Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 25

Social Exchange and Micro Social Order

Author(s): Edward J. Lawler, Shane R. Thye and Jeongkoo Yoon


Source: American Sociological Review, Vol. 73, No. 4 (Aug., 2008), pp. 519-542
Published by: American Sociological Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/25472543
Accessed: 14-09-2017 16:45 UTC

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms

American Sociological Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and


extend access to American Sociological Review

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Social Exchange and Micro Social Order
Edward J. Lawler Shane R. Thye
Cornell University University of South Carolina

Jeongkoo Yoon
Ewha Woman s University

This study uses an affect theory of social exchange (Lawler 2001) to investigate how and
when network structures generate "micro social orders." Micro social order entails
recurrent interactions, emotional reactions, perceptions of a group, and affective
sentiments. The core theoretical argument is that micro orders, involving behavioral,
cognitive, and affective dimensions, develop and are stronger to the degree that (I)
actors engage in highly joint tasks or activities and (2) these tasks generate a sense of
shared responsibility for the interaction outcomes. A laboratory experiment varies
different forms of social exchange?negotiated, reciprocal, generalized, and productive?
within a network structure, and offers strong support for the core expectation that
productive forms of exchange generate the strongest micro order. Conversely, generalized
exchange generates the weakest order, with negotiated and reciprocal forms in between.
In general, productive exchange bolsters more exchange behavior, more positive feelings,
perceptions of cohesion at the network level, and affective attachments to the network as
a social unit. This research has broad implications for the conditions under which task
activity promotes micro social orders that involve strong person-to-group ties (as
opposed to person-to-person ties) and affective sentiments regarding the social unit.

Turner 1978). When structures promote repeat


It tures
is generally understood
pattern and shape social interactionthat
and social struc ed interactions among the same individuals,
also that social interactions can generate, repro people tend to form enduring relations or group
duce, and sometimes alter social structures (e.g., affiliations (e.g., Emerson 1972a, 1972b;
Emerson 1981; Giddens 1984; Stryker 1980; Homans 1950). If enduring relations or affilia
tions form, the social units that frame or make
possible these relations?small groups, organ
The order of authorship is random and does not
reflect differential contributions. Direct correspon izations, or communities?may become objects
dence to Edward J. Lawler, Department of or realities for actors (Berger and Luckmann
Organizational Behavior, School of Industrial and 1967). It is plausible that people develop ties to
Labor Relations, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY social units, as they interact with each other, and
14853 (ejl3@cornell.edu). This research was sup that these ties are a separable, independent force,
ported by a collaborative National Science distinct from the ties people have to each other
Foundation grant (SBR-9614860) to Cornell (e.g., see Mead 1934; Parsons 1951; Tajfel and
University and the University of South Carolina. An Turner 1986). In this article, we ask how and
earlier version of this article was presented at the 2006 when social exchange processes generate per
Annual Meetings of the American Sociological son-to-unit ties that reflect micro social order.
Association. The authors thank Marty Kuhn for
The affect theory of social exchange (Lawler
designing the computer program and Jenny Craig,
Lisa Dilks, Lena Hipp, Elizabeth Mattern, Tucker
2001) guides our theoretical and empirical
McGrimmon, Jennifer Triplett, and Emily Arnold
analysis.
for help with the experiments. Shelley Correll and The distinction between person-to-person
Frank Flynn provided helpful comments on an ear and person-to-social unit ties has broad-reach
lier draft. ing implications for micro social order.

American Sociological Review, 2008, Vol. 73 (August:519-542)

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
520 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Individuals may be bound to each other primari We define a micro social order as a recurrent
ly by their interpersonal ties (e.g., friends, asso or repetitive pattern of activity (interaction,
ciates, or colleagues) or they may be conjoined transaction, exchange) among two or more
primarily by some common tie to a social unit actors with four attendant dimensions: (1) actors
(e.g., its mission, values, or identity-affirming exchange with or orient their behavior toward
features). Parsons (1951) argues that theorizing members of the social unit, (2) they experience
the problem of social order involves an analy global emotions from those interactions, (3)
sis of person-to-person and person-to-society actors come to perceive they are a social unit,
ties as analytically distinct phenomena, a view and (4) over time, individuals develop affective
traced to Durkheim ([1893] 1997). This dis attachments to the larger social unit (Lawler
tinction is also evident in Giddens's (1984) 2002). This concept of micro order interweaves
structuration theory, Collins's (2004) theory of collectively-oriented behavior (i.e., interactions
interaction ritual chains, and contemporary the with members or the group), positive affect
ories of economy and society (Swedberg 2003). (i.e., global emotions and affective attachments
Moreover, the two kinds of ties thematically to the unit), and group perceptions (i.e., a sense
appear in theories of collective action (Benford of unity or cohesion). In these terms, a network
and Snow 2000; Brewer and Gardner 1996; becomes a micro social order to the degree that
Prentice, Miller, and Lightdale 1994), embed it generates recurrent patterns of exchange, a
dedness in economic transactions (Granovetter sense of network cohesion, and positive feelings
1985, 1992; Uzzi and Lancaster 2004), and directed at the actors and the overarching net
structural cohesiveness and equivalence (Burt work. Together, these behavioral, emotional,
1978; Moody and White 2003). In more general and cognitive conditions imply that actors define
terms, person-to-unit ties are one aspect of the themselves with reference to a larger social unit
classic self/collectivity or individual/society and are willing to act on its behalf. Micro social
dichotomy that has historically framed socio orders involve the development of a self-to
logical theories of order. collectivity relationship.
We approach the problem of social order in The affect theory of social exchange (Lawler
this article from a social exchange perspective 2001) indicates that the structure of social
(see Cook and Emerson 1978; Ekeh 1974; exchange bears on the degree that micro social
Homans 1950; Lawler, Thye, and Yoon 2000; orders are likely to emerge from exchange
Molm 2003a). Our analysis begins with an processes. One important structural dimension
exchange network, defined as a set of possible is the connection between the giving behaviors
or potential ties that limit and constrain who may in the transaction. Business or economic trans
exchange and interact with whom. A social actions tend to be contractual, negotiated, and
exchange occurs when two actors give some explicit; the giving behaviors are closely con
thing of value to one another and receive some nected and tit-for-tat. Exchanges in friendship
thing of value in return (Emerson 1972a, 1972b; relations tend to be implicit and occur over
Wilier and Anderson 1981). The outcome of unspecified time periods; they lack the explic
interest is the micro social order that emerges it, tit-for-tat character of business transactions.
from the patterns of interaction or exchange Collective action involves person-to-collective
produced by the network. Micro social orders transactions wherein a jointly-produced good
can be construed as emergent social units with generates benefits for those who contribute to
group-like properties (e.g., see Lawler 2002; its production. Public goods dilemmas and infor
Lawler and Thye 1999); they can transform a mal employer-employee contracts tend to fit this
network, crosscut groups or organizations, or be pattern. Finally, the structural connections
subdivisions within a larger social structure. between giving behaviors may allow actors to
The concept of a micro social order is implicit only give and receive from different others with
in theorizing that falls under the broad umbrel in a larger group or social structure (Bearman
la of "microsociology" (Scheff 1990; Stolte, 1997; Malinowski 1922). Social exchange the
Fine, and Cook 2001). Our purpose here is to orists have conceptualized these exchange struc
theorize and empirically examine how and when tures as four forms of exchange referred to,
micro social order develops among a set of respectively, as negotiated, reciprocal, produc
actors who have structural ties to one another. tive, and generalized (Ekeh 1974; Emerson

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
SOCIAL EXCHANGE AND MICRO SOCIAL ORDER 521

1981; Lawler 2001; Molm 1994). Our theory LeDoux 1996), emotions induce organism-wide
hypothesizes that these forms of exchange dif neurological effects that generate a rudimenta
fer in their capacity to produce micro social ry awareness of a self-collectivity connection.1
order. Drawing on these literatures, everyday feelings
Beyond social exchange theory there are a from repeated interactions may foster the devel
wide range of approaches that address some opment of sentiments (positive or negative)
version of the stability and micro social order about a social unit, and it is important to under
problem. Rational choice theories emphasize stand the conditions under which this is likely
the role of monitoring, norms, and sanctions to to occur.
redress the tension between individual and col
lective interests (Coleman 1990; Hechter 1987; BACKGROUND: RELATIONAL
Nee and Ingram 1998). Norms and sanctions DIMENSIONS OF EXCHANGE
emerge because of "externalities" produced by
the widespread pursuit of individual self inter Social exchange theories conceive of relation
est. Social constructionist theories stress the ships in purely instrumental and transactional
consensual meanings and interpretations that terms. A basic tenet of social exchange theory
is that individuals form and maintain a rela
emerge endogenously among actors who engage
in regular or repeated interactions (Berger and tionship as long as the benefits from that rela
Luckmann 1967; Goffman 1959). Such mean tionship exceed those available elsewhere
ings can "objectify" relations or groups, mak (Emerson 1972a, 1972b; Molm and Cook 1995;
ing them "realities" for actors. Identity theories Wilier 1999). By implication, better offers or
emphasize how social interactions create and greater individual profits from alternatives break
sustain shared self-other definitions associated apart existing relations. This tenet is one reason
with structural roles, social categories, and that issues of power, reward allocation, and dis
group affiliations (Burke 1991; Hogg 2004; tributive justice have been central to the
Stryker 1980). Social exchange theories empha exchange-theoretic landscape. The exchange
size the role of trust and commitment in stabi network tradition, in particular, has focused on
lizing relations (Cook, Hardin, and Levi 2005; how network structures produce power gradients
Kollock 1994; Molm 2003a, 2003b). Although and stratification when the payoffs from
rational choice, social constructionist, identity, exchange benefit some individuals at the
and social exchange theories approach the expense of others (Cook et al. 1983; Emerson
self-collectivity relationship in varied ways, 1972a, 1972b; Markovsky, Wilier, and Patton
they have overlapping and convergent themes. 1988; Skvoretz and Lovaglia 1995; Stolte and
The affect theory of social exchange (Lawler Emerson 1977; Thye 2000a; Thye, Lovaglia,
2001) interweaves elements from each approach and Markovsky 1997; Wilier 1999). The rela
to incorporate an actor who experiences emo tional aspect of social exchange is tied to the fact
tion or affect from exchange. that structures tend to generate repeated
Emotions are generally defined as positive or exchanges among the same actors. Emerson
negative evaluative states with physiological,
neurological, and cognitive features (Damasio
1999; Izard 1991; Kemper 1978). Our theoriz 1 The organism-wide neurological effects mean
ing draws from work in psychology, sociology, that when an actor feels good he feels good all over;
and neuroscience. From psychology, emotions when an actor feels bad he feels bad all over. These
entail both a response to a stimulus (e.g., effects are due to chemical secretions?such as
exchange with another) and a stimulus that itself dopamine, epinephrine, and oxytocin?that stem
from different regions of the brain. Damasio (1999,
produces cognitive work (Clore, Schwarz, and
2001) indicates that these neurological secretions
Conway 1994; Izard 1991). From sociology,
generate the "feeling of feelings" and suggests these
cognitive work involves interpreting the mean
are the foundation for consciousness, that is, a sense
ing of emotions felt in the context of relation
of the self juxtaposed to the external objects or events.
ships, situational norms, and self-other For such reasons, neurological processes may pro
definitions (see Hochschild 1979; Kemper mote awareness of or attention to social unit affilia
1978; Smith-Lovin and Heise 1988; Thoits tions that are part of the context within which
1989). From neurobiology (Damasio 1999; emotions occur.

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
522 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

(1972b) portrays this as a key difference 1981; Wilier 1999). Third, the mechanism
between social and economic exchange. through which this occurs is emotional or affec
There are two general approaches to the rela tive. We posit, and have found empirically, that
tional aspect of social exchange. Emerson solving an exchange problem is an accom
(1972b, see also Homans 1961) adopts an "indi plishment that produces positive emotions (see
vidualistic" approach whereas Ekeh (1974; see Lawler et al. 2000; Lawler and Yoon 1996); and
also Malinowski 1922; Levi-Strauss 1969) under some conditions, actors associate these
offers a "collectivist" viewpoint. The individu emotions with their relational or group affilia
alistic approach starts with actors in a simple tion (Lawler and Yoon 1996,1998; Lawler et al.
network structure who have rational-choice or 2000).
behavioral incentives to exchange. Few, if any, The relational consequences of repeated
assumptions are made about a larger group or exchanges are most thoroughly documented in
social unit. Here, micro orders are emergent research on commitment in exchange relations
and necessarily tenuous as they are tied to indi (e.g., Kollock 1994). Commitment is generally
vidual self interest. Relations develop and pre defined as the tendency of actors to stay with
vail only to the degree that the incentives to and continue to exchange with those they have
exchange, preferences of actors, and structures exchanged with in the past (Kollock 1994;
of opportunity are stable. Relations as such Lawler and Yoon 1996; Molm, Takahashi, and
emerge out of individualist conditions. In con Peterson 2000). Research reveals greater rates
trast, the collectivist approach assumes a larg of commitment when actors face high uncer
er social unit or group affiliation. Social tainty or risk (Kollock 1994; Molm, Peterson,
exchanges as such are embedded within and and Takahashi 1999) and also when they have
reflect a cultural or normative order or frame equal power or high mutual power and depen
work (see Bearman 1997; Ekeh 1974). Here dence (Lawler and Yoon 1996). There are two
exchange takes on a more symbolic or expres analytically-distinct interpretations for the emer
sive character and is driven by the cultural gence of commitment in social exchange: trust
beliefs or norms of the larger social unit. In and affect. The trust interpretation asserts that
sum, the individualistic perspective draws atten individuals develop stable, ongoing relations
tion to the exchange processes through which in response to high risk and uncertainty (see
micro orders develop and are sustained, while Cook 2005; Kollock 1994; Molm 1994,2003a).
the collectivist account emphasizes how exoge From this perspective, commitment is a strate
nous conditions?structural or cultural?pro gy to reduce uncertainty in an unstable envi
mote cooperation and minimize opportunism ronment and trust is the "glue" that binds
(see also Fukuyama 1995). together relations and groups (see also
The affect theory of social exchange (Lawler Fukuyama 1995; Yamagishi and Yamagishi
2001) further develops and bridges the indi 1994). The affect explanation contends that
vidualist and collective approaches. It starts actors develop more stable, cohesive relations
with and assumes an individualistic context but and groups if and when exchanges generate
then shows how actors develop a collective positive feelings that actors associate with the
affiliation and affective ties. Our approach dif social unit (i.e., relation or group). Recent evi
fers from other social exchange approaches in dence suggests that uncertainty reduction and
several ways (for reviews, see Lawler and Thye affect are "dual processes" that operate in par
2006; Thye, Yoon, and Lawler 2002). First, we allel to promote stable, cohesive, ongoing
argue that in social exchange there are social exchange relations (see Lawler et al. 2000; Yoon
constructionist and identity processes that alter and Thye 2000). We focus here on the role of
the foundation of relationships and groups, affect.
essentially transforming them from transac The theory of relational cohesion (Lawler
tional (instrumental) to relational (expressive) and Yoon 1996) was the first to draw attention
entities. Second, we assert that this transfor to the role of affect in social exchange (see also
mation is most likely when structures lead the Lawler and Thye 1999). The central argument
same actors to interact or exchange repeatedly is that relations with more equal power-depen
over time, a condition that is generally assumed dence and greater mutual dependence produce
in much of social exchange theory (Emerson more frequent exchange between pairs of actors

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
SOCIAL EXCHANGE AND MICRO SOCIAL ORDER 523

in a network and this leads to relational com consider childrearing by two parents or partners.
mitments. These effects are indirect and oper If parental responsibilities are subjectively
ate through an endogenous causal chain: (1) defined to be loose and overlapping, rather than
more frequent exchange generates more posi divided precisely, "parenting" should foster a
tive feelings; (2) more positive feelings gener greater sense of joint responsibility. The key
ate a perception of the exchange relation as a point is that both objective and subjective con
unifying (cohesive) force; and (3) greater per ditions are important.
ceived cohesion promotes commitment behav The theory makes a sharp distinction between
ior (see Lawler and Yoon 1996,1998). Research global emotions that are immediately felt and
has consistently supported this exchange-to specific emotions that emerge from subsequent
emotion-to-cohesion chain and also affirmed
interpretations of global emotions or feelings.
that power dependence effects on relational This distinction is based primarily on Weiner's
commitments occur indirectly, through this (1986) attribution theory of emotion, but it also
process (Lawler and Yoon 1993, 1996, 1998; dovetails with Damasio's (1999) notion that
Lawler, Thye, and Yoon 2000,2006). The affect "feeling feelings" make salient that one is being
theory of social exchange (Lawler 2001,2002, affected in some way. Global emotions are invol
2006) addresses questions and issues that are untarily felt as a result of exchange or other
complementary to relational cohesion theory,
social interaction. Feeling up/down, good/bad,
focusing not on conditions of power, but on
or pleasure/displeasure are common examples.
determinants of social order across the forms of
Specific emotions are associated with, or direct
exchange. One question examined in the current
research is whether the relational-cohesion ed at, particular social objects such as self,
other, or a social unit. Examples include pride
process mediates the effects of forms of
in self and gratitude toward the other, shame in
exchange on micro social orders.
self and anger toward the other, and affective
attachments or detachments from a social unit.
THE AFFECT THEORY OF SOCIAL
In the theory, the specific emotions directed at
EXCHANGE self, other, or a social unit emerge as actors
The affect theory of social exchange posits that experience and interpret the sources of their
the task jointness of the exchange or activity global feelings. The theory's conceptual frame
determines whether actors perceive the social work for these emotions is provided in Table 1.
unit as a source of their individual emotions or Theory and research in psychology indicates
feelings. Actors attribute their individually-felt that people tend to attribute positive events (suc
emotions to their relations or groups if the task cess) to themselves and negative events (fail
is high in jointness; whereas if the task is low ures) to others or the situation (Jones and Davis
in jointness they attribute the emotions to their 1965; Kelley 1967; Mezulis et al. 2004). The
own or another's behavior. Jointness varies along implication is that individuals, even those
both objective and subjective dimensions. For engaged in a joint task, will be more inclined to
example, a manager may objectively structure attribute group success to their own efforts and
the tasks of a work group to be highly inter feel greater pride in self rather than gratitude
woven. The jointness of other tasks may depend toward the other. In the case of task failure, the
less on objective conditions and more on the predominant emotion would be anger toward
subjective framing of the task. To illustrate, one or more others rather than shame toward

Table 1. Emotions Directed at Each Object


Valence of Emotion
Social Object Positive Negative
Task Pleasantness Unpleasantness
Self Pride Shame
Other Gratitude Anger
Social Unit Affective Attachment Affective Detachment
Note: Reprinted from An Affect Theory of Social Exchange (Lawler 2001).

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
524 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

one's self. These self-serving attributions sug Proposition 1: The greater the nonseparability
gest that it is difficult for repeated exchanges to of task activities and outcomes, the greater
generate positive sentiments about relations or the perception of shared responsibility.
groups. The affect theory of social exchange Proposition 2: The greater the perception of
takes this as a challenge and specifies conditions shared responsibility for success or failure
under which social-unit attributions of emotion at a joint task, the more inclined actors are
will overcome or mitigate self-serving biases to to attribute the global emotions to social
produce person-to-unit attachments. units (relations, networks, or groups).
Specifically, the theory asserts there are struc
These propositions constitute a causal chain
tural (objective) and cognitive (subjective) con
wherein nonseparability of task activity gener
ditions that determine when global emotions
ates perceived shared responsibility and, in turn,
are attributed to social units. The primary struc
shared responsibility produces social unit attri
tural condition is the degree that each individ
butions of emotions (i.e., affective attachments).
ual's contributions to task success (or failure) are A theoretical link can be drawn between this
separable (distinguishable) or nonseparable causal sequence and that of relational cohesion
(indistinguishable). This comparison is informed theory. These two theories specify parallel yet
by Williamson's (1985) trenchant analysis of interrelated processes. Whereas the affect the
work conditions and governance structures. He ory theorizes the consequences of task non
argues that relational-team governance struc seperability, the theory of relational cohesion
tures are common where work structures make theorizes the effects of total and relative power
it difficult to distinguish individual contribu in the relation. All these factors capture and
tions, thus generating a sense of collective reflect types of interdependence that should
responsibility. One implication is that special yield greater exchange frequency. Nonsepara
ized or independent roles in a work setting make bility, as Williamson implies, involves more
salient individual responsibility; whereas col task interdependence, which enhances task coor
laborative or overlapping roles make salient dination, reduces the cost of monitoring others,
shared or collective responsibility. For our pur and yields a heightened sense of collective
poses, this implies that structures of collective responsibility. High total and equal relative
responsibility yield greater coordination or, in power, as documented in relational cohesion
our terms, successful social exchange. Adopting theory, entail greater outcome interdependence,
these notions from Williamson (1985), the affect which directly promotes concession making
theory characterizes the objective structural due to the profits at stake. Taken together, the
condition as the nonseparability of task behav overall implication is that task nonseperability
iors and contributions. should generate perceptions of shared respon
sibility and also activate the relational cohe
The subjective dimension of jointness is the
sion process linking exchange frequency
degree that the exchange task promotes a sense
to-emotion-to-cohesion. In this article, we
oi shared responsibility for success or failure at
empirically examine the link between the two
exchange. If social exchange generates a sense
theories by testing whether the relational
of shared responsibility, actors are more likely
cohesion process mediates the effects of forms
to interpret their individual feelings as jointly
of exchange on affective attachments to the
produced in concert with others and thus attrib unit.
ute those feelings to social units. To illustrate, To conclude, the strongest affective ties to the
if employees in a work team perceive a shared social unit occur when the structure of exchange
responsibility for team success, positive feelings entails high nonseparability and fosters a high
from doing the task are more likely to generate sense of shared responsibility. Theoretically,
affective attachments to the team. On the other
these propositions are applicable to any struc
hand, if members share in the responsibility for tural condition that generates variation in the
team failure, the resulting negative feelings are objective (nonseparability) or subjective (shared
likely to generate affective detachments from the responsibility) conditions. We next apply these
group. Given this logic, there are two core principles to the four forms of social exchange
propositions of the theory (Lawler 2001): illustrated in Figure 1.

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
SOCIAL EXCHANGE AND MICRO SOCIAL ORDER 525

C^=B <^-?
A A
Reciprocal Generalized

C B
C <- B *V?^f

A \/ ? A
Negotiated Productive
Figure 1. Diagram of Four Forms of Social Exchange

Productive exchange involves a jointly-pro


Agreements emerge from a process that entails
duced collective good wherein people offers,
unilater counteroffers, and mutual concessions.
ally provide benefits to the group and Actors' contributions to exchange?their offers
receive
benefit from it. Interdependence is high, yet
and concessions?are distinguishable, but there
is a joint
there are coordination problems that need to result
be produced by the explicit agree
solved to generate the common goodment andonalloterms of the trade. The jointness of the
exchange
cate collective benefits. This implies an "assurshould be salient in negotiated
ance game" in which the largest payoffsexchange,are and the sense of shared responsibil
from mutual cooperation (Kollock ity 1998).
for the result should be relatively high,
thoughcoau
Prototypes include a business partnership, lower than that found in productive
exchange. Thus, nonseparability and shared
thoring scholars, or a homeowners' association
working together to solve a community responsibility
problem. should result in global emotions
In each case, individual agents cannot beingaccom
attributed in part to the social unit, but
somewhat
plish the desired outcome alone but stand to reap attenuated relative to productive
significant benefits from cooperation. exchange.
Actors
make individual contributions but these areexchange is similar to negotiated
Reciprocal
interwoven in the joint products of their behav
exchange, except that giving and receiving are
ior. The affect theory asserts that nonseparabil
sequential, unilateral acts separated by time and
ity and perceptions of shared responsibility
provided without explicit expectations of reci
should be higher here than in other procity.
formsPatternsof of reciprocity can emerge over
exchange. The tendency to attribute emotions
time, however,to if actors make their giving con
the social unit (the network or group) should
tingent on the prior giving by the other (see
Molm etenvi
also be strongest in a productive exchange al. 1999). If A receives a unilateral ben
ronment. efit from B, A may feel obligated to provide ben
Direct exchange occurs when two or more efits in return to B; and if A gives unilateral
actors give directly to one another over time. benefits to B, A may come to expect that B will
There are two forms: negotiated and reciprocal. later reciprocate (Gouldner I960). Giving advice
Negotiated exchange involves bargaining over to a fellow employee, providing favors to a
the terms of an agreement. Through this process, roommate, and inviting colleagues to dinner
actors develop a contractual agreement that are acts that may initiate or become part of
allows them to provide benefits to one another reciprocal exchanges. A major issue for actors
(e.g., a salary for work or a price for a product). in reciprocal exchange is risk or trust, that is,

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
526 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

whether actors anticipate or expect reciprocal Hypothesis 3: Within direct forms of exchange,
cooperative behavior from others (Molm 2003a, negotiated exchange produces stronger per
2003b). Given that each act of giving is distinct, ceptions of shared responsibility and
however, the jointness of exchange is not as stronger global emotions than does recip
explicit or salient as in productive or negotiat rocal exchange.
ed exchange. The degree of nonseparability and Hypothesis 4: The strength of a micro social
sense of shared responsibility, therefore, should order is ordered as follows across forms of
be lower here.
social exchange: productive > [negotiated
Generalized exchange is an indirect form of > reciprocal] > generalized.
exchange that entails three or more actors who
can give to (and receive from) one other, but Hypothesis 4 has a number of subcompo
here, givers and receivers are not matched in nents that correspond to the four dimensions of
pairs. In an organization, a structure of gener micro social order. It predicts the ordering of (1)
alized reciprocity among different departments frequency of exchange, (2) global positive feel
exists if a department provides information to ings about the exchanges, (3) perceptions of
one other department but receives information network cohesion, and (4) affective attachments
about the social unit across the four forms of
from a different department. Other common
examples involve acts of generalized reciproc exchange. The experiment to follow tests the
impact of the forms of exchange on these dimen
ity such as helping a stranded motorist or open
sions of micro order.
ing a door for a stranger. Like productive
Other theoretical traditions predict different
exchange, a structure of generalized exchange
orderings among some of the forms of social
fosters high levels of interdependence and
exchange based on issues of risk, the expressive
makes coordination a significant problem.
value of reciprocity, and trust (Ekeh 1974; Molm
Unlike productive exchange, giving behaviors
2003a, 2003b). Molm and colleagues (2003a,
are highly separable; and, all things being equal,
2003b; Molm, Collett, and Schaefer 2007) pre
acts of giving benefit are unlikely to generate
dict and demonstrate empirically that recipro
much sense of shared responsibility. Thus,
cal exchange fosters more commitment and
based on the affect theory, generalized
stronger positive feelings about exchange part
exchange poses important obstacles to micro
social order.2 ners (Molm et al. 1999; Molm et al. 2000) than
does negotiated exchange. This suggests the
To conclude, applying core propositions of
opposite ordering for negotiated and reciprocal
the theory produces four general predictions
exchange (Hypothesis 3). Molm and colleagues
for forms of exchange, as follows:
also theorize that reciprocal exchange involves
Hypothesis 1: Productive exchange generates greater risk of nonreciprocity and more expres
stronger perceptions of shared responsi sive value than negotiated exchange due to the
bility and stronger global emotions than latter's explicit, binding character. As a result,
do direct or generalized exchange. giving behavior in reciprocal exchange is inter
Hypothesis 2: Direct exchange produces preted more positively by partners than giving
stronger perceptions of shared responsi in negotiated exchanges. Molm's logic further
bility and stronger global emotions than suggests that because generalized exchange
does generalized exchange. involves indirect, rather than direct, reciproci
ty, it generates the highest levels of expressive
value (Molm et al. 2007). As such, she predicts
that generalized exchange will produce even
2 Ekeh (1974) categorizes what we term produc stronger positive feelings and commitments
tive and generalized under the same rubric (general
than both negotiated and reciprocal exchange
ized) on the grounds that these are both collective
(see Molm 2003a). The collectivist approach of
forms involving high interdependence (see also
Ekeh (1974) and the individualist approach of
Yamagishi and Cook 1993). While we acknowledge
and accept Ekeh's (1974) observation, the affect the Molm (2003a, 2003b) both theorize that trust is
ory of social exchange suggests that different degrees higher in generalized than in direct exchange.
of shared responsibility render these qualitatively
Our research considers these alternatives in the
different. context of the first simultaneous examination of

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
SOCIAL EXCHANGE AND MICRO SOCIAL ORDER 527

all four forms of exchange identified in the exchange should reveal the following order for
exchange tradition.3 the specific emotions directed at self and other:
Hypothesis 5: The ordering of positive emo
Specific Emotions Toward Self and tions directed at self (pride) and other (grat
Other itude) across the forms of exchange should
correspond with the ordering of objective
Based on Propositions 1 and 2, objective task
task jointness: productive > [negotiated >
jointness and the sense of shared responsibili
ty determine whether social-unit or self-serving
reciprocal] > generalized.
attributions are likely to emerge. This has impliHypothesis 6: The ordering of negative emotions
cations for specific emotions directed at self and directed at self (shame) and other (anger)
others. To the degree that individuals engage in across the forms of exchange should be
social-unit rather than self-serving attributions, the inverse of the ordering of objective task
they should feel both pride in self and gratitude jointness: generalized > [reciprocal > nego
toward the other, following successful social tiated] > productive.
exchange. That is, gratitude toward the other
does not reduce the sense of pride in self, or vice
versa. By comparison, if actors engage in self Mediating Processes
serving attributions, they attribute positive
The linkages between structure, interaction, and
results to their own efforts and pride toward
outcome are defining characteristics of
self and gratitude toward others will thus be
exchange theories. A key issue is whether struc
inversely related. Therefore, the forms of social tures have direct or indirect effects on outcomes.
exchange that promote stronger micro social
Whereas Emerson (1972a, 1972b) and others
orders should also generate more pride and
(Wilier 1999; Markovsky et al. 1988) emphasize
more gratitude.
the direct effects of structure on outcomes,
The case of negative emotions is more com
recent work reveals a shift in emphasis toward
plex. On one hand, as with positive emotions,
the mediating effects for structure. This is most
when individuals fail to exchange and engage
clearly shown in research on commitment
in social-unit attributions both anger (toward the
(Kollock 1994; Lawler and Yoon 1996; Molm
other) and shame (toward the self) should be
et al. 1999) that emphasizes the mediating roles
mitigated as the focus is on the social unit.
of uncertainty reduction, trust, risk, and affect.
Given the theory, this would lead us to con
Emotional mediation is central to the theory of
clude that negative emotions will be less likely
relational cohesion, given its focus on the indi
to emerge within forms of exchange high on
rect effects of structural power on relational
objective task jointness. On the other hand, if
commitments through this causal chain:
individuals engage in self-serving attributions,
exchange frequency ?> positive emotions ??
failures to exchange should generate anger
toward the other but not shame toward the self. cohesion (Lawler and Yoon 1996; Thye et al.
2002). We propose that objective task non
This would suggest that the mean level of anger
seperability unleashes the endogenous process
will be greater than the mean level of shame.
of relational cohesion theory, thereby strength
Overall, the theory suggests that the forms of
ening affective attachments to social units. This
is based on the supposition that objective task
jointness promotes more frequent exchange by
3 We do not claim a competitive test vis-a-vis the promoting coordination and a sense of collec
formulations of Ekeh (1974) or Molm (2003a). This
tive responsibility. In turn, frequent exchange
study is designed to test implications of the shared
fosters more global positive feelings about the
responsibility logic of the affect theory, examining
exchange tasks, as well as a greater sense of
micro social order across all four forms of exchange
cohesion at the network level. Cohesion at the
simultaneously. We assume somewhat different ini
network level makes the network itself a rele
tial conditions (i.e., exchange partners need not
exclude connected others) relative to these authors, vant social object and possible target for affec
and as such, we see our approach and those of Ekeh tive sentiments. Thus, as a complement to
(1974) and Molm (2003a) as complementary We Hypotheses 1 to 4, we test whether the endoge
return to these differences in the discussion section. nous relational-cohesion process mediates the

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
528 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

impact of forms of social exchange on affective others.4 The actors are therefore "free" to con
attachments, as follows: struct any set or pattern of relations, which may
Hypothesis 7: The effects of forms of exchange involve varied rates or types of exchange with
on affective attachments are mediated by their prospective partners. Such networks are
the exchange-to-emotion-to-cohesion well-suited to studying emergent social process
process, specified by relational-cohesion es and are similar to many real-world contexts
where actors can create and sustain a set of
theory.
noncontingent relations. Another advantage is
To summarize, this article conducts the first
that these networks afford a very straightforward
explicit test of the affect theory of social way to compare the four structural forms of
exchange (Lawler 2001) simultaneously com
social exchange.5
paring the four forms of social exchange iden
tified by exchange theorists (Ekeh 1974;
Emerson 1972b; Lawler 2001; Molm 1994). In
Design and Procedures
basic terms, the theory identifies structural (task A total of 192 undergraduate students at a
nonseparability) and cognitive (perceptions of Northeastern and a Southeastern university par
shared responsibility) dimensions under which ticipated in the experiment for payment. The
social exchange generates emergent micro social
experiment consisted of a four condition, com
orders at the collective or group level. Applied
pletely randomized design that manipulated the
to the forms of exchange, the theory predicts that
four forms of social exchange. In all, 64 same
productive exchange will generate the strongest
sex triads were randomly assigned to one of
micro orders and generalized exchange the
the four experimental conditions (16 triads per
weakest, while the two forms of direct exchange
cell; 10 female and 6 male). Because data were
(negotiated and reciprocal) will fall in between.
collected at two universities, the experiment
counterbalanced gender and university affilia
METHOD tion within each experimental condition.
The Experimental Context Upon their arrival, subjects were randomly
assigned to separate cubicles where they read
The experiment, described below, created written
an instructions. The instructions described
interorganizational setting, in which three
the setting, which involved three small computer
small, entrepreneurial firms have comple
mentary strengths or niches and can reap ben
efits from an exchange of resources. Reflecting
4 In the parlance of network exchange theory "null
the four forms of social exchange, companies
connections" are theoretically distinct from negative
could explicitly divide profits from resources
(exclusive) or positive (inclusive) connections
(negotiated); develop a pattern of giving
(Brennan 1981; Wilier 1999). The vast majority of
resources to one another (reciprocal); partake networks studied are negatively or exclusively con
in a joint-venture (productive); or give and
nected (Molm and Cook 1995; Wilier 1999). Molm's
receive from different actors (generalized).theory and research examines negatively-connected
The setting was a three-actor, triadic network
networks (e.g., Molm 2003a, 2003b; Molm et al.
that varied only the form of exchange, as por1999) and observes that the salience of conflict is
trayed in Figure 1. greater in negotiated than reciprocal exchange. Our
use of null connections lessens the salience of con
Triads are a simple and straightforward net
flict across the forms of exchange because exclusion
work configuration for examining the emer
need not occur. We suggest that when conflict salience
gence of a micro social order (Simmel 1964).
is reduced the theoretical process specified by Molm
We designed the networks to capture a situation
and colleagues (2007) will be attenuated.
where: (1) actors have equal power because the
5 Simultaneously comparing all four forms of
network of opportunities for exchange does notexchange is complex. For instance, it may be impos
give any of them a structural advantage, and (2)
sible to instantiate an exclusively connected gener
each actor can exchange with any or all of thealized exchange in a triad. Our approach minimizes
other actors in the network to whom they are the ancillary or extraneous differences among the
connected. That is, on any given episode each
conditions in accord with the requirements of our the
can exchange with none, one, or both of theory.

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
SOCIAL EXCHANGE AND MICRO SOCIAL ORDER 529

firms (Alpha, Beta, and Gamma) and indicat iment. They received a running cumulative total
ed that each subject was the head of her respec of their own profits updated after each exchange
tive company. Each was informed that the opportunity or episode (see Molm et al. 1999).
company specializes in the production of mem Subjects were informed that their pay for the
ory chips but lacks the technology to make study was based entirely on the profits they
microprocessors. Subjects were told they could acquired for their companies, and at the con
acquire or receive such technology from the clusion of the session, the number of points
other companies. A diagram of the network was earned were converted to cash using a standard
present in each subject room to show who could formula.
give valued resources to whom, thus subjects
understood how each of the three participants Manipulation of Forms of Exchange
could interact with the others. The instructions
explained that there would be multiple "inter Across all conditions, the benefit from exchange
action episodes." All interactions took place and the expected value associated with each
using desktop computers and subjects were relation were constant and equal. Under all four
anonymous. forms of exchange, the expected value of what
In each episode, subjects decided whether to actors could receive from each viable exchange
give resources to one or more others, and these behavior is 800 points. If actors chose not to give
choices were made simultaneously by the three to or exchange with anyone, they received a
subjects. Productive, reciprocal, and generalized default payoff of 300 points (i.e., this 300 points
exchange involved a single choice, that is, to was forfeited if they gave to or exchanged in any
give or not to give. In the reciprocal and gen viable relation). The default profit was part of
eralized exchange conditions, the choice was the cover story designed to suggest that each
whether to unilaterally give to another; while in company had the capacity to generate a flow of
the productive exchange condition the choice profit independent of the other companies.
was whether to give to a joint venture. The Because this default payoff was forfeited if they
negotiated exchange condition entailed up to exchanged with or gave to another, it repre
three rounds of offers and counteroffers in an sents a constant and equal opportunity cost
effort to divide a pool of profits. To account for across the four experimental conditions. These
costs and benefits were held constant at the
the three rounds of negotiations and equate this
condition with the others on the number of relational level, that is, across all relations in all
interaction opportunities, there were a third four conditions the gain from exchange is 800
fewer episodes (16) in the negotiated condition points and the cost of exchange is 300 points.7
relative to all others (48).6 The specifics for each condition are given below.
All subjects were instructed to maximize the In negotiated exchange, actors negotiate with
profits of their own companies and, in accord two prospective partners in the three-actor net
with related research (e.g., Lawler et al. 2000; work at the same time, and each actor may reach
Lawler and Yoon 1996), they had information an agreement with either, both, or neither part
only on their own profit points during the exper ner. Each episode has up to three rounds of
negotiation; in each round, actors could repeat
their last offer or make a further concession by
raising their offer. They could not retract earli
6 In all conditions there are 48 opportunities to
er concessions. The negotiations continue until
interact (16 episodes X 3 rounds = 48 in negotiated;
48 episodes X 1 round otherwise). We chose this
number of opportunities to ensure the study would
generate reliable patterns of exchange, equate the 7 We used the default payoff to enhance the plau
four conditions in terms of time and number of obser sibility of the "cover story" and also to reduce the
vations in the statistical analysis, and maintain the exogenous experimental pressure on subjects to
involvement of the subjects. We used the results from exchange. This allows for more variation in giving
a series of pretests at each university to guide our rates, enhances our capacity to detect subtle differ
decision. In the case of negotiated exchange, prior ences in the emergence of micro order, and mirrors
research has found similar results with as few as 12 the opportunity or transaction costs associated with
episodes (Lawler and Yoon 1993) and as many as 20 many exchanges outside the lab. It thus provides a
episodes (Lawler et al. 2006). conservative yet strong test of our hypotheses.

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
530 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

either an agreement is reached or the end of the a different other. Individual contributions are
third round. An agreement occurs if the sum of structured such that A benefits B, B benefits C,
actors' claims or demands is equal to or less than and C benefits A (see Figure 1). An episode here
the total amount of joint profit on each relation consists of each subject simultaneously decid
(i.e., 1,600). The expected payoff per relation is ing whether or not to give resources to the con
800 points given all positions are of equal power.
tiguous other in the chain.8 To be consistent
If an individual is excluded from any exchange,
with the reciprocal condition and hold the rela
they receive the default 300 profit points for that
tional payoffs constant, the points given to the
episode.
other are valued at 800 profit points for the
The reciprocal exchange condition includes
receiver.9 Also, as with all other conditions, if
most of the elements and procedures Molm and
colleagues used in their research on reciprocal an individual decides not to give they receive the
and negotiated exchange (e.g., Molm et al. default payoff for that episode.
1999). Exchange relations can form, but they
involve cross-episode, sequential giving, rather Measures of Dependent Variables
than a within episode explicit agreement as
with negotiated exchange. In a given episode, Our theory predicts the ranking across the forms
every actor simultaneously decides whether to of exchange for each empirical indicator of
give resources (valued at 800 profit points to the micro order: (1) the rates of giving in the net
receiver) to one or both of their partners. If they work, (2) global feelings of pleasure/satisfac
do not give to either, they receive the default tion, (3) perceptions of network cohesion, and
payoff of 300 points, as in the negotiated con (4) affective attachment to the network as a
dition. whole. We also measure specific emotions to
In the productive exchange condition, each test for the predicted ordering across the con
subject simultaneously decides whether to ditions.
invest 800 points in a common account.
Resources flow to the account and benefits
flow from it. This is similar to an assurance
8 In both reciprocal and generalized exchange con
game in which the largest payoffs are from ditions subjects were explicitly told they are giving
mutual cooperation (Kollock 1998). The pay 400 points that will double to 800 points for the
offs from the joint venture are determined by receiver. This procedure has been used in related
the number who participate in the interaction. research on reciprocal (Molm, Collett, and Schaefer
If only one person contributes, the 800 points 2006) and generalized exchange (Yamagishi and
Cook 1993) and we included it for that reason. It has
are divided equally among the three actors such
no bearing on the incentives of actors.
that each actor receives 266 points from the
9 By definition, in generalized exchange with a
joint venture (of course, the two noncontribu
single-commodity, such as our triadic-chain, an actor
tors also earn the 300 point default payoff). If can benefit from only one other actor. We thus adjust
two actors give, their total contributions (800 ed the pay schedule here so that the total monetary
+ 800 = 1,600 total) are multiplied by 1.5 to value is equated with the other conditions. The expect
generate 2,400 points. This amount is then ed value of profit (800) is equated at the level of the
divided equally across the three such that each relation across all four forms of exchange. This means,
receives 800 profit points (again, the noncon however, that in a given episode within the generalized
tributor also earns the 300 point default). If all exchange condition actors could receive 800 points
three contribute, their total contributions (800 total, whereas they could receive 1,600 points maxi
+ 800 + 800 = 2,400) are doubled to yield mum in the other conditions (800 points x 2 rela
tions). To examine this, we ran an ancillary condition
4,800 profit points. This amount is then divid
of generalized exchange in which subjects could
ed equally across the three such that each
receive 1,600 points (instead of 800). The substantive
receives 1,600. The payoff is maximal when all results across all four dimensions of micro order (giv
three actors contribute and this amount is con
ing behavior, global emotion, cohesion, and affective
sistent with maximal payoffs in other condi attachment) were nearly identical, and there were no
tions. significant differences between the two versions of the
In the generalized exchange condition, each generalized exchange condition. These data are avail
subject can give to one other and receive from able from the authors upon request.

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
SOCIAL EXCHANGE AND MICRO SOCIAL ORDER 531

Behavioral Measures To measure global emotions the first ques


tionnaire asked subjects to "describe your feel
Proportion giving is the networkwide rate of
ings right now" along a series of nine-point
giving behavior divided by the total number of
semantic-differential items: pleased-displeased,
opportunities (range = 0 to 1). This is the most
happy-unhappy, satisfied-not satisfied, con
comparable behavioral measure across all forms
tented-discontented, and joyful-not joyful. We
of social exchange. In productive exchange it is
averaged the scores within the network to cre
giving to a group, in reciprocal it is giving to one
ate a single networkwide index (Cronbach's
or two others, in generalized it is giving to an
alpha = . 93).n
adjacent other, and in negotiated it is reaching
We measured perceptions of network cohe
agreement with one or two others.10 We analyze
sion on the first and second questionnaires.
the proportion of giving across all episodes and
Subjects were asked to "describe the network
also by round block (first half, second half) to
test for effects over time.
along each of the following": close-distant,
coming together-coming apart, solid-fragile,
Profit difference is a control variable in the
cohesive-divisive, and converging-diverging.
regression analyses testing the mediation
Again, we averaged scores across members of
hypothesis. This is measured at the network
the network to create a single network index.
level as the average of the absolute difference
Previous work (Lawler et al. 2000; Lawler and
in profits across the three relations. When all
Yoon 1993, 1996) documents that global emo
actors earn precisely the same profit this meas
tions and perceptions of either relational or net
ure equals zero; when there is some profit dif
work cohesion are distinct constructs and highly
ferentiation the index equals a positive value.
reliable (Cronbach's alpha = .94).
This measure essentially controls for the dif
The second questionnaire also measured the
ferences in the amount of rewards that actors
four specific emotions. These measures asked
receive over time.
subjects to describe their feelings on a single
nine-point scale directed at themselves (in the
Questionnaire Measures case of pride and shame) or nine-point scales
directed at each of the others (in the case of grat
The computer software administered three ques
itude and anger). The anchors for each Likert
tionnaires: one at the midpoint, one near the end,
item were: proud-not proud, grateful-not grate
and one at the end of the study. In the negotiat
ful, angry-not angry, and shameful-shameless.
ed condition, the first questionnaire came after
At the end, subjects received a post ques
the eighth episode (after the 24th episode in
the other conditions) and the second came after tionnaire containing the measure of affective
attachments to the group. The items (five) asked
the 16th episode (after the 48th episode in all
subjects how they feel about their relationship
others). The measures on each questionnaire
to the group, and they responded on the fol
were based on the theorizing. Drawing on rela
lowing nine-point scales: bad-good, attached
tional cohesion theory, we measured global
emotions and perceived cohesion on the first
detached, disloyal-loyal, disconnected
questionnaire. We measured affective attach connected, and negative-positive. We created
network-level scores by averaging individual
ments on the third (post) questionnaire because
ratings (Cronbach's alpha = .90).12 Finally, as a
the affect theory suggests they are an outcome.
To test for changes in cohesion over time, we
measured network cohesion on the second ques
tionnaire. We also measured the specific emo 11 For reasons outlined in Thye (2000b), we report
tions here because they follow the global ed reliability estimates as weighted averages across
emotions in the affect theory of exchange. the four experimental conditions.
12 A confirmatory factor analysis indicates that
affective attachment to the group is distinct from
global emotions and relational cohesion. The best fit
10 To illustrate, if each person in the reciprocal ting model occurs when each of the three factors is
exchange conditions gave to only one other on every treated as a distinct construct (chi-square = 385, df
round, the proportion of exchange is .50; if they gave = 76). In comparison, the goodness-of-fit index drops
to both others on every round the proportion is 1.0. significantly when the three measures are treated as

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
532 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Table 2. Means and Analysis of Variance for Key Measures across Conditions

Experimental Condition
Generalized Reciprocal Negotiated Productive
Global Emotion 4.49 (.95)a 6.17 (.87)b 5.37(1.02)b 7.10(1.01)c
F3>60 = 21.21***
Proportion of Giving .32 (.19)a .56 (.20)b .61 (.16)b .84 (.22)c
F3,60 = 20.19***
Network Cohesion 3.43(1.51)a 5.56(1.27)b 5.44(1.27)b 7.18 (1.26)c
F3j60 = 21.24***
Group Attachment 4.32(1.08)a 5.76 (.86)b 5.55 (.81)b 6.57 (1.07)c
F3,60= 14.95***
N_16_16_16_16
Notes: Standard deviations are in parentheses. Cells in a given row with different letters are signific
at the .05 level or greater using Duncan's Multiple Range Test for pairwise comparisons.

check on the logic of the theory, a singleThere


item are significant main effects
exchange structure on all four dimension
measured perceptions of shared responsibility
as follows: "When satisfactory results were
micro pro
order: the proportion of giving (F3 60
duced in the episodes, to what extent did 20.19,/?
you and < .001), the strength of global emot
the others share joint responsibility?" Subjects
(F3 60 = 21.21, p < .001), perceptions of netw
responded on a nine-point scale, from "not at (F360 = 21.24, p < .001), and affecti
cohesion
all" to "very much." attachments to the group (F360 = 14.95,
.001). Moreover, the post hoc tests find t
RESULTS exact same pattern for each variable. In eve
case, the productive exchange structure
The results are divided into three sections: (1) than the two direct forms of exchan
greater
analyses of variance to assess the main hypothe
(negotiated and reciprocal), which are great
ses, (2) a supplemental repeated-measures than the generalized-exchange structure. Th
analysis of variance to test for trends inonly
rates of
departure from the theory is that there a
giving and network cohesion, and (3) ordinary
no significant differences between negotiat
least squares regression models to test the
andmedi
reciprocal forms of exchange.
ation hypothesis. The logic underlying the affect theory asse
that different structures of exchange promo
Micro Social Order: different degrees of shared responsibility f
Hypotheses 1 to 4 the results of the interaction. An ANOVA on p
ceptions of shared responsibility reveals a s
We use one-way analyses of variance (ANOVA)
nificant main effect for exchange structure th
to examine the impact of the four structural
affirms the expected pattern (F3 60 = 14.54,/
forms of exchange on the four indicators of
.001; productive M = 7.9, negotiated M = 6.6
micro order: exchange frequency, global emo
reciprocal M = 6.2, and generalized M = 5
tions, perceptions of network cohesion, and
affective attachments to the social unit.The follow-up
Table 2 tests dovetail with those for mic
order. Productive exchange produces a great
contains the means, ANOVA results, and post
sense of shared responsibility than do the for
hoc tests that control the overall Type I error rate.
of direct exchange (negotiated and reciproca
and the direct forms of exchange generat
greater sense of shared responsibility than d
a single construct (chi-square = 1325, df= 77). The
best performing two-factor model occurs when rela
generalized exchange. Negotiated and reci
cal forms of exchange are not significantly
tional cohesion is combined with affective attachment
ferent from one another, which may explain
(chi-square = 373, df = 76). Together, this evidence
lack of other differences between these form
suggests the three constructs are theoretically and
empirically distinct. Overall, the results for shared responsibility

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
SOCIAL EXCHANGE AND MICRO SOCIAL ORDER 533

affirm a core proposition that enables the the alized exchange may occur early but then con
ory to make predictions for forms of exchange verge and "wash out" over time. For this analy
and (2) mirror perfectly the results for micro sis, we divided rates of giving into two time
social order.13 blocks (i.e., 24 episodes in each block for pro
In sum, the results provide clear and consis ductive, reciprocal, and generalized; eight
tent support for the affect theory. Productive episodes each for negotiated) and analyzed the
exchange generates the highest rates of giving, two measures of perceived cohesion (i.e., at the
the strongest positive emotion, greater percep 24th and 48th episodes; and the 8th and 16th in
tions of network cohesion, and the greatest negotiated exchange). Figure 2 shows the trends
affective attachment to the overall network. for giving behavior.
Generalized exchange produces the lowest lev The repeated-measures ANOVA for exchange
els (i.e., weakest micro order) on all of these (giving) behavior does not reveal an interac
dimensions. Productive exchange also generates tion effect between time block and exchange
the greatest sense of shared responsibility, structure on giving behavior (F7 m < U P =
whereas generalized exchange produces the n.s.). The differences across forms of exchange
least. The direct forms of exchange consistent emerge early and remain relatively steady. A
ly fall between these extremes. The fact that more refined analysis, dividing the blocks into
generalized exchange produces weaker indica four periods, also does not show an interaction
tions of micro order than do direct forms of
effect between exchange structure and time (F
exchange is contrary to some prior theorizing < 1; p = n.s.). The upshot is that rates of
(Ekeh 1974; Molm 2003a). exchange or giving behavior are relatively steady
Although predicted, we find no difference over time across all conditions.
between negotiated and reciprocal exchange. In contrast, the repeated-measures ANOVA
However, given Molm's (2003a, 2003b) research for perceptions of network cohesion reveals a
showing that reciprocal exchange fosters more significant interaction effect (F3 m = 4.65,p <
commitment than negotiated exchange, it is not .01), along with the main effect already report
surprising that the affect theory of social ed (F3,12o = 31.64, p < .001). Figure 3 illus
exchange fails here. We must note, though, that trates the pattern. Perceptions of network
Molm's (20003a, 2003b) negotiated < recipro cohesion became stronger over time in produc
cal prediction is also not supported, which rais tive exchange (Means = 6.27 to 7.18, t63 = 6.13,
es a question about the conditions under which p < .001), but they deteriorate in generalized
negotiated-reciprocal differences are likely to exchange (Means = 4.60 to 3.42, t63 = 7.12,/?
occur. We return to this issue in the discussion.
< .001). Negotiated and reciprocal exchange
generate similar levels of cohesion over time and
Over Time Effects there were no significant differences (Means =
5.79 to 5.44 in negotiated; Means = 5.78 to
To further pursue the difference between pro
5.56 in reciprocal). The fact that productive
ductive and generalized exchange, we examined
exchange produces a strengthening of network
the trends over time for giving behavior and
level cohesion and generalized exchange pro
for perceived network cohesion using a repeat
duces a weakening of cohesion is consistent
ed-measures analysis of variance. It is plausible
with the idea that productive exchange has
that differences between productive and gener
greater potential to endogenously generate
micro social order.

13 To further examine the role of shared responsi


bility, we regressed affective attachments on per
Emotions Directed at Self and Other
ceptions of shared responsibility, controlling for (Hypotheses 5 and 6)
exchange frequency, profit differences, and the forms
Table 3 shows the means and analyses of vari
of exchange. The results indicate a significant impact
ance for specific emotions directed at self
of shared responsibility on affective attachments (B
= .339, p < .01), as suggested by the affect theory. In and others. These effects are generally con
the context of the results for the forms of exchange sistent with Hypotheses 5 and 6. There are
and micro order, this adds further support to the significant main effects for gratitude toward
underlying logic of the theory. the others (F3 60 = 23.51, p < .001), for pride

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
534 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

1.0 -i

_ iY
.9

___^M __^M _ BBlockl


^H ^H |D Block 2

. Ml
Generalized Negotiated Reciproal Product
Figure 2. Proportion of Giving across Two Episode Blocks

in self (F360 = 13.12, p < .001),


andfor
theanger
most anger toward the other
as< a.001),
toward the others (F360 = 19.85,/? similar
andtrend with respect to p
for shame in self (F3f60 = 15.79, shame toward self.
p < .001).
Productive exchange produces the greatest
Three other patterns are worthy
gratitude toward the others, the greatest
First, comparing generalized to eac
expression of pride in self, and the of
form lowest
exchange, six of the eight dif
are significant
levels of anger and shame. In contrast, gen and support the
Generalized
eralized exchange produces the least gratitude exchange fosters more a

Table 3. Means and Analysis of Variance for Specific Emotions across Co

Experimental Condition
Generalized Reciprocal Negotiated
Gratitude toward Other 4.00 (1.36)a 6.07 (1.18)b 5.00
F3,60 = 23.51***
Pride in Self 5.46 (.94)a 6.27 (.90)b 5.77(1.02)ab 7.27 (.59)c
F3,60= 13.12***
Anger toward Other 4.17(1.22)a 2.33(1.55)b 3.24 (.86)c .98(1.14)d
F3,60= 19.85***
Shame toward Self 3.08 (1.16)a 2.23 (.83)b 2.58 (.83)ab 1.04 (.58)c
F3,60= 15.79***
N_16_16_16_16
Notes: Standard deviations are in parentheses. Cells in a given row with different letters are s
at the .05 level or greater using Duncan's Multiple Range Test for pairwise comparisons.

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
SOCIAL EXCHANGE AND MICRO SOCIAL ORDER 535

f?|i-|>|=
s4_H_H _H
1 ^H^H ^H ^H__M _liBto
|aBiock2

Bill Generalized Negotiated Recip


Figure 3. Perceptions of Network Cohesion acro

shame, as well as less pride and


additional
than did reciprocal exchange.
gratitude,
controls: profi
Pride and shame
ceived predictability, and i
emotion
in generalized exchange, used in
however, relationa
were not
Table exchange.
different from negotiated 4 shows the results
Second,
contrary to the affect theory,
First, recall negotiated
that the AN
exchange produces more anger and
2 establish thatless
the grati
form
tude toward the other than
cantly did reciprocal
impacts giving be
exchange. These findings support
equation the implica
in Table 4 indica
tions of Molm's (2003a, 2003b;
ior has the Molm
largestet al.
effec
2007) research indicating that
pleasure negotiated
(Beta = .543, p
exchange produces lesscentral
positive affect indicates
equation directed
at the exchange partner. Third, there is no dif
ings measured at time 1 h
ference between anger and shame
marginal) under
effect ongen
per
eralized exchange and thus no
measured atevidence for
time 2 (Beta
self-serving attributions
thetherein.
right equation finds t

Test of Mediating Process


(Hypothesis 7) 14 The measure of interes
identical to that from prio
To conduct an OLS analysis of the indirect
cohesion (Lawler et al. 2000
effects of forms of exchange, we created a set
1998). The index consists of
of dummy variables to capture the four forms
ing anchors: enthusiastic-u
of exchange. We then boring,
regressed giving behav
motivating-not motiv
ior, global emotions, interesting.
and perceived network
The measure of
cohesion on these dummies. Toof
consists make the
Likert analy
scale ite
sis comparable to related research
anchors: (Lawler et al.
unpredictable-pre
2000; Lawler and Yoon 1996), we included
tain, vague-clear, three
and ambi

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
536 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Table 4. Standard OLS Regression Coefficients Regressing Network Cohesion and Attachment on
Antecedent Variables with Perceived Predictability Controlled

Independent Variables Global Emotions Network Cohesion Affective Attachment


Generalized Exchange -.330** -.262* -.035
Negotiated Exchange -.345*** -.016 .011
Reciprocal Exchange -.017 -.115 .052
Proportion of Giving .543*** .465*** .203
Profit Difference -.099 -.139 .008
Pleasure/Satisfaction .221 .156
Interest/Excitement .04 .05
Perceived Predictability -. 107 .087
Network Cohesion ? .452***
R2_.1_.69_.1_
Notes: Generalized exchange, negotiated exchange, and reciprocal exchange are dummy variables. The om
category is productive exchange.
*p<.05; **/?<.01; ***/?<.001 (one-tailedtests).

cohesion has the largest effect on affective


of relational cohesion principles into the affect
attachments (Beta = .453,/? < .001).15 The theory
first of social exchange.
two findings replicate principles of relational
cohesion theory. The third finding showsDISCUSSION
how AND CONCLUSIONS
these effects also mediate the path from
Micro social orders emerge from and are sus
exchange behavior to affective attachments as
tained by a structure-interaction process or
the affect theory would suggest. Importantly, the
dynamic. Structure shapes who interacts with
effects of exchange behavior on positive emo
whom and how often. The resulting patterns of
tions are strong, as are the effects of network
interaction in turn generate a realized social
cohesion on affective attachments to the group.16
order, or stable set of ties among actors. The con
This confirms key junctures in the integration
cept of micro social order, as we conceive it,
captures the joint consequences of a "dialectic"
between structure and interaction. Micro social
15 The marginal effect for global feelings may be
orders lack the standard properties of full
due to the lag between time 1 (when the emotions
fledged groups (i.e., group goals, norms, or
were measured) and time 2 (when cohesion was
hierarchical structure), yet they involve more
measured). If we substitute the time 1 measure of
cohesion for the time 2 measure, global feelings of
than the minimal or purely "categorical groups"
pleasure have a sizeable, positive effect on the per of social identity theory (e.g., Hogg 2001). In
ceived cohesion (Beta = .301,/?<.01) and the other this sense, they occupy a space between pure
results do not change significantly. This trend is con ly cognitive groups and groups with explicit
sistent with prior research (Lawler et al. 2000; Lawler goals and organized activities. In this article, we
and Yoon 1996). analyze how and when structural forms of
16 Also of note, the zero order correlations between exchange within networks promote the emer
giving in the first block of episodes and global emo gence of micro orders at the network level.
tions (measured at the end of this block) indicate
Social exchange theory developed in sociol
that giving behavior has a significant correlation
ogy as a decidedly micro tradition focused on
with positive emotions in productive exchange (r =
how individuals interact and, in particular, on the
.71,/? < .01), and the correlations in reciprocal (r =
.64, p < .01) and negotiated (r = .77,p < .001) are sim rewards they provide to each other. Social
ilar to those for productive exchange. However, with
a generalized exchange structure, the correlation of
giving behavior and positive emotions is not signif four episodes preceding the post questionnaire, and
icant (r = .24,/? = n.s.). Under generalized exchange, these results were generally consistent with the results
there is no evidence for an effect of exchange (giv for affective attachment?namely, perceptions of
ing) behavior on positive emotions. Finally, we con network cohesion had a significant effect on giving
ducted a regression with giving proportion in the rate in the last four episodes (Beta = .295, p < .01).

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
SOCIAL EXCHANGE AND MICRO SOCIAL ORDER 537

exchange theory adopts an instrumental view of value. The argument is fairly straightforward: To
the human actor and a transactional view of the degree that actors infer shared responsibil
social interaction (Blau 1964; Emerson 1972a, ity from the structures of interaction, social unit
1972b; Homans 1961; Molm and Cook 1995). attributions are likely and person-to-group
These simplifying assumptions about actors attachments should flourish and grow. The result
and interaction are a source of theoretical is more group-oriented cognition, affect, and
strength, in part, because they enhance the behavior than is implied by standard incentive
capacity of exchange theories to address or be or reward-based explanations.
integrated with macro-sociological traditions In this research, we applied these principles
or fields such as organizations (e.g., inter to four structural forms of social exchange
organizational ties), stratification (e.g., social found in the literature (Emerson 1972a, 1972b,
inequality), or economy and society (e.g., social 1981; Lawler 2001; Molm 1994; Molm and
embeddedness) (Cook et al. 2005; Nee and Cook 1995): productive, negotiated, recipro
Ingram 1998; Pfeffer 1981; Uzzi and Lancaster cal, and generalized. The main prediction from
2004). The affect theory of social exchange the affect theory is that the strength of a micro
(Lawler 2001, 2002) begins with a different social order will vary based on the degree that
model of human actors, arguing that people are the task involves nonseparable (indistinguish
feeling, affective beings who form expressive able) contributions and produces a high sense
attachments to relations and groups within of shared responsibility. Productive exchange
which they interact and exchange rewards. should thus yield the strongest micro social
Emotions are internal events that, in Bandura's order, whereas generalized should yield the
(1977) terms, are self-reinforcing, and in weakest micro order. Both negotiated and recip
exchange-theory terms, are internal, self-gen rocal exchange should fall in between produc
erated rewards or punishments. The affect the tive and generalized, and they do. Negotiated
ory essentially connects the instrumental and exchange, however, does not produce stronger
rational components of action, which are micro social order than reciprocal exchange as
assumed in the exchange tradition, to the emo we anticipated.
tional and expressive components assumed by Our results consistently support core predic
sociological theories of emotion (e.g., Collins tions, except for the lack of difference between
2004; Heise 1979; Ridgeway and Johnson 1990; the negotiated and reciprocal forms. First, as
Smith-Lovin and Heise 1988; Turner 2000, expected, productive exchange generated the
2002). highest rates of exchange, the strongest feelings
The unique and most fundamental question of pleasure, the greatest sense of network-level
posed by the affect theory of social exchange is: unity or cohesion, and the strongest affective
Under what conditions do actors attribute their attachments to the network as a group. Second,
emotional experiences to a social unit? The generalized exchange produced the lowest rates
social unit may be a relation, group, network, of these phenomena. Third, across time, per
firm, organization, community, or even a soci ceived network cohesion increased under pro
ety. The theory puts forth a general process that, ductive exchange but declined under generalized
in principle, should apply to any social unit of exchange, suggesting the potential of the former
import to the interactions of actors. The theory to naturally generate micro orders. Fourth, and
contends that actors are likely to attribute their as expected, the two direct forms of social
emotions to social units that organize or shape exchange?negotiated and reciprocal?were
those tasks, especially if the tasks or activities significantly different from and fell between
are jointly undertaken and accomplished. productive and generalized exchange on all of
Theoretically, these could be local, immediate the micro-order dimensions studied here. As a
units or larger and more distant units (see whole, the results reveal a strikingly consistent
Collins 2004; Lawler 1992; Turner 2002; Yoon pattern across all relevant dimensions or indi
and Thye 2002). In either case, social-unit attri cators of micro social order.
butions of emotion are important because they The finding that generalized exchange pro
strengthen person-to-group attachments and, duces the lowest proportion of giving behavior
insofar as these attachments have an emotion and the lowest perceived network cohesion is
al character, they make that unit an object of inconsistent with Ekeh's (1974) theorizing and

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
538 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

some related research on generalized exchange its most abstract form, such a spark is lacking.
(e.g., Bearman 1997; Molm et al. 2007; Future research should theorize and investigate
Yamagishi and Cook 1993). Repeated oppor the conditions under which generalized
tunities to exchange in the generalized structure exchange will generate weak versus strong
did not generate a high proportion of exchange micro orders.18
behavior (giving) among members (see Buchan, The individualist (Emerson 1972a; Homans
Croson, and Dawes [2002] for similar results in 1950,1961; Thibaut and Kelley 1959) and col
a one-shot exchange). Ekeh's (1974) collec lectivist approaches to social exchange make
tivist concept of exchange, however, presumes different assumptions about the initial conditions
a larger normative framework and extant person for social exchange. The key problem for the
to-group ties within which exchanges occur. collectivist approach is to understand the ties
This may explain why generalized exchange and connections between the "local" exchange
produced a weak micro order in our study. Our processes and a larger collective or institution
experiment removed such factors given that our al framework. Sustained exchange is not possi
intention was to compare the capacity of the four ble, or expected, without the larger exogenous
forms of exchange to generate person-to-group framework. The individualist approach (Blau
ties, endogenously. In the collectivist frame 1964; Emerson 1972a; Homans 1961; Thibaut
work, person-to-group ties are essentially reaf and Kelley 1959) makes simplified and rela
firmed or symbolized by local micro social tively sparse a priori assumptions about the
orders. In the individualist framework, person structural context within which exchange takes
to-group ties are an emergent "collective" result place. Relations and groups ostensibly are built
of a structure-interaction dynamic. In this vein, and sustained from the "ground up" by repeat
our research identifies a process by which indi ed social interactions (e.g., Homans 1950) made
vidualist conditions of exchange evolve toward possible by structural conditions. From our the
collectivist conditions. ory, exogenous effects operate through the
We suspect that for generalized exchange to shared-responsibility mechanism.
produce an emergent micro order, some form of The only departure from the theory's predic
exogenous "spark" or structural push is need tions is the lack of differences between negoti
ed. Theoretically possible candidates include ated and reciprocal exchange across the
(1) a common group identity or affiliation dimensions of micro order. Our prediction
(Tajfel and Turner 1986), (2) a norm of gener (negotiated > reciprocal) is based on the propen
alized reciprocity (Gouldner 1960; Nee and sity for negotiated exchange to produce a greater
Ingram 1998), (3) cultural beliefs that foster sense of shared responsibility compared with
generalized trust in others (Fukuyama 1995; reciprocal exchange. In Molm's theory, recip
Yamagishi, Cook, and Watabe 1998), (4) a sense rocal exchange has stronger effects than nego
of individual accountability or responsibility
(Fox and Guyer 1978; Jerdee and Rosen 1974),
or (5) a lack of opportunity cost associated with 18 An alternative to the "spark" hypothesis is that
giving behavior (see Molm et al. 2007).17 In this generalized exchange produces weaker micro social
regard, our experiment suggests that, compared order when the network ties entail null connections,

with other forms of exchange, the structural that is, people can interact or exchange with anyone
they are connected to. On the other hand, generalized
capacity of generalized exchange to generate
exchange produces stronger micro order when the
emergent orders is lower, probably because, in
networks are exclusively or negatively connected. In
the former (representing our study), people can
exchange with up to two others under negotiated and
17 Molm and colleagues (2007) report one exper reciprocal exchange but only one other under gen
imental condition on generalized exchange using a eralized exchange; whereas in the latter (represent
cost not unlike our default payoff. They find that the ing the research of Molm and colleagues), negotiated
rate of giving in generalized falls from .81 to .41 when and reciprocal exchange involve conflict because
giving involves a cost. This is consistent with the rate one party must be excluded. These structural condi
of giving we report here (M = .32) and also that tions could account for the differences between our
found in a recent replication (Triplett and Thye 2007) results for generalized exchange and those of Molm
of our generalized exchange condition (M = .27). and colleagues.

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
SOCIAL EXCHANGE AND MICRO SOCIAL ORDER 539

tiated because the salience of conflict is lower times (reciprocal). Generalized exchange
in the former and people make more positive involves a chain of unilateral acts of giving.
inferences about a partner who gives unilater Our research demonstrates that productive forms
ally as opposed to one who agrees to negotiat of exchange produce the strongest order at the
ed contract terms (Molm 2003a, 2003b). From micro level. Overall, our theory and research
our theory, the most plausible explanation is illuminate how structure-interaction dynamics
that the negotiated exchange condition did not can endogenously generate micro social orders
generate a greater sense of shared responsibil and self-collectivity ties that are affectively
ity. From Molm's theory, it is possible that nego based and infused with expressive value.
tiated and reciprocal exchanges did not differ
because the salience of conflict did not differ. Edward J. Lawler is the Martin P. Catherwood
Recall, however, that we have some evidence in Professor of Industrial and Labor Relations and
support of Molm's theory?namely, that recip Professor of Sociology at Cornell University and
series coeditor (with Professor Thye) <?/Advances in
rocal exchange produced more gratitude toward
Group Processes. His theory and research (mostly
exchange partners (and less anger) than did
with Professors Thye and Yoon) concern the role of
negotiated exchange. emotion in social exchange, in particular how and
Our interpretation is that "null" networks when micro social orders develop in exchange struc
substantially reduced the salience of conflict tures. They are completing a theoretical book on
difference between negotiated and reciprocal social commitments.
exchange because all actors can be included in
Shane R. Thye is a Professor of Sociology at the
all exchanges under both regimes. We thus University of South Carolina and series coeditor
found no differences in micro order between
(with Professor Lawler) of Advances in Group
negotiated and reciprocal exchange because the Processes. With Professors Lawler and Yoon he is
conditions for such effects, specified by either completing a book and conducting additional
theory, were not present. Neither shared respon research on the affective foundations of micro social
sibility nor the salience of conflict differed order. Professor Thye also is conducting research
across these conditions. This interpretation leads on his status value theory of power, economic mod
to the hypothesis that differences between nego els of discrimination using contestants 'voting behav
tiated and reciprocal exchange are contingent on ior from the reality television show Survivor, and
differences in either the salience of conflict or emotional determinants of criminal sentencing rec
ommendations. His research has been generously
perceptions of shared responsibility. If only the
funded by the National Science Foundation over the
former occurs, reciprocal forms of exchange past decade.
should generate stronger micro orders than
would negotiated exchange. If only the latter Jeongkoo Yoon is Professor in the School of Business
occurs, negotiated exchange should generate Administration at Ewha Woman s University, South
Korea. His research focuses on power and exchange
stronger micro orders than would reciprocal
theories, with particular application to empower
exchange. If there are differences along both
ment, leadership, and organizational change. His
dimensions, the impact of reciprocal versus recent research projects examine how group emotions
negotiated exchange is determined by the rela in work teams affect team performance and trans
tive importance or weight people accord these formation. He is completing a book (with Professors
differences.
Lawler and Thye) on how and when people develop
To summarize, this article shows how dif commitments to groups, organizations, communi
ferent forms of social interaction or exchange ties, and nations.
affect the emergence of a micro social order in
a social network. Each form of exchange entails REFERENCES
a distinct type of connection between the behav
iors at the heart of social exchange processes. Bandura, Albert. 1977. Social Learning Theory.
Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Productive exchange interweaves individual
Bearman, Peter. 1997. "Generalized Exchange."
behaviors to generate a collective joint product.
American Journal of Sociology 102(5): 1383-1415.
Direct forms of exchange either involve an Benford, Robert D. and David A. Snow. 2000.
explicit contract specifying what each actor is "Framing Processes and Social Movements: An
to give (negotiated) or an implicit contingency Overview and Assessment." Annual Review of
between unilateral acts of giving at different Sociology 26:611-39.

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
540 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Berger, Peter and Thomas Luckmann. 1967. Social Part I: A Psychological Basis for Social Exchange."
Construction of Reality. New York: Anchor Books. Pp. 38-57 in Sociological Theories in Progress,
Blau, Peter. 1964. Exchange and Power in Social edited by J. Berger, M. Zelditch Jr., and B.
Life. New York: Wiley. Anderson. Boston, MA: Houghton-Mifflin.
Brennan, John S. 1981. "Some Experimental-. 1972b. "Exchange Theory Part II:
Structures." Pp. 189-204 in Networks: Exchange Exchange Relations and Networks." Pp. 58-87 in
and Coercion, edited by D. Wilier and B. Anderson. Sociological Theories in Progress, edited by J.
New York: Elsevier/Greenwood. Berger, M. Zelditch Jr., and B. Anderson. Boston,
Brewer, Marilynn B. and Wendi Gardner. 1996. "Who MA: Houghton-Mifflin.
is this 'We?' Levels of Collective Identity and Self-. 1981. "Social Exchange Theory." Pp.
Representations." Journal of Personality and Social 30-65 in Social Psychology: Sociological
Psychology 71(l):83-93. Perspectives, edited by M. Rosenberg and R. H.
Buchan, Nancy R., Rachel Croson, and Robyn M. Turner. New York: Basic Books.
Dawes. 2002. "Swift Neighbors and Persistent Fox, John and Melvin Guyer. 1978. "'Public' Choice
Strangers: A Cross-Cultural Investigation of Trust and Cooperation in n-Person Prisoner's Dilemma."
and Reciprocity in Social Exchange." American The Journal of Conflict Resolution 22(3):469-81.
Journal of Sociology 108(1): 168-206. Fukuyama, Francis. 1995. Trust: The Social Virtues
Burke, Peter J. 1991. "Identity Processes and Social and the Creation of Prosperity. New York: Free
Stress." American Sociological Review Press.
56(6):836^9. Giddens, Anthony. 1984. The Constitution of Society:
Burt, Ronald S. 1978. "Cohesion Versus Structural Outline of the Theory of Structuration. Berkeley,
Equivalence as a Basis for Network Subgroups." CA: University of California Press.
Sociological Methods & Research 7(2): 189-212. Goffman, Irving. 1959. The Presentation of Self in
Clore, Gerald L., Norbert Schwarz, and Michael Everyday Life. New York: Doubleday.
Conway. 1994. "Affective Causes and Gouldner, Alvin W. 1960. "The Norm of Reciprocity:
Consequences of Social Information Processing." A Preliminary Statement." American Sociological
Pp. 323-^17 in Handbook of Social Cognition, Vol. Review 25(2): 161-78.
1, edited by R. S. Wyer and T. K. Srull. Hillsdale, Granovetter, Mark. 1985. "Economic Action and
NJ: Erlbaum. Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness."
Coleman, James S. 1990. Foundations of Social American Journal of Sociology 91:482-510.
Theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Hechter, Michael. 1987. Principles of Group
Press. Solidarity. Berkeley, CA: University of California
Collins, Randall. 2004. Interaction Ritual Chains. Press.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Heise, David R. 1979. Understanding Events: Affect
Cook, Karen S. 2005. "Networks, Norms, and Trust: and the Construction of Social Action. New York:
The Social Psychology of Social Capital." Social Cambridge University Press.
Psychology Quarterly 68(1):4?14. Hochschild, Arlie Russell. 1979. "Emotion Work,
Cook, Karen S. and Richard M. Emerson. 1978. Feeling Rules, and Social Structure." American
"Power, Equity and Commitment in Exchange Journal of Sociology 85(3):551-75.
Networks." American Sociological Review Hogg, Michael A. 2001. "Self-Categorization and
43(5):721-39. Subjective Uncertainty Resolution: Cognitive and
Cook, Karen S., Richard M. Emerson, Mary R. Motivational Facets of Social Identity and Group
Gillmore, and Toshio Yamagishi. 1983. "The Membership." Pp. 323^19 in The Social Mind:
Distribution of Power in Exchange Networks: Cognitive and Motivational Aspects of
Theory and Experimental Results." American Interpersonal Behavior, edited by J. P. Forgas, K.
Journal of Sociology 89(2):275-305. D. Williams, and L. Wheeler. New York:
Cook, Karen S., Russell Hardin, and Margaret Levi. Cambridge University Press.
2005. Cooperation Without Trust? New York: -. 2004. "Social Categorization, Depersonali
Russell Sage Foundation. zation, and Group Behavior." Pp. 202-31 in Self
Damasio, Antonio R. 1999. The Feeling of What and Social Identity, edited by M. B. Brewer and M.
Happens: Body and Emotion in the Making of Hewstone. Maiden, MA: Backwell Publishers.
Consciousness. New York: Harcourt Brace. Homans, George Caspar. 1950. The Human Group.
-. 2001. "Fundamental Feelings." Nature New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.
413:781. -. 1961. Social Behavior: Its Elementary
Durkheim, Emile. [1893] 1997. The Division of Forms. New York: Harcourt, Brace & World.
Labor in Society. New York: Free Press. Izard, Carroll E. 1991. The Psychology of Emotions.
Ekeh, Peter. 1974. Social Exchange Theory. New York: Plenum Press.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Jerdee, Thomas H. and Benson Rosen. 1974. "Effects
Emerson, Richard M. 1972a. "Exchange Theory of Opportunity to Communicate and Visibility of

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
SOCIAL EXCHANGE AND MICRO SOCIAL ORDER 541

Individual Decisions on Behavior in the Common Mysterious Underpinnings of Emotional Life. New
Interest." Journal of Applied Social Psychology York: Simon & Schuster.
59:712-16. Levi-Strauss, Claude. 1969. The Elementary
Jones, Edward E. and Keith E. Davis. 1965. "From Structures of Kinship. Boston, MA: Beacon Press.
Acts to Dispositions: The Attribution Process in Malinowski, Bronislaw. 1922. Argonauts of the
Person Perception." Pp. 219-66 in Advances in Western Pacific: An Account of Native Enterprise
Experimental Social Psychology, Vol. 2, edited by and Adventure in the Archipelagoes ofMelanesian
L. Berkowitz. New York: Academic Press. New Guinea. London, UK: Routledge.
Kelley, Harold H. 1967. "Attribution Theory in Social Markovsky, Barry, David Wilier, and Travis Patton.
Psychology." Pp. 220-66 in Nebraska Symposium 1988. "Power Relations in Exchange Networks."
on Motivation, Vol. 15, edited by D. Levine. American Sociological Review 53(2):220-36.
Lincoln, NE: University of Nebraska Press. Mead, George Herbert. 1934. Mind, Self, and Society.
Kemper, Theodore D. 1978. A Social Interactional Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Theory of Emotions. New York: Wiley. Mezulis, Amy, Lyn Y. Abramson, Janet S. Hyde, and
Kollock, Peter. 1994. "The Emergence of Exchange Benjamin L. Hankin. 2004. "Is There a Universal
Structures: An Experimental Study of Uncertainty, Positivity Bias in Attributions? A Meta-Analytic
Commitment, and Trust." American Journal of Review of Individual, Developmental, and Cultural
Sociology \00{2):2>U-A5. Differences in the Self-Serving Attributional Bias."
-. 1998. "Social Dilemmas: The Anatomy of Psychological Bulletin 130(5):711-47.
Cooperation." Annual Review of Sociology Molm, Linda D. 1994. "Dependence and Risk:
24:183-214.
Transforming the Structure of Social Exchange."
Lawler, Edward J. 1992. "Affective Attachments to
Social Psychology Quarterly 57(3): 163-76.
Nested Groups: A Choice-Process Theory." -. 2003a. "Theoretical Comparisons of Forms
American Sociological Review 57(3):327-36.
of Exchange." Sociological Theory 21(1): 1-17.
-. 2001. "An Affect Theory of Social -. 2003b. "Power, Trust, and Fairness:
Exchange." American Journal of Sociology 107(2):
Comparisons of Negotiated and Reciprocal
321-52.
-. 2002. "Micro Social Orders." Social Exchange." Pp. 31-66 in Advances in Group
Processes: Power and Status, Vol. 20, edited by S.
Psychology Quarterly 65(1):4?17.
R. Thye and J. Skvoretz. Oxford, UK: Elsevier.
-. 2006. "Exchange, Affect, and Group
Molm, Linda D., Jessica L. Collett, and David R.
Relations." Pp. 177-202 in George C. Homans:
Schaefer. 2006. "Conflict and Fairness in Social
History, Theory, and Method, edited by A. J.
Exchange." Social Forces 84:2331-52.
Trevino. Boulder, CO: Paradigm Publishers.
Lawler, Edward J. and Shane R. Thye. 1999.
-. 2007. "Building Solidarity through
Generalized Exchange: A Theory of Reciprocity."
"Bringing Emotions into Social Exchange Theory."
American Journal of Sociology 113(l):205-42.
Annual Review of Sociology 25:217-44.
-. 2006. "Social Exchange TheoryMolm,
of Linda D. and Karen S. Cook. 1995. "Social
Exchange and Exchange Networks." Pp. 209-35
Emotions." Pp. 295-320 in Handbook of the
in Sociological Perspectives on Social Psychology,
Sociology of Emotions, edited by J. E. Stets and J.
H. Turner. New York: Springer. edited by K. S. Cook, G. A. Fine, and J. S. House.
Lawler, Edward J., Shane R. Thye, and Jeongkoo Boston, MA: Allyn and Bacon.
Yoon. 2000. "Emotion and Group Cohesion in Molm, Linda D., Gretchen Peterson, and Nobuyuki
Productive Exchange." American Journal of Takahashi. 1999. "Power in Negotiated and
Sociology 106(3):616-57. Reciprocal Exchange." American Sociological
-. 2006. "Commitment in Structurally Review 64(6):876-90.
Molm, Linda D., Nobuyuki Takahashi, and Gretchen
Enabled and Induced Exchange Relations." Social
Psychology Quarterly 69(2): 183-200.
Peterson. 2000. "Risk and Trust in Social
Exchange: An Experimental Test of a Classical
Lawler, Edward J. and Jeongkoo Yoon. 1993. "Power
Proposition." American Journal of Sociology
and the Emergence of Commitment Behavior in
Negotiated Exchange." American Sociological105(5): 1396-1427.
Review 5%(A)-A65-%\. Moody, James and Douglas R. White. 2003.
-. 1996. "Commitment in Exchange
"Structural Cohesion and Embeddedness: A
Relations: Test of a Theory of Relational
Hierarchical Concept of Social Groups."^merican
Cohesion." American Sociological Review Sociological Review 68(1): 103-27.
61(1):89-108. Nee, Victor and Paul Ingram. 1998. "Embeddedness
-. 1998. "Network Structure and Emotion and
in Beyond: Institutions, Exchange, and Social
Exchange Relations." American Sociological
Structure." Pp. 19-^45 in New Institutionalism in
Review 63(6):%1\-9A. Sociology, edited by M. C. Brinton and V Nee.
LeDoux, Joseph E. 1996. The Emotional Brain: The
New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
542 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Parsons, Talcott. 1951. The Social System. Glencoe,-. 2000b. "Reliability in Experimental
IL: Free Press. Sociology." Social Forces 78(4): 1277-1309.
Pfeffer, Jeffrey. 1981. Power in Organizations. Thye, Shane R., Michael J. Lovaglia, and Barry
Marshfield, MA: Pitman Publishing. Markovsky. 1997. "Responses to Social Exchange
Prentice, Deborah A., Dale T. Miller, and Jenifer R. and Social Exclusion in Networks." Social Forces
Lightdale. 1994. "Asymmetries in Attachments to 75(3): 1031-47.
Groups and to Their Members: Distinguishing Thye, Shane R., Jeongkoo Yoon, and Edward J.
Between Common-Identity and Common-Bond Lawler. 2002. "The Theory of Relational Cohesion:
Groups." Personality and Social Psychology Review of a Research Program." Pp 89-102 in
Bulletin 20(5):484-93.
Advances in Group Process, Vol. 19, edited by S.
Ridgeway, Cecilia L. and Cathryn Johnson. 1990.
R. Thye and E. J. Lawler. Oxford, UK: Elsevier.
"What Is the Relationship between Socioemotional
Triplett, Jenny and Shane R. Thye. 2007. "Eliciting
Behavior and Status in Task Groups?" American
Cooperation in Generalized Exchange: The Impact
Journal of Sociology 95(5): 1189-1212.
of Social Identity and Non-anonymity." The Annual
Scheff, Thomas J. 1990. Microsociology: Discourse,
Emotion and Social Structure. Chicago, IL:
Meetings of the American Sociological
Association, New York, NY.
University of Chicago Press.
Turner, Ralph H. 1978. "The Role and the Person."
Simmel, Georg. 1964. The Sociology of Georg
Simmel. Edited by K. H. W. Wolff. Glencoe, IL: American Journal of Sociology 84(1): 1-23.
The Free Press. Turner, Jonathan H. 2000. On the Origins of Human
Skvoretz, John and Michael J. Lovaglia. 1995. "Who Emotions. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Exchanges with Whom: Structural Determinants -. 2002. Face to Face: Toward a Sociological
of Exchange Frequency in Negotiated Exchange Theory of Interpersonal Behavior. Stanford, CA:
Networks." Social Psychology Quarterly Stanford University Press.
58(3): 163-77. Uzzi, Brian and Ryon Lancaster. 2004.
Smith-Lovin, Lynn and David R. Heise, eds. 1988. "Embeddedness and Price Formation in the
Analyzing Social Interaction: Advances in Affect Corporate Law Market." American Sociological
Control Theory. New York: Gordon and Breach Review 6%2>)'319^44.
Science Publishers. Weiner, Bernhard. 1986. An Attributional Theory of
Stolte, John and Richard M. Emerson. 1977. Motivation and Emotion. New York: Springer.
"Structural Inequality: Position and Power in Wilier, David. 1999. Network Exchange Theory.
Network Structures." Pp. 117-38 in Behavioral Westport, CT: Praeger Publisher.
Theory in Sociology, edited by R. L. Hamblin and Wilier, David and Bo Anderson. 1981. Networks,
J. H. Kunkel. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Exchange and Coercion: The Elementary Theory
Books. and Its Applications. New York: Elsevier.
Stolte, John, Gary Alan Fine, and Karen S. Cook. Williamson, Oliver E. 1985. The Economic
2001. "Sociological Miniaturism: Seeing the Big Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets,
through the Small in Social Psychology." Annual Relational Contracting. New York: Free Press.
Review of Sociology 27:387^*13. Yamagishi, Toshio and Karen S. Cook. 1993.
Stryker, Sheldon. 1980. Symbolic Interactionism: A "Generalized Exchange and Social Dilemmas."
Social Structural Version. Menlo Park, CA:
Social Psychology Quarterly 56(4):235-48.
Benjamin/Cummings Publisher.
Yamagishi, Toshio, Karen S. Cook, and Motoki
Swedberg, Richard. 2003. Principles of Economic
Watabe. 1998. "Uncertainty, Trust, and
Sociology. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Commitment Formation in the United States and
Press.
Tajfel, Henri and John C. Turner. 1986. "The Social
Japan." American Journal of Sociology
Identity Theory of Intergroup Behavior." Pp. 7-24
104(l):165-94.
in Psychology of Intergroup Relations, edited by Yamagishi, Toshio and Midori Yamagishi. 1994.
"Trust and Commitment in the United States and
S. Worchel and W. G. Austin. Chicago, IL: Nelson
Hall. Japan." Motivation and Emotion 18(2): 129-66.
Thibaut, John W. and Harold H. Kelley. 1959. The Yoon, Jeongkoo and Shane R. Thye. 2000.
Social Psychology of Groups. New York: Wiley. "Supervisor Support in the Work Place: Legitimacy
Thoits, Peggy A. 1989. "The Sociology of Emotions." and Positive Affectivity." Journal of Social
Annual Review of Sociology 15:311-42. Psychology 140(3):295-316.
Thye, Shane R. 2000a. "A Status Value Theory of -. 2002. "A Dual Process Model of
Power in Exchange Relations." American Organizational Commitment." Work and
Sociological Review 65:407-32. Occupations 29(1):97-124.

This content downloaded from 200.3.193.134 on Thu, 14 Sep 2017 16:45:18 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi