Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 18

Payroll Taxation in Canada:

An Overview
Livio Di Matteo
Michael Shannon*
Department of Economics
Lakehead University

D espite constituting the third most im-


portant source of revenue for Canadian
governments, payroll taxes receive relatively
Payroll Taxes in
Canada
little attention. This is particularly surprising
on two counts: first, there are important con- The federal and provincial governments im-
troversies regarding the employment effects pose payroll taxes with levies on both employ-
of these taxes and, second, payroll taxes ers and employees. The federal government
have grown substantially over the last 30 taxes employers and employees to finance un-
years and are likely to continue to increase in employment insurance and pensions. Prov-
the future. inces tax employers to fund workers com-
pensation and, more recently, health care and
Payroll taxes rose from 2.9 per cent of total education; Quebec levies both employers and
government revenue in 1965 to 12.9 per cent employees for its own pension plan.
in 1993. As a share of total labour income,
they increased from 1.9 per cent in 1961 to Over the last 30 years, the proportion of total
10.3 per cent in 1992. Payments for the three government revenue accounted for by payroll
major programs funded through payroll taxes taxes has quadrupled (Table 1). The average
Unemployment Insurance, the Canada and payroll tax rate (as a percentage of total labour
Quebec Pension Plans, and provincial work- income) rate jumped dramatically in 1966
ers compensation rose from 3.6 per cent of with the onset of the Canada and Quebec Pen-
GDP in 1985 to 5.1 per cent in 1992. sion Plans (C/QPP) and has risen steadily
ever since (Figure 1).
The goals of this article are to provide a com-
prehensive overview of payroll taxation, to Employer contribution rates for C/QPP and
consider its future direction, and to discuss its Unemployment Insurance (UI) have risen
potential impacts. We begin by outlining the substantially in recent years (Table 2). The
current state of payroll taxation in Canada, rate applied to contributable earnings for
chronicling its recent growth as a revenue C/QPP was 1.8 per cent for both employees
source. We also consider the range of mar- and employers from 1966 to 1986. Since then,
ginal payroll tax rates across provinces and they have risen 0.1 percentage points per year,
use earnings distribution data to determine reaching 2.6 per cent in 1994. These rates are
the groups facing the highest payroll tax rates. levied on wage and salary earnings between
We then discuss anticipated future trends. maximum pensionable earnings ($34,400 in
Following this, the impact of payroll taxation 1994) and the basic exemption ($3,400 in
on wages and employment is considered. We 1994).
conclude that these taxes do have a negative UI premiums are charged on earnings below
impact on employment; however, there are a a weekly maximum ($815 in 1994) which is
wide range of estimates as to the size of this linked to changes in the average industrial
effect. wage over an eight-year period. The employer
rate is 1.4 times that for employees.1 Under
current arrangements, those working less

Summer 1995 Canadian Business Economics 5


Figure 1 Payroll Taxes as a Percentage of butions to the UI fund from general reve-
Labour Income nues.2 Current premium levels are more than
Per cent three times higher than they were in 1966.
12
There have also been significant cyclical
10
movements in UI premium rates around the
upward trend. Premiums peaked following
8 the recession of the early 1980s, declining
once the debt accrued during the recession
6 had been paid off. Rates rose once again with
the recession of the early 1990s in order to meet
4
the growing cumulative deficit in the fund.
2 Workers compensation is financed by pro-
vincial levies on employer payrolls below a
0
26 29 32 35 38 41 44 47 50 53 56 59 62 65 68 71 74 77 80 83 86 89 92
specified maximum earnings per employee.
The tax or assessment rate applied to this base
Source: Canadian Economic Observer, Kesselman (1994). varies across industry rate groups.3 These
Notes: Payroll Taxes are defined as total contributions to Workers
Compensation, CPP/QPP and UI and Provincial Payroll Taxes for
rates are generally set at levels sufficient to
Health & Education. Labour income is wages, salaries and cover the projected costs of accidents incurred
supplementary labour income. by the rate group in each year. Additional sur-
charges may be added to cover costs of past
than 15 hours per week who earn below 20 unfunded accidents. Average rates have risen
per cent of the weekly maximum are exempt. substantially in several provinces (Table 2).
As Table 2 indicates, UI premiums have fol- No province experienced a fall in its average
lowed an upward trend since 1966. This re- assessment rate between 1966 and 1994.
flects rising unemployment, increases in self- Quebec, Manitoba, Newfoundland, and On-
financing requirements due to the generosity tario also levy additional payroll taxes to help
of benefits and, since 1990, the end of contri- finance health care and/or postsecondary

Table 1 Trends in Payroll Taxes as a Percentage of Total Government Revenue1


Canada/
Unemployment Workers Quebec Provincial
Year Insurance Compensation Pension Payroll Taxes2 All
1950 2.3 1.2 - - 3.5
1955 2.2 1.0 - - 3.2
1960 2.5 1.1 - - 3.6
1965 1.9 1.0 - - 2.9
1970 1.5 0.8 3.3 0.1 5.7
1975 3.0 1.2 3.0 0.3 7.5
1980 2.7 1.3 3.0 0.5 7.5
1985 4.6 1.4 3.0 0.9 9.9
1990 4.6 1.7 3.5 1.9 11.7
1992 5.9 1.6 3.8 1.8 13.1
1993 5.8 1.3 3.9 1.8 12.9
Sources: Canadian Tax Foundation (1993); Kesselman (1994); data from Statistics Canada.
1 Includes all three levels of government.
2 Refers to provincial payroll taxes brought in by Quebec, Manitoba, Ontario, and Newfoundland to finance health and
education.

6 Canadian Business Economics Summer 1995


education4. In Ontario, the Employer Health per cent. Now Quebec also has a business sur-
Levy was introduced in 1990. It is applied at a tax on the payroll tax which stands at 15 per
graduated rate to total annual gross wages, cent of the payroll tax. In 1994, the effective
salaries, and other remuneration paid by the payroll tax rate was 3.75 per cent.
employer. In 1994, the rate was 0.98 per cent Newfoundland brought in its payroll tax in
up to a $200,000 annual payroll, and rose to a 1990 to fund health care and postsecondary
maximum of 1.95 per cent for payrolls over education. It was imposed at a rate of 1.5 per
$400,000. cent on payrolls in excess of $300,000. In
Manitoba introduced a payroll tax in 1982. 1992, the commercial property tax for schools
The initial tax rate was 0.75 per cent, which was replaced by broadening the base for the
rose to 2 per cent in 1987; however, the payroll payroll tax. The exemption was lowered from
exemption was also increased from $50,000 to $300,000 to $100,000 of the annual payroll
$100,000. A payroll tax credit introduced in and the rate was increased from 1.5 to 2 per
1991 can reduce the rate by up to 0.3 per cent cent. The fishery, agricultural, and forestry in-
for firms with qualifying training costs. dustries which were originally exempted,
Quebecs payroll tax was introduced with its now are taxed at 1 per cent.
Medicare plan in 1970 at an original rate of 0.8

Table 2 Payroll Tax Rates, Workers Compensation Average Assessment Rates, Employer
UI and C/QPP Premiums, Provincial Payroll Taxes, 1966-941
Workers Compensation Average Assessment Rates Other Payroll Tax Rates
Provincial Taxes
CPP/
Nfld. P.E.I. N.S. N.B. Que. Ont. Man. Sask. Alta. B.C. UI2 QPP3 Que. Man. Ont.4 Nfld.
1966 1.62 n.a. 1.16 1.97 1.39 1.23 0.67 1.53 1.44 1.30 1.33 1.80 0 0 0 0

1971 1.62 n.a. 1.15 1.54 1.09 1.19 1.06 0.93 1.32 1.38 1.5 1.80 0.8 0 0 0

1976 1.42 n.a. 1.18 1.48 1.86 1.75 1.10 2.21 1.47 1.83 2.31 1.80 1.15 0 0 0

1981 1.49 2.44 1.26 1.38 2.10 1.66 0.89 1.31 1.60 2.52 2.52 1.80 2.63 0 0 0

1986 1.79 1.32 1.19 1.77 2.04 2.59 1.67 1.37 1.59 2.19 3.29 1.80 3.11 1.50 0 0

1991 2.92 1.95 1.66 2.04 2.32 3.20 2.25 1.63 1.85 1.82 3.54 2.30 3.55 2.25 .98/ 1.50
1.95
1992 3.00 2.00 1.98 2.13 2.50 3.16 2.16 1.65 1.98 2.02 4.20 2.40 3.75 2.25 .98/ 1.75
1.95
1993 3.23 2.22 2.28 2.19 2.75 2.95 2.16 1.60 2.04 2.16 4.20 2.50 3.75 2.25 .98/ 2.00
1.95
1994 3.18 2.07 2.54 2.15 2.75 3.01 2.12 1.67 2.13 2.42 4.30 2.60 3.75 2.25 .98/ 2.00
1.95
Sources: Association of Workers Compensation Boards of Canada; Kesselman (1994); Statistics Canada, Unemployment Insurance Statistics,
Health and Welfare Canada (1986).
1. In years where rates changed an average is reported.
2. Since 1971 this is 1.4 times the rate paid by employees. Pre-1971, employers and employees paid matching contributions which varied
with earnings.
3. Employees pay a matching rate. The 1994 Workers Compensation Assesment Rates are preliminary.
4. Rate varies by payroll size.

Summer 1995 Canadian Business Economics 7


Table 3 Payroll Tax Rates by Province: Employer Contributions Only
Nfld. P.E.I. N. S. N.B. Que. Ont.1 Man. Sask. Alta. B.C.

1966 4.75 n.a 4.29 5.10 4.52 4.36 3.80 4.66 4.57 4.43
1971 4.92 n.a. 4.45 4.84 5.19 4.49 4.36 4.23 4.62 4.68
1976 5.53 n.a 5.29 5.59 7.12 5.86 5.21 6.32 5.58 5.94
1981 5.81 6.76 5.58 5.70 9.05 5.98 5.21 5.63 5.92 6.84
1986 6.88 6.41 6.28 6.86 10.24 7.68 8.26 6.46 6.68 7.28
1991 8.76 7.79 7.50 7.88 11.70 10.99 10.34 7.47 7.69 7.66
1992 9.60 8.60 8.58 8.73 12.85 11.71 11.01 8.25 8.58 8.62
1993 9.93 8.92 8.98 8.89 13.20 11.60 11.11 8.30 8.74 8.86
1994 10.08 8.97 9.44 9.05 13.40 11.86 11.27 8.57 9.03 9.32

1. Ontario uses 1.95 as the rate of the Provincial payroll tax for 1987-1993.

Table 4 Marginal Payroll Tax Rates, 1991


Nfld. P.E.I. N.S. N.B. Que. Ont. Man. Sask. Alta. B.C.

Employer Rates Only


Under CPP 10.26 7.79 7.50 7.88 11.70 10.99 10.33 7.47 7.69 7.66
maximum*
Under UI 8.16 5.69 5.40 5.78 9.60 8.89 8.24 5.37 5.59 5.56
maximum
(over CPP)
Under WC 9.45 1.95 1.66 2.04 5.87 5.15 4.5 1.63 1.85 1.82
maximum
(over UI, CPP)
Above all 1.5 0 0 0 3.55 1.95 2.25 0 0 0
ceilings
Combined Employer and Employee Rates
Under CPP 15.08 12.61 12.32 12.7 16.53 15.81 15.16 12.29 12.51 12.48
maximum1
Under UI 12.98 10.51 10.22 10.6 14.43 13.71 13.06 10.19 10.41 10.38
maximum
(over CPP)
Under WC 4.42 1.95 1.66 2.04 5.87 5.15 4.5 1.63 1.85 1.82
maximum
(over UI, CPP)
Above all 1.5 0 0 0 3.55 1.95 2.25 0 0 0
ceilings

1. Above CPP minimum insurable earnings and with sufficient hours and earnings to be covered by UI.

8 Canadian Business Economics Summer 1995


The combined employer payroll tax rates the (annual) UI ceiling of $35,360 and conse-
from 1966 to 1994 are reported for each prov- quently had marginal rates equal to the sum
ince in Table 3. In most provinces, these rates of all tax rates excluding C/QPP. Workers
doubled or even tripled during the period. In compensation ceilings vary by province. In
1994, Quebec had the highest combined em- 1991, about 20 per cent of workers in most
ployer rate, at 13.4 per cent (compared to 3.13 provinces were paid more than the workers
per cent in 1966). The lowest rate was in Sas- compensation ceiling and consequently had
katchewan (8.57 per cent in 1994 compared to the lowest possible marginal payroll tax rate.
4.66 per cent in 1966).5 This minimum rate equaled the provincial
payroll tax rate (or 0 per cent in provinces
with no provincial payroll tax). In summary,
Impacts of Payroll about 20 per cent of workers faced the mini-
Taxes on Different mum marginal rate and 64 per cent faced the
maximum.
Employee Groups Data from the 1989 Labour Market Activity
Since economic models typically focus on Survey (LMAS) provide a similar picture. Be-
decisions at the margin, marginal payroll tax tween 63 per cent and 66 per cent of workers
rates are most relevant in evaluating the im- had earnings below the 1989 C/QPP ceiling of
pacts of these taxes. Marginal payroll tax rates $27,700.7 Estimates from the LMAS indicate
differ from the tax rates reported in Tables 3 that 55-58 per cent faced the maximum mar-
(plus employee contributions) because UI, ginal rate. Another 4-6 per cent were between
C/QPP, and workers compensation apply UI and C/QPP ceilings and 82-84 per cent were
only to earnings below a specified maximum below the workers compensation cutoff.
and because of our use of an average assess-
ment rate for workers compensation.6
The ceilings for UI, C/QPP, and workers Table 5 Percentage of
compensation, above which no tax is Employees Above
charged, mean that the marginal (and aver- Earnings Ceilings, 1991
age) tax rates will eventually fall as a workers
earnings rise. In 1991, for example, the maxi- Per Cent
mum marginal combined employer tax rate Earnings Above
for an Ontario worker was 10.99 per cent for Ceiling Maximum
those paid less than $30,500 who were UI in- CPP $30,500 35.9
surable. This fell to 8.89 per cent for those
earning between $30,500 and $35,360 (i.e., UI1 $35,360 28.0
those whose additional wage income was tax- Workers Compensation
able under all payroll taxes except C/QPP),
then to 5.15 per cent for those earning be- Nfld. $45,500 9.0
tween $35,360 and $42,000 (above the UI PEI. $25,000 29.1
maximum insurable earnings), and finally to
1.95 per cent for those earning more than N.S. $37,300 19.9
$42,000. Marginal rates by earnings level for N.B. $36,000 19.3
each province in 1991 are reported in Table 4.
Table 5 draws upon 1991 data on Canada Ont. $42,000 21.1
Pension Plan contributors to show the distri- Man. $38,000 17.5
bution of the workforce (excluding Quebec)
by marginal rate level. The annual payroll tax Sask. $39,000 17.5
ceiling for C/QPP was $30,500; in 1991, 64 per Alta. $40,000 21.2
cent of workers had earnings below this level
and consequently faced the maximum possi- BC. $45,800 16.5
ble marginal payroll tax rate (assuming they Source: Based on data from Health and Welfare
were all UI insurable). Another 7.9 per cent Canada (1991).
had earnings between the C/QPP ceiling and 1. Full-year equivalent

Summer 1995 Canadian Business Economics 9


The LMAS dataset can be used to determine province to province, largely because of dif-
the composition of the groups facing different ferences in financial circumstances. Data col-
marginal tax levels and, consequently, it indi- lected by the Financial Executives Institute of
cates where the impacts of the taxes are likely Canada (1995) for 1993 show that Saskatche-
greatest. As Table 6 indicates, the proportion wan ran a surplus while its pension liabilities
of those facing the top marginal rate is rela- were actually overfunded (Table 7). Three
tively high for women, young workers, the other provinces had surpluses but had plans
less educated, and those in the Atlantic Prov- with unfunded liabilities. Six provinces had
inces. Those employed in non-union jobs, deficits in 1993; of these, Ontario, Quebec,
with small employers, in the retail trade and and Nova Scotia also had substantial un-
service industries (especially accommodation funded liabilities.
and food), and in clerical, sales, or service oc- These financial positions suggest that as-
cupations are all substantially more likely to sessment rates in Ontario, Quebec, and Nova
be at the top rate than the average worker. In Scotia may have to rise substantially in the fu-
short, the low-wage sectors face the highest ture. In fact, since 1984, Ontarios assessment
marginal tax rates because of tax ceilings. It is rates have included a surcharge intended to
the workers in these sectors who bear the amortize the unfunded liability by 2014. The
brunt of these taxes8 Workers Compensation Board of Ontario
(1992) suggested that its financial position
Future Payroll Tax would require the average assessment rate to
rise to 3.98 per cent by 1996 and remain at
Trends that level for the rest of the amortization pe-
In this section, we consider whether the up- riod. However, because of the slow economic
ward trend in payroll tax rates is likely to con- recovery in Ontario since the 1990-91 reces-
tinue. Each tax is examined in turn. sion, the assessable payroll has not grown as
fast as projected and the post-1995 rate is now
Canada Pension Plan likely to be higher than the 3.98 per cent tar-
The increases in the C/QPP rates which get.9. Assuming a sustained one per cent rise
have occurred since 1986 are part of a in average assessment rates seems reasonable
planned long-term rate increase required to for Ontario. The problem is less severe in the
maintain the viability of the plan. The rate other two provinces with large unfunded li-
schedule projected sees combined employer- abilities and their required rate increases are
employee rates rising gradually from 5.4 per likely to be smaller than those in Ontario.10
cent in 1995 to 12.80 per cent in 2021 (Cana- The other two provinces with deficits, British
dian Institute of Actuaries, 1993). Columbia and Prince Edward Island, may
While this projection suggests substantial fu- also require rate increases but, given their
ture rate increases, it is not certain that this relatively small unfunded liabilities, the re-
rate schedule will actually be realized. At one quired increases could be quite small or sim-
level, the projection is based upon assump- ply temporary. Some rate reductions may
tions regarding future growth in wages and eventually be possible in those provinces run-
salaries, life expectancy, and other variables, ning surpluses; however, Alberta, New
which are themselves uncertain. At a more Brunswick, and Newfoundland do have sub-
fundamental level, the projection assumes stantial unfunded liabilities and rates may not
that program benefit levels and eligibility will come down for some time. Only Saskatche-
remain the same. Less drastic rate increases wan appears to be in a position to immedi-
would be required if the program were to be ately reduce rates.11
judged too costly, with the result that substan-
tial reductions in benefits and eligibility oc-
Unemployment Insurance
curred. Unemployment insurance premiums are
currently at a cyclical high and can be ex-
Workers Compensation pected to fall as the debt accrued during the
The likely course of future workers compen- last recession is paid off and a cumulative sur-
sation assessments varies substantially from plus accumulates. The combined employer-

10 Canadian Business Economics Summer 1995


Table 6 Percentage of Employees at the Maximum Payroll Tax Rate
by Selected Characteristic, 1989
All Employees 58.7
Men 47.4
Women 71.9
Age
16-24 72.2
25-34 61.3
35-44 48.7
45-54 52.6
55-64 54.2
Province
Newfoundland 67.2
Prince Edward Island 76.3
Nova Scotia 65.3
New Brunswick 67.2
Quebec 62.9
Ontario 55.6
Manitoba 63.9
Saskatchewan 62.6
Alberta 57.4
British Columbia 53.0
Education
Less than 8 years 69.0
Some secondary 63.5
High School 66.3
Some Post-secondary 63.9
Post-secondary Certificate 55.8
University Degree 38.0
Trades certificate 56.4
Employment Status
Full-time 57.9
Part-time 62.4

Summer 1995 Canadian Business Economics 11


Union Status
Union 50.2
Non-union 63.3
Industry
Primary 52.3
Manufacturing 53.8
Construction 57.3
Transportation, Communications and 43.1
other Utilities
Trade 68.2
Finance 64.0
Services 63.3
Public administration 47.4
Occupation
Managerial/ Professional 45.3
Clerical 75.9
Sales 64.3
Service 70.5
Primary 61.7
Processing 56.3
Metals, Machining 49.4
Product Fabrication 66.1
Mechanics/Repair 41.7
Construction 52.3
Transport 52.7
Material Handling/ Craft 57.9
Firm Size (Number of employees)
Less than 20 70.2
20-99 64.6
100-499 58.5
500 or more 48.1

Source: Based on Labour Market Activity Survey data.

12 Canadian Business Economics Summer 1995


employee rate is currently projected to fall Naturally, if more cuts are made to UI bene-
from 7.2 per cent in 1995 to 6.72 per cent in fits, and these savings are used to reduce pre-
1996 and 5.28 per cent in 1997 (Freeman, miums, then payroll taxes will fall further. Hu-
1995). This projected rate decline is slower man Resources Development Canada (1994)
than that which would have occurred if the has provided estimates of savings under a va-
1995 federal budget had not required the fund riety of reforms to UI. The elimination of Re-
to build a cumulative surplus of $5 billion gional Extended Benefits would provide the
prior to the next downturn rather than merely single largest saving of the options costed
eliminate the cumulative debt.12 Rates are ($4.5 billion). This would reduce combined
also unlikely to return to pre-recession lows employer-employee premiums by 1.63 per-
due to changes in financing made in 1990 centage points. This is likely an upper bound
which eliminated general revenue contribu- as it assumes the largest possible cuts and that
tions to the UI fund. Through the 1980s, the the savings are realized to their full extent as
share of UI benefits funded out of general premium reductions. It should be noted that
revenues was roughly 25 per cent (Employ- there could be other competing uses for these
ment and Immigration Canada, various savings, including new labour adjustment or
years). income support programs.
Since all costs must now be covered by pre-
miums, this change in financing will lead to a Provincial Payroll Taxes
substantial, permanent upward shift in pre- Substantial provincial debt (estimated at
miums. However, this upward pressure will $155 billion in 1994) will likely create pres-
be partly offset by cuts to benefits made in sure for new payroll taxes or for further rises
1993 and 1994. The present combined rate of in existing ones. Adding to these pressures are
7.37 per cent stands out markedly compared the cuts to federal transfers brought about by
to the pre-recession low of 4.35 per cent. Add- the replacement of the Established Program
ing 25 per cent to the latter figure (i.e., the for- Financing and the Canada Assistance Plan
mer general revenue contribution) suggests with the Canada Social and Health Transfer,
that rates could fall as low as 5.44 per cent, as announced in the 1995 federal budget.
which is near the currently projected 1997 Payroll taxes may be an attractive source of
rate. This may prove to be the new rate floor. additional revenue from a political perspec-
Table 7 Financial Positions of the Workers Compensation Boards,
1993
(millions of dollars)

Deficit/Surplus Unfunded Liability Assessable Payroll


Newfoundland 16 -119 2,921
Prince Edward -1 -10 547
Island
Nova Scotia -12 -461 4,640
New Brunswick 17 -66 N.A.
Quebec -65 -3,516 61,900
Ontario -504 -11,532 83,423
Manitoba 19 -72 5,856
Saskatchewan 4 62 6,860
Alberta 299 -277 23,010
British Columbia -94 -191 37,523

Source: Financial Executives of Canada Institute (1995)

Summer 1995 Canadian Business Economics 13


tive. Witness, for example, the relatively Summary
muted response to the introduction of the Em-
In conclusion, it seems likely that the long-
ployer Health Tax in Ontario in 1990, com-
term upward trend in payroll tax rates will
pared to the introduction of the Goods and
continue. This will be driven by rising C/QPP
Services Tax a year later. The existing provin-
contribution rates and reinforced by increases
cial taxes are nominally earmarked for par-
in other payroll taxes, particularly increases in
ticular expenditures (health in Ontario and
workers compensation assessments in some
Quebec, and health and education in Mani-
provinces. A possible source of relief is unem-
toba and Newfoundland). This makes it
ployment insurance, with premiums declin-
tempting to argue that pressure for rises in
ing as the expansion continues, as the debt in-
these taxes may be created by increases in
curred during the last recession is paid off,
health spending, as the population continues
and as UI benefits are cut and eligibility re-
to age. However, it is probably more accurate
quirements tightened. The combined effects
to view these taxes as just another source of
of falling unemployment and UI reform could
general revenue and, therefore, to think of fu-
more than offset rises in other payroll taxes in
ture trends as being tied to the provinces
the near term. However, as the economy
overall fiscal situation.
moves through the business cycle, UI premi-
Quebec will have a new one per cent payroll ums will stabilize and then rise, while C/QPP
tax in 1996 to raise funds for training. Levy- premiums will continue to climb, with the re-
grant schemes to fund training, which typi- sult that the overall payroll tax rate will prob-
cally use a payroll tax as the levy, have also ably increase.
been discussed as a possibility for Ontario in
the recent past although this may end with the
recent change in government. The Impact of Payroll
Moreover, relative to most types of taxation, Taxation
a major attraction of payroll taxes is their rela-
tively low cost of administration and compli- Economist and Business
ance. Once the tax is in place and the collec- Views
tion mechanisms established, raising further In simple economic models, a payroll tax
revenues from rate increases is a relatively levied on employers lowers labour demand,
simple matter. Ontario, for example, reported inducing a decline in wages which will par-
that for the fiscal year 1992-93, the adminis- tially or, if labour supply is perfectly inelastic,
trative costs of its payroll taxes amounted to wholly offset the effects of the tax on employ-
0.38 percent of the associated tax revenues ment.15 Alternatively, a payroll tax levied on
which are substantially lower than for most employees will decrease labour supply, lead-
other taxes (Kesselman, 1994: 182).13 ing to an increase in wages which will again
Another attraction of payroll taxation for pro- counter the initial effects of the tax on em-
vincial governments is the ability to shift ployment. In either case, the employers wage
some of the tax burden onto the federal gov- costs (tax inclusive) will rise while the net-of-
ernment. This effect operates through two tax wage received by workers will fall. Em-
channels. First, federal employees and agen- ployment will decline in either case (if neither
cies pay provincial payroll taxes in an effort to curve is perfectly inelastic) but no unemploy-
be consistent with other employers even ment will be generated by the tax since work-
though, technically speaking, the Crown is ers will remain on their labour supply curve
immune from taxation. Second, for federal in- and choose to work less at the lower net-of-
come tax purposes, incorporated and unin- tax wage. Thus, we have the result, familiar to
corporated businesses are able to deduct pay- economists, that the effect of the tax is the
roll taxes paid when calculating their income same regardless of whether it is levied on the
for the purposes of remitting federal income employer or the employee.
tax.14 Economists have placed the greatest empha-
sis on whether business or labour bears the
burden of the tax. The answer depends upon

14 Canadian Business Economics Summer 1995


how responsive the market wage rate is to the with an increase in the tax but, as there is no
introduction of the tax. If an employer payroll offsetting decline in wages, employment falls
tax eventually leads to a large offsetting fall in in the rigid-wage sector.
wages, then workers will bear much of the Furthermore, the fall in employment in the
burden of the tax. The same result is obtained rigid-wage case has the potential to increase
if an employee payroll tax induces only a unemployment since those losing their jobs
small increase in the wage. In either case, the will still want to work at the constant wage.
labour supply and labour demand elasticities The potential proviso is necessary since the
are the critical parameters in determining the disemployment effect may be specific to the
extent to which wages change and the degree rigid-wage sector. The existence of sectors
to which employment will change in response with flexible wages in which those losing jobs
to the wage change. in rigid-wage sectors can work will mean that
In Canada, especially for the approximately some of these unemployed workers will enter
35 per cent of the workforce covered by col- the flexible-wage sector, driving its wages
lective agreements, the simple model of sup- lower than the payroll tax would alone, until
ply and demand may not accurately reflect the unemployed are absorbed. Unemploy-
how wages are determined. Non-cooperative ment may still occur, but it will be of the
bargaining theory suggests that the effects of wait variety, as workers queue for jobs in
payroll taxes in a collective bargaining context the rigid-wage sector.16
will be in the same direction as in the simple If there is no other flexible-wage market to
model (Wilton and Prescott, 1993). Employ- which workers losing their jobs in the rigid-
ers will attempt to share the cost of an em- wage market can move, as is the case in mini-
ployer payroll tax with their unionized work- mum-wage labour markets, the effects of pay-
ers by trying to negotiate smaller wage roll taxes will be solely on employment and
increases. Unions will try to shift the em- will definitely create unemployment.17 The
ployee portion of a payroll tax to employers by rigid-wage case has received little attention
negotiating higher wage increases. from economists when examining payroll
There is a contrast between what might be taxes despite the common use of this assump-
called the business view or public view of tion in the macroeconomics literature.18
the effects of payroll taxes and the econo- It could also be argued that the business
mists view. Business groups view payroll view reflects a focus on the short-run effects
taxes as a tax on jobs and emphasize their of payroll taxes. This can be a legitimate view
employment effects. Quoting the Canadian if the wage adjustments stressed by econo-
Chamber of Commerce: Rising payroll taxes mists are slow, or if those employers that now
leave companies with little choice other than bear the costs of the tax may not be around to
to cut jobs or hire fewer people. (Globe and benefit from any longer-term wage decline
Mail, February 10, 1994). This view also has a which the tax may bring. Dahlby (1993) notes
following in government circles. Paul Martin that there is support in the empirical literature
has referred to payroll taxes as a cancer on for slow dynamic adjustment; some evidence
jobs (Freeman, 1995). Statements concern- on this point is presented in the next section.
ing the 1994 roll-back of UI premiums (Fi- It is also possible that business is not con-
nance Canada, 1994) and arguments made cerned with employment effects per se, but
for UI reform by Human Resources Develop- that emphasizing them is the best way to gar-
ment Canada (1994: 42-43) also emphasize ner support against a policy which creates a
employment effects. welfare loss for employers via reduced pro-
Can these two views be reconciled? Stressing ducers surplus and added costs of adminis-
employment impacts makes most sense to tering the tax.
economists if labour demand and supply Another surprising result from the business
curves are elastic or if wage rates are rigid and point of view is the economists prediction
the tax is levied on employers. In the former that it is irrelevant to the taxs eventual impact
case, any wage change induced by the tax will whether it is levied on employers or employ-
result in relatively large changes in employ- ees. It is hard to imagine, for example, that
ment. In the latter case, labour demand falls

Summer 1995 Canadian Business Economics 15


employer groups would be indifferent to a stable work patterns receive no such offset-
payroll tax levied on their wage costs or to a ting benefit and, given the lack of experience
surtax on wage income levied through the in- rating, end up subsidizing other employers.
come tax system. Yet the simple model sug- These arguments suggest that payroll taxes
gests that the effects would be much the with offsetting benefits should be analysed
same. Again, wage inflexibility may help to differently from other payroll taxes. However,
reconcile the two positions. In the presence of the differences between the two types of taxes
rigid wages above market-clearing levels, a may not be as stark as it first seems. In prac-
tax on labour income will have no effect on tice, the effect of a change in tax rates may be
employer wage costs or on employment; i.e. similar between the two types of taxes even
there will be no costs to employers. though the consequences of introducing the
two different types of tax from scratch may be
Offsetting Benefits very different. This is because the link be-
Some payroll taxes provide a benefit to the tween a change in the tax rate and changes in
employer which may, to some degree, offset offsetting benefits of the program funded may
the cost of the tax itself. Workers compensa- be weak. For example, current increases in the
tion premiums are paid by employers to fi- workers compensation assessments to pay
nance payments to injured workers. This sys- for unfunded benefits awarded in the past
tem provides two possible benefits to provide no offsetting benefit to current em-
employers: first, workers give up the right to ployees. Similarly, increases in C/QPP premi-
sue their employers in the event of a work- ums for todays young workers to pay pension
place injury and, second, since workers know liabilities of tomorrows retiring baby boom-
they will be compensated in the event of an ers provides little offsetting benefit for the for-
injury, this reduces any compensating wage mer. Reforms which strengthen links between
differential needed in more dangerous jobs.19 tax rate changes and benefit changes will re-
It is clearly inappropriate, then, to treat the en- duce the distortionary effects of these taxes.
tire workers compensation premium as a cost
The introduction of a payroll tax may pro-
to employers. Indeed, Vaillancourt and Mar-
vide another type of offsetting benefit to em-
ceau (1990) find that the effects of workers
ployers if it, or the program financed by the
compensation assessments are in the oppo-
tax, replaces an existing employer tax or dis-
site direction to the effects of other payroll
places a fringe benefit commonly provided by
taxes. They suggest that offsetting benefits
employers. The Ontario Employer Health Tax,
may help explain this.
for example, replaced Ontario Health Insur-
The offsetting benefit argument can also be ance Plan premiums which were commonly
applied to unemployment insurance and paid by employers (as a fringe benefit).20
C/QPP premiums. The greater security pro-
vided by UI and the post-retirement pension Ceilings and Floors
benefits through C/QPP may make workers An important feature of UI, C/QPP, and
willing to accept lower wages, thus offsetting workers compensation taxes is the existence
the employer portion of the tax. Only the pro- of a ceiling above which earnings are not
vincial payroll taxes have no apparent offset- taxed. Such ceilings lead to the differences in
ting benefit. marginal tax rates recorded in Table 4. At the
The lack of UI experience rating and the im- extreme, the marginal employer tax rate on an
perfect experience rating systems in workers extra hour worked by a worker with earnings
compensation programs weaken the benefit- above the ceilings of all payroll taxes is zero
tax link for individual employers. The pay-as- compared to at least 8.57 per cent and as high
you-go nature of C/QPP has the same effect. as 13.4 per cent for a low-wage worker in
Unemployment insurance may allow employ- 1994. These ceilings will make higher-wage
ers with unstable labour demand patterns to labour relatively cheaper at the margin, with
pay a lower wage than would be necessary the consequence that wage and employment
without UI. Consequently, the net effect of UI effects will be more severe for lower-wage
on employment could actually be positive workers. This can create a bias in favour of
among such employers. Of course, firms with hiring highly-paid workers. It also provides an

16 Canadian Business Economics Summer 1995


incentive to have current workers work more workers. Increases in workers compensation
hours rather than hire additional workers and assessments, however, actually appeared to
so favors full-time over part-time employ- increase wage growth. The authors use an off-
ment. The effects of ceilings also make these setting-benefit argument to explain this latter
taxes more regressive. result, noting the close tie between tax rates
These impacts will be less important for a tax and injury costs for workers compensation.
with offsetting benefits. With UI, for example, Beach, Lin, and Picot (1995) estimate a labour
earnings above the insurable ceiling are not demand equation derived from a CES produc-
taxed but, also, are uninsured. Consequently, tion function on pooled provincial employ-
wages for higher-paid workers may be greater ment and wage data for 1966-1993. Their re-
than if insurance applied to all earnings. sults are consistent with full shifting of the
employer payroll tax to workers through wage
The existence of minimum pensionable and
reductions. Wilton and Prescott (1993) exam-
insurable earnings under C/QPP and UI, and
ine the impact of income, sales, and payroll
the 15 hour per week requirement for UI, cre-
taxes on wage costs using data on private-sec-
ate biases in the opposite direction to ceilings.
tor collective agreements from 1979-1992. Us-
However, figures reported in an earlier section
ing several alternative specifications, they
suggest that ceilings are empirically more im-
find that higher employer payroll taxes actu-
portant than floors.
ally increase real wages. This is contrary to
Exempt or Low-Tax Groups the standard result from the simple supply-
If certain groups are exempt from the payroll demand model or the bargaining framework,
tax for example, the self-employed or some which lies behind Wilton and Prescotts
small businesses under provincial payroll specification.
taxes then such taxes will tend to depress The macroeconomic-labour literature,
wages (incomes) in the exempt group as well which aims to explain unemployment pat-
as the covered groups. In effect, the fall in la- terns by estimating aggregate labour market
bour demand in the covered group represents models, can also be used to assess the effects
a fall in labour demand for all workers of that of payroll taxes.23 In these models, employ-
particular skill level regardless of group and ment is negatively related to real wage costs
will therefore lower wages across groups. and real wages depend negatively on the un-
employment rate and positively on the
wedge, which is the difference between the
Empirical Work on wage cost to the employer (including tax) and
the Effects of Payroll the net wage of the worker. The payroll tax en-
ters the model as part of the wedge. As in the
Taxation simple model, a rise in payroll taxes increases
Dahlby (1993: 133), in reviewing the litera- the wedge, and therefore tax-inclusive wage
ture on the incidence of payroll taxes, notes costs, and this lowers employment. However,
that empirical studies....suggest that labour unlike the simple model, there is no assump-
bears over 80 per cent of the employer payroll tion that employment is determined along the
tax burden in the long run.21 The usual find- labour supply curve. Consequently, rising
ing is that, consistent with the simple model, payroll taxes raise wage costs and lower em-
wage rates adjust to offset payroll taxes result- ployment, but can also lead to unemploy-
ing in a significant shifting of the tax to la- ment. These unemployment effects of payroll
bour.22 This result suggests that it is incorrect taxes create downward pressure on wage
to ignore the wage effects of payroll taxes, as rates which partially offsets the original effect
the business view tends to do. of payroll taxes on wage costs.
A number of Canadian studies have exam- Our calculations based on Bean, Layard, and
ined the shifting issue. Using collective Nickell (1986) indicate that a one per cent rise
agreements data in Quebec, Vaillancourt and in payroll tax rates results in long-run in-
Marceau (1990) found the standard result that creases of 0.5 per cent in real wage costs and
increases in general payroll taxes reduced a -0.2 per cent decrease in employment. Bean,
wage growth with some of the tax, shifted to Layard and Nickells own simulations suggest

Summer 1995 Canadian Business Economics 17


that increases in the wedge raised the unem- roll taxes were progressive until about the 5th
ployment rate by 1.34 points between the decile, remained proportional for the next
early-1960s and the early 1980s a period in two, and then began to decline. Most likely,
which the unemployment rate rose by about the increased progressivity of the taxes at the
4.5 percentage points. Of the 1.34 point rise low to middle income ranges does not reflect
attributed to the wedge, our calculations sug- changes in tax design but rather the growth in
gest that about 25 per cent can be attributed to the importance of transfers as an income
the rise in payroll taxes alone. Simulations by source in the lowest deciles.
Keil and Symons (1990) indicate that 0.5
points of the 3 percentage point rise in unem-
ployment between 1981 and 1985 was due to
New Estimates of the
increases in the wedge. Again, based on our Impact of Payroll
calculations, about 22 per cent of this 0.5
point increase can be attributed to the rise in Taxation
payroll taxes. Measuring the impact of payroll taxes on em-
Both Bean, Layard, and Nickell and Keil and ployment and wages requires estimates of la-
Symons adopt dynamic specifications. Re- bour demand and supply elasticities. How-
sults from the former show a mean lag for em- ever, there are no generally accepted
ployment adjustment of 1.5 years. In the Keil estimates of these elasticities for the Canadian
and Symons model where dynamics are economy. Past studies report large differ-
slower, while a change in the payroll tax does ences.24
not affect long-run employment, it can have Table 8 presents estimates of the wage and
lingering negative effects as the economy employment effects of a one per cent rise in
moves toward equilibrium. This pace of la- marginal payroll tax rates based upon various
bour market adjustment lends some credence combinations of labour supply and labour de-
to the business view of the payroll-tax effect. mand elasticities. The elasticities used are
Both models, though, are consistent with the reasonable by standards of the literature, with
economists story in the long run. the exception of the -2.5 labour demand elas-
In general, then, studies support the stand- ticity (cases IV and VII) used by Keil and Sy-
ard model suggesting that the effects of pay- mons (1990), which is provided for contrast.
roll taxes on employer wage costs are moder- As the labour demand and supply elasticities
ated by changes in wage rates. Only the study increase, the effects of payroll taxes on em-
by Wilton and Prescott is at odds with this ployment increase; however, the results show
conclusion. This suggests that an important that for reasonable labour demand elastici-
effect of the rise in payroll taxes, then, has ties, these effects are not substantial.
likely been slower wage growth. In addition, The table also illustrates the sensitivity of the
the macroeconomic-labour studies suggest wage-shifting results to even the small range
that payroll taxes will reduce employment of elasticities considered. A labour demand
and raise unemployment though these effects elasticity of -0.3 and labour supply elasticity
may be transitional. Another interesting point of 0.15 implies that 33 per cent of the tax rise
arising from this literature and the study by is realized as a rise in labour costs and the rest
Wilton and Prescott is that the impact of a as a fall in employee pay. Elasticities of -0.15
payroll tax on labour markets can be expected and 0.5 more than reverse this result with the
to be much the same as other taxes (i.e. sales employer cost share at 77 per cent and the em-
and income taxes) which drive a wedge be- ployee burden at 23 per cent. Therefore, the
tween the supply and demand prices for labour. wage effects of the taxes may be particularly
Finally, the literature has also considered the hard to predict.25
distributional impact of Canadian payroll The top panel of Table 9 presents the long-
taxes. Recent work by Gillespie, Vermaeten, run effects of a one per cent rise in average
and Vermaeten (1995) has found that payroll (rather then marginal) payroll taxes, as de-
taxes were generally regressive with respect rived from the Bean, Layard, and Nickell
to family income from 1951-1969 but by 1988, model. These are closest to those obtained for
they had acquired an inverted U-shape. Pay-

18 Canadian Business Economics Summer 1995


case VI in the previous table (for a labour de- positive relationship between the average
mand elasticity of -0.3 and a labour supply payroll tax rate and real wages; however, this
elasticity of 0.5). The actual long-run labour coefficient is only marginally significant in the
demand elasticity in Bean, Layard, and levels version and insignificant in the first dif-
Nickell is -0.42. ferences version. Moreover, there is a negative
The bottom panel of Table 9 reports long-run and significant relationship between the real
impacts based upon our own estimates using wage variable and changes in employment
annual data for the period 1958-1992. We suggesting that increases in the average pay-
base our model on Bean, Layard, and roll tax rate can lead to a reduction in employ-
Nickells aggregate labour market model so as ment via changes in the real wage. The long-
to facilitate comparison as well as make use of run labour demand elasticity was -0.56.28
a standard and accepted modelling approach. These results suggest that the employment
This involves specification of a real wage effects of payroll taxes are non-trivial. Solving
equation and an employment equation (both the estimated equations for the long-run ef-
in log-linear form). In the model, the real fect of a one per cent rise in the average pay-
wage is explained by the wedge (including roll tax rate on employment indicates a rise in
payroll taxes), an indicator of labour market real wage costs of 0.56 per cent and a decrease
tightness (the employment rate), the capital- in employment of 0.32 per cent in the long run
labour ratio, and the unemployment insur- (Table 9). The wage received by workers
ance coverage rate. Employment depends would fall by 0.44 per cent. Using 1994 as the
upon the real wage, GDP, and the capital-la- base year, in the long run about 40,600 jobs
bour ratio. Both equations include quadratic would have been lost by such a policy action.
trend terms and allow for dynamic adjust- We emphasize that there are a wide range of
ment by including a one-period lag of the de- estimates of the actual magnitude of the job
pendent variable as a regressor. Modifications losses from payroll taxation because, ulti-
were made to reflect the current articles inter- mately, the size of the losses depends on esti-
est in payroll taxes.26 Both level and first-dif- mates of labour demand and supply. At the
ference versions of the model were estimated same time, the overall evidence is consistent
using two-stage least squares.27 with the view that payroll taxes reduce em-
The results broadly parallel those of Bean, ployment. The fact that since the 1960s the
Layard, and Nickell. The coefficient on the persistent upward trend in unemployment
wedge was positive and reveals that there is a has been accompanied by rising payroll tax

Table 8 Estimated Effects of a 1 Per Cent Rise in Marginal Payroll


Tax Rate
Various Labour Supply and Demand Scenarios

I II III IV V VI VII
Elasticity Assumptions
Labour Supply 0 0.15 0.15 0.15 0.50 0.50 0.50
Labour Demand all -0.15 -0.3 -2.5 -0.15 -0.3 -2.5
Effects of a 1 Per Cent Rise in Marginal Payroll Tax Rate
Employer Wage 0 0.50 0.33 0.06 0.77 0.63 0.17
Costs/share
Worker Wage/share -1 -0.50 -0.67 -0.94 -0.23 -0.37 -0.83
Employment 0 -0.08 -0.10 -0.14 -0.12 -0.19 -0.42
Jobs1 (000s) 0 9.5 12.7 18.2 14.6 23.9 53.0

1. Assumes employment before tax increase of 12,700,000.

Summer 1995 Canadian Business Economics 19


rates is probably not an entirely coincidental tive employment effects. In estimating the ef-
relationship. fects of payroll taxes, we emphasize that the
size of these impacts depends on the labour
demand and supply elasticities utilized. How-
Conclusion ever, there is no consensus estimate of these
Payroll taxes have grown to become the third elasticities. Our own estimates imply that a
most important source of government reve- one per cent rise in the average tax rate will
nue after personal income taxes and con- lead to a 0.56 per cent rise in wage costs and a
sumption taxes. Given the unfunded liability -0.32 per cent fall in employment.
problems in C/QPP and the workers com-
pensation schemes in some provinces as well Notes
as fiscal problems at both the provincial and * The authors wish to acknowledge the helpful com-
federal level, governments may attempt to ments of Jon Kesselman and two anonymous referees.
further exploit this tax base. In addition, the 1. Prior to 1971, premiums differed by earnings class.
relatively hidden nature of employer payroll The 1966 figure reported in Table 2 is an average.
taxes provides a further incentive for their use
2. The 1994 system is more generous than the 1966
given the current climate of resistance to vis- system in terms of level and duration of benefits.
ible tax increases. Generosity, however, peaked in the 1970s.
Payroll tax rates vary across provinces and 3. In some provinces, partial experience rating allows
industry groups because of the number of dif- rates to vary among firms within an industry rate
ferent taxes as well as differences in rates. We group as well.

found that when the composition of the 4. These taxes are examined in detail in Kesselman
groups facing tax levels is examined, low-in- (1994).
come groups faced higher marginal rates. 5. The summed rates in Table 3 apply to wage and
Women, young workers, those with less edu- salary earnings below the maximums specified for
workers compensation, C/QPP, and UI. Rates ap-
cation, employees in retail, clerical, and serv-
plicable to other types of labour income, such as
ices, and in small business generally, are fringe benefits, differ as UI and C/QPP exclude these
likely to be at high marginal rates and conse- while the provincial taxes do not. In each province,
quently bear many of the employment and employee contributions represented 5.67 per cent of
total labour income in 1994.
wage costs these taxes may produce.
The empirical literature suggests that payroll 6. The use of average workers compensation assess-
ments is unavoidable if figures are to be reported in
taxes raise employer wage costs and have im- summary form. Quebec, for example, had 341 indus-
portant negative consequences for take-home try rate groups in 1993. Note, however, that the use
wages. There is also some evidence of nega- of an average rate masks substantial variation in

Table 9 Estimated Effects of a One Per Cent Increase in Average


Payroll Tax Rate
Bean, Layard, and Nickell1
Wage Costs 0.5
Employment -0.2
Job Loss2 (000s) 25.4
Di Matteo and Shannon3
Wage Costs 0.56
Employment -0.32
Job Loss2 (000s) 40.6

1. Based upon estimates reported in Bean, Layard and Nickell (1986)


2. Assumes employment before tax increase of 12,700,000.
3. Details of estimates available from the authors.

20 Canadian Business Economics Summer 1995


rates between industry groups. For example, work- 24. For example, Woodland (1975) reports labour de-
ers compensation assessment rates ranged from mand elasticities by industry that range from -0.351
0.15 per cent to 23.6 per cent across Ontario rate (finance) to -0.009 (trade) while Merrilees (1982)
groups in 1992. reports small labour demand elasticities that are ac-
tually positive for certain age groups. The long-run
7. The range arises from the use of alternative meas-
labour demand elasticity for Canada in the Keil and
ures of earnings.
Symons (1990) model is -2.5 compared to -0.42 in
8. Again, the picture, especially by industry, is impre- Bean, Layard, and Nickell (1986). Beach, Lin, and
cise because of the use of average assessment rates Picot (1995) provide an estimate of roughly -.3. Hum
for workers compensation. and Simpson (1991) summarize the Canadian la-
bour supply literature reporting that uncompen-
9. The possibility of extending the amortization period sated labour supply elasticities are almost always
to 2024 or abandoning full funding for 70 per cent below 0.5 with a concentration of studies around
funding were also examined. These options would 0.4-0.5 and another group concentrated in the 0.1-
still require rate increases, but on a smaller scale 0.2 range. Some studies have even reported negative
than those necessary under the current plan. labour supply elasticities.
10. The unfunded liability was 9.8 per cent of assessable 25. Hamermesh (1993) concludes that near full-shifting
payrolls in Nova Scotia, 5.7 per cent in Quebec, and to labour is a reasonable assumption on the basis of
13.3 per cent in Ontario in 1993. low labour-supply elasticity estimates (mainly for
11. This discussion refers to rate adjustments required the United States).
to clear past liabilities. Considerable uncertainty 26. Specifically, two changes were made: (1) the
with respect to these future rate projections is intro- wedge was separated into payroll tax and non-
duced by changes in future accident rates and bene- payroll tax components and (2) rather than model
fits. The recent introduction of a wage-loss system the change in the real employer wage as a function
in Ontario, for example, makes future benefits for of the level of the wedge, we considered it more
permanent disability pensions less predictable. natural to express the level of the real wage as func-
12. The changes in the budget will tend to dampen cy- tion of the level of the wedge. Additional detail re-
clical rate swings requiring rates to be higher during ga rding the specification, data sources, and
upswings and lower during recessions than was the estimation are available from the authors.
case in the past. 27. This is in recognition of the simultaneity of the two
13. On the other hand, Vaillancourt (1986: 83) argues equations. Employment depends upon the real wage
that the total administrative and compliance costs and the real wage depends upon employment
of the personal income tax and payroll tax system through the employment rate.
in Canada account for about 6.9 per cent of tax reve- 28. These results from Table 9 are from the levels version
nues collected. of the model because it is not possible to simulate
14. The federal government has moved to curtail the long-run effects from the first- differences version of
deductibility of these provincial payroll taxes. the model.

15. Dahlby (1992) provides a thorough review of the


theoretical literature on payroll tax impacts.
References
Beach, Charles, Zhengi Lin, and Garnett Picot
16. See Mincer (1976) for a model with this type of
unemployment. (1995) The Employer Payroll Tax in Can-
ada and its Effects on the Demand for La-
17. This argument, combined with the observation that
bour, paper presented at the Conference
marginal payroll tax rates are highest for low-wage
workers, suggests that employment impacts may be
on Transition and Structural Change in
especially large for these workers. the North American Labour Market, John
Deutsch Institute and the Industrial Rela-
18. Mitchell (1993) provides a recent survey of the wage
rigidity literature.
tions Centre, Queens University, King-
ston.
19. See Meng (1989) for measures of compensating dif-
ferentials for dangerous jobs in Canada.
Bean, C., R. Layard, and S. Nickell (1986)
The Rise in Unemployment: a Multi-
20. Dahlby (1993: 81) notes that 65 per cent of premi- country Study, Economica, Vol. 53, pp.
ums were paid by employers.
S1-S22.
21. Hamermesh (1993: 172), however, is skeptical of Canadian Institute of Actuaries (1993) Cana-
these not very satisfactory studies.
dian Retirement Income Social Security
22. The supply-demand model suggests that an em- Programs, Report of the Task Force on So-
ployer payroll tax should decrease net-of-tax wages cial Security Financing (Toronto).
(or slow wage growth) while a tax on employees
should increase wage growth.
Canadian Tax Foundation (1993) The Na-
tional Finances (Toronto).
23. Layard, Nickell, and Jackman (1991) and Lindbeck
(1993) provide recent examples.

Summer 1995 Canadian Business Economics 21


Dahlby, Bev (1992) Taxation and Social In- Kesselman, Jonathan R. (1994) Canadian
surance, in R.M. Bird and J. Mintz (eds.) Provincial Payroll Taxation: A Structural
Taxation to 2000 and Beyond, Canadian and Policy Analysis, Canadian Tax Jour-
Tax Paper No. 93, Canadian Tax Founda- nal, Vol. 42, No. 1, pp. 150-200.
tion, pp. 110-165. Layard, R., S. Nickell, and R. Jackman (1991)
Dahlby, Bev (1993) Payroll Taxes, in A. Unemployment - Macroeconomic Perform-
Maslove (ed.) Business Taxation in On- ance and the Labor Market (Oxford: Ox-
tario (Toronto: University of Toronto ford University Press).
Press), Chapter 3. Lindbeck, A. (1993) Unemployment and Mac-
Employment and Immigration Canada (vari- roeconomics (Cambridge: MIT Press).
ous years) Annual Report (Ottawa: Sup- Meng, R. (1989) Compensating Differentials
ply and Services Canada). in the Canadian Labour Market, Cana-
Finance Canada (1994) Proposed Changes to dian Journal of Economics, Vol. XXII, No.
the Unemployment Insurance Program, 2, pp. 413-424.
Ottawa. Merrilees, W. (1982) Labour Market Seg-
Financial Executives Institute of Canada mentation in Canada: an Econometric
(1995) Workers Compensation in Can- Approach, Canadian Journal of Eco-
ada 1993 (Toronto). nomics, Vol. XV, pp. 458-473.
Freeman, Alan (1995) UI Premium Cuts on Mincer, J. (1976) Unemployment Effects of
the Horizon, Globe and Mail, March 7. Minimum Wages, Journal of Political
Gillespie, W. Irwin, Frank Vermaeten, and Economy, Vol. 84, pp. S87-S104.
Arndt Vermaeten (1995) Who Paid the Mitchell, D.J.B. (1993) Keynesian, Old
Taxes in Canada, 1951-1988, Carleton Keynesian, and New Keynesian Wage
Economics Paper, No. 95-02, Ottawa. Nominalism, Industrial Relations, Vol.
H a m e r m e s h , D . ( 1 9 9 3 ) Labor Demand 32, No. 1, pp. 1-29.
(Princeton: Princeton University Press). Vaillancourt, F. (1986) The Administrative
Health and Welfare Canada (1986) Income Se- and Compliance Costs of the Personal In-
curity Programs (Ottawa). come Tax and Payroll Tax System in Can-
Health and Welfare Canada (1991) Canada ada, 1986, Canadian Tax Foundation,
Pension Plan Contributors (Ottawa). Canadian Tax Paper no. 86.
Hum, D. and Simpson, W. (1991) Income Vaillancourt, F. and N. Marceau (1990) On
Maintenance, Work Effort, and the Cana- General Firm-specific Payroll Taxes, Eco-
dian Mincome Experiment, study pre- nomics Letters, Vol. 34, pp. 175-181.
p ared fo r t he Ec ono mi c Co unci l o f Wilton, D. and D. Prescott (1993) The Ef-
Canada (Ottawa: Supply and Services fects of Tax Increases on Labour Costs,
Canada). Government and Competitiveness Pro-
Human Resources Development Canada ject, Discussion Paper 93-29, School of
(1994) From Unemployment Insurance to Policy Studies, Queens University, King-
Employment Insurance (Ottawa: Supply ston.
and Services Canada). Woodland, A. (1975) Substitution of Struc-
Keil, M.W. and J.S.V. Symons (1990) An tures, Equipment and Labor in Canadian
Analysis of Canadian Unemployment, Production, International Economic Re-
Canadian Public Policy, Vol. XVI, No. 1, view, Vol. 16, pp. 171-187.
pp. 1-16. Workers Compensation Board of Ontario
(1992) WC Funding Strategy (Toronto).

22 Canadian Business Economics Summer 1995

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi