material deposits, from which 0.7 and the nature of coexistence of industries. Although this
0.3 tons of material are to be transported, respectively, theory is specific to a particular type of land use (i.e.,
to the place of production. Assuming both raw materials industries), it provides a useful theoretical construct for
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 131

analysing and understanding the factors responsible for


the location of an industry. With regard to its application
to developing countries (in market-oriented econo-
mies), this theory does seem to have potential. However,
its application specifically to Ahmedabad requires
historical data at least after Indias independence
(1947), which unfortunately is not available. Therefore,
it is not possible to test its application for Ahmedabad, Fig. 12. Upper and lower limits of range.
while acknowledging that it does indeed have the
potential to explain industrial location.
out from the central place, while that for cinema would
4.3.3. Central place theory (1933) cease at a very short distance.
Walter Christaller in 1933 attempted to demonstrate The other two important factors that influence range
the spatial effects of economic laws and rules on the are size of the central place and the density of
geography of settlements, and tried to explain the size, population. The larger the central place, the greater
number and location of cities in a region, in his central will be the range as compared to smaller central places.
place theory. Central places are defined as places (a This is because in a larger central place, the production
general term used for town/city/settlement) that have costs are relatively lower and a larger amount of sales
localisation of function. These places act as centres of permits a lower unit cost. Higher population density
the region in which they are situated. In contrast, there implies greater range, as again higher densities make
are dispersed places, which are defined as places that are production cheaper.
not central. The range of a good has its upper and lower limits.
A central place is called thus only when it performs The upper (or outer) limit denotes an area beyond which
the function of a centre, i.e. providing goods and there will be no buyer for that particular good from the
services to the region of which it is a centre. Goods central place (i.e., it will be cheaper to buy a good from
(including services) provided by central places are some other neighbouring central place). In other words,
called central goods and similarly those provided by it is the maximum distance people are willing to travel
dispersed places are called dispersed goods. Central to purchase a good. The lower (or inner) limit denotes
goods are necessarily produced and offered at few an area need for a firm/individual selling a good to exist
central points, in order to be consumed at many in business and make normal profits. In other words, it
scattered points (e.g., cars, doctors services, etc.). On denotes a minimum radius of a market area needed to
the other hand, dispersed goods are necessarily generate sufficient demand to support the supply of a
produced and offered at many scattered points, in good. In the literature produced by the followers of
order to be consumed at a few points (e.g., bread, Christaller, upper limit came to be known simply as
milk, etc.). Lastly, the term complementary region is range and the lower limit as threshold (see Fig. 12).
defined as the region for which the central place is the
centre. 4.3.3.2. The distribution of central places. Christaller
proposes three principles that could determine the
4.3.3.1. Range of central goods and its upper and distribution of central places in a region, which are
lower limits. Christaller then defines a very useful discussed below.
concept of range, which forms one of the key elements The marketing principle: if the distribution is entirely
of the central place theory. Range is defined as the based on the range of the good, then it would result in
distance up to which the population will still be willing evenly spaced central places with hexagonal markets
to purchase a good offered at a central place. Christaller areas (see Fig. 13(a)).
emphasises that, conceptually, range is an economic The traffic principle: if any of the cities distributed as
distance and not a mathematical one. per the market principle are smaller in size than
It should be noted that range also depends on the type expected, then this could be attributed to it not being on
of demand of the central good. If the demand is inelastic a major transport route. Conversely, if a smaller city
(i.e., urgent, non-substitutable), then the range is larger were on a major transport route, then it would be bigger
and if the demand is elastic (i.e., not urgent, in size than expected by the market principle. If
substitutable) then the range is smaller. For example, distribution were to adhere solely to the transport
the demand for medical services is likely to stretch far principle, then central places would be lined up on a
132 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Fig. 13. A system of central places.

transport route that fanned out from central places of 4.3.3.3. Observations from the case study of southern
higher order (see Fig. 13(b)). Germany. Based on the study of settlements in
The separation principle: unlike the previous two, southern Germany, Christaller concludes that the
which are economic, this principle is socio-political. marketing principle is the primary and chief law of
Political considerations sometimes distort the even distribution of central places. The transport and
spacing (and size) of cities. For example, if a region separation principle are only secondary laws causing
bans the sale of certain types of goods, then its central deviations. In practice, these two laws are effective
place will be less developed than the one in the under certain conditions only. In short, the interplay of
neighbouring region that does not have such restrictions all three principles generally explained the distribution,
(see Fig. 13(c)). size and number of central places in southern Germany.
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 133

Fig. 14. Development of central places in Ahmedabad sub-region.

Deviations not explainable economically, historically or shown in Fig. 14. Taking the old city of Ahmedabad as the
physiographically could be explained by people-related first order settlement, central place theory predicts six
causes or military reasons. second order settlements around the first order settlement
in the radius of 36 km. Indeed, in case of Ahmedabad,
4.3.3.4. Comments. Using this theory, it is possible to there are six second order settlements in a 30 km radius,
generate a network of hierarchically ordered centres in a albeit not forming a perfect hexagon. Boundaries of lower
region with predictable functional and location char- order settlements are also shown. It can be observed that
acteristics. Although Christallers framework in general in many instances these form hexagonal boundaries (with
applies to central places in a sub-region, this theoretical pentagonal or rectangular or irregular shaped boundaries
framework could also be applied to investigating the as well). In addition, the spatial arrangement as predicted
phenomenon of development of sub-centres and their by central place theory seems to show formation,
spatial distribution, within an urban area. demonstrating all three principles at work.
In a sub-regional context, a visual analysis of the The various principles of the system of central places
central place theory for the Ahmedabad sub-region is could also be applied to a smaller spatial scale (i.e.,
134 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Fig. 15. Development of commercial areas in Ahmedabad.

metropolitan area). In this context, looking at the uses based on von Thunens theory of agricultural land
distribution of centres (i.e., concentrated commercial uses. He considers where an individual (or household)
development), Ahmedabad has traditionally had its and a firm would locate in the city. He develops a very
historic CBD in the old city (see Fig. 15). Over the important concept of bid-rent that is used to arrive at an
years, new centres developed along Ashram Road and overall equilibrium in the market.
south of the CBD in 1980s, followed by CG Road Essentially, a bid-price curve for a household denotes
commercial development around the 1990s. In the next a set of land prices that the household could pay at
decade, the SG Highway in the western part (beyond the various distances, deriving a constant level of utility (or
AMC boundary) was the next major commercial satisfaction). In other words, an individual is indifferent
development. It is clear that these new centres did with regard to choosing locations on the bid-price curve
not follow a perfect hexagonal geometry as predicted by (see Fig. 16(a)).
the range concept under the marketing principle. On the other hand, the opportunities available to a
However, the deviation as predicted by Christaller household can be expressed in the form of a price
owing to the traffic principle is evident in the occurrence structure curve (see Fig. 16(b)). A household will choose
of the new commercial developments (post-1980s) in a point at which its utility is maximisedthis is a point
Ahmedabad, which have exhibited a linear form. where the price structure touches the lowest of the bid-
price curves (see Fig. 16(c)). Alonso similarly extends the
4.3.4. Urban bid-rent theory (1964) same concept to determining the location of a firm.
4.3.4.1. Theoretical underpinnings. William Alonso Market equilibrium will be achieved when no user of
in 1964 developed the theory of location of urban land land can increase their level of utility (in the case of a
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 135

Fig. 16. Residential bid price, price structure and equilibrium.

household) or their profits (in the case of a firm) by 4.3.4.2. Some applications. Alonso draws important
moving to some other location or by buying more or less conclusions pertaining to rising incomes, transport
land. Equilibrium requirements for land market are improvements, and zoning regulations on location
similar to any other economic good, i.e. at equilibrium behaviour, which are discussed as follows.
demand and supply quantities and prices must be equal. Effect of rise in income: The effect of rise in income
However, in the land market there are two goods has two facets. Firstly, it would tend to flatten the bid-
quantity of land and distance from the centre, but only price curve, resulting in preference for more peripheral
one transaction and one price (that of land). Hence, the location. Secondly, on the other hand, the marginal
simple requirements of the equation of demand and utility of land will decrease as more land is held, while
supply become much more complicated in the case of the marginal utility of distance may increase as
land market. It follows that a consumer with the steepest accessibility becomes scarcer relative to land. This
bid-price curve will locate near to the centre, and the will lead to steeper bid-price curves, resulting in
bid-price curves get flatter as the location moves away preference for more central location. Thus, the effect of
from the centre, as shown in the chain of bid-price rising income has a combined effect and hence the net
curves (see Fig. 17). effect cannot be generalised. What actually happens
136 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Fig. 17. A chain of bid-price curves.

depends on the rate at which the ratio of marginal utility land use locates elsewhere at a higher price with lower
of distance and land increases or decreases with regard utility (satisfaction or profits). Density zoning of the type
to the size of land holdings. In other words, if land that states minimum plot size (i.e., the user is compelled
holdings are bigger, rising incomes will imply flatter to buy more land than necessary), means the user will bid
bid-price curves (i.e., preference for more peripheral less per unit of land. If, on the other hand, a density zoning
location, e.g. some American cities) and if land regulation states maximum plot size (i.e., it does not
holdings are smaller, it will imply steeper bid-price permit the user to have as much land as desired), this
curves (i.e., preference for more central location, e.g. means the user will purchase more composite good to
some Indian and Latin American cities). maintain the same level of utility, in order to compensate
Effect of improvements in transport: If a city goes for decreased utility by the forgone land.
through technical improvements in transport (i.e., Higher-income people make higher bids in the
making commuting easier or less expensive, thereby periphery of the city, while lower-income people make
reducing the generalised cost of transport) then this higher bids near the centre of the city. Thus, in an area, if
would tend to flatten the bid-price curves. If this zoning regulation is set at minimum plot size, then high-
happens in conjunction with a marginal increase in income people would move in, and if it is set at
population, then city size will increase in terms of land maximum plot size, then lower-income people would
area (sprawl). On the other hand, if population increases move in. This strongly suggests that density zoning can
without transport improvements, then the city size will be used as an effective tool for an urban renewal
increase, mainly in terms of density. This is an programme.
important economic explanation of the evolving nature
of a citys spatial structure. 4.3.4.3. Comments. Alonsos theory of urban land use
Effect of zoning: Alonso concludes that land use and land rent derives from von Thunens theory of
zoning results in a discontinuity in the bid-price curve for agricultural land use. This theory shows how various
a particular user. The effects of this are simple: the land uses in an urban area bid to secure the optimum
highest bidder is disallowed; the second highest bidder locationa location that maximises their utility
(as allowed by the land use zoning regulation) will take (satisfaction, in the case of residents, and profits, in
precedence. In such a case, the bid price of the land will the case of firms). This theory further demonstrates the
be lower than the free market condition (i.e., had there effect of planning policies such as land use and density
been no zoning regulation). In other words, land use zoning on the location of activities. Alonsos work
zoning reduces the supply of land available for that could be considered very important, as it triggered
particular type of use, and for other allowable uses it extensive research on urban land use location models
means a slight reduction in competition. The displaced that are widely used today.
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 137

Although Alonsos (or von Thunens) framework


provides a good behavioural explanation of the process,
the problem with its application to present-day mid-size
or mega-cities is its assumption of a central place (or a
place of attraction) to which all actors in the economic
process are obliged to travel. Theoretically, for a
monocentric city, the land uses would arrange in
concentric rings, based on their bid-rent function (e.g.,
see Fig. 18). However, as seen in Fig. 7, organisation of
land uses in concentric rings in Ahmedabad is not
evident. The reason for this could be attributed to the
polycentric nature of Ahmedabad (as discussed in
Section 4.2.4 and Fig. 15) and indeed other contem-
porary metropolitan areas in developing countries.
Therefore, it becomes difficult to adapt this framework
to explain the location of land uses in such cities. The
multiplicity of centres in Ahmedabad implies that its
historical CBD is gradually losing its importance as a Fig. 18. Bid-rent theoryland use organisation.
main attractor, making the direct application of this
theoretical framework to Ahmedabad difficult. Fig. 19) was quite prevalent. However, the criticism of
the four-step model is that it ignores the fact that
4.3.4.4. Discussion. It is clear from the discussions in transport cost (or time) affects where land uses locate
this section that models can play an important role in (households and firms), and alterations in the spatial
city planning. Although the models discussed in these pattern of location of land uses change the pattern of
sections provide a useful theoretical way to understand spatial flows between origins and destinations. In
and analyse cities, applications for more practical general, there is a well-accepted methodology for
purposes in planning have become possible by representing the effects of changes in land use on the
embedding the theoretical constructs in larger spatial transport system, and this has been successfully
interaction modelling frameworks (discussed in the next modelled. However, there is no accepted methodology
section). for the converse relationship, i.e., the effects of transport
change on location of land use. In fact, there is not even
4.4. Introduction to LUTI models a consensus on what the effects are (Mackett, 2002). For
example, if fuel prices are increased, or if road pricing is
Predictive models have an explicit mathematical introduced, or if free buses are provided, then in the long
structure. As the name suggests, such models predict run, the location of land uses may change as a result. On
outcomes of a system of inter-related components, the other hand, if the distribution of population
based on a set of inputs (stimuli). This section discusses (housing) and/or economic activity (jobs) alters because
the basic structure of land usetransport interaction of redevelopment or new development, this influences
models, which serve as a typical example of predictive demand for transport.
models applied to urban systems, with various feedback LUTI models are used to study the impact either of
loops embedded in their structure. The purpose of this changes in land use on transport or vice versa. In
section is limited to the extent of providing a general addition, LUTI models can also be used to study the
understanding of how land use and transport interact in impacts of alternative futures to inform the urban
an urban system using some examples of existing LUTI development policy-formulation process. Over the past
models. The intention is not to describe the detailed few decades, especially in developed countries, national
working of LUTI models, which is comprehensively and local governments have been using LUTI models
covered in Wilson (1974), Echenique and de la Barra for testing the implications of proposed planning
(1976), de la Barra (1989), and Torrens (2000), amongst policies.
others.
In the early 1960s, the use of the conventional four- 4.4.1. The land usetransport relationship
step transport model (which has trip generation, trip Cites may be abstracted in terms of the functions
distribution, modal split and route assignment, see they perform and their physical form. Functions are
138 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Fig. 19. The land usetransport interaction.

Table 3 systems. In some models, the location of employment is


Four-way classification of land use and transport.
an exogenous input to the model and location of
Function Form residences is usually modelled using the bid-rent theory.
Land use Activities Buildings Models that also model the location of employment use
Transport Flows Channels factors such as availability of labour and its cost, and
Source: Mackett (1985) (who adapts from McLoughlin, 1969).
access to transport and its cost, in the process. Some
LUTI models are discussed in the next section.

aggregate actions of the population, such as residing, 4.4.2. The Lowry model
working, shopping, recreation, etc., which collectively Ira S. Lowry in 1964 developed the first LUTI model
could be termed activities. Performing these activities in his seminal work, The model of a metropolis, that
requires travelling from one place to another, which was based on Pittsburgh (USA) region (Lowry, 1964).
generates flows. The physical form of a city consists of Lowrys premise is that the place of employment
buildings and (transport) channels. By comparison, dictates where people live. He divided the employment
activities are performed in buildings and flows sector into two components: basic sector that caters to
generated by the activities traverse through the non-local demands of goods and services (i.e., those
channels. The four-way classification thus generated exported outside the urban area) and service sector that
is shown in Table 3. caters to the needs of the local population (i.e., retail
LUTI models can be thought of as two distinct shops, schools, etc.). In addition, Lowry identifies a
systems that are interconnected, schematically shown in household sector, which constitutes the residents who
Fig. 19. The land use model uses an equilibrium are directly related to the number of jobs available.
mechanism that balances the forces of demand and Their choice of a place of residence is closely linked to
supply and simulates the processes that affect the spatial their place of employment.
location of activities, i.e., households and firms (or The location of employment in the basic sector is
employment). The transport model takes the outputs of exogenously inputted into the model, based on the
the flow of activities to ascertain specific channels assumption that its location is not constrained by local
and transport modes likely to be chosen. If there are factors. This is used to estimate the location of
changes in the transport system, then this will change (employed) residents, based on a gravity model, which
the behaviour of location of activities, generating uses distance (or transport costs) between various
different flows, thus creating a feedback loop. Full- employment (zones) as a deterring function. The
fledged LUTI models in practice have a complex web of resident population so created will require further
several sub-models embedded in the structure of the two employment to provide them with local services. This
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 139

Fig. 20. General structure of Lowry model.

Fig. 21. General structure of MEPLAN model.

estimate of service sector employees is added to the que and others in 1969 took the Lowry model (Lowry,
total employment, and the model proceeds iteratively to 1964) as a starting point and extended it to include an
estimate population in each of the zones, until further explicit representation of the building stock that existed
changes in the population estimates become insignif- in an area. Further refinement of the model in terms of
icant. Fig. 20 schematically shows the process in the its calibration, and detailed development of the
Lowry model. The Lowry model is important in the transport side, took place in the 1970s. By 1977, the
history of LUTI modelling as it triggered development basic structure of MEPLAN was nearly complete and
of several Lowry-type models in the decades to follow, was developed into flexible software (Echenique,
each with specific improvements. 1994). MEPLAN applications to various cities over
the years are covered in Echenique (1983, 1986),
4.4.3. The MEPLAN model Echenique et al. (1990) and Echenique, Jin, Burgas, and
The MEPLAN suite of models stems from the work Gil (1994).
of Marcial Echenique and Partners, which was based on The MEPLAN modelling package is designed as a
the original work carried out at the Martin Centre, general abstract modelling framework to represent
University of Cambridge. The initial work by Echeni- socioeconomic phenomena with a spatial dimension. It
140 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

has a sophisticated and consistent mathematical accessibilities for use in the land use model. It contains
structure, embedded in the influential school of discrete the trip generation stage.
choice models and random utility theory (Domencich & The third is the transport module, which assigns the
McFadden, 1975). The general structure of MEPLAN is flow matrices to different modes and routes, and carries
schematically shown in Fig. 21. out capacity restraint on links to represent congestion on
It shows that the relationship between land use and roads and overcrowding on railways. It contains the
transport is treated as a market relationship. As in any modal split and assignment stages.
market, there are actors who demandin this case land/ The last is the evaluation module, which carries out
floorspace/buildings and transportand actors who the cost-benefit analysis of a particular policy compared
supply these. The interaction between the demand and to a base case. It represents both land use and transport
supply determines the equilibrium prices of buildings benefits, and produces further indicators on the
and transport. Prices thus act as a key measure of the performance of the system, such as average speeds,
way in which land and transport networks are assigned energy use, pollution emissions, and distribution of
to potential users, and determine the density of benefits by socioeconomic groups.
occupation of both land and transport. If the demand
for capacity of buildings or transport exceeds supply, 4.4.4. The TRANUS model
then prices go up, reducing demand until equilibrium is TRANUS (de la Barra, 1989) is an integrated land
established. Land and transport networks with higher use and transport modelling package developed by
demand end up being used at higher density, implying Tomas de la Barra in 1989, and can be considered
higher land values (rents) and congestion, respectively. conceptually similar to the MEPLAN model. The
Using the concept of land use and transport as system combines a state-of-the-art model of activities
interacting markets provides three advantages: location and interaction, land use and the real estate
market, with a comprehensive multi-modal transport
1. Modelling results produced can be justified on the model. The combination of these two models produces
basis of economic behaviour. the highest benefits, but the transport model may be
2. The model is suitable for analysis of policy used as a stand-alone component, especially for short-
alternatives, by allowing policy options to change term projections.
the demand and supply of land and transport Similar to MEPLAN, the theoretical framework of
elements (i.e., by using policy tools such as TRANUS also draws from many traditions, namely:
investment, regulation and pricing, or combinations spatial microeconomics (Alonso, 1964; von Thunen,
thereof). 1826); gravity and entropy maximisation (Lowry, 1964;
3. The outputs from the model are produced as a set of Wilson, 1970); and the inputoutput accounting frame-
prices and quantities, and therefore provide a basis work (Leontief, 1962). Like MEPLAN, TRANUS is
for formulating a system of economic evaluation of also embedded in the school of discrete models and
alternative policy options. random utility theory.
The general structure of the model, shown schema-
The MEPLAN package has four interrelated tically in Fig. 22, has two main sub-systems: activities
modules (Echenique, 1994; Williams, 1994). The first and transport. Within each sub-system, a distinction is
is the land use module, which estimates the spatial made between demand and supply elements that
location of activities such as employment and popula- interact to generate a state of equilibrium.
tion, and produces trade between zones. It incorporates The location and interaction of activities represent
three elements: an inputoutput model; an elastic the demand side in the activities sub-system. Activities
consumption model that allows the consumption of such as industries or households locate in specific places
goods, services and space to vary with prices and and interact with other activities to perform their
incomes; and a spatial choice model that predicts the functions. Activities also require land and floorspace in
location of activities such as households and employ- order to perform their functions. Such spaces are
ment. It contains a trip distribution stage. provided by developers in the real estate market, thus
The second is the land use transport interface representing the supply side. The interaction between
module, which converts the matrices of flows of trade these two elements must lead to a state of equilibrium. If
from the land use model into trip matrices disaggregated the demand for space is greater than the supply in a
by purpose, and also covers transport disutilities of specific place, land rent will increase to reduce demand.
travel from the transport module into trade disutilities or Consequently, land rents or real estate prices are the
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 141

Fig. 22. General structure of TRANUS model.

variable elements that lead the system to a state of activities. Consequently, accessibility feeds back into
equilibrium. the activities system, affecting the location and
In turn, the interaction between activities generates interaction between activities and the prices in the real
travel requirements. In the transport sub-system, estate market. Because it is a cost function, accessibility
demand is represented by the need for travel, which may also be called transport disutility.
may take the form of people travelling to their places of
work or services, or goods that are produced in one 4.4.5. The DELTA model
place and consumed in another. A distinction is made DELTA is a more recent model developed by David
between physical supply and operative supply. The Simmonds of David Simmonds Consultancy, originally
physical supply is made of roads, railways, maritime developed in the mid-1990s (Simmonds & Feldman,
routes or any other relevant component. The operative 2007) and formally published in 1999 (Simmonds,
supply is made of a set of transport operators that supply 1999). The overall aim of DELTA is to allow the
transport services, such as bus companies, truck development of land use models, which, in combination
companies, airlines, or even automobiles and pedes- with appropriate transport models, enable users to study
trians. The operative supply uses the physical supply to the future effects of both land use and transport policies,
perform its functions. singly or in combination, on both the land use and
Demandsupply equilibrium in the transport sub- transport markets.
system is achieved in two ways: prices and time. If the DELTA represents land use change over periods of
demand becomes greater than the supply for a particular time, linked to a transport model, which is run to model
service, the price of the service may increase, but it is the performance of the transport system at a particular
mainly the travel time that increases to achieve point in time. The transport model is therefore run
equilibrium. For example, if the number of passengers several times in any one test, rather than just once for a
boarding a bus is greater than the spare capacity of the horizon year. DELTA calculates all information about
service, then the waiting time will increase. Similarly, if households, population, employment and floorspace,
the number of vehicles along a road gets close to the which the transport model requires to generate travel.
capacity of the road, congestion is generated, thus DELTA thus replaces what is otherwise a process of
increasing travel times. In other words, time is an preparing exogenous planning data input.
important component in the demandsupply equili- The processes modelled in DELTA can be divided
brium in the transport system. into those that primarily affect spaces and those that
The result of such equilibrium is synthesised in the primarily affect activities. For those affecting space, it
concept of accessibility. It is the friction imposed by the predicts changes in the quantity and quality of
transport system that inhibits the interaction between floorspace available for occupation. Those affecting
142 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Fig. 23. General structure of DELTA model.

activities deal with household transitions and employ- scientific manner by modelling the behaviour of urban
ment growth or decline, location or relocation and actors as against a more intuitive approach (or
competition for space (the property market), and the informal commonsense approach, as Breheny and
employment status of individuals. The location or Foot (1986) call it) without models. However, as already
relocation model is the main locus of interactions, both reported in Section 2.4, developing such comprehensive
between activities and space and between land use and LUTI models in developing countries is problematic,
transport. The influence of transport operates through considering the dearth of availability of appropriate
sets of accessibility measures and through environ- data. Based on his experience in developing countries,
mental variables. Fig. 23 shows the main linkages Echenique (1983) points out that simple and robust
between the sub-models in DELTA model within a one- models could be built in situations with limited data. In
year period. this study, a simplified suite of models has been
DELTA consists of six urban and three regional sub- developed for the case study city of Ahmedabad
models. The urban sub-models estimate: (discussed in the next section) that uses the available
data to the best possible extent.
1. The development of buildings on land.
2. Demographic change and economic growth (apply- 5. SIMPLAN model: a brief introduction
ing growth rates which are either exogenous or
predicted in the regional components of DELTA). SIMPLAN is a suite of four modules for informing
3. Changes in car ownership. the process of city planning. Its development and
4. Location and relocation of households and jobs. calibration is a subject matter for a separate paper
5. Employment and status changes. (forthcoming) and is therefore not discussed here.
6. Changes in the quality of urban areas. However, a brief introduction, along with key equations
and a comparison of modelled outputs and observed
The regional sub-models represent:
data for base year 2001, is provided in this section.
7. Migration between different labour market areas.
The first module, called the trend analysis module
8. Investment in the regional economy (long-term
(TAM), is concerned with analysing the evolution of the
decisions affecting the future location of employment).
spatial structure of a city. This module currently uses
9. Production and trade in the regional economy
three spatial analysis tools, such as density gradients
(shorter-term effects on employment and freight
(Clark, 1951), dispersion index (Bertaud, 2001), and
transport).
concentration/de-concentration measure (SCATTER,
2005), see Appendix D. (Its application to Ahmedabad
4.4.6. A brief discussion on LUTI models is discussed in a forthcoming paper.) Such analysis not
As seen in the preceding sections, LUTI models only provides a quantitative understanding of the spatial
allow the planning process to be carried out in a more evolution of a city, but also helps inform the process of
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 143

formulating alternative future planning policies for choice decision could either occur simultaneously with
testing. The second module is an econometric location choice or could precede it, the conventional
residential location model (RLM), as it uses average hierarchy (i.e., location choice followed by mode
housing rents as part of the generalised cost (in addition choice) has been adopted. This is because doing so does
to transport costs) in a gravity-type allocation function not appear to have any inherent advantage over the
and currently deals with work trips. This module uses conventional hierarchy.
the microeconomic theory of demand and supply to The structure of the RLM is shown in Eq. (1), which
ascertain the consumption of residential floorspace in is similar to Mackett and Mountcastle (1997), but it has
each zone, based on the income and price elasticity of two crucial differences: firstly, it is by SEG, and
demand for housing floorspace. The study area workers secondly and more importantly, it uses housing rents as
are divided into four socioeconomic groups (SEGs) or part of the location cost in addition to the generalised
income groups (SEG1SEG4, representing profes- cost of travel. This aspect is important because housing
sional/managerial, administrative/clerical, semi-skilled, rents represent a substantial portion of the location cost
and unskilled workers, respectively). The demand and and are influential in determining location behaviour.
supply in each zone determines the average housing
rent, which is part of the location cost for households. Xim expbm cm
i j
Rm
ij E m
j P m m m (1)
As mentioned earlier, it was not possible to develop a i Xi expb ci j
full-fledged land LUTI model that considers all
activities in an urban system, due to data availability where Rmi j is resident worker of SEG type m locating in
constraints. However, it is believed that modelling zone i with a job in zone j; Emj is employment in zone j
residential location would be a significant step, by SEG type m; cm i j is the a composite measure of
considering that it is the single most dominant land generalised cost converted to Rs/day to avoid huge
use in most urban areas (about 4550% in Ahmedabad). magnitude of values. It is calculated as shown below:
The work trips are then split by mode, using a
multinomial logit modal split model (MSM), which cm m m
i j ri n i j f i j
forms the third module of SIMPLAN. After calibration,
where rim is the average imputed housing rent1 paid by
SIMPLAN can be used to test alternative planning
SEG type m in zone i obtained as ri unit  DFSDm i , in Rs/
policy alternatives for a future year, with appropriate
day (for details see Eqs. (2) and (3)), vm ij is the average
employment, dwelling floorspace, and transport inputs.
time cost for a round trip from zone i to j by SEG type m,
The fourth module, called ASM, is concerned with the
in Rs/day. Notes: (1) Modal split is not carried out at this
assessment of alternative planning policies against key
stage and hence average (harmonic mean) observed
economic, environmental and social indicators.
speed matrix is used in the calculation. Because of this
LUTI models usually have various stages. For
current limitation, congestion is not being modelled. (2)
example, de la Barra (1989) conceptualises the stages
In this study, for a future transport policy to be tested
and its hierarchical sequence as location choice, trip
(e.g., public transport-oriented, highway capacity
choice, mode choice, and route choice; while Echenique
expansion, or a combination), this matrix is modified
(2004) conceptualises it as location choice, mode
accordingly (not discussed in this paper). (3) The value
choice, time-of-day choice, and route choice. SIM-
of time used is 50% of hourly wage of a resident worker
PLAN considers two stages: location choice and mode
of SEG type m based on the literature review of travel
choice. The reason for eliminating the trip choice stage
time estimates. f ij is the average out-of-pocket expense
is because the key determinant of where households
(i.e., fuel, fare, etc.) for a round trip from zone i to j, in
locate is primarily driven by job location, and hence, in
Rs/day. Notes: (1) As modal split is not carried out at
this context, modelling only the work trips would
this stage, average out-of-pocket expenses are used in
suffice. The route choice and time-of-day choice stages
the calculation. (2) In addition, it is not possible to
have also been eliminated because generating traffic
create a feedback loop after modal split, as modal split
volumes by time of day is beyond the scope of a
is carried out at an aggregate level (i.e., not by SEG type
standard development plan-making exercise (at which
m, see Eq. (6)). In light of these limitations, it is
SIMPLAN is primarily aimed), in addition to the fact
believed that vm i j f i j would be an acceptable repre-
that this stage requires modelling of non-work trips,
such as shopping, education, recreational, etc. With
regard to the sequence of stages within SIMPLAN, 1
All references to average housing rents in this study mean imputed
although in theory it could be argued that the mode rents, unless stated otherwise.
144 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

sentation of generalised work travel cost. In other oscillations in the demandsupply ratio, enabling the
words, it is assumed that the nuances due to mode- model to converge quickly).
specific out-of-pocket expenses are insignificant insofar From the resident workers in a zone, the households
as being able to change location behaviour. Xim is a and population are calculated using observed resident
housing attractiveness factor by SEG type m to be workers per household (w) and population each
dm
calibrated, where, Xim Fi i and F i is the theoretical residential worker supports (also known as inverse
maximum supply of residential floorspace allowable in activity rate) (g), respectively; for a future year both w
a zone and dmi is a parameter to be calibrated for each of and g are forecasted.
the zones by SEG type m (which is set to unity initially). The structure of MSM is shown in Eq. (4), which
The purpose of this parameter is to factor for the calculates the proportion (or probability), Prki j , of
unexplained variation in making a zone more or less resident workers residing in zone i having a job in
attractive for housing. bm a parameter by SEG type m to zone j using mode k for travel to work. The modal
be calibrated. split model developed here involves three modes:
The average housing rent in each zone is obtained private automobile (PA) (two-wheelers and cars2);
using Eq. (2) and the new unit rent is calculated public transport (PT) (bus); and slow (SL) (bicycling
iteratively using Eq. (3) (which is conceptually similar and walking) and uses the standard multinomial
to Echenique, 2004). logit (MNL) formulation (Domencich & McFadden,
P unit 1975).
r  DFSDm m
i  Hi
ri m i (2)
Hi expVikj
Prki j P k
(4)
where k expVi j

 u where Vikj is the utility of choosing mode k formulated


Di
riunit riunit (3) as:
Si
where, riunit is the (new) unit monthly rent (Rs/m2) in Vikj ak bckij vtikj ak bckij v=btikj
zone i. riunit is the (previous) unit monthly rent (Rs/m2)
ak bckij ttikj (5)
in zone i. Di is the total residential floorspace
demanded
P (m2) in zone i which is calculated as: where ak is the alternative specific constant (assumed
m m m
m DFSDi  Hi , where DFSDi is the dwelling zero for the other modes); b is a parameter to be
2
floorspace demanded (m /dwelling) in zone i by SEG calibrated (Rs1); ckij is the cost of travel by mode k
type m (obtained from the equations of the respective (Rs); v is a parameter to be calibrated (min1); tikj is the
demand curves) and H denotes households. Si is the total time of travel by mode k (min); t is a new parameter,
residential floorspace supplied in zone i (obtained by which is v=b (Rs/min) and hence by definition is the
applying the average dwelling size to the dwellings in value of time.
2001). Note: The Census of India does not provide The proportion of work trips by mode k from zone i
information on dwellings; however, the numbers of to j is given as:
households are provided, and assuming a vacancy of
2%, dwellings for each of the model zones in 2001 are Rkij Prki j where Ri j
estimated accordingly. X
u is a control parameter estimated to be 0.10 (the Rm m
i j ; and Ri j is from Eq:1 (6)
m
purpose of this parameter is merely to control the
Data from an origindestination survey carried out
2 by DMRC (2004) has been used to calibrate the model.
It is acknowledged that in terms of safety and comfort, two-
wheelers and cars are perceived differently. However, these have been It should be noted that the survey is aggregated over all
amalgamated based on their common characteristics of being private income groups and hence this modal split model is
(i.e., available on demand). In addition, it should be noted that para- applied to the total trips by all SEG type.
transit modes are rarely used for work trips on a regular basis and SIMPLAN is developed in spreadsheet, with all key
hence have not been included in the model. However, for some work operations controlled by pressing buttons linked with
trips within and between peripheral areas of Ahmedabad, a particular
type of para-transit mode called chakda does exist (see Fig. 46). In the
macros (macros are sub-routines written in Visual Basic
future, such special modes could be included in the model should Application code, within the spreadsheet). This
observed data on their usage become available. provides a visually driven user interface, making the
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 145

Fig. 24. SIMPLAN modelling suite.

model simple to understand, operate and update. planning officials, which not only lends more transpar-
Therefore, it allows planners to prepare several policy ency, usually not associated with planning projects
alternatives with drastic variations, and to test these to involving mathematical modelling (wherein specific
see future implications, enabling them to make more tasks are outsourced to private consulting firms), but
informed decisions before arriving at the final plan. In also implies less financial burden on local authorities for
terms of computing times, running alternative policy outsourcing work.
options (like those discussed in the next section) takes The interrelationship between the four SIMPLAN
about five minutes on a standard personal computer. modules is shown schematically in Fig. 24, and the
Secondly, all testing can be carried out in-house by city overall structure of second and third modules, which
146 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Fig. 25. Structure of SIMPLAN core.

constitute the core of SIMPLAN, is shown in Fig. 25. bad, year 2021 has been adopted as the horizon year for
The working of the RLM is shown in Fig. 26 and a the urban planning policy alternatives in this study.
screen shot of the spreadsheet is shown in Fig. 27. Key An urban planning policy generally has two key
comparison of population, average trip distances and components: the urban form and transport. There can be
housing rents between modelled outputs and observed a variety of theoretical possibilities for these two
data is shown in Tables 4 and 5 and Fig. 28, components themselves and how they can be combined,
respectively. as shown schematically in Fig. 29.
In this study, it was thought prudent to examine two
6. Development of alternative policies for the extreme urban planning policies: compaction and
future dispersal. As Banister (2005) puts it, even making no
change needs to be placed in the same context (of other
6.1. Introduction potential choices), as this would have important
implications. Therefore, in addition, a trend policy is
Planning in Ahmedabad is governed by the Devel- also developed, which, by and large, represents
opment Plan, which is a statutory document enforceable continuation of current trends both in terms of spatial
by law. The DP is revised every 10 years. The current development and transport policies. However, com-
DP, which was first published in November 1997 and mitted projects like the Bus Rapid Transit System for
revised in May 1999, was for horizon year 2011. The Ahmedabad (BRTS), the implementation of which
next DP, due in the next couple of years, would be for began in 2007, has been included in all future policies.
the horizon year 2021. Therefore, for the sake of Thus, three alternative urban planning policies have
consistency with local planning agencies in Ahmeda- been developed, as described in Sections 6.36.5.
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 147

Fig. 26. SIMPLAN RLM stage operation.

6.2. Key modelling inputs spatial allocation per zone may be different, depending
on the alternative. It should be noted that the alternative
The key land use inputs to running SIMPLAN for each planning policy inputs are deliberately extreme or
of the urban planning policy alternatives are employment exaggerated, in order to amplify their effects.
per zone and dwellings floorspace supplied per zone. The The total employment for 2021 has been obtained by
study area is divided into 21 zones (modelled zones) and interpolation from LBGC (2001). The total dwellings
2226 are external zones (see Fig. 30). The totals for required in 2021 are derived as follows. The census data
employment and dwelling floorspace supply for the study from 1971 to 2001 shows that resident workers per
area remain the same for all alternative policies, but their household has been growing at an annual rate of
148 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Fig. 27. SIMPLAN screen shot (base year 2001).


B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 149

Table 4
Workers and population 2001 (modelled vs. observed) (thousands).
Zone Resident workers Households Population
Obs Mod % Diff: mod Obs Mod % Diff: mod Obs Mod % Diff: mod
vs. obs vs. obs vs. obs
1 111.3 111.3 0.0 69.5 73.1 5.2 372.6 366.5 1.6
2 59.3 59.3 0.1 38.0 39.0 2.6 178.5 195.4 9.5
3 41.3 41.3 0.0 26.5 27.1 2.5 127.4 136.0 6.8
4 117.8 117.8 0.0 77.5 77.4 0.1 369.5 388.2 5.1
5 62.3 62.3 0.0 37.7 40.9 8.6 205.2 205.2 0.0
6 162.6 162.7 0.0 110.6 107.0 3.3 585.6 536.4 8.4
7 66.3 66.3 0.0 38.7 43.6 12.6 194.1 218.7 12.6
8 180.9 180.9 0.0 105.7 118.9 12.5 557.5 595.9 6.9
9 55.2 55.2 0.0 46.8 36.3 22.5 226.8 181.9 19.8
10 105.0 105.0 0.1 65.5 69.0 5.5 345.3 346.0 0.2
11 109.2 109.2 0.0 75.7 71.8 5.1 357.7 359.6 0.6
12 a 6.0 6.0 0.0 2.9 3.9 36.1 14.7 19.8 34.3
13 3.5 3.5 0.3 2.1 2.3 6.3 10.6 11.4 7.5
14 16.3 16.3 0.3 11.1 10.7 3.7 54.7 53.7 1.8
15 26.1 26.0 0.1 17.7 17.1 3.5 84.3 85.8 1.8
16 15.2 15.2 0.0 9.1 10.0 9.7 44.4 50.1 13.0
17 14.9 14.9 0.0 9.4 9.8 4.4 48.2 49.0 1.8
18 87.0 87.0 0.0 57.5 57.2 0.5 270.6 286.6 5.9
19 86.2 86.2 0.0 60.0 56.6 5.6 290.4 283.9 2.2
20 38.0 38.0 0.0 27.8 25.0 10.0 136.8 125.3 8.4
21 135.9 135.7 0.1 96.1 89.1 7.3 467.3 446.6 4.4
Tot. 1500.1 1500.1 0.0 986.0 986.0 0.0 4941.9 4941.9 0.0
Key: diff: difference; mod: modelled; and obs: observed.
Note: [1] Observed values are from Census (2001a). [2] Although modelled and observed resident workers match within 0.5%, the households and
population have a discrepancy because an overall average of resident workers per household and inverse activity rate (or household size) has been
applied to the modelled resident workers in all zones.
a
It should be noted that zone 12 is a military cantonment area and hence most of the land is not in the open market and thus this zone is not being
properly modelled.

0.024%. Using this rate, w2021 is calculated and then the It is assumed in this 20-year period that average
total number of households in the modelled area for incomes will increase in real terms. In reality, this is
2021 is calculated as shown in Eq. (7). The dwellings reflected by households moving up the SEG ladder. This
required from 2021 to 2001 are calculated as shown in is done by increasing the proportion of SEG1 and SEG2
Eq. (8). households in 2021 based on trend analysis. In addition,
in the case of Ahmedabad, to simulate a rapidly grown
R2021 economy, incomes have been assumed to increase at a
H 2021 (7)
w2021 rate slightly higher than inflation. This is achieved by
assuming the increase in income per annum (5.5%) to
where H2021 is the total households in 2021 in the
be higher than the discount rate (5%). As a result of the
modelled area (zones 121); R2021 is estimate of workers
increase in average incomes in real terms, the 2021
both with residence and job in the modelled area (about
demand curves, as compared to 2001, shift to the right,
96% to total jobs in the modelled area); w2021 is the
as shown in Fig. 31. The equations of these curves are
projected resident workers per household.Using the total
used to calculate the dwelling floorspace demanded for
households obtained in Eq. (7), the estimate of dwelling
alternative policies.
units required in the 20-year period is then given as:

d20212001 d2021  d 2001 (8) 6.3. Trend policy 2021 (TR21)

where d2021 is dwelling units in 2021 obtained by assum- 6.3.1. TR21 land use inputs
ing one household consumes one dwelling and 2% As the name suggests, this policy represents a
vacancy rate of dwellings; d2001 is dwelling units in 2001. continuation of trends, both in terms of land use and
150 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Table 5 presented in Table 17 and zone-wise values are shown


Average trip distance (modelled vs. observed). in Appendix A).
SEG bm Modelled Observed It should be noted that using total employment for
ATD (km) ATD (km) a allocation resulted in a huge reduction in employment
SEG1 0.200 8.69 in certain zones (depending on the policy), implying
SEG2 0.235 7.53 that employment will move to different zones, dipping
SEG3 0.300 5.74 below the 2001 level in some zones. This is unlikely,
SEG4 0.510 5.12
given the current growth potential of Ahmedabad region
All SEG 6.22 6.006.50 and Gujarat as a whole. In other words, regardless of the
a
Data by SEG is not available; the aggregate range is based on policy, employment will still grow in absolute terms
LBGC (2001) and CEPT (2006). (albeit in varying magnitudes) in all zones. Therefore, it
was felt appropriate to deal with increments only. Total
employment is obtained by adding the increments to the
transport. LBGC (2001) report has employment base 2001 employment.
projections up to 2035, which are interpolated to The allocation of employment increments (by inner
2021 for SIMPLAN zones. However, this employment and outer zones) is carried out using Eq. (9)an
produces a proportion split of 65% for inner zones approach similar to Hansen (1959). In theory, it is
(zones 111) and 35% for outer zones (zones 1221), possible to control new jobs locations by planners, but
as against the 2001 proportion of 80%20%, this requires very strict land use regulations. Given the
respectively. On the other hand, if all of the new current statutory scope of the Ahmedabad Development
employment for period 20012021 hypothetically Plan (e.g., commercial development is allowed on roads
occurs only in outer zones, then this produces an with right of way of 18 m or more), this is very unlikely
employment proportion spilt by inner and outer zones to happen in Ahmedabad. Therefore, employment
of 60%40%, respectively, and thus the LBGC (2001) allocations are kept the same for all alternatives, and
employment projections could be considered a more only dwelling allocations are varied for alternative
radical scenario. Therefore, the zonal employment policies. Nonetheless, the effects of extreme versions of
was appropriately modified to achieve employment compaction and dispersal policies, with different
proportion of 75%25%, respectively (details are employment allocations, have also been tested (dis-

Fig. 28. Average zonal housing rents 2001 and 1996 land prices.
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 151

Fig. 29. Schematic policy alternativesurban form and transport.

cussed as part of sensitivity analysis in Section 8.0). shown in Eq. (10). The floor space index (i.e. the ratio of
total built-up area to plot area) for each zone is kept the
SE2001 PTQS2021 same as base 2001, as this remains unchanged for trend
Ei20212001 E20212001 P i 2001 i
2021
(9)
i SE i PTQS i
policy.

where Ei20212001 is the additional employment in zone i Ec RRv SC x PTQSI


di20212001 d 20212001 P i c i v i x (10)
in the period stated; E20212001 is the total employment
i Ei RRi SCi PTQSI
increment for the period stated (which was divided into
inner and outer zones); SEi is the share of employment where d20212001 is as calculated from Eq. (8); di20212001
in zone i in the year indicated; PTQSi is the public is the additional number of dwelling units supplied in
transport quality score in zone i in the year indicated for zone i in the period stated (which is converted to
the option under question.The allocation of the addi- floorspace); Eic is the employment in zone i (where,
tional dwelling units (di20212001 ) to the zones is carried Ei Ei2001 Ei20212001 and Ei20212001 is from Eq. (9));
using a similar equation to employment allocation, as RRni is the ratio of rent in zone i to the average for
152 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Fig. 30. SIMPLAN zones.

modelled area for base 2001; SCix is spare capacity in more intuitive approach, then they could directly input
zone i (depends on the FSI in that zone, which changes the dwellings by zone. Eq. (10) is used for allocating
depending on the policy under question); PTQSi is the dwellings for all 2021 alternative policies, which is then
public transport accessibility score in zone i; c; n; x; converted to floorspace. The average dwelling unit size
are parameters which are currently set to unity (but can in 2001 increases in 2021, based on a households
easily be changed, based on the value judgements of income elasticity of demand for housing.
local planners).
The allocation of dwellings was modified marginally 6.3.2. TR21 transport inputs
for zone 1 (walled city) because of the trend in The changes in transport systems are being
population decline, and zone 12 being a special zone represented by changes in the average travel times
(i.e., a military cantonment). It should be noted that if for all origindestination pairs. For private automo-
local authority planners are confident enough to use a biles, average travel speeds have been reduced from
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 153

Fig. 31. Change in demand curves for alternative policies.

base 2001, to account for congestion in inner zones, Average speeds assumed for all modes across all
and increased marginally in outer zones to reflect policies are shown in Appendix C, Tables C1C3.
augmentation of existing road capacity and new roads.
In addition, in cases where information has been 6.4. Compaction policy 2021 (CC21)
available, the network distances have been changed to
represent changes in the road network, such as flyovers 6.4.1. CC21 land use inputs
and underpasses. For public transport, the bus rapid This policy represents an alternative urban form, in
transit system (which is now being implemented in which most of the new residential development in the 20-
Ahmedabad), has been considered for all planning year period to 2021 takes place within inner zones (i.e.,
alternatives (with a superior version in compaction the AMC 2001 boundary, zones 111). The aim is to
policy). The public transport speeds have been concentrate dwellings, as far as possible, within the
increased, based on the predominant BRTS type existing footprint of the city, to reduce the overall travel
(i.e., exclusive BRTS, normal BRTS, or ordinary bus). distance to work and to create a modal shift in favour of
The current fare policy of the AMC (at 2001 prices) public transport. Corresponding changes in FSI are made,
has been adopted for the public transport system. in which FSI in inner zones is increased to 2.5, while in
Since private automobiles and slow modes usually outer zones it is retained at 1.0. In addition, the land
share the same road infrastructure, travel speed suitable for residential area has been increased to take
changes are in line with private automobiles, as into account conversion of non-residential uses to
discussed above. residential use. For example, there is a lot of derelict
Such assumptions have been made for trend and old textile mills land in eastern Ahmedabad that could be
other alternative policies described in the subsequent put to residential use under the compaction policy.
sections, because developing a network-based transport Employment by zone for 2021 is the same as trend policy.
model was beyond the scope of this study. However, any
commercially available transport model with network 6.4.2. CC21 transport inputs
modelling capability could be easily dovetailed with Travel speeds for private automobiles have been
SIMPLAN, to better simulate the transport system. reduced compared to trend policy to represent conges-
154 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Fig. 32. Dwelling inputs for alternative policies (20012021).

tion owing to the higher amount of population in inner infrastructure is part of roads, it will be of lower
zones, while for outer zones they are at par with trend quality than trend policy. The combined effect on the
policy. Network distances are the same as trend policy. infrastructure for slow modes is that slightly better
For the public transport system, a superior version (i.e., speeds are assumed than trend policy in inner zones.
better than the trend policy) has been assumed, to reflect
more investments in public transport. Therefore, travel 6.5. Dispersal policy 2021 (DS21)
speeds by public transport are more than the trend
policy, based on the type of bus service available in that 6.5.1. DS21 land use inputs
zone (i.e., exclusive BRTS, normal BRTS, or ordinary This policy represents an alternative urban form, in
bus). It is assumed that the pedestrian infrastructure which most of the new residential development in the
would be better than trend policy, but since bicycling 20-year period to 2021 takes place in outer zones. The
Table 6
Summary of land use and transport inputs.
S# Input Base 2001 Planning policy alternatives 2021
TR21 CC21 DS21
Land use
L1 Employment (taken up 1,500,068 2,038,434
by workers resident in
modelled area, i.e.,
zones 121)
Per zone: see Per zone: calculated based on Eq. (9), see Appendix A for details
Appendix A for details (different employment distribution per zone tested for sensitivity
analysis, see Section 9)

B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207


L2 Proportion of Based on LBGC (2001) Modified to account for increases in SEG1 and SEG2, based on trend analysis
employment
by SEG
SEG1: 8.4% SEG1: 10.2%
SEG2: 22.5% SEG2: 25.3%
SEG3: 41.2% SEG3: 38.5%
SEG4: 27.9% SEG4: 26.0%
L3 Distribution of Assumed based Unchanged
employment by SEG on local knowledge,
by zone but adjusted to
match totals in L2
L4 Floor space index (FSI) W-city: 3.0 Same as base W-city: 3.0 W-city: 3.0
Inner: 1.8 Inner: 2.5 Inner: 1.8
Outer: 1.0 Outer: 1.0 Outer: 2.0
Gngr: 1.8 Gngr: 2.0 Gngr: 1.8
L5 Land suitable Estimated based Changed for outer Changed for inner Changed for outer zones based on local knowledge to
for residential on existing land zones based on local zones based on account for conversions of greenfield sites to residential
use (LSR) use map and knowledge to account local knowledge to use (by way of market response to higher FSI)
satellite images for conversions of account for conversion
greenfield sites to of brownfield sites
residential use (a to residential
phenomenon use (by way of market
naturally occurring as response to higher FSI)
the city expands)
LSR inner: 8,195 ha LSR inner: 8,195 ha LSR inner: 9,780 ha LSR inner: 8,195 ha
LSR outer: 5,770 ha LSR outer: 6,587 ha LSR outer: 5,770 ha LSR outer: 7,404 ha
LSR total: 13,965 ha LSR total: 14,782 ha LSR total: 15,550 ha LSR total: 15,599 ha

155
156
Table 6 (Continued )
S# Input Base 2001 Planning policy alternatives 2021
TR21 CC21 DS21
2 2
L6 Dwelling 45,684,830 m 67,602,643 m (1,306,880 dwelling units)
floorspace supply (966,323 dwelling units).
Calculated based
on observed
households (Census, 2001a)
Per zone: see Appendix B Per zone: different for each zone calculated based on Eq. (10),
for details see Fig. 32 and Appendix B for details (Also, different dwellings

B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207


distribution per zone tested for sensitivity analysis)

Transport
T1 Average (network) Calculated from map Calculated from map (revising base year values after considering network changes)
distance OD matrix
T2 Average travel Harmonic mean
speeds OD matrix of zonal speeds
(see Appendix C, Tables C1C3).
T3 Average travel Calculated from
time OD matrix T1 and T2 above
T4 Out of pocket PA: Rs 1.86/km PA: Rs 2.13/km
expenses
PT: 2001 fares PT: 2001 fares (as advised by AMC)
SL: Rs 0.08/km SL: Rs 0.09/km
(see Appendix C,
Tables C4 and C5 for details)
T5 Generalised cost Calculate from
of travel T3 and T4 using
value of time estimated in T6
P
T6 Proportion of trips MNL modal split Rij (i.e., m Rm
i j ) from the residential location model is fed in to the modal split model
by PA, PT, SL for model calibrated to obtain person work trips by mode
calibration of modal split based on survey data
from LBGC (2001)
Key: W-city: walled city (zone 1); inner: area within AMC 2001 boundary (i.e., zones 111); outer: area outside AMC 2001 boundary (i.e., zones 1221); Gngr: Gandhinagar city (zone 21); OD:
origindesignation pair (of zones); PA: private automobile (two-wheeler, car); PT: public transport (bus); SL: slow (bicycle, walk); and MNL: multinomial logit.
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 157

aim is to increase dwelling supply in outer zones to from 2001 to 2021. In trend policy, rents have increased
achieve a better balance in housing rents over the in all except two zones, which have marginal reductions.
modelled area. Corresponding changes in FSI are made, In zone 3, the most affluent zone in Ahmedabad, rent has
in which FSI in outer zones is increased to 2.0, while for gone down by about 0.9% (see Table 7). The reason for
inner zones it is held the same as trend policy at 1.8. this is that the adjoining zones (i.e., zones 18 and 19) have
Employment by zone for 2021 is the same as trend become rather preferred zones for the affluent and hence
policy. In addition, the land suitable for residential use the overall demand for housing in zone 3 has gone down.
in outer zones has been increased higher than trend In similar vein, the development of zones 13 and 20
policy, to account for conversion of greenfield sites. (mainly underdeveloped areas in 2001) over the 20-year
period has reduced the demand in zone 21.
6.5.2. DS21 transport inputs An interesting spatial pattern of percentage change
Travel speeds for private automobile have been in rents emerges when the two diametrically opposite
increased for all zones over trend policy (with slightly policies are compared to trend policy. Rents increase in
more increase in outer zones) to represent the higher level the outer zones in compaction policy. This is because
of investments in road infrastructure (i.e., capacity the inner zones have a huge supply of dwellings,
expansion of existing roads and new roads). Network causing the rents to reduce, with the opposite effect in
distances are the same as trend policy. The public outer zones created due to lesser dwelling supply. A
transport system is assumed to be the same as trend similar pattern is observed in dispersal policy, but the
policy, as the BRTS is a committed project already under pattern is more of an eastwest divide, rather than inner
implementation. Since this policy is private automobile- and outer zones, owing to a larger supply of housing in
oriented, the bicycling infrastructure (which uses roads) western zones (especially outer zones).
also benefits from capacity expansion, while the Examining Table 8 (part A), which presents average
pedestrian infrastructure remains the same as base housing rents by SEGs, it can be seen that in trend
2001. However, the combined effect on the infrastructure policy, the effect of rent changes over base year is
for slow modes is that speeds decrease in walled city, and getting more pronounced as one moves from SEG1 to
increase in inner and outer zones over base 2001. In other SEG4. In terms of average housing rents compared to
words, better speeds are assumed in inner zones and trend policy, compaction policy is beneficial for SEG3
much better in outer zones, as compared to trend policy. and SEG4, while dispersal policy is beneficial to SEG1.
Key attributes of the inputs for all policies are This is because in the inner zones in compaction policy,
summarised in Table 6. Details of employment and where there is more supply of dwellings, there are about
dwelling inputs by zones are shown in Appendices A and 79% of SEG3 and SEG4 households locating, bringing
B and details of transport inputs are shown in Appendix C down the average rents (as against 76% and 67% in
(with base 2001 included in all for comparison) (Fig. 32). trend and dispersal policies, respectively (see Table 9).
On the other hand, in dispersal policy, wherein the
7. Summary of modelling outputs supply of dwellings is more in outer zones, 53% of the
SEG1 and SEG2 households are locating, pushing the
SIMPLAN model has been run for the various urban rents down (as against 39% and 32%, respectively, for
planning policies. However, for simplicity, only one of trend and compaction policies). In general, the pattern
the variations for each of the 2021 alternatives is of housing floorspace consumption (see Table 8, part B)
reported in detail: these are trend (TR21 ED63-37), is the reverse of that of rent, as in pure economic terms
compaction (CC21 D90-10), and dispersal (DS21 D10- these are inversely proportional, ceteris paribus.
90) (see Table 17). Key outputs of other policies are A summary of the key overall demographics is
presented in the section on sensitivity analysis (Section included in Table 10; the population per zone for the
8.0), with base 2001 outputs included for comparison. alternative policies by sub-regions and zones is
presented in Table 11; and gross population densities
7.1. Land use outputs are presented in Table 12. It can be seen that, in general,
in terms of percentage change, population increases
It can be seen from Fig. 33, which presents percentage more in trend policy in the outer zones than in the inner
change in average housing rents in trend policy compared zones. This is in tune with the observed trend of
to base 2001 and compaction and dispersal compared to dispersal tendency of Ahmedabad. As expected, the
trend, that the overall average housing rents have population increases more in the inner zones in
increased in the range of eight to 10% in the period compaction policy and in the outer zones in dispersal
158 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Fig. 33. Housing rentsbase 2001 and alternatives policies.

policy. Indicators to measure the change in spatial and modal split. Expectedly, both the passenger-
structure from 1971 to 2001 and 2021 modelled values kilometre and average trip distance and time are lowest
are shown in Fig. 34. Calculation details are shown in in compaction policy and highest in dispersal policy.
Appendix D. Although the average trip time (ATT) is highest in
dispersal policy, its percentage change with respect to
7.2. Transport outputs trend is much lower than average trip distance (ATD),
because of higher average travel speeds. The pattern
Transport outputs are presented in Table 13 as reverses in compaction policy, but not with a
passenger-kilometres travelled (by SEG and by mode), corresponding decrease in ATT, due to lower speeds.
average trip distance and time (by SEG and by mode), However, in case of public transport the proportionate
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 159

Table 7
Average housing rents by zones.
Zone Base 2001 TR21 % Change: TR21 CC21 % Change: CC21 DS21 % Change: DS21
vs. base 2001 vs. TR21 vs. TR21
1 2,380 2,675 12.4 2,663 0.4 2,663 0.4
2 2,957 3,195 8.1 3,187 0.3 2,904 9.1
3 3,531 3,499 0.9 3,731 6.6 3,482 0.5
4 2,566 2,718 5.9 2,670 1.8 2,653 2.4
5 2,355 2,519 7.0 2,502 0.7 2,439 3.2
6 1,950 2,156 10.6 2,073 3.8 2,207 2.4
7 2,447 2,542 3.9 2,524 0.7 2,722 7.1
8 2,282 2,507 9.9 2,392 4.6 2,551 1.8
9 1,438 1,689 17.5 1,558 7.8 1,787 5.8
10 2,152 2,165 0.6 2,023 6.5 2,318 7.1
11 2,045 2,072 1.3 2,052 1.0 2,263 9.2
12a
13 2,606 2,711 4.0 2,594 4.3 3,001 10.7
14 1,705 1,950 14.4 1,976 1.3 1,997 2.4
15 1,913 2,169 13.4 2,173 0.2 2,214 2.1
16 2,196 2,335 6.3 2,672 14.4 2,246 3.8
17 1,783 2,103 17.9 2,353 11.9 1,728 17.8
18 2,828 3,121 10.4 3,559 14.0 2,875 7.9
19 2,199 2,987 35.8 3,344 12.0 2,741 8.2
20 2,378 2,663 12.0 2,565 3.7 2,364 11.3
21 2,386 2,344 1.8 2,411 2.9 2,338 0.3
Avg. 2,313 2,520 8.9 2,538 0.7 2,508 0.5
a
Values for zone 12 are not reported.

Table 8
Housing rents and dwelling floorspace consumed by SEG.
Zone Base 2001 TR21 % Change: TR21 CC21 % Change: CC21 DS21 % Change: DS21
vs. base 2001 vs. TR21 vs. TR21
A. Average monthly households rent (Rs, 2001 prices)
SEG1 3,800 3,958 4.2 4,188 5.8 3,726 5.9
SEG2 2,743 2,894 5.5 2,929 1.2 2,903 0.3
SEG3 2,214 2,377 7.4 2,359 0.8 2,401 1.0
SEG4 1,665 1,801 8.2 1,776 1.4 1,803 0.1
ALL 2,313 2,520 8.9 2,538 0.7 2,508 0.5
B. Average floorspace/dwelling consumed (m2)
SEG1 70.8 77.0 8.7 75.0 2.5 79.0 2.6
SEG2 54.5 58.9 8.2 58.5 0.8 58.7 0.3
SEG3 45.2 48.1 6.6 48.5 0.7 47.6 1.0
SEG4 34.5 36.2 4.7 36.8 1.9 36.3 0.4
ALL 46.4 50.7 9.1 50.7 0.0 50.7 0.0

reduction in ATD is substantial, benefiting from a roads), which has slightly reduced the network distance
superior public transport system (see Table 14). It as compared to the base year.
should be noted that the overall ATD from base to trend The modal split, both overall and by sub-regions, is
has reduced. This is unusual, but it may be attributed to presented in Table 16 (along with the average trip
a combined effect of two factors. Firstly, the dispersal of lengths for reference) and Fig. 35. The overall modal
jobs to outer areas has meant a reduction in ATD for split for the alternative policies is as expected. In that,
outer to inner and outer to outer zones work trips (see the share of private automobile is increasing from 2001
Table 15). Secondly, there have been improvements in to 2021 for both trend and dispersal policies.
the road network in the trend policy, especially in outer Owing to a better public transport system in all
zones (e.g., some new road links and better intra-zonal alternative policies than the base year, the share of public
160 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Table 9
Households by income groups in sub-regions.
Sub-regions Base 2001 Trend 2021 Compaction 2021 Dispersal 2021
High-income group (SEG1 and SEG2)
Inner zones 192,953 (63%) 290,784 (61%) 323,032 (68%) 220,813 (47%)
Outer zones 111,380 (37%) 182,349 (39%) 150,101 (32%) 252,320 (53%)
Sub-total 304,333 473,133 473,133 473,133
Low-income group (SEG3 and SEG4)
Inner zones 511,309 (75%) 648,728 (75%) 679,725 (79%) 570,235 (66%)
Outer zones 170,402 (25%) 211,690 (25%) 180,693 (21%) 290,183 (34%)
Sub-total 681,711 860,418 860,418 860,418

Total 986,043 1,333,552 1,333,552 1,333,552

Table 10
Summary of key demographics.
Item 2001 2021
Employment 1,570,399 2,131,828
Resident workers 1,500,068 2,038,434
Households 986,043 1,333,552
Population 4,941,905 6,410,819

Table 11
Populationbase 2001 and alternative policies (thousands).
Base 2001 TR21 CC21 DS21 % Change
TR21 vs. base 2001 CC21 vs. TR21 DS21 vs. TR21
By sub-regions
Inner 3,520 4,517 4,821 3,803 28 7 16
Outer 1,422 1,894 1,590 2,608 33 16 38
Total 4,942 6,411 6,411 6,411 30 0 0
By zones
1 372.63 425.16 434.40 407.56 14 2 4
2 178.53 278.53 298.20 204.16 56 7 27
3 127.35 214.60 261.46 159.80 69 22 26
4 369.48 533.65 576.32 411.27 44 8 23
5 205.16 227.75 231.17 218.09 11 2 4
6 585.63 562.74 569.52 531.55 4 1 6
7 194.11 314.87 348.85 245.81 62 11 22
8 557.47 682.88 708.21 646.41 22 4 5
9 226.77 217.44 216.76 195.64 4 0 10
10 345.28 509.81 563.54 377.59 48 11 26
11 357.67 549.12 612.14 404.95 54 11 26
12 14.71 27.11 21.84 25.06 84 19 8
13 10.61 22.89 17.32 41.89 116 24 83
14 54.73 68.87 46.23 99.84 26 33 45
15 84.28 108.71 81.93 143.59 29 25 32
16 44.37 86.79 57.14 139.51 96 34 61
17 48.17 87.29 62.69 128.11 81 28 47
18 270.57 447.31 396.06 792.20 65 11 77
19 290.36 315.12 307.22 374.87 9 3 19
20 136.77 205.78 153.24 278.73 50 26 35
21 467.26 524.40 446.56 584.18 12 15 11

Total 4,942 6,411 6,411 6,411 30 0 0


B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 161

Table 12
Population densitiesbase 2001 and alternative policies (gross density in persons per hectare).
Sub-region Base 2001 Trend 2021 Compaction 2021 Dispersal 2021
Inner zones 190 243 260 205
Outer zones 40 54 45 74
Overall 92 119 119 119

Table 13
Summary of transport outputs by SEG.
Item Base 2001 Trend 2021 Compaction 2021 Dispersal 2021
Work trips (same as no. of resident workers)
SEG1 125,857 208,381 208,381 208,381
SEG2 337,125 514,838 514,838 514,838
SEG3 618,931 784,663 784,663 784,663
SEG4 418,155 530,552 530,552 530,552
ALL 1,500,068 2,038,434 2,038,434 2,038,434
Work trip passenger-km [millions] (one-way/day)
SEG1 1.09 1.59 1.35 2.45
SEG2 2.54 3.48 3.27 3.61
SEG3 3.55 4.08 3.93 4.17
SEG4 2.14 2.60 2.60 3.67
ALL 9.32 11.75 11.15 13.91
% Change vs. base 26% 20% 49%
% Change vs. trend 5% 18%
Average work trip distance [km] (one-way)
SEG1 8.69 7.63 6.46 11.77
SEG2 7.52 6.75 6.36 7.01
SEG3 5.74 5.20 5.00 5.32
SEG4 5.12 4.90 4.89 6.93
ALL 6.21 5.76 5.47 6.82
% Change vs. base 7% 12% 10%
% Change vs. trend 5% 18%
Average work trip time [min] (one-way)
SEG1 55.37 49.40 40.76 65.27
SEG2 49.00 45.54 41.60 43.65
SEG3 40.15 37.78 35.74 35.58
SEG4 38.86 37.30 36.19 44.96
ALL 43.06 40.81 37.85 43.09
% Change vs. base 5% 12% 0%
% Change vs. trend 7% 6%

transport has increased markedly, with highest in higher speeds. However, since a network-based conges-
compaction policy (attributed to a superior public tion assignment model is beyond the scope of this study,
transport system than trend and dispersal policies). Slow this effect is not modelled accurately, and is therefore a
modes have shown an overall decrease over the 20-year limitation. However, any standard commercially avail-
period, which is generally as expected, because of able transport model with network modelling capability
increase in incomes (translating to either higher vehicle could be used for this purpose.
ownership or higher affordability for using public The variations by sub-regions are also generally as
transport). Though dispersed policy has higher highway expected. For shorter commutes (i.e., inner to inner
capacity (and thus higher average travel speed, especially zones) the share of private automobile and slow modes
for private automobile (see Table 14)), the share of has decreased for all alternative policies, compensated by
private automobile compared to trend policy has not and attributable to a better public transport system than
increased significantly (only about 2%). In theory, this base year. For the second category of shorter commutes
analysis be more, owing to lower generalised costs due to (i.e., outer to outer zones) the simulated existence of a
162 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Fig. 34. Spatial indicators for alternative policies.


superior public transport system has not decreased the allocation of dwellings and employment, and the second
share of private automobile; however, it has had a is income variation, discussed in the following sections.
substantial reduction in the share of slow modes. This
could be attributed to better speeds in outer zones in 8.1. Variation in dwellings and employment
general. With regard to the longest commuting trips (i.e., allocation
outer to inner zones), the share of private automobile for
all alternative policies has gone down, compensated for As mentioned before, several variations of the
by an increase in public transport and slow modes. On the alternative planning policies for 2021 were tested to see
other hand, for the second longest commuting category the effects of variations in dwellings and employment
(i.e., inner to outer zones), the superior public transport distribution. For each of compaction and dispersal
system has not had an effect on reducing the share of policies, three other alternatives were developed with
private automobile, except for compaction policy. It the same employment and different dwelling inputs and
would therefore appear that public transport is a more one set of inputs with both employment and dwelling
preferred mode for journeys beyond a certain threshold. inputs different from trend policy. As mentioned before,
In the case of Ahmedabad, the inner to outer zone several variations of employment and dwelling inputs
commutes (averaged over all modes) for all alternatives were tested, but only key input sets (nine) are presented
range from 13 to 17 km, while the average outer to inner in Table 17.
zone commutes range from 18 to 19 km (see Table 15). A summary of key outputs is presented in Table 18.
Therefore, such a threshold could be around 17 km in the In compaction policy with same employment but
case of Ahmedabad. different dwelling allocations (columns df), it can
be seen that an extreme version (i.e., having all of the
8. Sensitivity analysis new dwelling in inner zones, CC D100-0) is more
favourable in terms of overall passenger-kilometres and
Sensitivity on two accounts has been tested. The first average trip distance and time, but least favourable in
is with regard to variation in physical aspects, such as terms of speed, which is attributable to more conges-
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 163

Table 14
Summary of transport outputs by mode.
Item Base 2001 Trend 2021 Compaction 2021 Dispersal 2021
Work trip passenger-km [millions] (one-way/day)
Private auto 3.65 3.68 2.98 4.87
Public transport 2.41 4.07 4.63 4.46
Slow 3.26 4.00 3.54 4.59
ALL 9.32 11.75 11.15 13.91
Average work trip length [km] (one-way)
Private auto 6.68 5.61 4.99 7.03
Public transport 7.58 7.31 7.21 8.57
Slow 5.13 4.84 4.43 5.56
ALL 6.21 5.76 5.47 6.82
Average work trip distance [min] (one-way)
Private auto 29.02 26.23 24.83 27.06
Public transport 64.66 54.97 47.47 60.67
Slow 44.29 42.82 39.85 45.47
ALL 43.05 40.81 37.85 43.09
Average work trip time [min] (one-way)
Private auto 13.82 12.82 12.05 15.58
Public transport 7.03 7.98 9.12 8.47
Slow 6.95 6.79 6.67 7.33
ALL 8.66 8.47 8.67 9.50

Table 15
Average work trip lengths by origindestination (km).
Policy Living in Job in ALL
Inner Outer
Base 2001 Inner 4.04 12.19 4.05
Outer 21.30 7.43 11.64
ALL 5.91 7.44 6.21
Trend 2021 Inner 4.49 14.24 4.52
Outer 19.10 6.48 8.72
ALL 5.51 6.54 5.76
Compaction 2021 Inner 4.77 16.70 4.96
Outer 17.75 6.32 7.01
ALL 5.03 6.83 5.47
Dispersal 2021 Inner 3.73 12.97 3.74
Outer 18.37 6.68 11.33
ALL 6.87 6.68 6.82

tion. In terms of average housing rents, this policy is With regard to those versions of compaction and
least favourable but most favourable in terms of work dispersal policies (in which employment is also altered
travel costs, due to lowest average trip distance and compared to trend policy, i.e., CC ED92-08 and DS
time. An exact mirror image is depicted in dispersal ED22-78, respectively), dispersal policy has lower
policy. In other words, the mildest version of dispersal passenger-kilometres, ATD and ATT as compared to
policy (i.e., having 80% of new dwellings in outer trend. This may seem counter-intuitive at first, but the
zones, DS D20-80) is more favourable in more aspects reason for this is that dispersing employment to outer
than an extreme version. However, interestingly, in zones has resulted into shorter commutes (i.e., more
terms of economic benefits, the picture is different people are living as well as working in outer zones). On
(discussed in Section 9.4 as part of the assessment of the other hand, concentrating most of the new
other alternative policies for sensitivity analysis). employment in inner zones in compaction policy has
164 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Table 16
Modal split aggregated by OD (work trips).
Item Modal split Average trip length (km)
a
BS01 (%) TR21 (%) CC21 (%) DS21 (%) BS01 TR21 CC21 DS21
Overall
PA 28.9 32.2 29.3 34.0 6.68 5.61 4.99 7.03
PT 17.4 27.3 31.5 25.5 7.58 7.31 7.21 8.57
SL 53.8 40.5 39.3 40.5 5.13 4.84 4.43 5.56
Inner to inner zones
PA 35.9 32.6 29.0 33.6 4.37 4.53 4.38 3.91
PT 21.1 28.1 32.7 24.1 4.33 5.58 6.33 4.06
SL 43.0 39.3 38.3 42.2 3.62 3.68 3.73 3.41
Inner to outer zones
PA 25.1 28.4 19.3 35.3 12.21 13.74 14.69 12.93
PT 16.8 40.1 60.0 30.2 12.17 15.10 18.12 13.27
SL 58.1 31.6 20.7 34.4 12.19 13.62 14.46 12.74
Outer to inner zones
PA 52.1 29.2 23.5 36.6 21.16 18.38 16.29 18.31
PT 28.7 40.4 50.1 36.0 23.66 20.94 19.61 19.53
SL 19.1 30.4 26.4 27.4 18.98 17.35 15.52 16.92
Outer to outer zones
PA 28.3 31.7 31.0 33.1 7.55 6.19 5.93 6.47
PT 10.8 22.2 24.9 22.0 9.62 8.15 7.93 8.66
SL 60.9 46.1 44.2 44.9 6.50 5.87 5.67 5.86
Key: BS01: base 2001; PA: private automobile (two-wheeler, car); PT: public transport (bus); and SL: slow (bicycle, walk).
a
Base year values are from LBGC (2001).

resulted in longer commutes than its counterpart trip distance and time is noticed. A plausible explana-
dispersal policy. This is because some of the outer tion that could be offered for this is that to compensate
zones have higher housing attractiveness, implying that for lower incomes, households locate a bit further
SEG1 and SEG2 households prefer to locate in these (implying cheaper housing rents) in order to satisfy their
zones but have jobs in inner zones. However, both these total household budget, whilst deriving the same level
policies do not fare well in the economic benefits of satisfaction (or utility). The increase in work travel
(discussed in Section 9.4). costs are in line with the increase in average trip
distance and time. The change in modal split is
8.2. Variation in income insignificant. Changes in the economic benefits for both
the scenarios are discussed in Section 9.4.
As shown in Fig. 31, it was assumed that incomes
increase in real terms. However, if a scenario were 9. Assessment of alternative planning policies
envisaged where the income levels in 2021 remained the
same at 2001 level in real terms, then these would have Assessment, in the context of planning policies, is
some variation on the outputs. These have been the process in which various pro and cons of the
presented in Table 19. It should be noted that for outcomes of alternative policies are estimated (quanti-
simplicity this has been tested only for policies CC D90- tatively and/or qualitatively), in order to create a
10 and DS D10-90 (i.e., the policies presented in detail comparative picture of the alternative policies. The term
in Section 7.0). assessment is usually used ex-ante, while evaluation
From Table 19, it can be seen that if incomes do not is preferred ex-post. The assessment process produces
increase in real terms, then as a consequence, the distilled information that helps improve the decision-
average housing consumption reduces slightly more for making process by providing decision makers with an
higher income groups and less for lower income groups, objective framework from which a desired policy could
with a corresponding reduction in average housing rents be chosen for adoption, or combinations thereof can be
for all alternative policies. A slight increase in average developed for further testing.
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 165

Fig. 35. Modal split aggregated by OD (work-trips).

9.1. Economic assessment and the lowest is in dispersal policy. The work travel
cost includes out-of-pocket expense and value of time
9.1.1. Housing and work travel costs based on the income of workers. The average transport
Key economic outputs from the model are average cost per household in trend policy has reduced. The
housing rents and work travel costswhich together prime reason for this is that the introduction of the
could be seen as constituting the bulk of the cost of BRTS (which is present in all alternative policies, but
livingpresented in Table 20. Other costs, like non- did not exist in the base year) has contributed to the
work travel, food, clothing, etc., are assumed to be the overall travel time savings. Comparing the three
same across alternative policies for the purpose of alternative policies, since the average work trip distance
assessment in this study. and time are highest in dispersal policy and lowest in
It can be seen from Table 20 that, as expected, the compaction policy, expectedly, the work travel cost per
average housing rents per household have increased in household is also highest and lowest, respectively. The
absolute terms (in the range of eight to 10%). Although total costs (i.e., rents plus work travel, which constitute
the differences in average housing rent for 2021 policies the bulk of the cost of living) as compared to trend
are marginal, the highest rent is in compaction policy policy, are lower in compaction and higher in dispersal,
166
Table 17
Summary of inputs for 2021 policies.
Items Base TR21 CC21 variations (with same DS21 variations (with same CC21 Diff emp and DS21 Diff emp and
2001 (%) ED63-37 employment, but different employment, but different dwellings dwellings
(%) dwellings) dwellings)

B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207


CC CC CC DS DS DS CC DS
D80-20 D90-10 D100-0 D20-80 D10-90 D0-100 ED92-08 ED22-78
(%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%) (%)
Employment increment: 63 63 63 63 63 63 63 92 22
inner zones
Employment increment: 37 37 37 37 37 37 37 8 78
outer zones
Employment total: 80 75 75 75 75 75 75 75 83 65
inner zones
Employment total: 20 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 17 35
outer zones
Dwelling increment: 63 80 90 100 20 10 0 92 22
inner zones
Dwelling increment: 37 20 10 0 80 90 100 8 78
outer zones
Dwelling total: 70 68 73 75 78 57 55 52 76 58
inner zones
Dwelling total: 30 32 27 25 22 43 45 48 24 42
outer zones
Totals: Employment 2001 = 1,500,068; 2021 = 2,038,434; dwellings 2001 = 966,323; 2021 = 1,301,806.
Increments: Employment 2021 = 538,366; dwellings 2021 = 335,483; Key: diff = different; emp = employment.
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 167

the latter being attributed to higher work travel costs.


However, dispersal policy yields higher economic
benefits, as explained in the next section.

9.1.2. Consumer and producer surplus in housing rent


In the above section, the costs to the citizens of
Ahmedabad were analysed. However, as a society, these
costs are incurred by consumers and accrued to suppliers
(or producers). Therefore, these costs do not give a
complete picture of the net economic benefits or welfare
to society as a whole. In order to do so, the surplus to
society has to be estimated. This surplus can be split into
two, based on which group it accrues to: the consumers or
the producers. Consumer surplus is the difference
between what consumers are willing to pay for a good
(or service) and what they actually pay (represented by
the area labelled consumer surplus in Fig. 36). The Fig. 36. Consumer and producer surplus.
producer surplus can be defined as the difference between
the price for which a producer would be willing to
provide a good (or service) and the actual price at which
the good (or service) is sold (represented by the area
labelled producer surplus in Fig. 36). Consumer surplus
and producer surplus definitions are adapted from
Samuelson and Nordhaus (2001), Perloff (2004), Katz
and Rosen (2005), and Krugman and Wells (2005).
To estimate the total consumer surplus, the demand
curves in Fig. 31 can be used. However, unfortunately,
there are no past studies in Ahmedabad available on the
elasticity of housing supply from which supply curves
can be estimated. Therefore, a rather simplistic
assumption is made: if the price is zero there would
be no supply of housing.3 In other words, the supply
curve, assumed to be a straight line, would pass through
the origin and point E (see Fig. 36). In this case, the Fig. 37. Change in consumer surplus.
producer surplus in zone i by household of SEG type m
is simply half of the expenditure (or revenue).
In SIMPLAN, the housing demand is given by the The consumer surplus (for zone i by household of
following equation (see Fig. 31): SEG type m) can be calculated as:

pm Zqe
i pmax expbq (11)
CSm
i pmax expbqdq  pe qe (12)
0
3
This may not be entirely true, as even at some unit price greater
than zero, producers would not be willing to supply housing if that Producer surplus as explained above is calculated as:
unit price is lower than unit production costs. However, this threshold
value (which is the intercept of the supply curve on the unit price axis) 1
will vary depending on the location, as the land cost is one of the PSm
i pq (13)
2 e e
biggest components of unit price (while construction costs are usually
fairly uniform across the city). In addition, there could be changes in The total consumer and producer surplus can be
the threshold value if zoning regulations vary by location. Therefore,
it would not be appropriate to have an average threshold for the study
estimated, respectively, as:
area as a whole. In absence of any substantial information, based on XX
which such a threshold for each zone can be estimated, this rather CSmi (14)
simplistic assumption has been made. m i
168
Table 18
Sensitivity analysisdwellings and employment variations.
Items Base 2001 TR21 ED63-37 CC21 variations (with same employment, DS21 variations (with same employment, CC21 Diff emp DS21 Diff emp
but different dwellings) but different dwellings) and dwellings and dwellings

B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207


CC D80-20 CC D90-10 CC D100-0 DS D20-80 DS D10-90 DS D0-100 CC ED92-08 DS ED22-78
a b c d e f g h i j k
Passenger-km [millions] 9.32 11.75 11.49 11.15 11.06 13.46 13.91 14.40 11.71 11.43
% Change vs. trend 2.2% 5.1% 5.9% 14.6% 18.4% 22.6% 0.3% 2.7%
ATL [km] 6.21 5.76 5.64 5.47 5.42 6.60 6.82 7.07 5.75 5.61
% Change vs. trend 2.2% 5.1% 5.9% 14.6% 18.4% 22.6% 0.3% 2.7%
ATL [min] 43.05 40.81 38.7 37.8 37.7 42.1 43.1 44.3 39.7 36.3
% Change vs. trend 5.1% 7.2% 7.6% 3.1% 5.6% 8.5% 2.6% 11.0%
Speed [km/h] 8.66 8.47 8.73 8.67 8.64 9.42 9.50 9.58 8.68 9.27
% Change vs. trend 3.1% 2.3% 1.9% 11.1% 12.1% 13.1% 2.4% 9.4%
Modal split: PA [%] 28.9% 32.2% 29.3% 29.3% 29.2% 33.9% 34.0% 34.0% 29.1% 33.6%
Modal split: PT [%] 17.4% 27.3% 31.5% 31.5% 31.8% 25.4% 25.5% 25.7% 32.3% 24.3%
Modal split: SL [%] 53.8% 40.5% 39.2% 39.3% 39.0% 40.6% 40.5% 40.3% 38.6% 42.1%
Rent [Rs/month] 2,313 2,520 2,531 2,538 2,544 2,512 2,508 2,502 2,522 2,525
% Change vs. trend 0.5% 0.7% 1.0% 0.3% 0.5% 0.7% 0.1% 0.2%
Transport cost [Rs/month] 2,749 2,613 2,469 2,412 2,401 2,761 2,832 2,912 2,527 2,373
% Change vs. trend 5.5% 7.7% 8.1% 5.7% 8.4% 11.4% 3.3% 9.2%
Cost of living [Rs/month] 5,061 5,132 5,000 4,950 4,945 5,273 5,339 5,414 5,049 4,899
% Change vs. trend 2.6% 3.5% 3.6% 2.7% 4.0% 5.5% 1.6% 4.5%
Note: Results for CC D90-10 and DS D10-90 are given for comparison; Key: diff: different; emp: employment.
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 169

Table 19
Sensitivity analysisincome variation.
Items Real income increase scenario No real income increase scenario % Change
TR21 CC21 DS21 TR21 CC21 DS21 No real income increase vs.
real income increase
TR21 CC21 DS21
2
SEG1: dwelling size consumed (m ) 77.0 75.0 79.0 71.6 69.9 73.3 7.0% 6.9% 7.2%
SEG2: dwelling size consumed (m2) 58.9 58.5 58.7 54.9 54.5 54.7 6.9% 6.8% 6.8%
SEG3: dwelling size consumed (m2) 48.1 48.5 47.6 45.0 45.4 44.6 6.4% 6.4% 6.3%
SEG4: dwelling size consumed (m2) 36.2 36.8 36.3 34.0 34.5 34.0 6.0% 6.3% 6.2%
Passenger-km [millions] 11.75 11.15 13.91 12.11 11.42 14.27 3.1% 2.5% 2.6%
ATL [km] 5.76 5.47 6.82 5.94 5.60 7.00 3.1% 2.5% 2.6%
ATL [min] 40.81 37.8 43.1 41.78 38.5 44.0 2.4% 1.8% 2.1%
Speed [km/h] 8.47 8.67 9.50 8.53 8.72 9.55 0.7% 0.6% 0.5%
Modal split: private auto [%] 32.2% 29.3% 34.0% 32.1% 29.2% 34.0% 0.1% 0.2% 0.1%
Modal split: public transport [%] 27.3% 31.5% 25.5% 27.6% 31.8% 25.7% 1.1% 0.9% 0.8%
Modal split: slow [%] 40.5% 39.3% 40.5% 40.2% 39.0% 40.2% 0.7% 0.6% 0.6%
Rent [Rs/month] 2,520 2,538 2,508 2,361 2,376 2,349 6.3% 6.4% 6.3%
Transport cost [Rs/month] 2,613 2,412 2,832 2,676 2,456 2,894 2.4% 1.8% 2.2%
Cost of living [Rs/month] 5,132 4,950 5,339 5,037 4,832 5,244 1.9% 2.4% 1.8%

Table 20
Summary of housing rent and work travel costs (Rs, 2001 prices).
Indicator Base 2001 TR21 CC21 DS21
[a] Monthly households rent cost
Total 2,313 2,520 2,538 2,508
% Change vs. base 8.9% 9.7% 8.4%
% Change vs. trend 0.75% 0.47%
[b] Monthly households transport cost for work trips (incl. time)
Total 2,749 2,613 2,412 2,832
% Change vs. base 4.9% 12.3% 3.0%
% Change vs. trend 7.7% 8.4%
[c] Monthly households cost of living [a + b]
Total 5,061 5,132 4,950 5,339
% Change vs. base 1.4% 2.2% 5.5%
% Change vs. trend 3.5% 4.0%

XX
PSm
i (15) where DCS is the change in consumer surplus; q, p are
m i demand and price, respectively; 0, 1 are sub-scripts
However, it is not necessary to calculate the total indicating a reference (datum) policy and an alternative
consumer surplus as discussed above, since only the policy, respectively. Eq. (16) has to be suitably modified
change in these quantities is important. Alternatively, to Eq. (17), to include the households to calculate
the change in consumer surplus can be calculated by overall quantities of change in housing rent consumer
using the rule of a half (see Fig. 37) as a reasonably surplus for the modelled area.
accurate approximation. It can be shown that the area
1
labelled change in consumer surplus in Fig. 37 is given DCSm m m
i qT Hi;T qA Hi;A pT  pA (17)
by Eq. (16). For the sake of consistency with consumer 2
surplus in transport, which has been calculated using the
where DCSm i is the change in housing rent consumer
rule of a half (see Section 9.1.3), the consumer surplus
surplus in zone i by SEG type m; q, p are demand (m2/
in housing rent is also calculated by the same method.
dwelling) and price (monthly unit rent in Rs/m2),
1 respectively (from Fig. 31); Him is the households in
DCS q0 q1 p0  p1 (16)
2 zone i by SEG type m; T, A are sub-scripts indicating
170 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Table 21 trend policy and an alternative policy (compaction or


Change in housing rent consumer and producer surplus (million Rs/ dispersal policy in this case), respectively.
month, 2001 prices).
The total change in housing rent consumer surplus is
Indicator CC21 vs. TR21 DS21 vs. TR21 then given by:
Change in consumer surplus XX
SEG1 38.01 50.24 DCSm i (18)
SEG2 16.30 9.88 m i
SEG3 12.12 15.16
SEG3 12.81 12.00 The change in consumer and producer surpluses
ALL 29.38 32.96 (using Eqs. (17) and (15), respectively) for each
Change in producer surplus alternative policy against the trend policy is shown in
SEG1 15.68 15.83 Table 21, with differences between trend and alternative
SEG2 5.96 1.56 policies by SEG shown in Fig. 38.
SEG3 4.63 5.94 It can be seen that the change in consumer surplus
SEG3 4.44 0.35
ALL 12.57 7.98
with respect to trend is highest in dispersal policy and
lowest in compaction policy. From the graphical
Total (welfare) 16.81 24.98
comparison presented in Fig. 38, as compared to trend
policy, dispersal turns out to be significantly better for
SEG1 and SEG2, while compaction is better for SEG3
and SEG4. The overall explanation that could be offered

Fig. 38. Housing consumer and producer surplus by SEG.


B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 171

Table 22 (see Table 9). The scenario is reversed in compaction


Average housing rent by SEG and sub-region (Rs/month, 2001 prices). policy, in which a higher proportion of poorer house-
SEG and sub-region Base 2001 TR21 CC21 DS21 holds (SEG3 and SEG4) prefer to live in inner zones,
SEG1 thereby benefiting from lower rents in inner zones as
Inner zones 3,993 3,989 4,030 4,097 compared to dispersal policy.
Outer zones 3,564 3,924 4,435 3,639 If the change in consumer and producer surplus by
ALL 3,800 3,958 4,188 3,726 inner and outer zones is graphed, then an interesting
SEG2 pattern emerges (see Fig. 39). Consumer surplus is
Inner zones 2,797 2,927 2,856 3,067 positive for compaction in inner zones and negative for
Outer zones 2,634 2,832 3,111 2,679 outer zones, while for dispersal, it is negative in inner
ALL 2,743 2,894 2,929 2,903
zones and positive in outer zones. The change in
SEG3 producer surplus nearly exhibits the same patterns as
Inner zones 2,235 2,393 2,311 2,474
consumer surplus, but reverses for inner and outer
Outer zones 2,162 2,336 2,518 2,241
ALL 2,214 2,377 2,359 2,401 zones. In overall terms, housing suppliers benefit more
in compaction because of spatial monopoly powers,
SEG4
Inner zones 1,673 1,802 1,753 1,834
which is not the case in dispersal policy.
Outer zones 1,634 1,801 1,883 1,752
ALL 1,665 1,801 1,776 1,803 9.1.3. Consumer surplus in transport
Overall The change in transport consumer surplus can be
Inner zones 2,292 2,466 2,425 2,496 given using the rule of a half (see Fig. 37), which
Outer zones 2,364 2,648 2,883 2,525 requires passenger-kilometre and average generalised
ALL 2,313 2,520 2,538 2,508 cost per trip as tabulated in Table 23 (base 2001 values
are presented for comparison). It should be noted that
since this calculation uses the aggregated passenger-
for this is that, in dispersal policy, a higher proportion of kilometre, there is no need to carry out the calculation
wealthier households (SEG1 and SEG2) prefer to live in by household (or trip makers), as in the case of
peripheral areas (see Table 9) as depicted by their ATD consumer surplus in housing rent. Eq. (16) can be
(see Table 13) and hence benefit from the lower rents suitably modified to Eq. (19) for calculating the change
(see Table 22) and consequently more per capita space in transport consumer surplus. The overall change is

Table 23
Summary of consumer surplus in transport.
Indicator TR21 CC21 DS21
[q] Passenger-km (millions, one-way per day)
Private auto 3.68 2.98 4.87
Public transport 4.07 4.63 4.46
Slow 4.00 3.54 4.59
ALL 11.75 11.15 13.91
[p] Generalised cost per trip including timea (Rs/km) (2001 prices)
Private auto 5.60 5.82 4.98
Public transport 6.24 5.56 5.87
Slow 6.65 6.77 6.16
ALL 6.18 6.01 5.65

Change in transport consumer surplus (million Rs one-way per day, 2001 prices) CC21 vs. TR21 DS21 vs. TR21
Private auto 0.74 2.63
Public transport 2.98 1.60
Slow 0.44 2.09
Total 1.80 6.32
a
Value of time (VOT) is from the MSM. This is different from the VOT in RLM, which is by SEG. As a sensitivity test, using the weighted average
VOT from RLM, the change in transport consumer surplus (vs. trend) for compaction and dispersal works out to be 1.59 and 4.29, compared to 1.80
and 6.32, respectively. Although the magnitudes are different, as expected, the direction of change is the same.
172 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Fig. 39. Housing consumer and producer surplus by SEG and sub-region.

P k
then given as k DCS . users in outer areas, where normal buses would share
the road infrastructure with other modes.
1
DCSk qkT qkA pkT  pkT (19)
2 9.1.4. Estimates of costs
It is important to estimate the costs for the 2021
where DCSk is the change in transport consumer surplus alternative planning policies to calculate the net
by mode k; qk is the demand (in passenger-kilometre, economic benefit. Since the population is the same
one-way per day) by mode k; pk is the price or general- for all alternative policies, the overall cost of popula-
ised cost of travel including time per trip (in Rs/km) by tion-based infrastructuresuch as water supply, sew-
mode k; T, A are sub-scripts indicating trend policy and erage treatment, other civic amenities like public
an alternative policy (compaction or dispersal policy in schools, parks and gardens, etc.is assumed to remain
this case), respectively. more or less the same across the alternative policies. For
It can be seen that in compaction policy, owning to example, theoretically, although in compaction policy,
the superior public transport system, the consumer the underground infrastructure (such as water supply,
surplus in public transport in much higher than in trend sewerage, telecom, etc.) could be shorter, its installation
policy, but road-based modes are less beneficial than in in already well-developed and populated areas is more
trend. In dispersal policy, road-based modes are more expensive. On the other hand, in dispersal policy it
beneficial, owing to higher investments in road transport could be lengthier, but with lower installation costs, due
infrastructure. In addition, this road infrastructure to vacant or less developed areas. A similar argument
investment has proved beneficial to public transport would also apply to roads. In addition, it is acknowl-
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 173

Table 24
Estimates of transport costs (million Rs, 2001 prices).
Item TR21 CC21 DS21
BRTS costs
Capital cost (basic) [2006] 9,901.49
Capital cost (basic) [2001] 7,758.08
Cost increase factor 1.00 1.86a 1.00
Capital cost (modified) [a] 7,758.08 14,446.47 7,758.08
O and M cost (@5%) [b] 387.90 722.32 387.90
Total cost [a +b] 8,145.98 15,168.80 8,145.98
Total additional BRTS cost (vs. trend) [I] 7,022.81 0.00
Road costs
Length in 2001 (km) 3,111
Average width in 2001 (m) 25.00
Road area in 2001 (m2) 77,770,000
Capacity increase factor 1.00 0.00 2.00
Road capacity enhancement per annum 0.26% (5.36%) 0.00% (0.00%) 0.52% (11.00%)
(values in brackets are for 20012021)
New road area required 20012021 (m2) 4,171,819 0 8,555,672
Capital cost of new roads (@Rs 781.75/m2)b [c] 3,261.32 0.00 6,688.39
O and M cost (@5%) [d] 163.07 0.00 334.42
Total cost [c + d] 3,424.38 0.00 7,022.81
Total additional road costs (vs. trend) [II] 3,424.38 3,598.43
Total additional transport costs (vs. trend) [I + II] 3,598.43 3,598.43
a
Estimated to achieve the same difference in total costs vs. trend as dispersal.
b
Rs 1110/m2 in 2008 prices discounted to 2001 prices @5%.

edged that there would be subtle variations in the investment cost increase, over trend policy, is the same
manner of provision of these facilities, but these are for both compaction and dispersal policies (which
insignificant insofar as being able to create substantial turned out to be 1.86, i.e., within the acceptable range).
cost differences. Therefore, civic infrastructure costs, Since the non-BRTS public transport routes run on
both hard and soft, are assumed to be the same across normal roads in mixed traffic, the overall cost of these
alternative policies. However, transport infrastructure is are the same across all 2021 alternative policies. It is
the single most important element that is different acknowledged that there would be variations in the
across alternatives. This includes the public transport overall fleet size for buses, routing, frequencies and
system and road capacity (new and augmentation). administrative setup, depending on the location of the
During this authors visit to Ahmedabad for data zone amongst alternative policies. However, it is
collection and obtaining feedback on the proposed presumed that these variations will be subtle enough
approach, meetings were held with city engineers and not to significantly affect the overall costs estimates.
planners to obtain block cost estimates. Based on this In terms of road capacity enhancement, the AMC
information and discussions with them, transport costs trend data (AMC, 2007) for three decades was analysed
estimates have been prepared, which are presented in and the per annum growth in road capacity was
Table 24. The total BRTS cost from the report (CEPT, calculated. This was then projected for the decades
2006) has been adopted and converted to 2001 prices (at 20012011 and 20112021. The growth rate per annum
5% discount rate). in the 20-year period from 2001 to 2021 turns out to be
With regard to the differences of transport costs 0.26%. For dispersal policy, this is assumed to be double
amongst alternative policies, it was assumed that in that of trend, and for compaction policy, no new road
compaction policy, most of the BRTS routes would be network growth is assumed. It should be noted (as
totally grade-separated with better frequency. From the explained before) that only those costs that are different
discussions held with the city officials of Ahmedabad in across alternative policies are estimated.
August 2008, it was learnt that such upgrading of the
BRTS could roughly translate to about 1.52.0 times the 9.1.5. Summary of benefits and costs
cost of a basic BRTS (which is part of both trend and The summary of benefits and costs of compaction
dispersal policies). For this exercise, the cost increase and dispersal policies compared to trend policy are
factor is estimated, such that the total transport presented in Table 25. Benefits (from Table 21) are
174 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Table 25
Annual estimates of benefits and costs vs. trend (million Rs, 2001 prices).
Item Compaction Dispersal
2021 2021
Annual benefits
Change in housing rent consumer surplus 352.55 (29.38a  12) 395.24 (32.96  12)
Change in housing rent producer surplus 150.81 (12.57  12) 95.75 (7.98  12)
Change in transport consumer surplus 1,037.53 (1.80  48b  12) 3,638.87 (6.32  48b  12)
Total 835.79 3,938.66
Annual costs
BTRS additional cost (values in brackets are total costs) 563.53 (7,022.81) 0.00 (0.00)
New roads and capacity augmentation additional cost 274.78 (3,424.38) 288.75 (3,598.43)
(values in brackets are total costs)
Total 288.75 288.65
Net benefit (benefitscosts) 547.04 3,649.91
a
Monthly values are rounded so it will not give exact annual values.
b
Two work trips per day  24 working days in a month = 48 trips in a month.

converted to annual values. Costs are converted to equal different across alternative policies (see Table 8).
annual instalments, such that the sum of the present However, this can easily be calculated from the
value of all 20 instalments (i.e., 20012021) equals the modelled outputs should Ahmedabad civic authorities
total cost in 2001 prices. In P
other words, this is done by decide to adopt such a structure in the future, as against
finding x in C, where C n x=1 rn , is the cost their current practice of a flat property tax structure
difference in 2001 prices (including operation and based on floor area.
maintenance), r is the discount rate and n is the number The other item that could be considered in economic
of years (20 in this case). For example, the annual cost assessment is the fuel tax revenue. However, this has not
difference of Rs 563.53 million for BTRS costs in been considered, as currently fuel tax is collected by the
compaction policy in 2001 prices (in Table 25), add up state government and the magnitude of ploughing some
to Rs, 7022.81 million after discounting at 5% for each or all of it back into the municipal authorities treasury
year to 2021 (in Table 24). is not known.
The idea is to see how the alternative planning
policies fare against trend policy, which allows decision 9.2. Environmental assessment
makers to see its pros and cons in a more objective
manner. It should be noted that, since detailed 9.2.1. Resources: new land required for residential
estimation of all the costs is not carried out, it was use
not possible to calculate the net present value of costs The most important resource in urban development
and hence the internal rate of return. Nonetheless, it is is land. Based on the FSI and density estimates, the total
believed that in the absence of a detailed and land required for new dwellings from 2001 to 2021 is
sophisticated financial analysis, the estimates presented estimated and then converted to annual values, as
in Table 25 would provide a reasonable comparison. It presented in Table 26. As expected, compaction
can be seen from Table 25 that both the alternative requires the lowest amount of land for new dwellings
policies turn out to be better compared to trend in and dispersal the highest.
economic terms. However, compared to trend policy, Although not presented here, the estimates shown in
dispersal policy has a substantially huger net benefit Table 26 are available at a zone level and hence the
than compaction policy. authorities can use them in preparing detailed zoning
There are other benefits to the government, such as and development control regulations. This would be
property tax. However, since the total supply of useful in introducing caveats into the development plan,
residential floorspace in the model is the same across where the estimated amount for residential use is
all policies, the totals would be same. In the case of a tax expected to be met with difficulty, thereby enabling the
structure based on SEGs, this would produce different authorities to alter the zoning and development control
revenues, as consumption of floorspace is slightly regulations at a more local level than is currently being
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 175

Table 26
Estimate of land required for new dwellings (annual estimates in ha).
Sub-region Trend 2021 Compaction 2021 Dispersal 2021
Inner zones 195 245 31
Outer zones 188 39 388
Total 384 285 419
% difference with trend 2021 26 9

done. If necessary, alterations to development control bons, particulate matter, and methane. However, all of
regulations could be fine-tuned iteratively before these except CO2 can be controlled through catalytic
finalising the development plan. converters and other add-on technologies. At present,
With regard to use of building materials, it is there is no technological means to reduce CO2
acknowledged that there would be subtle changes across emissions, other than through the use of alternative
the alternative policies, depending on building typology fuels, such as electricity and hydrogen (Banister, 2005).
(i.e. high-rise vs. low-rise). However, since the total Therefore, only CO2 emissions have been considered in
supply of dwelling floorspace is the same across all this study.
alternative policies, the changes are assumed to be The CO2 emissions for base year and each of the
insignificant. Lastly, energy use in buildings (i.e., policies are estimated, based on the passenger-kilo-
heating, ventilation and air conditioning, elevators, etc.) metre outputs from the model, by converting them to
could vary, depending on building typology. However, vehicle-kilometres, using average vehicle occupancy. It
since plot-level base year information is not available, it is expected that by 2021 all buses will be running on
was not possible to assess this aspect across the compressed natural gas fuel and therefore only private
alternative policies. automobiles are considered. It should be noted that, due
to lack of availability of data on para-transit modes used
9.2.2. Emissions: vehicular CO2 for work trips (known locally as chakda, see Fig. 46),
In addition to CO2, there are several other types of which currently run on diesel, these are not included in
emissions, such as carbon monoxide, volatile organic the model and hence their emissions cannot be
compounds, nitrogen oxides, nitrous oxide, hydrocar- estimated. However, in the future it is quite likely that
Table 27
Estimate of CO2 emissions for private automobiles (annual estimates, except mentioned otherwise).
Item Units Base 2001 TR21 CC21 DS21
6
Passenger-km 10 2104.61 2117.47 1714.82 2803.96
6
Vehicle-km 10 1940.09 1922.96 1557.30 2546.39
Of which, two-wheeler (2W) 106 1670.05 1529.54 1238.69 2025.42
Of which, car 106 270.04 393.42 318.61 520.97
2W CO2 ton 133,604 122,363 99,095 162,034
Car CO2 ton 43,206 62,948 50,978 83,356
Total CO2 ton 176,810 185,311 150,073 245,389
Daily CO2 per capita g 124.23 100.37 81.28 132.91
Difference with trend 2021 ton (%) 35,238 (19%) 60,078 (32%)
Notes and assumptions

 Annual passenger-km is obtained by converting values from Table 14 by multiplying them by 576 (i.e., 24 working days/month  2 work trips/
day  12 months).
 Average vehicle occupancy of two-wheeler (2W): 1.05.
 Average vehicle occupancy of car: 1.30.
 Share of 2W and car (2001): 86% and 14%, respectively.
 Share of 2W and car (2021): 80% and 20%, respectively [projected based on 19612006 trends (AMC, 2007)].
 Weighted average vehicle occupancy: 1.08 (2001) and 1.10 (2021).
 CO2 emission rates: 80 g/km (2W) and 160 g/km (car). Adapted from two recent studies of cities in the Indian context: Bhajracharya (2008) and
Hickman, Saxena, and Banister (2008). The latter study has value in the range of 120240 for most popular cars in India. Values for 2021 are
reduced by 10% to account for improvement in vehicle technology in the 20-year period.
176 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

these, like auto-rickshaws (a three-wheeler, predomi- acknowledged that these two factors could change
nantly para-transit mode), would be compulsorily the estimates slightly and thus this is a limitation of
converted to compressed natural gas-fuelled engines. the study. However, this could be overcome by
The CO2 emissions for private vehicles are presented in collecting data for Indian roads and establishing a
Table 27 and the associated assumptions are shown relationship between average vehicular speeds and CO2
below the table. emissions.
It can be seen from Table 27 that, as expected, CO2
emissions are highest in dispersal policy, due to a higher 9.3. Social aspects
vehicle-kilometre figure. In terms of percentage change
with regard to trend, it is about 32% higher, while for Assessing the social aspects of alternative policies
compaction policy it is about 19% lower. However, it quantitatively has always remained a challenge in the
should be noted that, as mentioned earlier, network realm of public policy. The key reason for this is the lack
congestion is not modelled, which makes these of agreement amongst experts on what factors
estimates indicative. For example, in compaction constitute social wellbeing and how to measure them.
policy, in certain already well-developed inner zones, In this study, the following aspects have been
it is quite likely that the traffic in peak times could be considered, based on the outputs available, which can
startstop, resulting in more CO2 emissions. On the be quantified per zone and, if appropriate, aggregated
other hand, a compensating effect in dispersal policy for the modelled area: (1) mix of socioeconomic groups
could take place, wherein higher travel occurs, but at in a zone and sub-regions and its total effect; (2) social
higher speeds, thereby reducing CO2 emissions. It is equity in distribution of change in housing rent

Table 28
Distribution of each SEG by sub-region.
SEG1 (%) SEG2 (%) SEG3 (%) SEG4 (%)
Base 2001
Walled city (zone 1) 3 7 8 8
Inner West (zones 24) 27 20 13 10
Inner East (zones 511) 25 40 51 62
Outer East (zones 1216) 2 4 5 6
Outer West (zones 1720) 25 15 15 12
Gandhinagar city (zone 21) 18 14 8 3
Trend 2021
Walled city (zone 1) 2 5 9 6
Inner West (zones 24) 25 20 13 13
Inner East (zones 511) 26 40 51 60
Outer East (zones 1216) 3 4 6 5
Outer West (zones 1720) 32 17 14 13
Gandhinagar city (zone 21) 13 14 7 3
Compaction 2021
Walled city (zone 1) 4 7 9 4
Inner West (zones 24) 30 23 14 14
Inner East (zones 511) 27 42 54 64
Outer East (zones 1216) 3 3 4 4
Outer West (zones 1720) 26 15 13 11
Gandhinagar city (zone 21) 10 11 6 3
Dispersal 2021
Walled city (zone 1) 0 5 10 5
Inner West (zones 24) 9 19 11 8
Inner East (zones 511) 10 34 47 51
Outer East (zones 1216) 2 6 7 10
Outer West (zones 1720) 60 21 18 24
Gandhinagar city (zone 21) 19 15 7 3
Notes: (1) Columns total 100%. (2) Grey cells in trend denote values higher than base 2001, while in compaction and dispersal they indicate values
higher than trend policy. (3) Based on trend projections, the overall proportions in 2021 of SEG1 and SEG2 have increased and those of SEG3 and
SEG4 have decreased.
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 177

Table 29
Proportion of SEGs in each sub-region.
Sub-region SEG1 (%) SEG2 (%) SEG3 (%) SEG4 (%)
Walled city (zone 1)
Base 2001 4 21 47 28
Trend 2021 2 20 53 25
Compaction 2021 6 25 53 16
Dispersal 2021 0 20 61 19
Inner West (zones 24)
Base 2001 15 30 36 19
Trend 2021 16 32 32 21
Compaction 2021 17 32 30 21
Dispersal 2021 8 39 36 17
Inner East (zones 511)
Base 2001 4 18 43 35
Trend 2021 5 21 41 33
Compaction 2021 5 21 41 33
Dispersal 2021 2 21 44 32
Outer East (zones 1216)
Base 2001 4 18 42 36
Trend 2021 7 21 44 29
Compaction 2021 8 20 41 31
Dispersal 2021 3 20 39 38
Outer West (zones 1720)
Base 2001 14 23 41 22
Trend 2021 20 26 33 21
Compaction 2021 19 26 36 20
Dispersal 2021 25 22 28 25
Gandhinagar city (zone 21)
Base 2001 17 36 38 10
Trend 2021 16 42 34 8
Compaction 2021 15 41 35 9
Dispersal 2021 21 42 29 8
Notes: (1) Rows total 100%. (2) Based on trend projections, the overall proportions in 2021 of SEG1 and SEG2 have increased and those of SEG3
and SEG4 have decreased.

consumer surplus; and (3) job and workforce accessi- notably the magnitude of increase in SEG1 in Outer
bility. West is staggering. Overall, it would appear that SEG1
are the most mobile in response to changes in spatial
9.3.1. Mix of socioeconomic groups policy.
SIMPLAN outputs households by SEG for each The other significant observation (see Table 29) is that,
zone. For better comprehension, these were amalga- as compared to trend policy, in all sub-regions, except
mated into six sub-regions of the study area. Table 28 Outer West and Gandhinagar city, SEG1 in dispersal
shows the proportion of each SEG by the six sub- policy has declined, with the strongest decline in Inner
regions, while Table 29 shows the proportion of SEG in West, with a reversed pattern in compaction policy.
each of the six sub-regions (also mapped in Fig. 40). Although the mix of SEGs by zone (or sub-region)
A key observations from Table 28 is that, in general, can be examined, an attempt has been made to obtain an
compared to trend policy, in compaction, the proportion overall picture across alternative policies. To do so, it is
of households is increasing in the inner zones (zones 1 proposed to use Gini coefficients (Gini, 1912).
11), with a gradual decrease in magnitude from SEG1 to Proportions of SEG1SEG4 households for each zone
SEG4, with a corresponding decrease in the outer zones are compared to the total proportions of SEGs for the
(zones 1221), albeit not that steep. This pattern is study area (which remain the same for all alternative
nearly reversed in dispersal policy. However, most policies). This is achieved by calculating the Gini
178 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Fig. 40. Proportion of SEGs in each sub-region.


B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 179

Table 30
Gini coefficients of mix of socioeconomic groups.
Zone Zone name TR21 CC21 DS21
1 Walled city 0.11 0.02 0.09
2 Vasna-Paldi 0.23 0.25 0.14
3 Navrangpura-Gandhigram 0.06 0.16 0.34
4 Naranpura-Vadaj-Sabarmati 0.11 0.09 0.03
5 Dudheshwar-Madhupura-Girdharnagar 0.15 0.12 0.20
6 Saraspur-Asarwa 0.08 0.09 0.10
7 Naroda-Sardarnagar 0.04 0.01 0.09
8 Bapunagar-Rakhial-KokhraMehmdabad 0.19 0.18 0.18
9 Nikol-Odhav 0.11 0.13 0.13
10 Maninagar-Kankaria 0.31 0.39 0.22
11 Vatva-Badodara 0.09 0.12 0.08
12 Cantonment 0.06 0.21 0.02
13 Bhat-Chiloda-Nabhoi 0.13 0.28 0.08
14 Kathwada-Muthiya 0.07 0.03 0.21
15 Singarva-Vastral-Ramol 0.07 0.07 0.12
16 Aslali-Lambha-Piplaj 0.10 0.09 0.33
17 Sharkej-Gyaspur-Okaf 0.33 0.30 0.68
18 Thaltej-Vastrapur-Vejalpur-Makarba-Ambli-Shilaj 0.18 0.17 0.20
19 Sola-Gota-Chandlodia-Ghatlodia-Ranip 0.25 0.27 0.34
20 Adalaj-Chandkheda-Kali-Motera-Zundal-Khoraj 0.06 0.07 0.04
21 Gandhinagar City 0.28 0.25 0.33
Sum of Gini coefficients 3.02 3.30 3.95
Variations by inner and outer zones
Inner zones total (weighted) 1.48 1.57 1.60
Outer zones total (weighted) 1.54 1.73 2.34
Note: [1] Value as nearer to zero indicate SEG mix in a zone is closer to SEG mix of the study area.

coefficients for each of the zones using Eq. (20), as the zones). Since, by definition, the values range from zero
first step. to one, the lowest total value would imply a
X socioeconomic mix closest to that of the study area.
Gi 1  m
xm  xm1 ym
i yi
m1
(20) In this sense, trend policy is the first, followed by
compaction and dispersal policies. This could imply
where Gi is the Gini coefficient for zone i; x is the that altering the urban form to a preconceived
cumulative proportion of SEG type m in the study area; structure (e.g., compact or dispersed) leads to a sub-
ym
i is the cumulative proportion of SEG type m in zone i. optimal SEG mix as compared to trend, with dispersal
In Eq. (20), the absolute value is taken into account, policy being the least favourable, created by a
as by definition the Gini coefficient ranges from zero significantly lopsided SEG mix in the outer zones
to one, with zero denoting total equality of distribution as compared to trend. However, for the inner zones,
(i.e., in this case the SEG mix in a zone is identical to the alternative policies do not deviate much more than
the study area) and one denoting total inequality of the trend (which could be attributed to fact that inner
distribution (i.e., in this case the SEG mix in a zone is zones are already well developed compared to outer
in stark contrast to the study area). Table 30 shows the zones, creating an inertia effect).
value for each of the alternative policies by zone. In
this case, the problem with Gini coefficients is that 9.3.2. Social equity
these are given for each of the zones. Although each The distribution of economic benefits spatially and
zone can be compared across alternatives, this does across SEGs can be viewed as an aspect of social equity.
not give an overall effect of the distribution of In this case, only the consumer surplus in housing rent is
households by SEG, as can be seen for the shaded cells used, as it is output from the model by zone and by SEG.
in Table 30. Therefore, as the second step, to obtain an It should be noted that transport consumer surplus is an
overall picture, it proposed to sum the Gini coeffi- aggregated value across SEGs and hence its distribution
cients for the study area (and also by inner and outer is not output from the model.
180 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Table 31
Distribution of change in consumer surplus in housing rent (million Rs/month, 2001 prices, vs. trend 2021).
SEG % of households a Compaction 2021 Dispersal 2021
SEG1 10.2 38.01 50.24
SEG2 25.3 16.30 9.88
SEG3 38.5 12.12 15.16
SEG3 26.0 12.81 12.00
ALL 100.0 29.38 32.96
a
Total households = 1,333,558.

The overall distribution of benefits of change in distribution to a single number across alternatives
consumer surplus is shown in Table 31 (repeated from would not be appropriate. Decision makers could
Table 21), which shows a very interesting pattern. The further comprehend this aspect by looking at the spatial
higher income households (SEG1 and SEG2) benefit in distribution of change in consumer supply in housing
dispersal policy but are worse off in compaction policy, rent by SEG and by zone, as shown in Fig. 41.
with a reversed pattern with regard to low-income Access to private gardens could also be included as a
households (SEG3 and SEG4). In theory, some form of social indicator in assessment. However, unlike most
ideal distribution across SEGs could be assumed and developed countries, the housing typology in Ahme-
both compaction and dispersal policies could be dabad, which is predominantly flats and row houses
compared to it. However, each society would view (and presumably in other developing countries as well)
the importance (weight) of benefit or loss accruing to a does not allow for private gardens. Even high-income
particular SEG differently, and hence boiling down this households live in flats, with proportionately very few

Fig. 41. Distribution of economic benefits in housing rent.


B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 181

living in bungalows. In addition, the data required to based (denoted as zone j). Both these accessibility
establish a baseline status of people having access to measures enable decision makers to see how alternative
private gardens are not available. Therefore, on these dispositions of employment and dwellings and transport
accounts, this aspect cannot be included in the policies affect accessibility. A popular general structure
assessment. for accessibility measure is:
X
9.3.3. Accessibility Ai j
W j f ci j (21)
Hansen (1959) in his seminal paper, How acces-
sibility shapes land use, provides a very useful where Ai is accessibility of zone i with respect to the
definition of accessibility as the potential of opportu- opportunity W under question; f(cij) is a function of the
nities of interaction (for more details, the reader is generalised cost of travel from i to j (which could be
referred to Geurs & van Wee, 2004, who provide a expressed either in monetary terms per trip or time per
useful summary of the various accessibility definitions trip). Note: Depending on whether the accessibility is
that have been propounded over the years, and Ingram, resident-zone based or employment-zone based, the
1971, and Harris, 2001, for discussions on conceptual sub-scripts would change accordingly.
and operational aspects of accessibility). However, it is
important to specify accessibility to what and by whom. 9.3.3.1. Workforces accessibility to jobs. This mea-
With regard to urban areas, it is useful to denote sure denotes how accessible employment is for the
accessibility for people at location A to opportunities at workforce resident in zone i and can be measured by
location B. In terms of measurement, accessibility has suitably modifying Eq. (21) as follows:
been conceptualised as being a function of the number X
JAi E expbci j
j j
(22)
of opportunities and the distance separating them.
However, it is better to use a generalised cost measure, where JAi is the accessibility to jobs for workforce in
rather than distance, as doing so enables accessibility to zone i; Ej is employment in zone j; cij is a generalised
be measured over time and/or across alternative spatial cost per trip (Rs/trip); b is the aggregate distance decay
configurations of location of people and opportunities. parameter estimated in the multinomial modal split
An accessibility measure can be seen as an indicator model.
of the impact of land use and transport developments It should be noted that part of accessibility, as
and policy plans on the functioning of society in expressed by Eq. (22), is indirectly already built into the
general. In other words, it provides a measure of the SIMPLAN allocation equation (see Eq. (1)) and
potential access to opportunities experienced by therefore is reflected in the location of households
individuals or groups of individuals (Geurs & van and ultimately in the consumer surplus in housing rent.
Wee, 2004). Therefore, in assessing alternative policies, However, the purpose here is to create a graphical
it is useful to know the measure of accessibility offered representation of accessibility to gain a better under-
by each policy. standing of its magnitude and spatial distribution by
There are many approaches to measuring accessi- zones at a more aggregate level.
bility. Harris (2001) reviews these approaches and
opines that a more flexible method would be to use a 9.3.3.2. Employers accessibility to workforce. This
continuous declining function of separation between A measure denotes how accessible the workforce is for
and B; the same method has been adopted in this study. employers located in zone j and can be measured by
The second aspect to measuring accessibility is suitably modifying Eq. (21) as follows:
deciding the As and Bs. With regard to comparing X
alternative planning policies, workforce and employ- WA j R expbci j (23)
i i
ment are the two key elements. In this study, both these
have been considered, i.e., accessibility to jobs by where WAj is the accessibility to workforce for employ-
workforce and accessibility to workforce by employers. ers in zone j; Ri is resident workers in zone i; other
Geurs and van Eck (2001) term these as supplied and parameters are the same as Eq. (22).
demanded activities, respectively. DfT (2003, 2004) Kwok and Yeh (2004) suggest that overall accessi-
also propose these two types of accessibility in bility could be determined by weighting zonal
assessing the wider economic benefits of transport accessibility by share of population (i.e., resident
schemes. The first measure is residence-based (denoted workers or employment). Mathematically, the overall
as zone i in this study), and the second is employment- accessibility measure for the study area (given by
182 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Eq. (24)), for both workers and employers, is identical. Table 32


Accessibility indexes (index numbers).
X Ri

JA JAi P or WA Sub-region Trend 2021 Compaction 2021 Dispersal 2021
i
i Ri
! Inner zones 100 121 95
X Ej Outer zones 100 97 155
j
WA j P (24) Overall 100 117 104
jE j

The overall accessibility calculated using Eq. (24),


represented as index values (with trend as 100), is compaction policy offers higher job accessibility than
presented in Table 32. It can be seen that, overall, dispersal policy in about 64% of inner zones and about
compaction policy offers higher accessibility, and half of outer zones. In terms of workforce accessibility,
expectedly, it is higher in inner zones and lower in as expected, dispersal policy is much higher in outer
outer zones, with vice versa for dispersal policy. zones and compaction is much higher in inner zones.
Fig. 42 gives accessibility calculated by Eqs. (22) Accessibility for each of the zones by mode has also
and (23), for each of the zones, converted to index been calculated, as it shows the effects of changes in the
values. It can be seen that, as compared to trend, generalised cost of travel across alternative policies (see

Fig. 42. Accessibility indexes by zone.


B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 183

Fig. 43. Accessibility indexes by zone and by mode.

Fig. 43). It can be seen that, in general, both job and transport for the population and in this regard, it could
workforce accessibility by private automobile in be seen as a social objective.
compaction policy is much lower, and vice versa for Owing to a much higher quality of public transport
dispersal. Conversely, for public transport, compaction infrastructure in the inner zones, the overall PTQS is
policy offers much higher job and workforce accessi- appreciably higher in compaction. In dispersal policy,
bility, and vice versa for dispersal. this is lower than trend, but this is only a marginal
Lastly, based on the public transport quality in each difference.
zone, a public transport quality score (PTQS) was
assigned (used in Eqs. (9) and (10)), ranging from one to 9.4. Sensitivity analysis: assessment summary of
six, with one denoting very poor and six, excellent. A other alternatives
weighted average score for the study area, calculated
using the share of population as the weight, is presented As mentioned in Section 8.0, several other variations
in Table 33. This score in a sense denotes an aggregate of the alternative policies were tested as part of the
effect of the potential of distribution of access to public sensitivity analysis. Land use and transport outputs have

Table 33
Public transport quality score.
Item Base 2001 TR21 CC21 DS21
Average PTQS 2.70 3.72 4.79 3.57
Percentage change (TR vs. BS and Alts vs. TR) (%) 38 29 4
184
Table 34
Assessment indicators from sensitivity analysis (part 1). Dwellings and employment variations.
Items TR21 ED63-37 CC21 variations (with same employment, DS21 variations (with same employment, CC21 Diff emp. DS21 Diff emp.
but different dwellings) but different dwellings)) and dwellings and dwellings
CC D80-20 CC D90-10 CC D100-0 DS D20-80 DS D10-90 DS D0-100 CC ED92-08 DS ED22-78
a c d e f g h i j k
Economic indicators
Benefits (vs. trend) [billion Rs/year]
DCS in housing rent 1.220 0.353 0.769 0.526 0.396 0.125 0.320 0.587
DPS in housing rent 0.093 0.151 0.196 0.058 0.096 0.137 0.023 0.047

B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207


DCS in transport 1.335 1.038 0.863 3.259 3.639 3.997 1.053 2.576
Benefits total (A) 0.208 0.836 0.290 3.728 3.939 3.986 1.396 3.210
Costs (vs. trend) [billion Rs/year]
Public transport 0.564 0.564 0.564 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.564 0.564
New roads and capacity augmentation 0.275 0.275 0.275 0.289 0.289 0.289 0.275 0.289
Costs total (B) 0.289 0.289 0.289 0.289 0.289 0.289 0.289 0.852
Net benefits (AB) 0.081 0.547 0.002 3.439 3.650 3.697 1.108 2.358

Resources and environment


Residential land for new development 384 300 285 275 425 419 415 284 418
(ha/year)
% Change (vs. trend) 22 26 28 11 9 8 26 9
Annual CO2 emission (thousand tons) 185 154 150 148 237 245 254 154 197
% Change (vs. trend) 17 19 20 28 32 37 17 6

Social indicators
Social
P equity
squared deviations 53 78 122 47 100 196 6 35
SEG mix: sum of Gini coefficients
Inner zones 1.48 1.53 1.57 1.63 1.58 1.60 1.61 1.72 1.36
Outer zones 1.54 1.57 1.73 1.92 2.28 2.34 2.39 1.53 1.96
Overall 3.02 3.10 3.30 3.56 3.86 3.95 4.00 3.24 3.32
Accessibility indexes
Inner zones 100.0 118.2 120.6 121.9 97.7 95.2 92.3 135.2 81.7
Outer zones 100.0 102.5 97.4 91.6 147.2 155.1 163.1 69.4 204.6
Overall 100.0 115.9 117.3 117.5 104.9 103.9 102.5 125.6 99.5
Public transport quality score 3.72 4.77 4.79 4.80 3.59 3.57 3.54 4.82 3.57
Note: Results for CC D90-10 and DS D10-90 are given for comparison.
Table 35
Assessment indicators from sensitivity analysis (part 2). Income variation.
Items Real income increase scenario No real income increase scenario % Change
TR21 CC21 DS21 TR21 CC21 DS21 No real income increase vs. real
income increase
TR21 CC21 DS21
a
Economic indicator: benefits [billion Rs/month]

B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207


DCS in housing rent (vs. trend) 0.353 0.396 0.365 0.474 3% 20%
DPS in housing rent (vs. trend) 0.151 0.096 0.128 0.088 15% 8%
DCS in transport (vs. trend) 1.038 3.639 1.023 3.617 1% 1%
Benefits total 0.836 3.939 0.786 4.002 6% 2%

Environmental indicators
Residential land for new development (ha/year) No change as supply is same across alternative policies for both scenarios
Annual Co2 emission (thousand tons) 185 150 245 190 153 252 3% 2% 3%

Social indicators
Social equity
P
squared deviations 78 100 59 73 24% 27%
SEG mix: sum of Gini coefficients
Inner zones 1.48 1.57 1.60 1.53 1.60 1.63 2.9% 2.1% 1.9%
Outer zones 1.54 1.73 2.34 1.71 1.84 2.39 11.2% 6.3% 2.0%
Overall 3.02 3.30 3.95 3.24 3.44 4.02 7.2% 4.3% 2.0%
Accessibility indexes
Inner zones 100.0 120.6 95.2 100.0 121.2 94.8 0.5% 0.4%
Outer zones 100.0 97.4 155.1 100.0 96.9 155.6 0.6% 0.3%
Overall 100.0 117.3 103.9 100.0 117.6 103.8 0.3% 0.1%

Public transport quality score 3.72 4.79 3.57 3.71 4.78 3.56 0.1% 0.2%
a
Costs remain the same in both income scenarios.

185
186 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

already been presented in Tables 18 and 19. In this the society from a set of alternatives, as this could
section, a summary of the assessment of key aspects is become a very subjective process. This problem grows
presented (see Tables 34 and 35). in importance if the actions under consideration
It can be seen from Table 34, that in terms of ultimately determine the welfare and wellbeing of a
economic benefits, the extreme version of dispersal region, as is often the case in development planning.
(DS D0-100) is the best, while compaction (CC ED92- Often matters could be compounded when there are
08) works best if employment is also concentrated in mutually conflicting sets of criteria or objectives within
inner zones. In other words, if dispersal policy is to be the alternatives (Nijkamp & Voogd, 1983). They
pursued, then releasing more land (leading to a higher consider multicriteria analysis (known popularly as
supply of residential floorspace) in the outer areas MCA in recent literature) as an important assessment
proves best economically, and if compaction policy is tool in this process. Further to this, they distinguish two
pursued, then compacting both residential development MCA approaches: discrete and continuous. Discrete
and jobs proves most beneficial. The new residential MCA implies that there is a finite number of explicitly
land required is least in the extreme version of formulated alternatives that are being considered.
compaction (CC D100-0) and dispersal (DS D0-100), as Continuous MCA means that the alternatives them-
expected (as in both cases no new land is required in the selves are not explicit, but only their dimensions are
inner and outer zones, respectively). The emissions are known, and then from a feasible area, the optimum
in line with the passenger-kilometres (see Table 18). In solution is sought. They briefly explain about nine
terms of social indicators, the results are mixed. Both discrete MCA methods and it is clear from the
the mildest versions of compaction (CC D80-20) and discussion that each of these methods has its own
dispersal policies (CC D20-80) are better in terms of merits and demerits. The choice of method essentially
socioeconomic mix of households. Social equity in depends on the context and type of modelling outputs
distribution of change in housing rent consumer surplus, available for assessment.
for both compaction and dispersal policies, wherein In practice, usually a local expert group is convened
employment is also altered (i.e., CC ED92-08 and DS and the various indicators and the weights to be attached
ED22-78, respectively), appears to perform the best to each indicator are finalised. Such an approach could
overall. The overall accessibility and PTQS is best in the take several months to finalise. Considering the time
extreme version of compaction policy (CC D100-0) limitation in the study, it was not possible to arrange for
and mildest version of dispersal policy (DS D20-80). a local expert group. Therefore, it has not been possible
However, as expected, altering employment inputs in to prepare a detailed assessment matrix comparing the
compaction policy (CC ED92-08) proves to be most alternative planning policies. However, since the
beneficial in terms of public transport aspects. alternatives are precisely known, the discrete MCA
It can be seen from Table 35 that if income does not approach could be adopted for this study, bearing in
increase in real terms, then the overall effect on the mind that assigning relative importance to the various
benefits is not significant and the same is the case with aspects of assessment indicators (i.e., its weights) is a
regard to environmental indicators. If incomes increase highly political process.
in real terms for all households, then it seems to create a On the other hand, planners could employ an
better mix of SEGs. Lastly, if incomes do not increase in approach wherein key outcomes of alternative policies
real terms, the pattern of distribution of benefits is the are presented to decision makers under broad headings,
same for both compaction and dispersal policies, but the such as economic, environment, and social (similar to
overall benefits reduce in compaction policy and those shown in Section 9.1). As van Wee (2002) puts it,
increase in dispersal policy. The variations in sum of policy makers can explicitly ask for evaluation criteria
Gini coefficients for SEG mix and accessibility indexes and indicators that they consider relevant (and have the
are not significant. Overall, it would appear that changes same assessed). Healey (2007) argues that plan making
in income in real terms obviously affects magnitudes of and agreed strategies of one period have been pushed to
outputs, but the direction of the outputs does not alter the sidelines or deliberately overridden by shifts in
significantly. political priorities or by the force of particular interests.
This author thinks that it is important for planners to
9.5. A discussion on assessment matrix make the technical outputs of the assessment process
available to policy- and decision makers (who are
It can be a daunting task for planners and decision usually politically appointed, but have a reasonable
makers to choose the best or optimum outcome for technical background). Based on such outputs, the latter
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 187

group could then make more informed judgements, at many levels, such as greener fuels, better vehicle
translating into policy decisions issued to the local technology, and appropriate travel demand management
authorities. measures within each of the alternative policies. As
mentioned before, as a limitation of this study, better
9.6. Conclusions on assessment representation of network congestion can have a
deteriorating effect in compaction policy and a compen-
The outputs of SIMPLAN were assessed under three sating effect in dispersal policy, with regard to the total
key headings: economic, environmental and social. It CO2 emissions from private vehicles at the city level. It
was shown that dispersal policy is much better from an should be noted that changes relating to fuel and vehicle
economic perspective. The general economic argument technology and associated costs are related to national
is that releasing more land for development in the outer and global economic policies and standards, and therefore
areas of an existing city (which consequently implies a are usually beyond the scope of local planners. At best,
higher supply of dwellings) reduces average housing they can anticipate such changes and build alternative
rents. The downside of dispersing cities is that the scenarios for the sensitivity testing of planning policies.
monetary cost of travel increases, owing to higher The socioeconomic mix of households turned out to
average trip lengths. However, in general, the cost of be most favourable in trend policy, followed by
housing rents is a transfer of payments in the city system compaction and dispersal. Social equity in distribution
from consumers to producers. A more important of change in consumer surplus in housing rent appears
economic effect is captured by looking at the consumer to be best for both compaction and dispersal policies,
surplus to the society, in which the dispersal policy when employment inputs are also altered (with respect
proves to be substantially better. to trend). Considering overall accessibility as a social
In terms of environmental resources, in this study, indicator, compaction policy is the most favourable,
the only variable output from the model is land required followed by dispersal. Lastly, potential of access to
for new residential development. It was seen that, public transport service is highest in compaction policy,
compared to trend policy, compaction policy consumes with dispersal policy only marginally lower than trend
less land (26%) and dispersal policy consumes more policy. In general, it appears that it may be possible to
land (9%), both of which are as expected. Some address some of the environmental and social short-
consider that using a smaller amount of new land for comings of dispersal policy by travel demand manage-
development is an advantage in itself. This authors ment measures and stricter zoning norms for location of
view is that consuming more or less land is beside the new employment, respectively.
point, as essentially land use is being transferred from As can be appreciated from the above discussion, it is
one economic use to another (e.g., say from agriculture nearly impossible to pin down one alternative as the
to urban residential, in this case). Obviously, agricul- most desirable. However, what this exercise demon-
tural land is lost in the process, but dispersing cities strates is that it is possible to evaluate the pros and cons of
implies that agricultural land use is faced with higher each of the alternative policies, thereby allowing planners
competition from urban land uses, implying that the and decision makers to gain more scientific knowledge
agriculture sector needs to become more efficient in on their implications. The next step to follow from such
terms of yield per square unit of land (e.g., through an academic exercise is that the local authorities
technological advancement in cultivation). Because of responsible for preparing the city plan devise a policy
the global influences on cities (such as rapidly that includes the best bits from all alternatives tested. For
globalising food markets), a citys reliance solely on example, the principles of compaction and dispersal
its hinterland for food supply is decreasing. Of course, policies could be tried out in certain zones, producing a
exploring the complex economic relationships between combined policy. In essence, more insightful planning
a city and its regions (and beyond) is beyond the scope policy alternatives specific to the local context could then
of the current research and hence conclusive remarks be tested and evaluated, before finalising the plan.
cannot be made. What can be said, though, is that when
assessing alternative policies, the consumption of new 10. Feedback
land for development should not be seen, a priori, as
having any negative effect on the wellbeing of society. 10.1. Background
It was shown that the CO2 emissions from private
vehicles were highest in dispersal policy (i.e., 32% higher It was felt necessary to present the approach
than trend policy). This is an issue that needs to be tackled developed in this study to obtain feedback from the
188 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

local government planners and decision makers rigour and to take a scientific approach in making city
responsible for preparation of the DP. A local quasi- plans. They could start with a simplified urban
government agency kindly agreed to coordinate the simulation model, and once they have adopted it, they
presentations and meetings. In addition, the trip to can then enhance and update the model, as more
Ahmedabad in August 2008 was used as an opportunity disaggregated data become available, to make it a more
to interact with academics and professionals and to powerful tool to aid their decision-making capabilities,
discuss various aspects of the research. Eight presenta- over the years. A summary of the key concerns raised in
tions and meetings were held, as listed below. the above presentations and meetings, and this authors
Presentations and meetings with government plan- responses to them, are presented in the next section.
ners and decision makers.

1. Presentation to staff of Ahmedabad Municipal 10.1.1. Summary of key feedback and responses
Corporation, Ahmedabad Urban Development Au- During the presentations and meetings, many
thority, and Gandhinagar Urban Development Cor- questions and concerns were raised by government
poration, and other governmental organisations planners and decision makers, and practitioners. The
involved in DP making (2 August, Ahmedabad). key concerns and this authors responses (in italics) are
2. Meeting with Dr J.G. Pandya, Manager, Bhaskar- discussed below.
acharya Institute for Space Applications and Geo-
Informatics (BISAG), Gandhinagar and formerly 1. Currently housing schemes by private developers are
CEO of Ahmedabad Urban Development Authority constructed and then provision of transport facilities
(26 August, Gandhinagar). follows. This approach is not appropriate. There
3. Meeting with Mr P.L. Sharma, Officer on Special should be an interactive process adopted while
Duty, Urban Development and Urban Housing making city plans.
Department, Government of Gujarat (26 August, Yes. This model takes into account transport costs
Gandhinagar). as part of the location cost. Therefore, alternative
4. Presentation to the special taskforce on urban transport policies could be tested (with accompa-
planning at the Ahmedabad Municipal Corporation, nying urban form policy) to arrive at an appropriate
headed by the Municipal Commissioner (28 August, combination.
Ahmedabad). 2. We may want to allow compact development in
certain areas and dispersed development in other
Presentation with academics and professionals. areas.
Yes. It is possible to test alternatives wherein some
1. Presentation to practising planning professionals and zones in the model are treated for compact
academics at HCP Desing and Project Management development and other zones for dispersed develop-
(8 August, Ahmedabad). ment. In fact, the purpose of such a model is precisely
2. Presentation to academics and practising planning to test such combinations as felt appropriate by local
professionals at the Centre for Environmental government planners to see their implications before
Planning and Technology University (11 August, finalising the DP.
Ahmedabad). 3. We have to identify the civic needs of the population
3. Presentation to academics at the Sardar Vallabhbhai in various parts of the city and then decide the land
National Institute of Technology, Surat (22 August, requirements for such facilities.
Surat). What facilities are needed is an aspect that has to
4. Presentation to academics at the Centre for Social be ascertained by the urban local body in charge of
Studies, Surat, with representation from Surat preparing the city plan (and hence is external to the
Municipal Corporation (22 August, Surat). model). However, since the model outputs population
at a zone level, once the civic facilities needed are
Overall, it was acknowledged by the decision makers identified, based on population estimates, land can
and government planners that such an analytical be easily earmarked zone-wise in the plan for such
approach should indeed form the basis of all planning facilities. Currently, this is not possible as the AMC
exercises, and therefore is highly welcomed. Practi- area is treated as one zone in the DP.
tioners were of the opinion that it is imperative for urban 4. We should be able to update the model, as new data is
local government authorities to impart more analytical available.
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 189

Yes. This model is spreadsheet-based and hence all map. In addition, based on the policy adopted, zoning
aspects of it are easily changeable because of the of residential use into sub-categories (as per the
visually driven user-friendly interface. Various inputs current practice of DP) can also be included.
worksheets can be easily updated as and when new 9. Certain areas of the city are highly susceptible to
data and information are available. Local authority communal violence. There have been cases of mass
planners, with basic computer literacy, can be quickly movement of people from one area to the other after
trained to operate and update the model with ease. episodes of communal violence. How does the model
5. Can issues like flood- or earthquake-proneness be deal with such situations?
taken into account in the model, as these are likely to The population is segregated by income groups
change for different parts of the city? and not religious groups (although there might be a
Yes. Such aspects make a zone less attractive for weak to moderate correlation between income and
residential location, which, in theory, is captured in religion). Therefore, housing location preferences,
the housing attractiveness factors for each zone purely based on religious aspects, are not modelled.
calibrated for the base year 2001. However, for The housing attractiveness factors for each zone are
example, it is likely that effects on residential calibrated for year 2001, which reflects an aggre-
location due to the 26 January 2001 earthquake gated behaviour. However, if there are enough
were not fully captured in the 2001 Census. In sample survey data available to track movements
addition, if there is information available based on of people over the years based on religious
sample survey, the model could be re-calibrated preferences, then it should be possible to include
between census years (which are every 10 years). this in the model. Currently, no such information is
6. Is the carrying capacity (of each zone) taken into available for Ahmedabad.
account for future years?
Yes. The model allocates dwelling floorspace 10.2. SIMPLAN application to DP making
based on an allocation equation that includes the
spare capacity of each zone. This is estimated based One of the key outputs of the Ahmedabad Devel-
on the FSI in each zone and the land potentially opment Plan is a land use zoning plan for the horizon
available for residential use. year. In the current method of preparing the DP,
7. The base year rent patterns produced by the model population projections are carried out without any
seem to be very realistic (see Fig. 28). However, is the reference to future employment location. At the level of
model capable of capturing property speculation in an urban area, this is not appropriate. Since all proposals
housing rents in the future? in the DP follow from the population projections, it
The phenomenon of property speculation could be said that the proposals are based on an
decreases the potential supply of dwellings, with a unsound foundation.
resultant increase in prices. If there are more policy As discussed in Section 9.2.1, estimates of new
constraints (e.g., in compaction policy there would be residential land required can be made by zone. Based on
constraints on the release of new land) then the these, residential zoning regulations can be prepared
magnitude of speculation is likely to increase in more accurately compared with the current method of
pursuit of more profits (because of higher price using blanket-type zoning. This gives the local
increases). In this sense, speculation is a function of authorities more flexibility in zoning the land for
the policy constraints. residential use. Similarly, new land required for
8. Can the outputs of the model be transformed into a commercial use can be estimated, based on the
land use map, as this is what the local planning employment inputs for each zone.
authorities ultimately make? For other areas in the zoning plan, SIMPLAN
Yes. Since the population distribution for a future outputs of resident workers, households and population
urban policy is at a zonal level, all land-consuming by each zone, can be used to estimate infrastructure
activities, such as residential, commercial, civic services at a more detailed level than is currently being
amenities, etc., can be estimated and shown on a land done. From the requirements estimated, the areas of
use map. In the current study, this step in not existing facilities (2001) are to be deducted to calculate
demonstrated, as detailed plot level information is the infrastructure required for 20012021. This can be
not available. However, if a base year map at plot easily turned to land areas based on the local norms and
level is created, exact locations of new land uses can be shown on a spatially more disaggregated scale on
required for the future can be easily marked on a a map compared to the current practice.
190 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

With regard to transport infrastructure, since the will certainly make the outputs coarser than what the
inputs are based on network distances, new road available data could best provide. However, this
alignments and capacity augmentations proposals can limitation does not appear to be an imminent issue,
be checked using SIMPLAN until satisfactory outputs given the scope and level of detail addressed in the
are achieved. This is completely different from the current DP-making practice. Of course, once such a
current approach, wherein transport infrastructure is model is adopted, the local authority can always make it
simply imposed on the plan without reference to its more spatially disaggregated, in order to use the outputs
future implications. for a neighbourhood level of planning (the second tier
It should be noted that in this study a detailed land after the DP). A possible approach could be to use much
use plan for the horizon year of 2021 has not been smaller zones (or grid-based cells, if plot level base year
developed from the modelling outputs. The reason for map is available), but this would increase the
this is twofold: firstly, this is something that needs to be computational requirements. Because of the spread-
done in close collaboration with the local authorities, or sheet-based structure, a quick run using different spatial
alternatively by the authorities themselves, and sec- levels of disaggregation could be tried out to ascertain
ondly, being an academic exercise, taking this route the magnitude of accuracy gained at the cost of adding
would be inappropriate considering the time limitation the computational complexity, based on which the local
of the study. However, as discussed above, given the authority can make a decision as to what level of spatial
outputs from SIMPLAN a much more detailed land use disaggregation should be adopted.
zoning plan than the current one can be prepared. The second simplification is modelling only resi-
dential location. The limitation of this is that only
10.3. SIMPLAN simplifications and its application journey-to-work trips are output and other trips, such as
limitations education, shopping, social, etc.) are ignored. The
outputs cannot therefore be used to represent the entire
The first simplification is spatial disaggregation, in urban system. For example, the total CO2 emission is
which zones larger than the census wards are used. This not modelled and therefore is not useful for cross-cities,
Table 36
SIMPLAN simplifications limitations, and possible solutions.
S. No. Simplification Limitations and/or caveats for use of outputs Possible solutions
1 Lower level of spatial disaggregation of More aggregation of employment, Given the simplicity of operation of the
zones (than Census wards). dwellings, and planning inputs, hence model, it would be possible to quickly
interpreting results with regard to try out different spatial scales to
smaller areas with the model would be weigh the accuracy gained at the cost of
coarser. computational complexity.
2 Modelling of only residential location Only journey to work trips are output As and when more observed data to
(employment location modelling not (other trips such as education, calibrate the model are collected,
carried out but is given as external shopping, and social/recreation are not addition of non-work travel can be
inputs to the model). modelled). Therefore, outputs cannot carried out incrementally without
be used to represent the entire system, major structural changes to the model,
e.g., estimates of CO2 emissions are given its spreadsheet-based structure.
with regard to only work trips.
3 Modal split model being calibrated Calculations of consumer surplus in It is fairly easy to recalibrate the
based on all trips without SEG transport by mode are indicative. modal split model if such data
disaggregation (due to lack of observed are available.
data for work travel trips by SEG).
4 Network assignment of journey to work Network congestion is not modelled Commercially available transport
trips is not carried out, on the grounds and hence cannot be fed back into the models with network assignment
that for an academic study it is residential location model. Estimates of capability could be easily dovetailed
impractical, both in terms of funding CO2 emissions cannot be made at a with SIMPLAN.
and time constraint, to build a network local level.
model of Ahmedabad.
5 Employment inputs are only by SEG Economic vitality (usually measured Employment inputs by sector and by
without sub-categorisation by industry by the mix of jobs by sector) and its SEG (creating a two-way matrix) could
sector (e.g., primary, secondary and social implications cannot be be easily introduced into the model
tertiary), due to lack of economic estimated. with minor structural changes, should
census data. such data be made available.
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 191

comparison. However, for comparing alternative poli- background. Since the literature on this debate is vast,
cies for the same city, this limitation is not particularly only a brief discussion is included here.
significant. As and when more observed data are In theory, cities could be categorised as being either
collected to calibrate the model, the addition of non- compact or dispersed (and, of course, there could be
work travel can be carried out incrementally without cities that may exhibit both properties). A theoretical
major structural changes to the model, given its manifestation of a compact form could be thought of as
spreadsheet-based structure. people living at high densities, with high levels of public
The third simplification is lack of calibration of the transport, walking and bicycling use, and perhaps
modal split model without SEG disaggregation. shorter average trip distances. On the other hand, a
However, this is simply an issue related to lack of theoretical manifestation of a dispersed city could be
availability of observed data by SEG. This limitation thought of as people living at lower densities, with most
implies that the estimates of consumer surplus in trips being performed by private automobiles, and
transport are indicative. However, it is fairly easy to perhaps longer average trip distances. Burchell et al.
recalibrate the modal split model if such data is (2002) in their report, Cost of sprawl2000, conclude
available. that sprawl has both positive and negative effects.
The fourth simplification is ignoring the assignment Amongst the key benefits reported in this study are:
of trips onto actual transport network. Again this affordable housing, as land further out is cheaper;
simplification is sought on the grounds that, for housing with larger per capita interior and exterior
academic study, it was thought impractical (both in space; lesser travel times for suburban-to-suburban
terms of funding and time constraints) to build a commuters; and lesser intensity of traffic congestion in
transport network of Ahmedabad. This limitation low-density areas. On quality of life aspects, lower
implies that network congestion cannot be modelled crime rates and better quality of schools are reported.
and hence cannot be fed back into the residential The key negative effects of sprawl are higher costs of
location model. In addition, localised estimates of CO2 infrastructure and public services operations; more
emissions cannot be made. This limitation can be easily vehicle miles travelled; longer travel times; higher per
overcome (if adequate funds are available with the local capita travel costs; higher reliance on private auto-
authority) by dovetailing SIMPLAN with commercially mobiles; excessive transport energy use; and loss of
available transport model with network assignment agricultural and environmentally fragile land. On
capability (which includes the highly resource-con- quality of life aspects, the negatives reported are: more
suming task of building the transport network, say in a air pollution; weakened sense of community and
GIS environment). fostering of social exclusion; and spatial mismatch.
The fifth simplification is that employment inputs are (Spatial mismatch is a phenomenon described first by
only by SEG, without sub-categorisation by industry Kain in 1968, in which the poor are forced to live in
sector (e.g., primary, secondary and tertiary), due to a central cities owing to exclusionary land use zoning
lack of economic census data. This limitation implies policies, which limits their access to suburban blue-
that economic vitality (usually measured by the mix of collar jobs (see Anas, Arnott, & Small, 1998; Ihlanfeldt,
jobs by sector) and its social implications cannot be 1992; Kain, 1992).)
estimated. However, if an economic census (or even a Newman and Kenworthy (1989a, 1989b), from their
sample survey on a regular basis) is carried out by the study of 32 cities in North America, Australia, Europe,
local authority, then employment inputs by SEG and Canada and Asia, concluded that as urban density
sector (creating a two-way matrix) could be easily decreases, gasoline consumption increases markedly,
introduced into the model with minor structural with 30 persons per hectare being suggested as the cut-
changes. The above discussion is summarised in off mark (see Fig. 44). They report negative correlations
Table 36. of land use and transport variables, such as land use
intensity, traffic restraint, and public transport use, with
11. Conclusions gasoline use, suggesting that if a city wanted to lower its
gasoline use and automobile dependence, it ought to
11.1. On alternative urban forms increase land use intensity and degree of centralisation,
and improve its public transport. However, Newman
At this point, an understanding of the merits and and Kenworthys notion of correlation between density
demerits of alternative urban forms, as reported by and energy use in transport has been refuted; for
academics and professionals, would provide a useful example, Gordon and Richardson (1989) say that their
192 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Fig. 44. Relationship between density and gasoline use.

analysis is faulty, the problems are wrongly diagnosed, strong preference for their own large private plots of
and that their policy and planning prescriptions are land face significant tradeoffs if they must locate in
inappropriate and unfeasible. In addition, a later study compact cities. Sprawled cities offer both firms and
by Gordon (1997) uses data from Newman and households more choices, while the diversity of
Kenworthy (1989a), and recalculates the correlation consumer choices for firms and households is likely
after incorporating fuel prices. He finds that it is indeed to shrink in compact cities. Findings from a study of
the price of fuel that accounts for variations in transport English cities (Burton, 2000), investigating the validity
energy use, rather than density, and opines that higher of the claims that a higher-density urban form promotes
fuel prices would also tend to generate more compact social equity, indicate that compactness (compact city)
settlement patterns (a finding similar to Clark (1951). A is likely to be negative for certain aspects, e.g. less
recent study (Brownstone & Golob, 2009) concentrat- domestic living space, lack of affordable housing, and
ing on California (based on a sample National increased crime levels. However, it may offer benefits,
Household Survey) concludes that density directly such as improved public transport use, reduced social
influences vehicle usage, and both density and vehicle segregation, and better access to facilities. In general,
usage influence fuel consumption. Comparing two these conclusions are similar to the benefits of sprawl as
households that are similar in all respects except reported by Burchell et al. (2002), but in contrast with
residential density, a lower density of 1000 (roughly those of Newman and Kenworthy (1989a, 1989b) and
40% of the mean value) housing units per square mile Brownstone and Golob (2009). On commuting times,
implies a positive difference of almost 1200 miles per Kahn (2006) concludes that compact cities feature
year (4.8%) and about 65 more gallons of fuel per greater congestion and higher commute times, while in
household (5.5%). sprawled cities certain global environmental external-
From a broader perspective, Kahn (2006) reports that ities, such as greenhouse gas production, are likely to be
there is no correlation between quality of life and a exacerbated (but technological advance has mitigated
citys spatial structure. He further concludes that many of the environmental problems associated with
compact cities, with all employment located in the sprawl). An empirical study of US cities by Gordon,
CBD, limit economic opportunities. Firms that need Kumar, and Richardson (1989) concludes that a
large parcels of land to operate and people who have a polycentric and dispersed metropolitan area facilitates
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 193

shorter commuting times. Both these conclusions are consumer surplus in both housing rent and transport.
similar to Burchell et al. (2002). This is because of higher housing rents and lower
A study by Lin and Yang (2006) of medium- and proportionate change in generalised travel costs, as
small-sized cities in Taiwan suggests that the influence compared to average trip distances for private and slow
of the compact-city paradigm (i.e., a high-density modes (implying higher generalised cost per kmsee
pattern and intensification) has a direct negative effect Table 23). As expected, in terms of land requirements, a
on environmental and social sustainability, but posi- compact form consumes less. With regard to CO2
tively affects economic sustainability (indirectly, i.e. via emissions, compaction policy was the most beneficial,
(creation of a) mix of (land) uses)the latter being in but it needs to be borne in mind that congestion effects
contrast with what Kahn (2006) concludes. Lin and could tilt the balance. In terms of social aspects, the
Yang acknowledge that their findings do not present a SEG mix of households achieved in compaction is
full and accurate picture of the sustainability of the better than dispersed policy (albeit not so compared to
compact-city paradigm in Taiwan, owing to sample size trend policy). This is in contrast with the findings of Lin
and data limitations; nonetheless, they do cast doubt on and Yang (2006), who conclude that compact form has a
whether the compact-city paradigm is good for all negative effect on social aspects. In summary, it
sustainability issues. In contrast, Gordon (2008) opines therefore appears that the performance of urban forms
that the social and political implications of sustained has a strong bearing on the specific attributes of the
efforts to promote higher densities by means of severely context, such as type of economy, cultural preferences
restricting greenfield development, which would raise and political environment, and does not appear to have
dwelling prices and restrict access to housing, would be globally generalisable merits or demerits.
unacceptable. On similar lines, Brueckner (2000), in the
context of US cities, concludes that greatly restricting 11.2. On the model structure and operationality
urban expansion might needlessly limit the consump-
tion of housing space, depressing the standard of living Some of the LUTI modelling approaches prevailing
of American consumers. Rather, the approach to adopt in developed countries were discussed in Section 4.4.
would be one that recognises the damage done by an Literature with specific references to developing
unwarranted restriction of urban growth, such as countries opines that although full-fledged LUTI
development taxes and congestion tolls, which attack models are difficult to develop given the data
sprawl at its source by correcting specific market availability constraints, it is possible to build simplified
failures. Specifically researching social interaction and models from available data to inform planning policy-
urban sprawl, a recent study by the same author making. In this study, such an approach was demon-
(Brueckner & Largey, 2008) indicates that density and strated for Ahmedabad and it was shown how the
social interaction may be negatively correlated. current approach to planning can be enhanced to better
From the above discussion, it appears that both forms inform the plan-making process.
of urban development have merits and demerits With regard to operating the model, a spreadsheet-
reported in the literature, but neither form has a set based approach was adopted to reinforce the simplicity.
of settled arguments as to which form is absolutely This approach offers a visually driven user-interface and
better than the other, which was corroborated by the therefore improves the understanding of the processes
finding of this study. It would also appear that cities within the model and makes it more flexible for
across the globe exhibit different responses to urban operating and updating the model (which was also
form. This perpetual debate, on which city form is ideal, corroborated by government decision makers and
was addressed in this study in the context of developing planners, to whom it was presented in August 2008).
countries. It showed that indeed a compact or dispersed The other advantage is the speed of running the model.
form does not appear to be an outright winwin As discussed in Section 11.1, it is apparent that neither
proposition. As shown in Section 9.1, in economic of the alternative urban forms is optimum in an absolute
terms, a dispersed form offers more benefits. This sense and that each of them offers different benefits.
finding is in line with Burchell et al. (2002) and Kahn Planners must therefore test alternative designs and
(2006), but in contrast with Lin and Yang (2006), learn from the quantified merits and demerits of
Newman and Kenworthy (1989a, 1989b), and Brown- alternative urban forms (like the ones tested in this
stone and Golob (2009). Purely from the perspective of study), or combinations of such forms, to pursue the
travel time savings, it was shown that a compact form optimum outcome for the local context in question. This
achieves more, but suffers when it comes to the is precisely possible given the speed advantage in
194 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

addition to the in-house running capability of the model interaction tradition (e.g., Lowry, etc.) and micro-
owing to its simplicity. For example, planners can economic theory of demandsupply (e.g., MEPLAN,
quickly and reliably test different FSI norms by zone etc.) to developing countries with data availability
(i.e., can have an appropriate mix of compaction and constraints.
dispersal) to arrive at a final plan. The spatial 3. Applying the classical theories of spatial organisa-
disaggregation of outputs would allow planners to tion to Ahmedabad, it was seen that Ahmedabad does
make more detailed land use zoning plans and not conform to the concentric zone theory, but does
accompanying DCRs than is currently possible. In exhibit the formation of wedges of sectors along
addition, preliminary testing of a transport policy transport routes, as suggested by sector theory. The
package (e.g., new arterial roads, capacity expansion of formation of multiple centres is also evident in
existing roads, dedicated busways, etc.) in conjunction Ahmedabad, as suggested by the multiple-nuclei
with a land use/spatial policy package can be carried out theory.
quickly. By associating SIMPLAN with any commer- 4. Though Ahmedabad is relatively more compact
cially available transport network modelling software, compared to some other cities of the developed
the reliability of outputs from testing transport policies world, analysis of the past 30-year data indicates that
could be enhanced. the city has a tendency towards dispersal. In addition,
a reduction in population density in central areas and
11.3. On the context of developing countries an increase in peripheral areas is observed for
Ahmedabad. These trends are likely to continue for
Scholarly literature on urban development and some time in the future.
planning in developing countries indicates that dis- 5. Analytical models of location and land use were
aggregated temporal and spatial data limitations make applied to Ahmedabad. In that, it was shown that the
the application of model-based planning approaches monocentric bid-rent theory was not applicable
challenging (Chatterjee & Nijkamp, 1983; Srinivasan, directly to Ahmedabad, owing to its polycentric
2005). In addition, it maintains that interaction between character (see Fig. 15). However, the distribution of
the scientific community and the administrative and settlements in the Ahmedabad sub-region did show
political personnel concerned with city planning has some sort of formation, as suggested by the central
decreased over the years (Chatterjee, 1983). place theory.
This study demonstrated that, although challenging, 6. In the context of Ahmedabad, dispersing the city in
it is possible to apply analytical tools and develop terms of dwellings is more beneficial economically,
simplified urban models to inform plan making using and the more extreme the dispersal policy, the
available data. This authors interaction with decision better it is. If compaction needs to be pursued, then it
makers and planners during the course of this study appears to perform better when both dwellings and
indicated that they are open and willing to adopt the jobs are considered. In terms of consumption of land
path of a more scientific approach to planning. Overall, for new development, obviously, by definition
the interaction was very welcoming, and indicates their compaction policy consumes least land. In addition,
willingness to bridge the gap between theory and CO2 emissions are least in compaction, because of
practice, if appropriate efforts are made. shorter average trip distances (but bearing in mind
that road congestion is not modelled). With regard to
11.4. Summary of key research findings the mix of households by income group, trend policy
is optimum, followed by compaction and then
The findings from this study have been mentioned in dispersal (with milder versions of both performing
the text as appropriate. However, the purpose of this relatively better). In terms of social equity, it appears
section is to summarise the key ones, as follows. that compaction and dispersal policies perform
relatively better if both dwellings and employment
1. The current plan-making approach followed by the are altered. Fig. 45 provides a snapshot summary of
planning authorities in Ahmedabad lacks a quanti- key assessment indicators.
tative framework, insofar as being able to test and
assess alternative planning policies before arriving at 11.5. Suggestions for further research
the final plan.
2. It is possible to apply urban modelling approaches With regard to the perpetual debate on compact vs.
prevalent in the developed world, rooted in the spatial dispersed city form, it was seen in the previous section
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 195

Fig. 45. Snapshot summary of key assessment indicators.

that neither of these urban forms offers an outright addition, by dispersing employment for Ahmedabad, it
adoptable urban policy to pursue. This author is was learnt that indeed work trip distances do reduce (see
therefore led to believe that the intricacies of how Table 18). However, more case studies need to be
cities work and sustain themselves successfully are conducted in developing countries to explore the
more to do with economic factors, rather than just performance of different physical forms and transport
physical factors such as the city form and transport networks when combined with economic factors (such
network geometry. Many scholars appear to be critical as the generalised cost of location and travel, and the
of the tacit assumption that high density promotes lower cost of employing people (not addressed in this study)).
energy use or that low-density, dispersed settlements In recent times, the view that IT-based communica-
have a negative effect on the environment. It is clear that tion technology (such as the internet, mobile wi-fi,
a deeper understanding of the way people locate and videoconferencing, etc.) has an impact on travel
travel is the key to solving the energy use problem. In behaviour, is gathering research momentum. It is not
196 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

clear that a strong connection exists, but nonetheless it ing the strength of this relationship needs to be
is worth exploring in developing countries like India, undertaken. Also, given the fact that developing
where the IT sector has been booming for the last countries have a higher level of non-motorised travel,
decade or so. In this study, this connection was not it would be interesting to compare with developed
addressed, due to lack of data on such activities. countries its implication on physical activity, in addition
However, the next Census is round the corner (i.e., to the differences in the pace of growth, economic and
2011) and with the possibility of supplementing data socio-cultural factors.
gathering on employment activities with sample Suggestions for specific further work in the context
surveys, this aspect can be included in urban modelling. of Ahmedabad that crop up from the various limitations
Another debate gathering momentum in recent times outlined in the study are summarised as follows. It is
is the connection between the built environment and likely that these could apply to other Indian cities, and
health, both in terms of air quality and physical activity. cities in other developing countries.
Handy, Boarnet, Ewing, and Killingsworth (2002)
conclude that the available evidence lends itself to 1. City-region analysis of economic activity needs to be
the argument that a combination of urban design, land undertaken, in order to initiate the modelling of
use patterns and transportation systems that promotes employment location, with the possibility of inte-
walking and bicycling will help create active, healthier grating modelling techniques from new economic
and more liveable communities. However, they indicate geography (usually associated with Paul Krugman,
that collaborative research efforts that build on the Anthony Venables, Masahisa Fujita, Jacques-
research paradigms of the fields of both urban planning Francois Thisse, amongst others; see Mikkelsen,
and public health are essential to making further 2004, and Lafourcade & Thisse, 2008). If employ-
progress in the effort to build healthier and more ment is output from the model by SEG then it could
liveable communities. On similar lines, Frumkin be used in making more detailed land use regulations
(2002), while investigating the relationship between pertaining to commercial use. In addition, the SEG
sprawl and health, concludes that data show both health mix of jobs in each zone could be used to calculate a
benefits and costs. Frumkin particularly picks up on the measure of vitality, which could be a useful social
unequal distribution of the adverse health effects of indicator.
sprawl. Frank (2000) concludes that although there are 2. If employment location is not modelled, then sample
studies that show the existence of a relationship surveys need to be undertaken at zone level to
between the built environment and physical activity ascertain employment mix by SEG to create more
and health, their findings have been refuted, based on accurate inputs and enhanced economic outputs.
methodological grounds and inaccurate interpretation 3. The distinction between basic and service (local)
of data. Frank, Engelke, Schmid, and Killingsworth sector employment (as is usually done in Lowry-type
(n.d.) carried out an extensive literature review on the models, see Section 4.4.2) was not possible in this
relationship between physical activity and the built study, owing to the lack of data availability on the
form. They concluded that in the American context, proportion of employment strictly due to local
empirical research supports the claim that important population. On the other hand, in recent years, this
relationships exist between urban form and travel author has witnessed a new, emerging phenomenon
behaviour. However, the general dearth of good in Ahmedabad, of people doing local shopping in
empirical literature on the effects of these variables places much further away from their residences
on physical activity patterns is problematic. Part of the (though not supported by quantitative evidence)
problem lies in the inherent complexity involved in dubbed mall culture by the local media. The prime
adequately measuring many of the urban form and reason for this is the rapid springing up of shopping
demographic variables and in disentangling the cause- malls all over the city in the last eight years or so. The
and-effect relationships between them. Findings based propensity of citizens to shop in malls could be
on a more recent study (Frank, Saelens, Powell, & attributed to products being available more cheaply
Chapman, 2007) that used 2000 samples in neighbour- than at the local grocers, and the ability of malls to
hoods in the metropolitan region of Atlanta, USA, combine entertainment with shopping in the form of
suggest that creating walkable environments may result cine-multiplexes, cafes, game arcades, etc. It is very
in higher levels of physical activity. likely that this phenomenon exists in other cities of
It is clear from the above discussion that further India and the world. A similar pattern of non-local
research on fine-tuning the methodology for ascertain- access exists in Ahmedabad with private schools
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 197

Fig. 46. Chakdaa ride-shared para-transit mode.

(traditionally, the employees of which are treated as 6. Surveys to establish the relationship between average
serving the local population). Therefore, studies need vehicular speeds and emissions in the Indian context
to be undertaken to establish the proportion of service (wherein both vehicular and road conditions are very
employment strictly servicing the local population likely to be different from other countries) need to be
and its trend in the future to better inform the undertaken. Using such a relationship, accurate
modelling process. estimates of the impact of vehicular emissions can
4. Sample surveys to ascertain modal split by SEG and be made (see Section 9.2.2), which also ties in with
by trip purpose need to be undertaken, in order to the following point.
directly apply modal split by SEG to journey-to-work 7. Local authorities should develop a road network at
trips by resident workers rather than at an aggregated least of the main roads of the city in a GIS environment
level, to correct the discrepancy between value of to enable network modelling. This would enable
time (VOT) from the modal split model and appropriate land usetransport feedback, making the
residential location model. In addition, this would modelling outputs more realistic (see Section 7.2). In
also improve the estimation of change in transport addition, this creates a feedback loop that is useful in
consumer surplus (see note below Table 23). modelling network congestion, making transport
5. Para-transit modes (usually ride-shares for work trips outputs more realistic and enabling more accurate
used by low-income people, like the one shown in estimation of CO2 emissions (see Section 9.2.2).
Fig. 46) are not considered. However, based on this 8. Economic studies investigating the price elasticity of
authors local knowledge, this mode is increasing in housing supply need to be undertaken to improve the
preference for work trips within and between estimation of producer surplus (see Section 9.1.2).
peripheral areas of Ahmedabad, owing to lower 9. Economic studies looking at the role of agricultural
restrictions imposed by authorities with regard to land in city-regions, and its significance in the light of
operation, and low frequency or no bus routes. rapidly globalising food markets, need to be carried
Therefore, such modes in the future need to be out in developing countries to better inform the
incorporated into the model, supported by adequate debate on conversion of agricultural land to urban
sample surveys on its usage. Researching motorisa- uses (see Section 9.6).
tion in developing countries, Kutzbach (2009)
suggests that it is important to include all available Given that Ahmedabad has well-reputed academic
modes in modelling. institutions for architecture and planning and manage-
198 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

ment studies most of the further research suggestions disaggregated data become available, to make it a more
discussed above could be carried out by post-graduate powerful tool to aid their decision-making capabilities
students as part of their masters/doctoral dissertation, over the years.
in close collaboration with the Ahmedabad Urban Overall, the simplicity of operating and updating
Development Authority and the Ahmedabad Municipal SIMPLAN and its low resource intensiveness (in terms
Corporation. of both time and money), allowing the testing of several
planning alternatives, make this approach, in the Indian
11.6. A final note context, innovative in its own right. The proposed
approach goes beyond the conventional realm, by using
This research study set out to explore how a more simple yet robust tools, developed with appropriate
scientific and transparent approach could be introduced consideration to both data and resource constraints
to enhance planning in the context of developing posed by the local context. However, in the realm of
countries, where data constraints pose significant applied research, this study is not an end in itself, owing
challenges. Based on the census data and past studies to the limitations outlined above (see Table 36). Rather,
commissioned by the government of Gujarat, a it represents a first step in trying to bring a more
simplified modelling suite called SIMPLAN was scientific temperament and transparency to planning in
developed. A spreadsheet environment was used to developing countries, by introducing a model-based
develop the model to provide visually driven user- approach. A study attempting to link land use and
interface, making it simpler to understand, operate and transportation, based on the case study of Delhi, India
update the model. (Srinivasan, 2005) reaches a similar conclusion,
SIMPLAN was used to test and assess alternative suggesting that the idea of a data-based land use and
urban planning policies for year 2021 and it was transportation plan, instead of one based on ideology
demonstrated how to use the model outputs to enhance alone, must be incorporated into the planning process.
the plan-making process. In addition, the modelling This study could serve as a useful precedent to
outputs allowed us to inform the wider debate on researchers working on developing countries for
compact vs. dispersed urban forms. It was shown that, in furthering contributions to both the theory and the
the context of the case study city of Ahmedabad, neither practice of urban planning.
policy provides an outright winwin solution. This
study demonstrates that each city has to test out the pros
Acknowledgements
and cons of such policy alternatives for themselves
before forming macro-level plans for the future.
The author wishes to acknowledge the advice of
A series of presentations and meetings was held in
Professor Marcial Echenique and Dr Ying Jin, Depart-
August 2008 in Ahmedabad with government decision
ment of Architecture, University of Cambridge.
makers and planners, and planning professionals, in
Gratitude is expressed to Cambridge Commonwealth
order to obtain feedback on the proposed approach.
Trust, Hinduja Cambridge Trust, Churchill College, and
Overall, it was acknowledged by the decision makers
Kettles Yard Travel Fund for part funding support. All
and government planners that such an analytical
tables and figures are created by the author unless
approach should indeed form the basis of all planning
mentioned otherwise. The views expressed in this paper
exercises, and therefore is greatly welcomed. Practi-
are solely those of this author.
tioners were of the opinion that it is imperative for urban
local government authorities to impart more analytical
rigour and a transparent approach in making city plans. Appendix A. Employment inputs2001 and
In that, they could start with such a simplified urban 2021
simulation model, and once they have adopted it, they
can then enhance and update the model, as more See Table A1
Table A1
Employment inputs2001 and 2021.
Zone Zone name PTQS Base Trend 2021 Trend Compaction and dispersal Compaction Dispersal
2001 (LBGC, 2001) policy 2021 policies (with same employment) with with
not useda different different
employment employment
BS01 TR21; DS21 CC21 CC CC CC DS DS DS CC 92-08 DS 22-78
80-20 90-10 100-0 20-80 10-90 0-100
1 Walled city 4 5 6 211,805 272,829 296,477 296,477 313,478 236,965
2 Vasna-Paldi 4 5 6 49,169 52,344 65,109 65,109 72,842 54,900

B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207


3 Navrangpura-Gandhigram 3 4 5 129,851 133,660 162,515 162,515 181,924 141,871
4 Naranpura-Vadaj-Sabarmati 3 4 5 92,779 98,684 117,185 117,185 129,841 101,556
5 Dudheshwar-Madhupura- 2 3 4 75,891 79,592 90,806 90,806 100,225 81,339
Girdharnagar
6 Saraspur-Asarwa 2 3 4 124,326 131,074 149,112 149,112 164,342 133,374
7 Naroda-Sardarnagar 4 5 6 66,315 71,861 88,202 88,202 98,304 74,310
8 Bapunagar-Rakhial- 3 4 5 209,700 219,251 263,422 263,422 293,910 229,883
KokhraMehmdabad
9 Nikol-Odhav 4 5 6 46,597 49,495 61,631 61,631 69,079 52,218
10 Maninagar-Kankaria 4 5 6 93,205 97,321 122,680 122,680 137,890 104,234
11 Vatva-Badodara 2 3 4 100,730 108,845 121,743 121,743 133,162 108,070
12 Cantonment 2 3 4 13,862 15,794 15,774 15,774 15,775 15,298
13 Bhat-Chiloda-Nabhoi 1 2 3 7,532 16,471 11,562 11,562 8,380 15,160
14 Kathwada-Muthiya 1 2 3 6,480 16,008 10,588 10,588 7,209 13,042
15 Singarva-Vastral-Ramol 1 2 3 13,894 35,649 23,165 23,165 15,457 27,963
16 Aslali-Lambha-Piplaj 2 3 4 10,523 26,136 17,876 17,876 12,097 26,687
17 Sharkej-Gyaspur-Okaf 3 4 5 15,086 42,224 28,195 28,195 17,904 46,157
18 Thaltej-Vastrapur-Vejalpur- 2 3 4 78,538 182,128 129,192 129,192 90,270 198,543
Makarba-Ambli-Shilaj
19 Sola-Gota-Chandlodia- 2 3 4 57,702 165,071 106,304 106,304 66,874 147,086
Ghatlodia-Ranip
20 Adalaj-Chandkheda- 1 2 3 26,534 75,550 46,849 46,849 29,518 53,401
Kali-Motera-
Zundal-Khoraj
21 Gandhinagar City 2 3 4 69,548 148,444 110,047 110,047 79,954 176,378
Total 1,500,068 2,038,434 2,038,434 2,038,434 2,038,434 2,038,434
Key: PTQS = Public transport quality score; BS01 = Base 2001.
a
Not used for inputs but is shown just for comparison.

199
200
Table B1
Dwelling inputs2001 and 2021.
Zone Zone name Base (total Dwelling increments 20012021
dwellings)
Trend policy Compaction variations (with same Dispersal variations Compaction with Dispersal with
employment) (with same employment) different different
employment employment
CC80-20 CC90-10 CC100-0 DS20-80 DS10-90 DS0-100 CC92-08 DS22-78
1 Walled city 68,140 3,192 10,871 15,288 10,000 1,000 1,000 0 10,000 2,000
2 Vasna-Paldi 37,262 18,205 20,773 22,250 24,211 3,042 1,498 0 22,889 3,486

B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207


3 Navrangpura-Gandhigram 25,947 7,979 14,755 18,653 23,828 9,698 4,777 0 20,347 5,000
4 Naranpura-Vadaj-Sabarmati 75,977 32,876 38,261 41,359 45,471 7,503 3,696 0 42,616 8,823
5 Dudheshwar-Madhupura- 36,944 3,482 4,770 5,511 6,495 1,846 909 0 5,803 2,243
Girdharnagar
6 Saraspur-Asarwa 108,414 12,809 15,889 17,662 20,014 3,828 1,885 0 18,351 4,646
7 Naroda-Sardarnagar 37,962 22,162 27,507 30,581 34,662 5,674 2,795 0 31,885 6,486
8 Bapunagar-Rakhial- 103,567 11,682 18,898 23,049 28,559 7,112 3,503 0 24,824 8,421
KokhraMehmdabad
9 Nikol-Odhav 45,909 8,585 9,592 10,172 10,941 962 474 0 10,428 1,106
10 Maninagar-Kankaria 64,149 27,559 33,979 37,673 42,576 6,709 3,305 0 39,339 7,734
11 Vatva-Badodara 74,139 64,715 77,151 84,305 93,801 20,738 10,214 0 86,920 24,977
12 Cantonment 2,840 1,085 100 100 0 1,000 1,000 1,000 78 1,000
13 Bhat-Chiloda-Nabhoi 2,096 1,567 746 365 0 5,000 5,000 5,000 308 5,000
14 Kathwada-Muthiya 10,909 5,314 605 292 0 10,000 10,000 10,000 235 10,000
15 Singarva-Vastral-Ramol 17,379 6,301 1,180 584 0 12,000 12,000 12,000 449 12,000
16 Aslali-Lambha-Piplaj 8,943 8,726 2,328 1,161 0 15,000 15,000 15,000 898 15,000
17 Sharkej-Gyaspur-Okaf 9,188 6,835 3,297 1,646 0 12,000 12,000 12,000 1,193 12,000
18 Thaltej-Vastrapur-Vejalpur- 56,314 33,004 20,108 10,048 0 111,579 126,209 140,839 7,996 113,939
Makarba-Ambli-Shilaj
19 Sola-Gota-Chandlodia- 58,833 9,128 3,185 1,590 0 25,464 31,124 36,783 1,140 22,434
Ghatlodia-Ranip
20 Adalaj-Chandkheda- 27,221 15,954 5,083 2,539 0 27,689 33,485 39,280 1,825 17,863
Kali-Motera-Zundal-Khoraj
21 Gandhinagar City 94,187 39,398 31,481 15,732 0 52,714 60,685 68,656 13,033 56,399
Total 966,323 340,558 340,558 340,558 340,558 340,558 340,558 340,558 340,558 340,558
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 201

Appendix B. Dwelling inputs2001 and 2021 performance of a city. The argument is that the spatial
structure of a city can be defined by two complementary
See Table B1 components: (a) the distribution of population over
space; and (b) the pattern of trips made by people from
Appendix C. Transport inputs2001 and 2021 their residences to any other destination. Bertaud (2001)
maintains that the pattern of trips could be encapsulated
C.1. Private automobile (PA) speeds in the average distance per person to the centre. This is a
weighted average using the population of each ward as
the weight. Bertaud (2001) argues that, everything else
C.2. Public transport speeds being equal, in a city with a small built-up area the
distance per person to the centre will be shorter than in a
C.3. Slow mode speeds (bicycling and walking) city with a larger built-up area. Therefore, in order to
have a comparative measure of shape between cities, it
C.4. Vehicle operating and maintenance costs is necessary to have a measure independent of the area
calculations and assumptions of the city. This could be achieved by taking the ratio of
the average distance per person to the centre and the
average distance per person to the centre of a circle
C.5. Public transport (bus) fares whose area would be equal to the built-up area. Such a
measure, called the dispersion index r, can be
Appendix D. Spatial change indicators mathematically expressed as:
P P
Indicators to measure the change in the spatial n d i wi di wi
r p or r n (A1)
structure using population data by SIMPLAN zones, are 2=3 A=p 2=3r
described below.
where di is the distance of the centroid of the ith tract (or
D.1. Dispersion index ward or zone) from the CBD, weighted by the tracts
share of population wi; A is the built-up area of the city;
Alan Bertaud (Bertaud, 2001; Bertaud & Malpezzi, r is the radius of a circle with area A; n is the total
2003) proposed a measure to describe the shape number of tracts.
Table C1
Private automobile (PA) speeds (base values in km/h and alternative policies in % change over base).
Zone Zone name Base 2001a TR21 (%) CC21 (%) DS21 (%)
1 Walled city 10.0 10.0 15.0 2.5
2 Vasna-Paldi 15.5 5.0 10.0 10.0
3 Navrangpura-Gandhigram 15.5 5.0 10.0 10.0
4 Naranpura-Vadaj-Sabarmati 15.5 5.0 10.0 10.0
5 Dudheshwar-Madhupura-Girdharnagar 12.0 5.0 10.0 10.0
6 Saraspur-Asarwa 12.0 5.0 10.0 10.0
7 Naroda-Sardarnagar 12.0 5.0 10.0 10.0
8 Bapunagar-Rakhial-KokhraMehmdabad 12.0 5.0 10.0 10.0
9 Nikol-Odhav 12.0 5.0 10.0 10.0
10 Maninagar-Kankaria 12.0 5.0 10.0 10.0
11 Vatva-Badodara 12.0 5.0 10.0 10.0
12 Cantonment 15.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
13 Bhat-Chiloda-Nabhoi 18.0 2.5 0.0 25.0
14 Kathwada-Muthiya 18.0 2.5 0.0 25.0
15 Singarva-Vastral-Ramol 18.0 2.5 0.0 25.0
16 Aslali-Lambha-Piplaj 18.0 2.5 0.0 25.0
17 Sharkej-Gyaspur-Okaf 18.0 2.5 0.0 25.0
18 Thaltej-Vastrapur-Vejalpur-Makarba-Ambli-Shilaj 18.0 2.5 0.0 25.0
19 Sola-Gota-Chandlodia-Ghatlodia-Ranip 18.0 2.5 0.0 25.0
20 Adalaj-Chandkheda-Kali-Motera-Zundal-Khoraj 18.0 2.5 0.0 25.0
21 Gandhinagar City 20.0 2.5 0.0 10.0
a
Based on CEPT (2006) and Adhvaryu (1995).
202 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Table C2
Public transport speeds.
Base year 2001 Horizon year 2021
Code Base Code TR21 (%) CC21 (%) DS21 (%)
1 = Good PT 85% of PA 1 = Exclusive BRTS 20 50 20
2 = Moderate PT 80% of PA 2 = Normal BRTS 10 35 10
3 = Poor PT 75% of PA 3 = Ordinary bus 5 15 5
Notes: [1] Each zone is assigned a code and accordingly the speeds are calculated. [2] For year 2021, percentage change over base is applied as
shown.

Table C3
Slow mode speeds (bicycling and walking).
Base year 2001 Horizon year 2021
Code Base Code TR21 (%) CC21 (%) DS21 (%)
1 = Walled city 85% of PA 1 = Walled city 10.0 7.5 5.0
2 = AMC 60% of PA 2 = AMC 5.0 2.5 2.5
3 = AUC-AMC 50% of PA 3 = AUC-AMC 2.5 0.0 5.0
Notes: [1] Each zone is assigned a code and accordingly the speeds ares calculated. [2] For year 2021, percentage change over base is applied as
shown.

The numerator (i.e., the actual distance) in distance) is the average distance to the centre
Eq. (A1) is the average distance per person to of a circle (or cylinder with unit height) of
the centre (CBD or the geometric centre, as the equivalent area and uniform population density (see
case may be) and the denominator (i.e., the theoretical Fig. D1).

Table C4
Vehicle operating and maintenance costs calculations and assumptions.
Item Unit 2001 % Increase assumed Period 2021
2W Car Bicycle 2W Car Bicycle
Life years 7 12 5 10 20 years 8 13 6
Average km driven in km 60,000 100,000 10,000 10 20 years 66,000 110,000 11,000
vehicle life
Capital cost Rs 20,000 275,000 600 6 pa 64,143 881,962 1,924
Salvage value a Rs 7,519 51,399 298 6 pa 24,114 164,845 957
[a] Capital cost/km Rs/km 0.21 2.24 0.03 0.61 6.52 0.09
Maintenance Rs/year 500 1,000 100 6 pa 1,604 3,207 321
and repairs
[b] Unit maintenance Rs/km 0.06 0.12 0.05 0.19 0.38 0.16
cost
Mileage km/l 30 10 0 15 20 years 35 15 0
Fuel cost Rs/l 31 31 0 6 pa 98 98 0
[c] Unit fuel cost Rs/km 1.02 3.06 0 2.84 6.54 0
Final unit cost Rs/km 1.29 5.42 0.08 3.64 13.45 0.25
[a + b + c]
% Share 86 14 80 20
Average unit cost Rs/km 1.86 0.08 5.64 0.25
(weighted)
Average unit cost Rs/km 1.86 0.08 2.13 0.09
(2001 prices)
a
Vehicle depreciation per year is assumed to be 15%.
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 203

Table C5
Public transport (bus) fares (2001 prices).
Distance (km) Fare (Rs) Distance (km) Fare (Rs) Distance (km) Fare (Rs) Distance (km) Fare (Rs)
02 1 1012 7 2022 9 3032 11
24 3 1214 7 2224 10 3234 12
46 4 1416 8 2426 10 3436 12
68 5 1618 8 2628 11 3638 12
810 6 1820 9 2830 11 3840 13

Fig. D1. Calculation of dispersion index.

D.2. H-indicator (concentration/de-concentration under question and the start year of analysis. If H > 0
measure) then dispersion is likely to occur, and for H < 0,
concentration effects may dominate.
Inspired by physics, the H indicator (SCATTER,
2005) in discrete terms, i.e., if the area under study is
References
divided into n zones is defined as:
X X Abelson, P. (2000). Economic and environmental sustainability in
2
H i
ri ri A i or H P r2
i i i
(A2) Shanghai. In C. Pugh (Ed.), Sustainable cities in developing
countries. London, UK: Earsthscan.
where Pi is the population of the ith zone; Ai is the area Adhvaryu, B. (1995). Busway transit for Ahmedabad. Unpublished
MTech dissertation, School of Planning, CEPT University, Ahme-
of the ith zone; ri is the population density of the ith
dabad, India.
zone (i.e., Pi =Ai ); ri is the straight-line distance of Adhvaryu, B. (2009). Enhancing planning in developing countries:
centroid of the ith zone from the centroid of the Urban modelling for Ahmedabad, India. Unpublished PhD dis-
CBD (or centroid of the study area). sertation, University of Cambridge, UK.
By definition, if H is increasing over time, then it can Alonso, W. (1964). Location and land use: Towards a general theory
be concluded that the city is dispersing and vice versa. of land rent. Cambridge, MA, USA: Harvard University Press.
Alonso, W. (1968). Urban and regional imbalances in economic
Further to this, a relative concentration measure Hrel is development. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 17,
introduced to assess how outer areas are changing in 114.
relation toPcentral areas. Hrel is calculated by using AMC (Ahmedabad Municipal Corporation) (2007). Statistical outline
Pi =1=n i Pi instead of Pi in Eq. (A2). Thus, if Hrel of Ahmedabad City 200607. Available at http://www.egovamc.-
is increasing over time, it indicates that the outer urban com/amc_budget/Outline%202006-07.pdf. Accessed 9 December
2009.
ring is growing faster in relative terms than the urban AMC (Ahmedabad Municipal Corporation) (2009). Investing in solu-
rel
centre. Lastly, H (or H ) can be calculated as the tions that address climate change and energy security, Ahmeda-
percentage difference between H (or Hrel) for the year bad, Gujarat, India. Presented at Coimbatore, international
204 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

workshop on improved urban environment on 13 March 2009. Cambridge Futures. (1999). Cambridge futures. Cambridge Univer-
Available online at www.iclei.org. sity Press: Cambridge, UK.
Anas, A., Arnott, R., & Small, K. A. (1998). Urban spatial structures. Carter, H. (1995). The study of urban geography (4th ed.). London,
Journal of Economic Literature, 36, 14261464. UK: Arnold.
AUDA (Ahmedabad Urban Development Authority) (1988). Draft Census (of India). (1991). General population tables, part II-A(i).
development plan of AUDA 1991 (Part-I and Part-II). Ahmedabad: New Delhi, India: Office of the Registrar General and Census
Ahmedabad Urban Development Authority. Commissioner.
AUDA (Ahmedabad Urban Development Authority) (1997). Revised Census (of India) (2001a). Primary census abstract for Gujarat,
draft development plan of AUDA 2011 AD, Part-I, Volume 2: Daman & Diu, and Dadra & Nagar Haveli: Census of India
Surveys, studies and analysis. Ahmedabad, India: Ahmedabad 2001 (CD-ROM). New Delhi, India: Office of the Registrar
Urban Development Authority. General and Census Commissioner.
Ballaney, S. (2008). Town planning mechanism in Gujarat, India. Census (of India) (2001b). Table 1, Series A. New Delhi, India: Office
Washington, DC: The World Bank. of the Registrar General and Census Commissioner.
Banister, D. (2005). Unsustainable transport: City transport in the Census (of India) (2001c). Table 30. New Delhi, India: Office of the
new century. Abingdon, UK: Routledge. Registrar General and Census Commissioner.
Beier, G. J. (1976). Can the Third World cities cope? In P. K. Ghosh CEPT (Centre for Environmental Planning and Technology Univer-
(Ed.), (1984). Urban development in the Third World. Westport, sity) (2006). Bus Rapid Transit System (BRTS), Ahmedabad (Final
CT: Greenwood Press. Report). Retrieved from http://www.egovamc.com/BRTS/
Bertaud, A. (1996). Ahmedabad: Land issues & recommendations. BRTS.ASP. Accessed 9 December 2009.
Retrieved from http://alain-bertaud.com/images/AB_Ahmed_Re- Chadwick, G. (1971). A systems view of planning: Towards a theory of
port.pdf. Accessed 9 December 2009. the urban and regional planning process. Oxford, UK: Pergamon.
Bertaud, A. (2001). Metropolis: A measure of the spatial organization Chapin, F. S., Jr. (1965). Urban land use planning (2nd ed.). Urbana,
of 7 large cities. Retrieved from http://alain-bertaud.com/images/ IL: University of Illinois Press.
AB_Metropolis_Spatial_Organization.pdf. Accessed 9 December Chatterjee, L. (1983). Urban and regional policy issues in developing
2009. countries: An introduction. In L. Chatterjee & P. Nijkamp (Eds.),
Bertaud, A., & Malpezzi, S. (2003). The spatial distribution of Urban and regional policy analysis in developing countries.
population in 48 world cities: Implications for economies in Aldershot, UK: Gower.
transition. Retrieved from http://alain-bertaud.com/AB_Files/ Chatterjee, L., & Nijkamp, P. (1983). Urban and regional policy
Spatia_%20Distribution_of_Pop_%2050_%20Cities.pdf. design in developing countries. In L. Chatterjee & P. Nijkamp
Accessed 9 December 2009. (Eds.), Urban and regional policy analysis in developing coun-
Bhajracharya, A. R. (2008). The impact of modal shift on the transport tries. Aldershot, UK: Gower.
ecological footprint: A case study of the proposed Bus Rapid Christaller, W. (1933). Die Zentralen Orte in Suddeutschland, Jena.
Transit System in Ahmedabad, India. Unpublished MSc disserta- English translation by C. W. Baskin (1966). Central places in
tion, Enschede, The Netherlands: ITC. Southern Germany. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
Breheny, M. J., & Foot, D. H. S. (1986). In place of models? Assessing Clark, C. (1951). Urban population densities. Journal of the Royal
the urbanisation effects of Londons proposed third airport. In B. Statistical Society, 114, 490496.
Hutchinson & M. Batty (Eds.), Advances in urban systems mod- Cohen, M. A. (1976). Cities in developing countries: 19752000. In P.
elling. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier. K. Ghosh (Ed.), (1984). Urban development in the Third World.
Brownstone, D., & Golob, T. F. (2009). The impact of residential Westport, CT: Greenwood Press.
density on vehicle usage and energy consumption. Journal of de la Barra, T. (1989). Integrated land use and transport modelling:
Urban Economics, 65, 9198. Decision chain and hierarchies. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
Brueckner, J. K. (2000). Urban sprawl: Diagnosis and University Press.
remedies. International Regional Science Review, 23(2), 160 DfT (2003). The wider economic impacts sub-objective. Transport
171. analysis guidance unit 3.5.8. London, UK: Department for Trans-
Brueckner, J. K., & Largey, A. G. (2008). Social interaction and urban port. Retrieved from http://www.webtag.org.uk/webdocuments/
sprawl. Journal of Urban Economics, 64, 1834. 3_Expert/5_Economy_Objective/3.5.8.pdf. Accessed 9 December
Burchell, R. W., Lowenstein, G., Dolphin, W. R., Galley, C. C., 2009.
Downs, A., Seskin, S., Still, K. G., & Moore, T. (2002). Costs DfT (2004). Measuring accessibility for the appraisal of wider
of sprawl2000. TCRP Report 74, Transport Research Board, economic benefits. Transport analysis guidance unit 3.5.11. Lon-
National Research Council. Washington, DC: National Academy don, UK: Department for Transport. Retrieved from http://
Press. www.webtag.org.uk/webdocuments/3_Expert/5_Economy_Ob-
Burgess, E. W. (1925). The growth of a city: An introduction to a jective/3.5.11.pdf. Accessed 9 December 2009.
research project. In R. E. Park, E. W. Burgess, & R. D. McKenzie DfT. (2005). Land-use/transport interaction models. Transport anal-
(Eds.), The city: Suggestion for investigation of human behaviour ysis guidance unit 3.1.3. London, UK: Department for Transport.
in the urban environment. Chicago, IL, USA: University of Retrieved from http://www.webtag.org.uk/webdocuments/
Chicago Press. 3_Expert/1_Modelling/3.1.3.htm. Accessed 9 December 2009.
Burton, E. (2000). The compact city: Just or just compact? A pre- DMRC (Delhi Metro Rail Corporation) (2004). Ahmedabad metro &
liminary analysis. Urban Studies, 37(11), 19692001. regional rail system (Phase-1). Detailed project report. Prepared
Byahut, S., & Parikh, D. (2006). Integrated disaster mitigation in for Gujarat Industrial Development Board (GIDB), Gandhinagar.
urban planning practices in India. Final report of the ProVention Domencich, T. A., & McFadden, D. (1975). Urban travel demand: A
Consortium. Environmental Planning Collaborative, Ahmedabad, behavioural analysis. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Hol-
India. land Publishing.
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 205

Echenique,M. (1972). Models: A discussion. In L. Martin& L. March Gordon, P., Kumar, Aj. , & Richardson, H. W. (1989). The influence of
(Eds.), (1972). Urban space and structures. Cambridge, UK: metropolitan spatial structure on commuting time. Journal of
Cambridge University Press. Urban Economics, 26(2), 138151.
Echenique, M. (1983). The use of planning models in developing Gurumukhi, K. T. (n.d.). Land pooling technique: A tool for plan
countries: Some case studies. In L. Chatterjee & P. Nijkamp implementationan Indian experience. Retrieved from http://
(Eds.), Urban and regional policy analysis in developing coun- www.gisdevelopment.net/application/urban/products/
tries. Aldershot, UK: Gower. mi03215pf.htm. Accessed 9 December 2009.
Echenique, M. (1986). The practice of modelling in developing Handy, S. L., Boarnet, M. G., Ewing, R., & Killingsworth, R. E.
countries. In B. Hutchinson & M. Batty (Eds.), Advances in urban (2002). How the built environment affects physical activity: Views
systems modelling. Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier. from urban planning. American Journal of Preventive Medicine,
Echenique, M. (2004). Econometric models of land use and transport. 23(2S), 6473.
In D. A. Hensher, K. J. Button, K. E. Haynes, & P. R. Stopher Hansen, W. G. (1959). How accessibility shapes land use. Journal of
(Eds.), Handbook of transport geography and spatial systems. the American Planning Association, 25(2), 7376.
Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier. Harris, B. (2001). Accessibility: Concepts and applications. Journal of
Echenique, M., & de la Barra, T. (1976). Compact land use/transport Transportation and Statistics, 4(23), 1530.
models. In P. W. Bonsall, Q. M. Dalvi, & P. J. Hills (Eds.), Urban Harris, C. D., & Ullman, E. L. (1945). The nature of cities. Annals of
transport planning: Current themes and future prospects. Tun- the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 242, 7
bridge Wells, UK: Abacus Press. 17.
Echenique, M., Jin, Y., Burgas, J., & Gil, A. (1994). An integrated Harvey, J. (1996). Urban land economics (4th ed). Basingstoke, UK:
land-use/transport strategy for the development of the central Macmillan.
region of Chile. Traffic Engineering and Control, 35(9), 491497. Healey, P. (2007). Urban complexity and spatial strategies: Towards a
Echenique, M. H. (1994). Urban and regional studies at the Martin relational planning for our times. Abingdon, UK: Routledge.
Centre: Its origins, its present, its future. Environment and Plan- Herbert, J. D. (1979). Urban development in the Third World: Policy
ning B: Planning and Design, 21(5), 517533. guidelines. New York: Praeger Publishers.
Echenique, M. H., Flowerdew, A. D. J., Hunt, J. D., Mayo, T. R., Hickman, R., Saxena, S., & Banister, D. (2008). Breaking the trend:
Skidmore, I. J., & Simmonds, D. C. (1990). The MEPLAN models Visioning and backcasting for transport in India & Delhi (VIBAT
of Bilbao, Leeds and Dortmund. Transport Reviews, 10(4), 309 India & Delhi). Scoping report (Final draft). http://www.adb.org/
322. Documents/Produced-Under-TA/39578/39578-REG-DPTA.pdf.
Frank, L. D. (2000). Land use and transportation interaction: Implica- Accessed 10 September 2008.
tions on public health and quality of life. Journal of Planning Ihlanfeldt, K. (1992). The spatial mismatch between jobs and resi-
Education and Research, 20, 622. dential locations within urban areas. Cityscape: Journal of Policy
Frank, L. D., Saelens, B. E., Powell, K. E., & Chapman, J. E. (2007). Development and Research, 1, 219244.
Stepping towards causation: Do built environments or neighbor- Ingram, D. R. (1971). The concept of accessibility: A search for an
hood and travel patterns explain physical activity, driving, and operational form. Regional Studies, 5(2), 101107.
obesity? Social Science and Medicine, 65, 18981914. Jacquemin, A. R. A. (1999). Urban development and new towns in the
Frank, L. D., Engelke, P., Schmid, T. L., & Killingsworth, R. E. (n.d.). Third World: Lessons from the New Bombay experience. Alder-
How land use and transportation systems impact public health: A shot, UK: Ashgate.
literature review of the relationship between physical activity and Kahn, M. E. (2006). The quality of life in sprawled versus compact
built form. ACES: Active Community Environments Initiative cities. Paper prepared for the OECD/ECMT Regional Round Table
Working Paper #1. 137, Berkeley, CA, 2728 March 2006.
Frumkin, H. (2002). Urban sprawl and public health. Public Health Kain, J. F. (1992). The spatial mismatch hypothesis: Three decades
Reports, 117, 201217. later. Housing Policy Debate, 3, 371392.
Geurs, K.T., & van Eck, J. R. R. (2001). Accessibility measures: Katz, M. L., & Rosen, H. S. (2005). Microeconomics (3rd ed). Boston,
Review and applications. RIVM report 408505 006. The Nether- MA: McGraw-Hill.
lands: National Institute of Public Health and the Environment. Krugman, P., & Wells, R. (2005). Microeconomics. New York: Worth.
Retrieved from http://www.rivm.nl/bibliotheek/rapporten/ Kutzbach, M. (2009). Motorization in developing countries: Causes,
408505006.pdf. Accessed 9 December 2009. consequences, and effectiveness of policy options. Journal of
Geurs, K. T., & van Wee, B. (2004). Accessibility evaluation of land- Urban Economics, 65(2), 154166.
use and transport strategies: Review and research directions. Kwok, R. C. W, & Yeh, A. G. O. (2004). The use of modal
Journal of Transport Geography, 12, 127140. accessibility gap as an indicator for sustainable transport devel-
Gilbert, A., & Gugler, J. (1992). Cities, poverty, and development. opment. Environment and Planning A, 36, 921936.
Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. Lafourcade, M., & Thisse, J.-F. (2008). New economic geography: A
Gini, C. (1912). Variabilita e mutabilita. Reprinted in: E. Pizetti, & T. guide to transport analysis. Working Paper 2008-02. Paris School
Salvemini (Eds.), Memorie di metodologica statistica (1955). of Economics. http://www.pse.ens.fr/document/wp200802.pdf.
Rome, Italy: Libreria Eredi Virgilio Veschi. Accessed 9 December 2009.
Gordon, I. (1997). Densities, urban form, and travel behaviour. Town LBGC (Louis Berger Group Consortium) (2001). Feasibility study
and Country Planning, 66, 239241. on integrated public transit system (IPTS) for Ahmedabad.
Gordon, I. (2008). Density and the built environment. Energy Policy, Interim Report, Section-1. Prepared for Gujarat Industrial
36, 46524656. Development Board (GIDB).Gandhinagar: Government of
Gordon, P., & Richardson, H. W. (1989). Gasoline consumption and Gujarat.
cities: A reply. Journal of the American Planning Association, Leontief, W. (1962). Inputoutput economics. New York: Oxford
55(3), 324346. University Press.
206 B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207

Lin, J.-J., & Yang, A.-T. (2006). Does the compact-city paradigm Simmonds, D. C., & Feldman, O. (2007). Advances in integrated
foster sustainability? An empirical study in Taiwan. Environment urban/regional land-use/transport modelling using the DELTA
and Planning B: Planning and Design, 33, 365380. package. http://www.davidsimmonds.com. Accessed 7 December
Lowry, I. S. (1964). A model of metropolis. Santa Monica, CA: The 2007.
Rand Corporation. SOLUTIONS (200408). Sustainability Of Land Use and Transport In
Mackett, R. (2002). Integrated land usetransport models. Lecture Outer NeighbourhoodS project. UK: University of Cambridge.
notes for Unit T5: Transport demand and its modelling. Inter- www.suburbansolutions.ac.uk. Accessed 9 December 2009.
collegiate MSc Transport course, Imperial College London and Srinivasan, S. A. (2005). Linking land use and transportation in a
University College London. rapidly urbanizing context: A study in Delhi, India. Transporta-
Mackett, R. L. (1985). Integrated land use transport models. Transport tion, 32, 87104.
Reviews, 5(4), 325343. Todaro, M. P. (1979). Urbanisation in developing nations: Trends,
Mackett, R. L., & Mountcastle, G. D. (1997). Development of the prospects, and policies. In P. K. Ghosh (Ed.), (1984). Urban
Lowry model. In A. G. Wilson, P. H. Rees, & C. M. Leigh (Eds.), development in the Third World. Westport, CT: Greenwood
Models of cities and regions: Theoretical and empirical develop- Press.
ments. Chichester, UK: John Wiley & Sons. Torrens, P. M. (2000). How land-use transportation models work.
McLoughlin, J. B. (1969). Urban and regional planning: A systems Working Paper 20. Centre for Advanced Spatial Analysis (CASA),
approach. London, UK: Faber & Faber. UCL, London. www.casa.ucl.ac.uk/working_papers/Paper20.pdf.
Mikkelsen, E. I. (2004). New economic geographyan introductory Accessed 16 December 2009.
survey. Tromso, Norway: NORUT Samfunnsforskning AS. United Nations (2005). World population prospects: The 2002 revision
www.nfh.uit.no/dok/norut_notat_eirik_im_-_new_economic_ and world urbanization prospects: The 2003 revision. Population
geography_survey.pdf. Accessed 9 December 2009. Division of the Department of Economic and Social Affairs of the
Modelistica (2006). General description of TRANUS system. http:// United Nations Secretariat. http://esa.un.org/unup. Accessed 9
www.modelistica.com/download.htm. Accessed 10 September December 2009.
2007. United Nations (2006). World population prospects: The 2004 revision
Molai, L., & Vanderschuren, M. J. W. A. (2003). Optimising settle- and world urbanization prospects: The 2005 revision. Population
ment locations: Land-use/transport modelling in Cape Town. Division of the Department of Economic and Social Affairs of the
Paper presented at 22nd annual Southern African transport con- United Nations Secretariat. http://esa.un.org/unup. Accessed 9
ference, Pretoria. http://www.utrg.uct.ac.za/publications/down- December 2009.
loads/molaivander2003.pdf. Accessed 22 October 2006. United Nations (Department of Economic, Social Affairs) (1970).
Newman, P. W. G., & Kenworthy, J. R. (1989a). Cities and automobile Developing a strategy for urbanization. In K. Pradip (Ed.), (1984).
dependence: A source book. Aldershot, UK: Gower. Urban development in the Third World. Westport, CT: Greenwood
Newman, P. W. G., & Kenworthy, J. R. (1989b). Gasoline consump- Press.
tion and cities. Journal of the American Planning Association, US Census Bureau (2001). Population change and distribution: 1990
55(1), 2437. to 2000. http://www.census.gov/prod/2001pubs/c2kbr01-2.pdf.
Newman, P. W. G., & Kenworthy, J. R. (1992). Is there a role for Accessed 9 December 2009.
physical planners? Journal of the American Planning Association, von Thunen, J. H. (1826). In P. Hall (Ed.), Der Isolierte Staat. English
58(3), 353362. translation by C. M. Wartenberg (1966). Von Thunens Isolated
Nijkamp, P., & Voogd, H. (1983). A survey of multicriteria analysis in State. London, UK: Pergamon Press.
development planning. In L. Chatterjee & P. Nijkamp (Eds.), van Wee, B. (2002). Land use and transport: Research and policy
Urban and regional policy analysis in developing countries. challenges. Journal of Transport Geography, 10, 259271.
Aldershot, UK: Gower. Weber, A. (1909). Theory of the location of industries. English
Perloff, J. M. (2004). Microeconomics (3rd ed.). Boston, MA: Pearson translation with introduction and notes by C. J. Friedrich
Addison Wesley. (1929). London, UK: University of Chicago Press.
Potter, R. (1992). Urbanisation in the Third World. Oxford, UK: Webster, C. (2010). Pricing accessibility: Urban morphology, design
Oxford University Press. and missing markets. Progress in Planning, 73, 77111.
Rivkin, M. D. (1976). Land use and the intermediate-size city in Webster, F. V., & Paulley, N. J. (1990). An international study on
developing countries: With case studies of Turkey, Brazil, and land-use and transport interaction. Transport Reviews, 10(4),
Malaysia. New York: Praeger Publishers. 287308.
Samuelson, P. A., & Nordhaus, W. D. (2001). Economics (7th ed.). Williams, I. N. (1994). A model of London and the South East.
New Delhi, India: Tata-McGrawHill. Environment and Planning B: Planning and Design, 21(5), 535
SCATTER (2005). Final report of Sprawling Cities And TransporT: 553.
From Evaluation to Recommendations research project. http:// Wilson, A. G. (1970). Entropy in urban and regional modelling.
www.casa.ucl.ac.uk/scatter/download_final.html. Accessed 10 London, UK: Pion.
September 2006. Wilson, A. G. (1974). Urban and regional models in geography and
Simmonds, D. C. (1999). The design of the DELTA land-use model- planning. London, UK: John Wiley & Sons.
ling package. Environment and Planning B: Planning and Design, World Bank. (2008). World development report 2009: Reshaping
26(5), 665684. economic geography. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

Bhargav Adhvaryu completed his PhD at the Martin Centre for Architectural and Urban Studies, Department of
Architecture, University of Cambridge, UK in May 2009, and was a member of Churchill College. He has about 11
years of experience in teaching, research and consulting. From December 2004 to January 2007, he worked as
B. Adhvaryu / Progress in Planning 73 (2010) 113207 207

Research Associate at the same department. Prior to that, he taught post-graduate planning students at CEPT
University, Ahmedabad, India for three years; undergraduate architecture students at SCET, Surat, India for one year,
and undergraduate civil engineering and post-graduate planning students at SVRCET, Surat for a year. He was also
Project Manager at EPC, Ahmedabad, an urban planning consulting firm, for four years. Dr Adhvaryus additional
qualifications are: MSc Transport & DIC (Imperial College London & University College London, UK); MTech
Planning (CEPT University, Ahmedabad, India); BEng Civil (SVRCET, Surat, South Gujarat University, India), and
DipCEng (Surat, India).

View publication stats

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi