Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 20

World Development Vol. 30, No. 11, pp.

18451864, 2002
2002 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved
Printed in Great Britain
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev 0305-750X/02/$ - see front matter
PII: S0305-750X(02)00120-1

Homo Economicus Goes to War:


Methodological Individualism, Rational Choice
and the Political Economy of War
C. CRAMER *
University of London, UK
Summary. Neoclassical economic theories of violent conict have proliferated in recent years
and, with their application to contemporary wars, have inuenced donors and policy makers. This
paper reviews the intellectual foundations and empirical substance of such theories and oers a
critique drawing on a political economy perspective. There are strong grounds for arguing that
orthodox economic theories of war are reductionist, speculative, and misleading. Theories that are
driven by methodological individualism are compelled somehow to model the social as it aects
contemporary warfor example, by appeal to indices of ethno-linguistic fragmentationbut do so in
ways that fail to capture reality and its variations.
2002 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words war, political economy, development theory, methodological individualism

1. INTRODUCTION native approaches in political economy can


provide this economic content more eectively.
Neoclassical economic theories of conict At its close, the paper suggests some of the
have proliferated in recent years. They have basic elements of a richer analysis of contem-
an increasing inuence in donor, academic and porary conicts, predominantly in less devel-
nongovernmental organization circles, though oped and/or transitional economies.
they are often consumed only through easily Development economics has arrived rather
digestible, nontechnical presentations with an late to the eld of conict. Economic theory
obvious, if arguably only partial, relation to the in general has not been much devoted to ex-
realities of contemporary conicts around the plaining war. Exceptions include Keyness two
world. Such theories also commonly arouse extraordinary works conceived in response to
disquiet, or what their proponents might feel is the problems of warEconomic Consequences
a knee-jerk reaction; but widespread discomfort of the Peace (1920) and How to Pay for the War
with neoclassical economic theories of armed (1978)rather than focusing on war itself;
conict in developing countries is also typically Langes work (1970), which provided some
weakened by an incomplete appreciation of the grounds for the parallel analysis of war econ-
theories and models in question. This paper omies and centrally planned socialist economies
contributes to the literature on conict by of- as mobilized economies (Sapir, 1990); and, in
fering a short survey of the common themes the eld of development, Prests (1948) work on
and intellectual foundations of these theories the economics of war in primary commodity
and by laying out a critique from a political producing countries. In the somewhat broader
economy perspective. This is especially relevant eld of historical political economy, there are
since many noneconomists welcome econo-
mists models of conict because they oer the
economic, or material, content that is often
missing in other analyses. Yet, this paper ar- * The author is grateful to a number of people who have
gues, rational choice theories of conict based given comments on earlier versions of this paper, in-
on neoclassical economics are unconvincing cluding Stephen Jackson, Andy Storey, Ben Fine, Jon-
theoretically and where they have empirical athan di John, John Sender and two anonymous
content this is largely arbitrary. Further, alter- referees. Final revision accepted: 24 May 2002.
1845
1846 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

enduring classics such as Wolf (1969), Moore characteristics of orthodox economic theory
(1967), and Scott (1976). and its pretensions to colonising the social sci-
But both development economics and devel- ences in general. Thus, I argue that rational
opment studies in general were largely silent on choice theories of conict typically lay waste to
the subject during the later 1970s and the 1980s, specicity and contingency, that they sack the
for whatever reason, though the overwhelming social and that even in their individualism they
ideological hold of the Cold War doubtless had violate the complexity of individual motivation,
something to do with this. During the 1990s all razing the individual (and key groups) down to
this changed, and rapidly. Reecting a general monolithic maximizing agents. Arguably, the
encroachment into the social sciences by ortho- extension of orthodox economics to explaining
dox economics, economic models of conict armed conict does not even have a logical
based on methodological individualism and justication in terms of the fundamental prin-
rational choice began to proliferate, led by ciples of neo-classical economics (Zarovski,
Hirshleifer (1987, 1994) and Grossman (1991). 1 2000).
Of course, an old critique of neoclassical eco- The following section sets out the main
nomics was precisely that it evaded matters of common features of mainstream economic the-
power and conict. Now, however, neoclassical ories of conict, clarifying the ways in which a
economics has been wheeled out to confront variety of models build upon shared assump-
these issues head on. The result has been tions of choice theoretic logic. Thus, models of
what some call an expansion of the domain conict provide for a combination, as it were, of
of economics (Alchian, quoted in Bowles, a felicic and a bellicose calculus, oras Hir-
Franzini, & Pagano, 1999, p. 7) and what shleifer (1994) puts itfor a combination of the
others call a process of economics imperial- way of Coase with the way of Macchiavelli. 3
ism (Fine, 1999, 2001). Hirshleifers tongue is These economic models of conict have a strong
only partly in cheek when he writes, of the in- appeal, even to many who are made uneasy by
tellectual continent of violence and conict on their attempt to capture, or reduce, conictual
which economists have alighted relatively re- relations in the language of algebraic identities
cently, that: and dierentiation. The next section of this
paper briey explores the sources of this appeal
As we come to explore this continent, economists will and also identies some immediate causes for
encounter a number of native tribeshistorians, so- analytical concern. Following sections discuss
ciologists, psychologists, philosophers, etc.who, in in more detail two principal weaknesses. The
their various intellectually primitive ways, have pre- rst is revealed in empirical applications of the
ceded us in reconnoitering the dark side of human
activity. Once we economists get involved, quite
neoclassical logic, which have thus far dealt in
properly we will of course be brushing aside these highly unsatisfactory (empirically and concep-
a-theoretical aborigines. (The footnote to this quote tually) proxies for the proposed behavioral
explains: When these researchers do good work, they drives of Homo economicus. The second major
are doing economics! (1994, p. 3)). 2 aw in these theories is the analytical awk-
wardness with which they manage the inevitable
In claiming the leading role among the need to model the social. Finally, in the con-
dramatis personae of social science (Bowles clusion, in response to the colonizing cam-
et al., 1999), Homo economicus has clearly re- paign of neoclassical economics the paper oers
vealed a more passionate aspect by engaging in a manifesto for an analytical liberation struggle.
conicts, seeking power or consuming posi-
tional goods (Pagano, 1999). How well this
creature plays the part in these roles remains 2. OPPORTUNITY KNOCKS:
questionable. Rational choice models of con- ANALYTICAL FOUNDATIONS
ict follow the precepts and developments of OF NEOCLASSICAL MODELS
neoclassical economic theory well. I argue, OF CONFLICT
however, that they also follow neoclassical
economics by repeating its well-known short- Rational choice, methodologically individu-
comings. War is often an especially sharp alist models of conict typically build on the
reection of tendencies and characteristics idea of two groups or players. In some the
common in societies not at war. Likewise, game pits a ruler or incumbent against a rival.
perhaps economic theories of conict and civil Others (Grossman, 1991; Azam, 2001) have the
war give especially sharp insights into the state in conict with subject-rebels. In each case
HOMO ECONOMICUS GOES TO WAR 1847

there is little or no disaggregation or strati- commodities. Rebellion is thus clearly akin to


cation of the players. 4 In some models out- rent seeking (Neary, 1997): it is a distortionary
comes (in terms of social waste and political devotion of resources to the pursuit of the fruits
instability) may depend on whether the incum- of imperfect competition. 5 The occurrence and
bent or state has an edge (Mehlum & Moene, implications of conict may be inuenced by
2000); in others, e.g., Collier (various), the the symmetrical or asymmetrical features of
presumption is that wars start with the decision the strategic game, e.g., by whether the in-
of rebels and the analysis abstracts from much cumbent powerholder has an edge (Mehlum
of state policy and from state violence. There is & Moene, 2000).
no discussion of where the players come from If this tradeo is the basic premise of models
other than as the product of relevant econo- of conict, then it is necessary to determine
mistic calculations, to be discussed below. the factors that might trip the switch activating
While in some models the players are simply the choice of war. In other words, under what
rivals for the rent associated with power, in circumstances do groups develop mutually
most they are granted some social or collective inconsistent opportunity sets (Hirshleifer,
identity, typically in the form of ethnic or reli- 1994) that make ghting more protable on
gious labels. This is discussed further, below; the margin than peaceable exchange? One of
but it might be noted that in Hirshleifer (1994), the most basic circumstances is poverty or
for example, collective identity is regarded as a slow growth. Poverty may cause conict in
residue of Darwinian survival processes gener- various ways, but the clearest expression of its
ating durable animosities, rather than having treatment in neoclassical models of conict is
modern, political and ideological roots and in- Hirshleifers argument that the poor have a
uences. Both players or organizations are as- comparative advantage in violence. While it
sumed to be maximizing agents and the paucity seems obscene in the light of the widespread
of discussion of either group leads to a common and persistent evidence of coercive recruitment
elision between these agents and individuals. of children and young adults into military
Typically, they are driven by the urge (this groups in, e.g., Sierra Leone or Angola, the
seems to be the only occasion where compul- argument is nonetheless made that the oppor-
sion is relevant, all else being decided in the tunity cost of insurgency for, especially, young
realm of choice) to maximize power or wind- males in poor countries where there are few
fall gains from victory (or just from conict alternative opportunities for gainful employ-
itself). ment is clearly low. Essentially, this is simply a
This is particularly stark in Collier and formal version of the widespread common
Hoeers models, stressing as they do greater sense assumption that in poor countries life
predictive power in the causation of civil war is cheap.
for loot than for justice, for greed than There are other factors, however, aect-
grievance, but actually the same core rea- ing the probability of the relative protability
soning holds in all such models, including those of violent conict. For example, Azam (2001)
from which their work is derived. For the claims that the likelihood of war turns on
common key to these models is the idea of whether there are credible signals of inter- and
a tradeo. For Hirshleifer people face a intraethnic redistributive resource allocations,
choice between producing and appropriating. If given an initial endowment of ethnic capital.
the opportunity cost of appropriative activity, Redistributive mechanisms may take various
i.e. violence and conict, is not prohibitive forms. For example, high public sector wages
then violence will ensue; put dierently, actors for ocials drawn from across ethnic groups,
choose conict where this is more protable at enabling an intra-ethnic trickle down, might be
the margin than exchange. Grossman (1991), more eective in keeping the peace than rela-
Azam (2001), and others similarly focus on a tively anonymous provision of public goods
risk versus payo tradeo: conict is dangerous (Azam, 2001). Collier (Collier & Hoeer, 1996,
but if the payo outweighs calculated risk, war 1998) begins by stressing the gains from victory
is chosen or more time is allocated to insur- and the governments potential expenditure on
gency. Conict, civil war, or insurrection is defence as the factors determining the utility of
then an investment or resource allocation de- rebellion. The calculation by prospective rebels
signed to raise the probability of toppling the is mediated by how easy it will be to mobilize
government or of drawing monopoly prots support, i.e. by the characteristics of the col-
from the loot or instant taxation of primary lective action challenge in a given society. As
1848 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

shown in greater detail below, this is under- produce sucient conict. Similarly, there is a
stood principally in terms of ethno-linguis- time-consistency problem in that actors of vi-
tic fragmentation. Later versions of Colliers olence are presumed not to trust the promises
models (Collier, 2000; Collier & Hoeer, 1999, of leaders, reasonably expecting them to renege
2001), placing less emphasis on the probability on their mobilizing pledges to put right a range
of victory, highlight the availability of lootable of social wrongs or sources of grievance. On the
primary commodities and the availability or other hand, appealing to peoples demand for
otherwise of peaceable economic activities to instant gratication through loot nicely over-
young males. So-called greed variables such comes these diculties.
as these are found by Collier and Collier &
Hoeer to be far more robust predictors of
civil war than grievance factors such as re- 3. THE LURE OF ORTHODOXY
pression or exclusion, somewhat contrarily to
Azams (2001) otherwise analytically related Such are the axioms, assumptions and logic
model. that have informed much recent thinking on the
The orthodox economists toolkit has other economics of war, particularly of so-called civil
compartments too, yielding nuanced variations wars in developing countries. They have also
around this basic model. Hirshleifer (1987), for ltered into policy debates, especially through
example, wields diminishing returns, compara- their inuence on the research initiative of the
tive advantage, and CobbDouglas production World Bank on the economics of civil war,
functions as relevant to the incidence and out- crime and violence. 6 (The debate has in some
comes of conict. Thus, production functions arenas been reduced to the overly simplistic
may relate ghting inputs on two sides to out- greed versus grievance dichotomy.) This kind
puts in the form of victories and defeats. Azam of explanation of conict has a wider appeal
(2001, p. 432) introduces the assumption that too, perhaps for three main reasons. Firstly,
there are locally increasing returns to scale in many of those concerned by a high prevalence
rebellion, such that there is a critical mass of of civil conicta crude term used here simply
resources to be invested in rebellion activity for conveniencetend to recoil in righteous
before there is any chance of overthrowing horror from the implications of the widely cited
the government. Few would argue with this new barbarism thesis associated with Robert
probably: though this is insucient to le- Kaplan. 7 Kaplan (1994) suggested that West
gitimate the overall model. Meanwhile, another African and Yugoslav wars manifested a prob-
compartment of the toolkit reveals a kind of lem of loose molecules stirred into a frenzy
adhesive holding the model together, i.e. un- of violence by, essentially, Malthusian pres-
certainty. Imprecision and inconsistency in the sures and the nightmare of urbanization. The
application of this variable in the models sug- rational choice theory of conict oers an an-
gests that it is something of a residual used to alytical godsend to those made viscerally anx-
patch up the holes in a model and stop it from ious by the senseless anarchy story. 8
collapsing. Hirshleifer (1994, p. 5) suggests that Second, neoclassical economic explanations
uncertainty on the conict side swamps that of conict oer a corrective to the assumption
on the side of co-operation; but acknowledges that inequality produces resistance and conict.
that it is not clear how exactly uncertainty will Since Plato at least it has often seemed obvious
aect the likelihood of conict as an outcome that injustice and gross inequality would pro-
of the interaction of opportunities and prefer- duce conict. Much work on Central American
ences (on preferences, see below). conicts prioritises the causal role of inequality
Finally, again in the more applied models (Boyce, 1996; Booth, 1991), while others nd
there is more attention to collective action a more general signicance (albeit probabilis-
problems and varieties of market failure. For tic and along with other factors) of income
example, Colliers (2000) explanation for his inequality in the origins of complex humani-
empirical ndings that greed variables predict tarian emergencies (Nafziger, 1996). But, as
civil war better than do grievance variables Trotsky and others have suggested, if the ob-
turns on these issues. Rebellion against injustice jective conditions of revolution were sucient
has something of the qualities of a public good to cause revolutions, then much of the world
and, therefore, will also display the weaknesses would be in a more or less permanent condition
of a public good, primarily susceptibility to free of revolution. Moreover, it has become clearer
riders: hence, injustice might exist but will not that injustice and inequality do not inevitably
HOMO ECONOMICUS GOES TO WAR 1849

or in any direct, functional sense produce extremely common, there is evidence of instant
conict. 9 Grenier (1996), for example, shows gratication by soldiers in the form of looting.
well how structural injustice explanations tally The capacity of orthodox economic theory
weakly with the incidence, timing and outcomes to make of these material issues something
of Central American conicts. 10 In another more than the stu just of rich description or of
example, from the Jubba Valley in southern consumer campaign morality has given them
Somalia, the question is considerable advantage.
Despite the apparent appeal and formal ele-
how to understand Gosha peoples choices to partici- gance of orthodox economic explanations of
pate within and actively seek incorporation into a so- violent conict, there are strong grounds for
ciety which subjugated them, and how to understand arguing that these explanations are extremely
their creative ability to manage the juxtaposition of reductionist, highly speculative, and profoundly
domination and accommodation (Besteman, 1999, p. 9). misleading. For example, the presence of pri-
mary commodities in an economy or their ease
Third, the appeal of the new economics of lootability is an absurdly simplistic, overly
of conict lies in the fact that it is a material- direct rationalization of the role of material re-
ist explanation of conict. Whatever else con- sources in conict. This approach may be con-
temporary armed conicts are about, powerful trasted, e.g., with analyses of the origins of three
material interests clearly are signicant in distinct and competitive liberation movements
shaping the conicts and in their causation. in Angola ghting for independence from
This dimension was often neglected in overde- Portugal in the 1960s and 1970s and laying the
pendence on global ideological explanations basis of the MPLA/UNITA war since indepen-
of Cold War conicts in Africa, Asia and the dence. 12 For these analyses stress dierent
Middle East. 11 It has also been sidelined in the material interests underlying political mobili-
more nave explanations of more recent con- zation and ideology in each of the parties con-
icts in terms of primordial ethnic antipathies, tending to dominate the anti-colonial war and
in which this rigid hatred was seen as more post-independence politics: the FNLA, UNITA
important than any other factor. Yet there is no and the MPLA (Clarence-Smith, 1980; Bir-
denying the signicance of material interests in mingham, 1992). Relevant interests included the
the origins of conicts, even if at times (e.g., in frustration of dispossessed northern Angolan
Colombia) it is dicult to separate their role coee farmers (in the area providing most sup-
in the origins of conict from their inuence on port to the FNLA) whose farms were ex-
the characteristics and durability of conict. propriated by Portuguese settlers and whose
Timber and diamonds in Liberia and Sierra prospects of wage employment were cut short by
Leone, opium in Afghanistan, coca in Colom- settler use of migrant labor from the Ovimb-
bia, land and qat in Somalia, oil and diamonds undu highlands. They included these migrant
in Angola, tropical hardwoods in Cambodia, laborers and the farmers of the central highlands
and so on all feature large in any understanding plateau (the heartland of UNITA support). And
of conict. Arguably, pressure of population on they included the interests of those employed in
land combined with collapse of international manufacturing and clerical positions in and
coee prices was critical to the background around Luanda (the MPLAs domain).
to the Rwandan genocide (Andre & Platteau, To reduce the role of the material to the
1998; Austin, 1996). Vicious processes of asset lootability of primary resources (and therefore
transfer are common to the conicts in Sudan, the protability at the margin of conict and
Somalia and many other places (Besteman, violence over co-operation and exchange) con-
1999; Dueld, 1994; Ndikumana, 1998, p. 32). jures up Gramscis denition of economism, in
Meanwhile, conict in the Kivus (north and which
south) in the Democratic Republic of Congo
(DRC) has been driven to a signicant extent by an economic fact it means the self-interest of an in-
by a contest for control over the protable local dividual or small group, in an immediate. . . sense. . .
section of the marketing chain for tantalite, [it] is content to assume motives of mean and usurious
the heat-resistant metal used in space craft, self-interest, especially when it takes forms which the
mobile phones and computer game consoles law denes as criminal (Gramsci, 1971, p. 163).
(Jackson, 2001; Moore, Nabudere, & Kibas-
ambi, 2001). Time preference and credibility Gramsci dened economism as presenting
problems do seem to be overcome where, as is causes as immediately operative that in fact
1850 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

only operate indirectly, overestimating me- grievance, individual choice or unambiguous


chanical causation and indulging in doctri- coercion, in some circumstances. 15
naire pedantry (p. 178). The economism and Building on these doubts, the rest of this
reductionism of these models is certainly worse paper introduces three main sources of weak-
than anything to be found in Marxism, other ness in orthodox economic theories of conict
than in its most vulgar forms. and their relevance to contemporary civil
Even if axiomatic abstractions are merged wars. The rst weakness lies in the choice of
with variables imported by selection from sty- proxies used in attempts to add empirical con-
lised facts, neoclassical economic theories of tent to the theoretical postulates: these proxies
conict remain, as theories, abstract. They are are empirically and conceptually fragile. Sec-
completely speculative until some empirical ond, theories of conict rooted in micro-foun-
content is added. Given that the social, the dations of methodological individualism and
cultural, the historical, etc. are left out of the rational choice cannot avoid somehow bringing
initial framework, when they are brought back in the social: yet this endeavor is, again,
in later (which is inevitable) their incorporation empirically and analytically a failure. Third,
is arbitrarily selective. What is the basis for even if these orthodox economic theories and
assuming that people everywhere experience a econometric applications might capture a por-
choice of conict or co-operation dened solely tion of the reality of conicts, albeit crudely,
in terms of protability, where historical evi- they completely fail to capture one of the most
dence suggests that conict often is institu- signicant features of all conicts, i.e. struc-
tionalized (i.e. the rules of the game are tural and relational change.
conictual) and that the conditions of co-
operation and exchange are typically forged,
often slowly, out of conict (Tilly, 1992; How- 4. PROXY WARS
ard, 2001)? What is the basis for deciding that
people cannot be mobilized by ideology or In The Periodic Table, Primo Levi (1986)
promises of change (including change in mate- nds in one of his tales the following moral:
rial conditions of employment or production)
because of time-preference or leadership credi- that one must distrust the almost-the-same. . . the
bility problems, when history and contempo- practically identical, the approximate, the or-even,
all surrogates, and all patchwork. The dierences
rary democratic politics are virtually dened by can be small, but they can lead to radically dierent
political enthusiasm for all manner of pledges consequences, like a railroads switch points; the
despite their frequently being unfullled? 13 chemists trade consists in good part in being aware
What is the basis for deciding that collective of these dierences, knowing them close up, and fore-
action is necessarily framed in terms of his- seeing their eects. And not only the chemists trade.
torically xed ethnic capital or scores of
ethno-linguistic fragmentation, where evidence If there is anything substantial in the rational
suggests that ethnicity is commonly historically choice economists models of violent conict, it
dynamic and far from even in its organizing will emerge through empirical testing. But,
hold on people, and where there is no evidence where this testing has been done it has been,
that ethnic aliation is always prioritized over inevitably, through the use of proxies. What
other sources of collective identity, including matters, then, is whether the dierence between
class? Moreover, why must it be accepted that a proxy and the reality to which it is meant to
social phenomena are best apprehended be tagged makes a dierence: whether their
through individual rational choice (and a very signals might divert the train of analytical and
narrow notion of rationality) rather than rela- policy-making attention onto a siding. Do the
tional rationality and social and historical proxies actually measure what they purport to
constraints on choice? 14 On what grounds measure? There are two dimensions to an-
should we ignore the gray areas between choice swering this question: are the data adequate
and compulsion in human activities including and are the proxies conceptually or substan-
conict? For fear and obeisance to de facto tially equivalent to the thing they are meant
authorityas well as acquiescence with strong to represent? 16
mobilizing ideologies not through acceptance The most widely known use of proxy mea-
but through desperate eorts to resist local surements for rational choice models of violent
structures of oppressionare motivations that conict or civil wars currently is in the work of
might be more signicant than either greed or Collier and Hoeer. An early version (Collier
HOMO ECONOMICUS GOES TO WAR 1851

& Hoeer, 1996) posited that the utility of mogeneous society, controlling for other char-
choosing rebellion (Uw ) was a function of the acteristics.
probability of victory (p) and the gains to rebels Collier and Hoeer (1999) and Collier (2000)
upon victory (T), the potential for government engage more directly in the greed versus griev-
defence spending (D), the expected duration of ance question, separating the two motivations
the conict (M) and the co-ordination costs of and selecting proxies for each. Greed or loot
mobilizing for rebellion (C), such that: 17 seeking is proxied by the share of primary
commodities in total exportsbecause this
Uw fpD:T ; M; Cg represents the ease of instant taxation by loot-
The proxies chosen for the incentive for re- ingand by the proportion of young males in
bellion aimed to capture potential government the total population combined with average
military expenditure and revenue-raising ca- years of schooling (the latter supposed to cap-
pacity through three variables: income per ture the availability of economic opportunities
capita, the natural resource base, and the de- other than violence and looting in an econ-
gree of inequality in a society. Hence, poorer omy). Grievance or justice-seeking as a cause of
countries are more prone to conict because, civil war is captured by the almost-the-same
with income per capita at a low level, there is or practically identical proxies of economic
insucient tax-raising capacity to deter rebel- growth in the ve years prior to a conict,
lion. The use of inequality, measured in Gini scores of repression and restricted political
coecients, as a proxy for potential govern- rights, inequality (reappearing not as a proxy
ment defence spending is especially interesting. for potential government revenue but for
The reasoning adopted in Collier and Hoeer grievance), and ethno-linguistic fragmentation.
(1996) is that high inequality reects the pres- A little confusingly, some of these proxies, e.g.,
ence of an elite liable to encourage the gov- dependence on primary commodities, are swit-
ernment to raise taxation of elite wealth if this ched in Collier and Hoeer (2001) to stand not
is temporarily necessary to repel rebellion and for motive (i.e. greed) but for opportunity. 18
thereby preserve this unequal status quo. The use of these proxies does seem to be
The gains to rebellion conditional upon vic- patchwork. The argument that high degrees of
tory are assessed via the proxy of the natural inequality generate a greater capacity for tax-
resource endowment, which has uncertain ation of capital is derived from Alesina and
consequences given that resource endowment Rodrik (1994). Their argument, however, had
also aects the governments potential defence nothing to do with the self-preservation in-
spending. The proxy for the costs of rebel stincts of the wealthy but rather proposed that
co-ordination is the ethno-linguistic fragmen- where there is high inequality there will be
tation index (with complete homogeneity democratic pressure, exercised by the median
scoring zero and maximum fragmentation voter, for higher capital taxation, which in turn
scoring 100). The proposal here was that would harm growth prospects as this taxation
would reduce incentives to invest. The in-
the cost of co-ordination is. . . a quadratic function of equality/taxation proxy for potential govern-
the degree of cultural fractionalization, initially de- ment military expenditure and hence for the
creasing in it as potential rebels are distinguished from incentive/disincentive for rebellion is also
governments supporters, and then increasing in it as awed in two other respects. First, it makes
potential rebels are distinguished from each other (p. 5). something of a nave assumption about the
willingness of elites to be taxed: it is not clear
Collier and Hoeer (1998) amend this model, that even in democratic Latin American states,
retaining its core hypothesis and some of the for example, high inequality has made a sub-
proxies but combining ethno-linguistic with stantial dent, through eective tax increases, in
religious fractionalization and dropping in- the Gini coecient (Szekely & Hilgert, 1999).
equality completely from the model. The pur- Tax evasion remains extremely widespread in
pose of econometric analysis using proxies to many such countries. In countries threatened by
quantify indirectly the proposed variables in conict capital ight also has to be expected. 19
the models is, of course, to achieve predictive Second, the nancing of war is rather more
(probabilistic) power and Collier and Hoeer complex than is conveyed by this notion of
(1998) generates implications such as: For readily exible tax rates. Most wars have been
example, a highly fractionalized society such as nanced to signicant degrees, historically, by
Uganda would be about 40% safer than a ho- borrowing and by inationary money printing
1852 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

(Galbraith, 1975). Certainly tax increases have (Anderson, 1991). What matters more, then, is
been critical over the long-term but where this surely how ethnicity or race or whatever form
has been so, for example, during the consoli- collective identity takes does or does not come
dation of most European states, this has tended to play a signicant role in the origin and fea-
to involve hard-won innovations in scal insti- sibility of conict (Turton, 1997). 20 Mean-
tutions rather than quick x appeals to the while, regarding the second condition, it is
coers of the rich (Tilly, 1992; Ferguson, 2001). increasingly clear that in apparently obviously
The commitment by the wealthy, or by capi- ideological conicts such as the Zimbabwean
talists, to supporting the funding of war has liberation war and in apparently clearly eth-
been more complex, varied and politically con- nic conicts such as Rwanda, there is a range
tested than can be captured by a proxy like this. of sources of mobilization, and motivation,
Condence in these proxies must be under- enabling violent collective action. Primary
mined, also, by the way in which one proxy, among these is force itself. Coercion, whether
inequality, is used across models: rst it is taken subtle or brutal, is a common constant of most
as almost-the-same as the self-preservation in- contemporary conicts. This in itself suggests
stinct of elites and hence of the scal prospects that, however neat the t with some qua-
for war nance; then it is dropped as not the dratic function of the role of ethnic fractional-
same as anything; then it is reintroduced as ization or indeed with the availability of
almost-the-same as the source of injustice and instantly taxable primary commodities, such
hence potential grievance-fuelled conict. incentives and organizing principles are typi-
Ethno-linguistic fragmentation is used fairly cally insucient to make war work, either for
constantly as a proxy for co-ordination costs rebels or incumbent governments. Meanwhile,
and so for the likelihood of collective action. there is evidence of a range of agendas of social
For this to be eective as a proxy, to be conict that aect peoples readiness to ght or
practically identical to the actual possibilities logistically to support civil conict, aside from
of and constraints on mobilization for collec- straightforward protability at the margin.
tive action, two conditions must be met. The These include gender and generational conict
rst is that ethnicity is the only signicant cat- and highly personal or interpersonal relations
egory of collective identity and aliation, and of rivalry and envy.
that it operates in the same way across all so- A further diculty with the proxies used in
cieties such that more, or less, of it (fragmen- these models is that it is far from obvious that
tation) will have much the same consequences the proxy is being assigned to the appropriate
irrespective of geographical and historical object. Preponderance in exports of primary
context. The second condition is that there are commodities might indicate the availability of
no other eective sources of mobilization. Evi- lootable goods and so make violence more
dence suggests that neither condition holds. protable at the margin than the dreary grind
Ethnicity has played a very secondary role at of underemployment and poverty. But in doing
most in many conicts and the intensity of this it might just as well be a proxy for failed
ethnic animosity does not seem to vary with policy, missing economic dynamism, a proba-
dierences in the index of fragmentation. Its ble shortage of consumer goods and imports
signicance has been highly particular and very and widespread grievance or dissatisfaction
dierent across, for example, Somalia, Rwanda, with this predicament. There is the further
Sierra Leone, Liberia and Angola. Likewise, problem that the category primary commod-
ethnicity may have played a role in Central ities is absurdly broad. Open cast or alluvial
American conicts but it has hardly been a diamonds might be easy to loot (for soldiers)
dominant cause in many, and clearly its role but not deep-mined diamonds, or aluminum,
has varied between El Salvador, Mexico and oil, etc. Other primary commodities like cotton
Nicaragua. In Yugoslavia ethnicity only came or cocoa do not generate prot levels associated
to matter politically in a distinctly modern with conict commodities. Others still, such as
way, that is, as an outcome of economic, ad- coee, have often been associated with conict
ministrative, and political policies and experi- but not in a direct way through lootability. One
ences from the 1950s onward (Schierup, 1992, approach that has added a much needed detail
1993); and then in a cumulative, modular or to the analysis of commodities in conictand
mimetic way drawing on real and imagined that nds still that commodities are subsidiary
pasts in a way very similar to the spread of to political dynamicsis the political geogra-
nationalism as an imagined community phy of Le Billon (2001).
HOMO ECONOMICUS GOES TO WAR 1853

Similarly, a low average for years of school- pagne together. That is called national unity. While
ing might represent the lack of decent oppor- this is going on, we get nothing. Have you ever seen
tunities for (nonconictual) gainful employment any of the national leaders losing one of their own
children in this war? Why is it always us? This has
and therefore reveal a low opportunity cost of gone beyond a joke. We are going to loot all their
conict: however, it might just as well reect or houses and tomorrow, when we rebuild the country,
be directly a source of social anger. 21 Evidence perhaps we will nally have a job to go to (quoted
for this is especially sharp for Sierra Leone, in Bazenguissa-Ganga, 1999, p. 48). 27
where poor educational attainment has, re-
portedly, fuelled grievances among young age The claims of political leaders or the state-
cohorts who have appealed for improved re- ments of individual rebels or soldiers are bound
source allocations to schools, in a country with to be partial and subjective, but surely it would
a particularly strong educational heritage in be absurd to regard them as having no infor-
sub-Saharan Africa (Richards, 1996). Since mational content? As Keen (2001) argues, a
loot has been a central feature of the Sierra more useful focus for research than the sepa-
Leone conict, within the framework of the ration of greed and grievance is the way in
orthodox economic models of conict this which they interact, most notably how the
presents a paradox of apparently coexisting greedy manipulate the grievances of others.
grievance and greed. 22 Further, to complicate matters, it is far from
One way to resolve the paradox is to appeal obvious that a given conict, e.g., a civil war,
to the false consciousness argument, as Col- is a single phenomenon whose quantiable ag-
lier (2000) does by arguing that the narrative gregates clearly reveal individual preferences.
of grievance has no informational con- For example, participants in a conict may take
tent. 23 Another is to reject the categorical part through varying degrees of coercion or
distinction between greed and grievance as voluntary choice and may represent a range of
false. In this case it becomes clear that greed agendas of diering passions and interests that
and grievance do not just coexist in the origin overlap in the overall conict. Kriger (1992)
of conict, but that they might be internally shows how many dierent forms of conict were
related to one another. 24 Put dierently, where fought under the mantel of the liberation war in
does greed, or loot-seeking, or aggressive Zimbabwe. Among these conicts, many women
goods and prot acquisition behavior come were more or less coercively mobilized behind
from? Is it not feasible that greed emerges from the Zanu-PF war eort but still used the war to
grievance? 25 If Kosovo Albanians want better advance their own gender-related conicts.
material conditions (and even if some of them Similarly, part of the motivation for young
emerge as wartime entrepreneurs, proteers, males joining the war was not necessarily grand
etc.) is this a manifestation of the aggregated hopes of relief from racial discrimination, or
greed of individual Kosovo Albanians or of a immediate material gains, but escape from the
historical and relational grievance given par- oppressive hierarchy of rural life dominated by
ticular historical and political opportunities? 26 male elders. Each of these levels or types of
How big is the dierence and might the two conict subsumed in the greater war contains its
combine in the mobilization and decision own specic history of social relations, and its
making of individuals? Another example of the own complex mixture of direct interest in ma-
ambiguous mingling of greed and grievance as terial gain with a push for changes in the rules or
a motivation for violence is given in the wide- customs of social relationships. This degree of
spread political violence during the 1990s in complexity has not, to date, been captured by
Congo-Brazzaville, chiey by a range of mili- neoclassical theory, nor by the proxies used in
tias with dierent political aliations. Looting applications of the theory.
in Brazzaville in 1997 was known as slaugh- The false consciousness argument is based on
tering the pig or, referring to the Elf Aqui- a rigid conceptual distinction between greed
taine-controlled oil eld of Nkossa, Nkossa, and grievance, it is sustained by the conceit that
everyone gets his share, both capturing a the proxies used in applications of the models
criticism of the failure by the political elite to are genuinely almost-the-same as their ob-
redistribute the wealth of the country. As one jects, and lastly it depends on the reliability of
militiaman put it, when accused of theft: the data explored to test the model. But, there
are hugely signicant empirical weaknesses with
You call that stealing? When they incite us to kill, they most, probably all of the proxies employed.
call it human folly, then afterwards they drink cham- Inequality data are notoriously frail, especially
1854 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

for use in crosscountry comparisons (and a Arrow (1994), for example, argues for the reli-
fortiori for sub-Saharan Africa, where many ance of all neoclassical models on irreducibly
recent conicts have taken place). 28 Produc- social categories and at least suggests that the
tion data emphasizing the preponderance of implications are not always compatible with
primary commodities are prone to errors, neo-classical paradigms, particularly rational
thanks to unrecorded manufacturing activity choice (p. 8). The discussion above of proxy
and the elision in some data sets (particularly measures suggests, for example, how ungainly
concerning mining) between manufacturing economic models can become when they deal in
and primary commodity activities (Riddell, variables such as ethno-linguistic fragmenta-
1990; Yeats, 1990). Data on educational at- tion. Hirshleifer (1994) introduces the social
tainment have their weaknesses, but beyond the element through the role of preferences, ex-
crude gures there are problems in assuming a plained in terms of, for example, strong group
direct, universal and predictable relationship identication or its converse, xenophobia (both
between educational attainment and viable accounted for in Darwinian evolutionary
economic opportunities, e.g., in employment terms). Ethnicity is the main preference or at-
(Bennell, 1996; Pritchett, 1997). The relation- titudinal variable, as we have seen, in Colliers
ship depends, among other things, on the various models. But when the social is stripped
availability of agricultural wage labor (rarely from the starting principles and axioms of a
captured eectively in rural survey data) and model and then reintroduced later, it is not
on the particular set of policies adopted by surprising that the t is awkward.
governments. Finally, the ethno-linguistic This shows particularly strongly in em-
fragmentation index is far from foolproof pirically applied models, where the social,
(McIlwham, 1998). Needless to say, data ob- accounting for preferences, has to take a
servations for countries already aected by quantiable and comparable form such as the
conict are even more unreliable, when many cumbersome ethno-linguistic fragmentation
goods are traded illegally and statistical services index. The result is a virtually arbitrary appeal
do not have the same reach as in peacetime to the social and a distinctly functional under-
(Cramer & Weeks, 2000). standing of social variables. Azam (2001) ac-
The use of conceptually and empirically knowledges that ethnicity falls short of
vague proxies is an instance of the more general providing even the beginning of an explana-
problem of the empirical weakness, arbitrary tion of conicts in Africa. Nonetheless, in
prioritization of particular variables, and ma- setting up a model in which state formation is a
nipulation of technique over and above the transitional process starting from an institu-
search for truth in econometrics. Main- tional endowment of ethnic division, and in
stream economists and econometric practitio- which the objective of state formation seems to
ners such as Mayer (1993) and Leamer (1983) be to provide a credible substitute for ethnic
have often cautioned against the frequent, al- capital (p. 430), Azam repeats the assumption
most institutionalized abuse of technique. More that ethnic aliation is the primary form taken
radical critics, such as Lawson (1997), have by collective identity and social organization in
argued for the more fundamental failure as an Africa and that its operations are equivalent
analytical device of econometrics. throughout Africa. Indeed, the

ethnic group is the natural component of a rebellion


5. FIGHT FOR YOUR PREFERENCES! against the state, as the many links that exist among
THE CONFLICT BETWEEN its members provide an ecient way of overcoming
METHODOLOGICAL INDIVIDUALISM the free-rider problems involved in mobilizing a rebel-
AND THE SOCIAL lion or insurgency.

When orthodox economics deals in ethnic If this were so self-evident, some rebels in
fragmentation or in collective action questions, Africae.g. Renamo in Mozambiquehave
it is engaging with social issues. Again, this is made remarkably poor use of ethnic capital.
not unusual: mainstream economics has be- Ethnicity seems to have been relatively weak
come more open in confronting the social in its compared with organization around nationalist
sweeping colonization of the social sciences. ideals and a shared local history of repeated
But, the encounter between methodological oppression in the relatively straightforward re-
individualism and rational choice is fraught. lationship between rebels and local population
HOMO ECONOMICUS GOES TO WAR 1855

in the dark forests of Matabeleland during In short, rational choice economic models of
the liberation war in Zimbabwe (Alexander, conict are extreme in their reductionism and
McGregor, & Ranger, 2000). The dissidents fail in explanatory terms. Arguably, this failure
leaving the NZA after independence did so not is predictable from the very founding principles
so much from an Ndebele will to collective re- of neoclassical economics. For, as Zarovski
bellion against the state but from a desperate argues, neoclassical economics does not oer a
compulsion to self-preservation (Alexander basis for generalization of rational choice to all
et al., 2000). In the war in Liberia it is fairly social phenomena. Thus, many neoclassical
clear that ethnicity played at most a minor and economists, and their founding fathers, ac-
secondary role (Ellis, 1999). As Azam himself knowledge the distinctiveness of noneconomic
points out, the RUF in Sierra Leone had no phenomena, accept that Homo economicus is an
ethnic support and no national program abstraction and an abstraction, at that, of one
(2000, p. 439); and the urban rebellion in Mali dimension of human behavior, and even in the
that led to the overthrow of General Moussa market economy eventually realize that life is
Traore was not an ethnic rebellion but a gen- ontologically irrational (Zarovski, 2000, p.
eral response to Traores policy of gradual 453). 30 The point may be made by showing
reduction of state involvement in the accumu- how one particularly open exercise in building
lation of human capital. Lemarchand (1994, on neoclassical foundations an explanation of
p. 4) agrees: that the tribalist argument is power relations basically accepts its own limi-
singularly unhelpful for a comprehension of tations. Pagano (1999) distinguishes between
African conict situations has been demon- private goods, public goods and positional
strated repeatedly. Indeed, the central para- goods. Positional goods have properties that
dox of the Burundi situation (is how) centuries are the opposite of those of public goods: for
of relatively peaceful commingling between the consumption of positional goods, rather
Hutu and Tutsi, cemented by their shared loy- than implying like a public good the impossi-
alty to a common set of institutions, (could) bility of excluding consumption by others, im-
suddenly dissolve into fratricide (Lemarc- plies the ineluctable inclusion of negative
hand, 1994, p. 3). consumption by others. One persons enjoy-
If there are severe problems with the way in ment of a positional good deprives others of
which the social is introduced into rational that good (Hirsch, 1997); e.g., if the good
choice, methodologically individualist models confers power on its positive consumer, the
of conict, there are also problems deriving negative consumer has to experience subordi-
from the failure to incorporate the social, or to nation. Hence, the consumption of positional
embed the economic and individual in the so- goods is necessarily conictual. Positional
cial, relational and historical. Greed, for ex- competition may aect the ex ante desirability
ample, is not conceived in these models as a of having market transactions for positional
relational concept. Greed relates individuals to goods (p. 71). Here we have not the happen-
objects directly: other people become simply stance of Hirshleifers mutually inconsistent
obstacles that may be overcome by violence if opportunity sets but a directly relational
the opportunity cost of this action is suciently analysis: a problem not of the natural scar-
low. In other words, the objects (the lootable city economics is accustomed to dealing in,
primary commodities) are of primary causal but of social scarcity. The diculty with this
signicance, other people of secondary signi- analysis is, however, that despite its pretensions
cance at best aside from some xed and prior it is not consistent with methodological indi-
ethnic capital. Hence, greed in these models vidualism and rational choice. The focus on the
contrasts with concepts such as envy or mimetic positive/negative consumption of positional
rivalry, which are inherently relational and goods depends for its coherence on a set of
provide grounds for rooting an analysis of positions in social structures, positions into
the role of resources and commodities within which individuals slot more or less inter-
specic relational structures and histories. 29 changeably and that are the nuts and bolts of a
Where relations are concerned, it is necessary to structure of social relations. Yet this demotes
explore their precise characteristics in dierent the individual within the analytical framework
contexts, an analytical process that, even where and constrains individual choice within social
comparative, does not lend itself to large cross- structure and what must often be (in the posi-
sectional samples and econometric testing for tive/negative consumption image) basically
regular patterns of events freed from context. power relations. Furthermore, while natural
1856 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

scarcity may stress a problem common across If the question of how to pay for a war is not
societies, social scarcity stresses a problem the same as that of what caused a war, none-
which diers widely from one society to the theless the modalities of war nance, or the
other and is strictly related to changes in social material reproduction of conict, is not a sim-
relations. Pagano also recognizes that one way ple technical question. For, rst, the means of
to expand positive consumption of positional war nance may sustain capital accumulation
goods is by manipulating the preferences of (and hence an interest in continued conict)
others, i.e. raising their willingness to consume and, in the process, accelerate social change
the corresponding negative amount; and that including disruptive class formations and a
achieving a less conictual society may involve long-term political settlement. Second, those
diluting peoples taste for positional good engaged in economic activities during war that
consumption. He notes that economics com- both sustain conict and enable private capital
monly takes preferences as given (as the models accumulation are often very much people
discussed above do), and hints strongly that whose material and political interests were at
neoclassical economics is not up to the chal- stake in the origin of the conict. This is not the
lenge of studying these problems of changing same as saying that their quest for loot of Sierra
preferences. 31 Others might more explicitly Leonean diamonds or Cambodian tropical
recast this discussion in terms of the role of hardwoods or Afghan opium is precisely what
ideology, culture, hegemony, and political caused the war.
struggle. 32 We seem here to be in the opposite I am suggesting that the roots of conict do
predicament to that claimed by Hirshleifer, i.e. lie in political economy, but that this involves
it might be argued that when economists do investigating the changes in social relations and
good work they are doing political economy, material conditions within which individuals
not neoclassical economics. act constrained by available social knowl-
Arguably, then, orthodox economic models edge (Arrow, 1994), compelled by instincts of
of conict begin with a set of arbitrary as- survival as much as by the drive for political
sumptions; eorts to test them empirically have power, not so much making rational choices as
so far foundered on misleading use of proxies; resolving internal struggles, and so on. In de-
and these models have not succeeded in incor- veloping a political economy of conict, it is
porating the irreducibly social on which they also necessary to include the signicance of the
depend. The emphasis on protability at the means of conict themselves, i.e. the conditions
margin or loot-seeking as a cause of war does of availability of guns and related technology;
not necessarily lead to, but certainly in in- and to acknowledge that violent conict, like
stances has led to, a fetishizing of commodities. other forms of social organization and inter-
Yet how a war is paid for is not equivalent to action, is modular and commonly reproduced
what caused a war. Two examples make this by a form of copying or spillover. 33 Otherwise
clearer. First, oil and diamonds fuel war in it is not possible to answer questions like the
Angola. These resources clearly aect the du- one posed by Lemarchand (above) for Burundi:
rability of this conict and they determine why conict at a particular moment when many
many of its characteristics. But they are not the of the variables have been in place for long
original cause of conict. Indeed, an earlier periods of time without provoking violent
phase of this war was sustained less by these conict. A political economy approach, rooted
natural resources and more by Cold War mili- in the analysis of social relations and the
tary aid to both sides, yet while this aid did powerful inuence on those relations of mate-
have more to do with the origins of the conict rial conditions, clearly has to give a prominent
still that nancing (and attendant political role to the analysis of capital and of not just
meddling) was only a part of the origin of the class formation but class disintegration too.
conict. Second, tantalite deposits are crucial From this perspective two more factors emerge
to the characteristics of warfare in the Kivu more clearly as inuencing conicts than they
regions of eastern DRC; but again, they did not are credited in many of the models outlined
by themselves cause the conict. Conict in above. First, policy and domestic political
Kivu had its origins both in the Rwandan war struggle within countries dominate real out-
and genocide and its aftermath and in the col- comes. Specic political decisions, strategies
lapse of Mobutus domination of Zaire (and in and contests in the former Yugoslavia before
a history of Rwandan involvement in the region the 1990s, in Nicaragua leading up to and fol-
of the Kivus). lowing the Sandinista revolution, in Uganda
HOMO ECONOMICUS GOES TO WAR 1857

and Rwanda leading up to the 1990s, and so on production during colonialism and by the place
had immense impact on the generation of Angola had in the politics of the Cold War (and
armed conict. Second, capital and capitalism its aftermath).
is an international phenomenon and always has The question of change is important in de-
been. None of the so-called civil wars of recent ning the grounds for an alternative analytical
times can be explained without the dimension framework for understanding contemporary
of the interests and activities of international conicts. Neoclassical models of conict often
capital linkages. Trends since the end of the emphasize the socially wasteful consequences of
Cold War in production of arms (privatiza- conict. In this they tie in with rent-seeking
tion and diversication of production sites in- analysis and also with what was once called the
ternationally, partly prompted by evasion of liberal interpretation of war (Milward, 1970):
tighter trade regulations in some countries than the presumption that the consequences of
otherssee Lumpe, 2000); the interests of conict were exclusively negative, a presump-
mining companies, mineral traders and indus- tion that was challenged by analysis of the First
tries associated by a variety of linkages to these World War but one that has been inuential in
activities; privatized security rms; and indeed post-Cold War costs of war analyses (e.g.,
the businesses of aid (ICRC, 2000): all these Stewart, 1993; Stewart & Fitzgerald, 2000).
and more are features that help to repro- Like the rent-seeking literature and liberal in-
duce violent conict internationally (Dueld, terpretation of war exercises, neoclassical modes
2001). of conict ignore the distinctions between
conicts that emerge from studying conict and
change, and indeed conict and class formation
and relations. Put simply, and by analogy with
6. CONCLUSIONS: LIBERATING THE Khans (1995) discussion of rent seeking, some
POLITICAL ECONOMY OF WAR FROM conicts might have consequences that are
ECONOMICS IMPERIALISM value-enhancing in the medium to long run
while others might have dierent consequences.
Joanna Bourke, in An Intimate History of This would depend on the political settle-
Killing (1999), argues that combatants in major ment forged in conict and, in turn, on the
international 20th century wars often insisted political economy of change that contributed to
on the myth of their own agency, asserting their the origins of conict. (In many cases it is still
own individuality and responsibility in the too soon to be able to judge this outcome either
midst of disorder. This is not to argue that way, however.)
order and consistency could actually be Among the levels at which an analysis of
achieved. . . But the acceptance of agency en- change can proceed are those dened in terms
abled combatants to take that one step towards of, rst, an end of empire syndrome and,
the making of a bearable, and possibly enter- second, primitive accumulation. It is dicult
taining war (p. 370). The arguments set out to account for the timing and geographical in-
above suggest that neoclassical economics does cidence of conict without including some at-
something very similar: faced with the com- tention to end of hierarchy moments, or regime
plexity of conicts, and indeed of the social in changes and their huge capacity to open up the
general, it insists on the myth of rational choice scope for desperate conict over position,
individualism, even in the midst of evidence of power, wealth, voice, survival, etc. (Howard,
a range of structural constraints on individu- 2001). From this perspective it is no surprise
alism and of compulsions other than utility that conicts have broken out in rashes at the
maximization that constrain choice and pro- end of colonial periods or at the end of the
duce a diversity of war rather than a single Cold War oras in Rwandawhere there has
type. Agency is involved in the origins of con- been external pressure for democratization. 34
ict, choices are made, and economic incentives The end of a domestic regime and the end of
do matter, as do individuals. But they are in- straightforward Cold War patterns and rela-
uenced by and operate very much within tions combined in Zaire/DRC to contribute to
specic conditions and social and historical a rash of conicts within that country since the
features of change. In Angola, for example, the late 1990s. Clearly, end-of-hierarchy predica-
choices open to Jonas Savimbi (and his adver- ments are not sucient to cause conicts, but as
saries) were shaped and constrained by the or- a facilitating factor it is probably worth paying
ganization of political power and economic them more attention than they receive in most
1858 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

analyses and conict prevention policy-making just the fact of the presence of tantalite depos-
paradigms. In the same way, the modular or its. 35
mimetic dimension of conict and in particular This last example also highlights another di-
the tendency to regional spillover eects needs mension of the political economy of conicts
to play a greater role in explanations of con- that is dealt with, if at all, very weakly in neo-
ict. Wallensteen and Sollenberg (1998) have classical economic models of conict: that is,
stressed very eectively the signicance in re- their international dimensions, or better, their
cent intrastate conicts of regional conict role in international capitalism. 36 Each civil
complexes. war that could be cited around the world
The other main level at which change matters during, say, the past decade has been only in-
far more than it is given credit for in neoclas- completely explicable without due attention to
sical economic models is the level of class international political intervention and eco-
formation, class relations, and primitive accu- nomic interests, where these interests may in-
mulation. The dynamics of an eective transi- volve both traditionally licit and illicitly traded
tion to capitalism in Yugoslavia and the commodities. 37
policies that aected the lives (and scope for Meanwhile, one further factor that plays very
collective action in class terms) of workers, little role in neoclassical explanations of conict
peasants, and capitalists there threw the coun- and that itself needs to be understood in terms
try into a deepening crisis in which political of changes in international political economy
opportunists and primitive accumulators were and particular strategies of capitalists in indi-
able to manipulate the resources of collective vidual states is that of the supply of the means
imagination onto which hard-pressed Yugo- of violent conict, i.e. arms. While changes
slavs were thrown back (Schierup, 1992). The (end-of-regime changes) associated with the
processes of asset transfer referred to by end of the Cold War have had a major inu-
Dueld (1994) and Keen (1994) in Southern ence on the supply and cost of arms within
Sudan and elsewhere are also instances of regions including Southern Africa and Af-
primitive accumulation, in which one (poten- ghanistan, it is also necessary to trace shifts in
tially capitalist) class brutally prises away land, production. These shifts include privatization
livestock and other assets from their previous and a diversication of production rms and
owners or occupiers and, in the process, prises national sites of production (partly as major
these people away from their means of repro- industrialized country producers seek to relo-
duction, creating refugees, slaves, ghters and cate production in middle income countries like
migrant laborers, all of whom might be ex- Brazil or Turkey in an eort more easily to
pected to contribute over time to a process of evade international, e.g., EC, constraints on
proletarianization. Conict in Angola since trade in arms).
before independence took on patterns and di- There is not enough space in this paper to
visions that were driven to a very signicant trace more fully a political economy framework
degree by the ways in which collective identities for understanding conicts: however, three
(partly racial/ethnic/regional, partly ideologi- brief points may be made in conclusion. First,
cal) were shaped by evolving material interests research and analysis need to focus on relations
given the peculiarities and variations of the of force rather than just choices of violence.
spread of capitalism within colonial Angola. For instance, there is a need empirically to ex-
The constraints imposed by the Somoza regime plore the contrast between the idea of the
both on peasants and workers and on Nicara- comparative advantage of the poor (leading
guas capitalist class were critical to the for- them to allocate more time to violence) and the
mation of a shifting balance of class forces and possibility that violence is forced upon many
political interests that led to the Sandinista people and that even if they are not directly
revolution, that shaped that revolution, and press-ganged into militias violence may repre-
that aected the nature of the domestic resis- sent a horric last resort. 38 Furthermore, re-
tance to that revolution. In the Kivu districts lations of force are often institutionalized
of eastern DRC the possibilities and con- historically as, for example, they have been in
straints on a moment of primitive accumula- Rwanda since the colonial period in particular.
tion (by Rwandan political and military Second, there needs to be more research than
ocials and others, as elsewhere in the country has yet been undertaken on the role of partic-
by Zimbabwean military ocers and others) is ular policy developments. For example, some
what drives violence and conict rather than argue that market liberalization within devel-
HOMO ECONOMICUS GOES TO WAR 1859

oping countries reduces the propensity to con- Third, there needs to be more analysis of cap-
ict by dissipating rent; but others argue that italism rather than commodities, of social re-
liberalization and other associated structural lations rather than only individual choices, and
adjustment processes can be associated with a of policy rather than merely structural deter-
heightened vulnerability to conict (Cramer & minism by objective conditions of oppression
Weeks, 2002; Storey, 1998; Herring, 2001). or opportunities for greed.

NOTES

1. An interesting related question is whether wars 9. On inequality and conict see Cramer (2001) and
themselves have changed or simply the way they are Stewart (2000).
understood (Buijtenhuijs, 2000).
10. There is no shortage of objective reasons for
2. For rather dierent perspectives on the colonization revolt in Central America, but the ideological shifts of
of the social sciences by economics, see Hirschman the past four decades do not correspond directly to any
(1970, p. 19) and Fine (1999). obvious mutation in the socioeconomic environment.
Second, there is a correlation between this ideological
3. In the way of Coase, individuals never pass up the uctuation and the periodization of internal wars in the
chance of mutually benecial exchange, while the way of region (Grenier, 1996, p. 34).
Macchiavelli provides that people will not pass up the
opportunity for coercion if this serves maximization
11. Some might argue that material factors did play a
goals.
lesser role during the Cold War, playing second ddle to
ideology and global politics: assuming we can distin-
4. A very good illustration of the fragmented and guish materialism from these factors neatly, this argu-
internally divided characteristics of one rebel movement ment certainly undermines recent empirical tests of
is presented in Guevaras (2001) journal describing part neoclassical conict models since these tests examine
of the Congolese rebellion against Tshombes govern- samples including Cold War era conicts. On the other
ment in 1964. hand, there is a plausible argument that both left and
right did neglect the intricate political economy of
5. This can lead to the implicationas it does for conict in Angola, Mozambique, Nicaragua, and else-
Azam (2001)that donor policies must not undermine where.
state formation and that high public sector wages might
be worth the resulting shortfall in public goods
12. More recent examples of a richer materialist
spending if they ensure peace.
analysis of conicts include Keen (2001) and Dueld
(2001). See also Cramer (1994) and Marchal and
6. See www.worldbank.org/conict. Messiant (2001).

7. The chief intellectual foundation of Kaplans article


13. Indeed, recent political developments in Zimba-
was Homer-Dixon (1991).
bwe, including the countrys costly involvement in war in
the DRC as well as populist encouragement of violence
8. Others have taken the idea of what might be called a against white farmers within Zimbabwe, might suggest
new barbarism more seriously, though also viewing it in that conict can be a response to fading delivery on
a more serious light than did Kaplan. For example, earlier promises and hopes rather than a pre-emptive
Hobsbawm (1998) claims that the 20th century repre- evasion based on the calculation of peoples rational
sented a return to barbarism in the sense of a loss of time preferences. Grenier (1996) argues for the powerful
enlightenment values. Keane (1996) focuses on what he role of a moment of ideological mimesis (following the
calls uncivil war. Meanwhile, there are those like Cuban revolution) within Central America as a deter-
Lindqvist (1998) and Mann (1999) who, more in the minant of conicts and their timing in that region.
vein of Walter Benjamins comment that every document
of civilization is at the same time a document of
barbarism, highlight the specically European, 19th 14. Even at the level of the individual choosing war
century roots of 20th century global brutality and these models ignore the rationality of managing con-
genocide. icts, rationality not necessarily conned to means-ends
1860 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

calculus and not exclusively tied to maximization inappropriate in those many war contexts that cannot
(Hampshire, 2001); such models also ignore individuals be characterized, even just prior to the outbreak of war,
themselves as sites of struggle or internal conict. as democratic.
Particularly good applications of more subtle thinking
on rationality in economics and the social sciences are
Sen (1986) and Pizzorno (1986). 20. One approach to understanding the role of ethnic-
ity in conict is Stewarts (2000) argument that ethnicity
matters when combined with horizontal inequality.
15. On peasant support for radical rebels in El Salva-
dor, see Grenier (1996).
21. As Stewart (2000) argues, it is not just the quantity
of education that matters to socially conictual out-
16. The Collier and Hoeer models, and other related comes but its distribution given categorical inequalities
models, dier signicantly in their specication. Meth- drawn up along lines of collective identities; thus
odologically, the typical technique is to use probit and unequal educational access was prevalent from colonial
tobit testing to observations. With these techniques it is times in Rwanda, Burundi, and until the Khymer
less clear what signicance is really attributable to given revolution, in Cambodia. In post-colonial Burundi there
variables and a great deal of the results is determined were deliberate attempts to limit educational access by
in the sampling. For example, in Collier and Hoeer the Hutu, while educated Hutu were targeted for killing
(1999) a table summarizing the models predictions in the 1970s (p. 5).
lines up predicted no and yes outcomes of war
against actual events. If we look at the 27 countries in
22. For a similar argument see Keen (2001).
the sample that did have civil wars we nd that the
model predicts half and fails to predict half. The dice
appear a little loaded when one sees that the sample 23. It should be noted that while Collier emphasizes
includes 20 OECD countries in the total of 98, including the apparently denitive disincentive to rebellion that is
Australia, Canada, Finland, France, Iceland, Japan, the collective action and free rider problem, Grossman
Malta, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Spain, (1991) in stressing expected private returns to insurgents
Sweden, the United Kingdom and the United States. rather than social benets at least seems to acknowledge
that individualist choice theoretic theories are comple-
mentary to those emphasizing social factors more.
17. In the 1998 version of this model, population size
and a discount rate are added to the utility function, and
the proxy for rebel co-ordination costs is amended to 24. See Lawson (1997) on internal relations, whereby
include ethnic and/or religious fragmentation rather one thing only exists in terms of its ties to another.
than just ethno-linguistic fragmentation.
25. One could note that in one of the early texts of
18. Collier and Hoeer (2001) appears to be a partial object relations theory in psychoanalysis, Klein (1997)
retreat from some of the claims of earlier versions and makes precisely this argument that greed and grievance
are inextricably and internally related.
makes the rather more limited claim that wars occur
generally where wars are possible (i.e. underlying
reasons and motivations for war might be very wide- 26. See, for example, Independent International Com-
spread but require some mixture of opportunities if they mission on Kosovo (2000).
are actually to take place, or not just to break out but to
scale up and last long enough to break into the set of 27. Similarly, the evidence of predatory taxation in
wars dened as substantial enough for inclusion in the Liberia does not exclude the possibility of politics in the
sample). Thus, if dependence on primary commodity programs of armed forces there (Atkinson, 1997).
exports is a particularly powerful risk factor this
might be because they oer scope for extoriton by rebels: 28. Colliers argument that inequality data are reliable
Whether such extortion directly motivates rebellion, or because they have successfully been used in models
simply makes viable the violent pursuit of other objec- explaining growth ignores the fragility of those growth
tives, is beyond the scope of this paper (Collier & models drawing on endogenous growth theory and new
Hoeer, 2001, p. 2). political economy assumptions (see Cramer, 2000).

19. Furthermore, as one anonymous reviewer of this 29. On mimetic rivalry and violence see Girard (1977,
paper pointed out, median voter theory is rather 1996).
HOMO ECONOMICUS GOES TO WAR 1861

30. Ontological irrationality is conceived in terms of contemporary conicts is Moore et al. (2001), which
inconsistency, action outside means-ends frameworks, focuses on the case study of the DRC.
the inuence of internalized habit, and so on.
36. On the role of war in the contemporary world
31. Some, like Gintis (1998) are more condent that economy see Cramer (2002) and Dueld (2001).
preferences (which for Gintis may be endogenously
determined) are susceptible to policy and to economic
modelling. 37. See Reno (1996) for outside commercial interests in
Sierra Leone; Gourevitch (1998) for the combination of
32. For Hirsh, who also argued that the traditional external interests and decision-making failures inuenc-
individualist analytical framework of economics was ing the genocide in Rwanda, and Global Witness (1998,
inadequate, the challenge was a moral one. 2002) on Angola; and for one analysis of an earlier form
of external intervention promoting conict in Southern
33. This is clear from the prevalence of regional Africa, Minter (1994). The signicance of borders and
conict complexes (Wallensteen & Sollenberg, 1998), crossborder spillovers, especially clear recently in Libe-
from the evidence of the historical persistence of war, ria/Sierra Leone and Rwanda/Burundi, echoes the sig-
e.g., in Africa (Justice Africa, 2000), and from the nicance of borders to Wolfs (1969) work on peasant
imagery of identication with global violencemost rebellions.
notably the Rambo lookalikes and video popularity in
Somalia, in Sierra Leone, and in KwaZulu/Natal (see, 38. This argument is analogous in social terms to the
e.g., Richards, 1996; and Kaarsholm, 2001). argument of Grossman (1995) that soldiers, indeed all
humans, powerfully resist wherever possible the need
34. On the scope for conict to break out during actually to kill someone, that they go to great lengths to
moments of democratization, see Snyder (2000). avoid doing so even if they may be happy to engage in
the rituals of aggressive posturing, etc., and that in the
35. One of the few analyses directly to address prim- absence of nely tuned conditioning the act of killing
itive accumulation as a central feature in explaining is very much a last resort for most people.

REFERENCES

Alesina, A., & Rodrik, D. (1994). Distributive politics Bennell, P. (1996). Rates of return to education: does the
and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Econom- conventional pattern prevail in sub-Saharan Africa?
ics, 109(2), 465490. World Development, 24(1), 183199.
Alexander, J., McGregor, J., & Ranger, T. (2000). Besteman, C. (1999). Unraveling Somalia: race, violence,
Violence and memory: one hundred years in the dark and the legacy of slavery. Philadelphia: University of
forests of Matabeleland. Oxford: James Currey. Pennsylvania Press.
Anderson, B. (1991). Imagined communities: reections Birmingham, D. (1992). Frontline nationalism in Angola
on the origin and spread of nationalism (second ed.). and Mozambique. Trenton, NJ: Africa World Press
London: Verso. and London, James Currey.
Andre, C., & Platteau, J. P. (1998). Land relations under Booth, J. (1991). Socio-economic roots of national
unbearable stress: Rwanda caught in the Malthusian revolts in Central America. Latin American Research
trap. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organisa- Review, 26(1), 3374.
tion, 34(1), 147. Bourke, J. (1999). An intimate history of killing: face to
Arrow, K. (1994). Methodological individualism and so- face killing in twentieth-century warfare. New York:
cial knowledge. American Economic Review, 84(2), 19. Basic Books.
Atkinson, P. (1997). The war economy in Liberia: a Boyce, J. (Ed.) (1996). Economic policy for building
political analysis. Relief and Rehabilitation Network peace: lessons from El Salvador. Boulder, CO: Lynne
Paper 22, London, ODI. Rienner.
Austin, G. (1996). The eects of government policy on the Bowles, S., Franzini, M., & Pagano, P. (Eds.) (1999).
ethnic distribution of income and wealth in Rwanda: a The politics and economics of power. London: Routl-
review of published sources. Mimeo, Department of Eco- edge.
nomic History, London School of Economics, London. Buijtenhuijs, R. (2000). Peasant wars in Africa: gone
Azam, J.-P. (2001). The redistributive state and conicts with the wind? In D. Bryceson, C. Kay, & J. Mooij
in Africa. Journal of Peace Research, 38(4), 429444. (Eds.), Disappearing peasantries? rural labour in
Bazenguissa-Ganga, R. (1999). The spread of political vi- Africa, Asia and Latin America. London: Intermedi-
olence in Congo-Brazzaville. African Aairs, 98, 3754. ate Technology Publications.
1862 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Clarence-Smith, G. (1980). Class structure and class Girard, R. (1977). Violence and the sacred. Baltimore,
struggles in Angola in the 1970s. Journal of Southern MA: The John Hopkins University Press.
African Studies, 7(1), 109126. Girard, R. (1996). Mimesis and violence. In J. G.
Collier, P., & Hoeer, A. (1996). On the economic causes Williams (Ed.), The Girard reader. New York: The
of civil war Mimeo. Oxford: Centre for the Study of Crossroad Publishing Company.
African Economies. Global Witness (1998). A rough trade: the role of
Collier, P., & Hoeer, A. (1998). On the economic causes companies and governments in the Angolan conict.
of civil war. Oxford Economic Papers, 50, 563573. London: Global Witness. Available at <www.one-
Collier, P., & Hoeer, A. (1999). Justice-seeking and world.org/global witness/reports/Angola/title.html >.
loot-seeking in civil war. Washington DC: World Global Witness (2002). All the presidents men. Global
Bank. Witness, London.
Collier, P. (2000). Doing well out of war: an economic Gourevitch, P. (1998). We wish to inform you that
perspective. In M. Berdal & D. Malone (Eds.), Greed tomorrow we will be killed with our families: stories
and grievance: economic agendas in civil wars. Boul- from rwanda.
der, CO: Lynne Rienner. Gramsci, A. (1971). Selections from the prison notebooks.
Collier, P., & Hoeer, A. (2001). Greed and grievance in London: Lawrence and Wishart.
civil war. Washington DC: World Bank. Grenier, Y. (1996). From causes to causers: the etiology
Cramer, C. (1994). A Luta continue? The political of Salvadoran internal war revisited. The Journal of
economy of war in Angola and Mozambigue. Ph.D. Conict Studies, 2643.
dissertation, Cambridge University, UK. Grossman, D. (1995). On killing: the psychological cost
Cramer, C. (2000). Inequality, development, and eco- of learning to kill in war and society. Boston: Little,
nomic correctness. Department of Economics Work- Brown and Company.
ing Paper no. 105, School of Oriental and African Grossman, H. I. (1991). A general equilibrium model of
Studies, London. insurrections. American Economic Review, 81, 912
Cramer, C. (2001). Economic inequality and civil conict. 921.
Paper presented at the Fourth Attore della Violenza, Guevara, E. Che. (2001). The African dream: the diaries
Attore della Reconciliazione conference, Cortona, of the revolutionary war in the Congo. London:
organized by the Fondazione Giangiacomo Feltri- Harvill Panther.
nelli, June. Hampshire, S. (2001). Bertrand Russell: the ghost of
Cramer, C. (2002). Capitalism, violence, and war. In A. madness, 19211970 by Ray Monk. New York
Saad-Filho (Ed.), Anti-capitalism: a Marxist intro- Review of Books, XLVIII(8), 4244.
duction. London: Pluto Press. Herring, R. J. (2001). Making ethnic conict: the civil
Cramer, C., & Weeks, J. (2000). War and agriculture. war in Sri Lanka. In M. J. Esman & R. J. Herring
Special chapter in FAO, The State of Food and (Eds.), Carrots, sticks and ethnic conict: rethinking
Agriculture, 2000. Rome: FAO. development assistance (pp. 140174). Ann Arbor:
Cramer, C., & Weeks, J. (2002). Macroeconomic stabi- University of Michigan Press.
lization and structural adjustment. In E. W. Nafziger Hirsch, F. (1997). Social limits to growth. London:
& R. Vayrynen (Eds.), The prevention of humanitar- Routledge.
ian emergencies. London: Palgrave. Hirschman, A. O. (1970). Exit, voice and loyalty:
Dueld, M. (1994). The political economy of internal responses to decline in rms, organizations and states.
war: asset transfer, complex emergencies and inter- Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
national aid. In J. Macrae & A. Zwi (Eds.), War and Hirshleifer, J. (1994). The dark side of the force.
hunger: rethinking international responses to complex Economic Inquiry, 32, 110.
emergencies. London: Zed Books. Hirshleifer, J. (1987). Conict and settlement. In J.
Dueld, M. (2001). Global governance and the new wars. Eatwell, M. Milgate, & P. Newman (Eds.), New
London: Zed Books. Palgrave dictionary of economics. London: Macmil-
Ellis, S. (1999). The mask of anarchy: the destruction of lan Press.
Liberia and the religious dimension of an African civil Hobsbawm, E. (1998). Barbarism: a users guide. In E.
war. London: Hurst. Hobsbawm (Ed.), On History. London: Abacus.
Ferguson, N. (2001). The cash nexus: money and power in Homer-Dixon, T. (1991). On the threshold: environ-
the modern world, 1700-2000. London: Allen Lane. mental changes as causes of acute conict. Interna-
Fine, B. (1999). A question of economics: is it colonising tional Security, 76116.
the social sciences? Economy and Society, 28(3), 403 Howard, M. (2001). The invention of peace. London:
425. Prole Books.
Fine, B. (2001). Economics imperialism and intellectual ICRC (2000). War, money and surviva1. Geneva: ICRC.
progress: the present as history of economic thought? Independent International Commission on Kosovo
History of Economics Review, 32(1), 1036. (2000). The Kosovo report. Oxford: Oxford Univer-
Galbraith, J. K. (1975). Money: whence it came, where it sity Press.
went. London: Deutsch. Jackson, S. (2001). Our riches are being looted! War
Gintis, H. (1998). The individual in economic theory. economies and rumour in the Kivus, DR Congo.
Mimeo Department of Economics, University of Mimeo, International Famine Centre, University of
Massachusetts, Amherst. Cork, Cork, Ireland.
HOMO ECONOMICUS GOES TO WAR 1863

Justice Africa (2000). Who ghts? who cares? war and McIlwham, F. (1998). Africas growth tragedy reconsid-
humanitarian action in Africa. de Waal, A., Justice ered. SOAS Department of Economics MSc Disser-
Africa/InterAfrica Group, USA-Eritrea: Africa World tation, SOAS, London.
Press Inc. Mehlum, H., & Moene, K. (2000). Contested power and
Kaarsholm, P. (2001). Generation violence and cultural political instability. Paper presented at EEA 2000
styles: the micro-politics of a KwaZulu-Natal slum Congress in Bozen-Bolzano, Italy.
settlement. Presented at conference on Actors of Milward, A. (1970). The economic eects of the two world
Violence, Actors of Reconciliation organized by the wars on Britain Prepared for the Economic History
Fondazione Giangiacomo Feltrinelli, Cortona, June Society. London: Macmillan.
1516. Minter, W. (1994). Apartheids contras: an inquiry into
Kaplan, R. (1994). The coming anarchy: how scarcity, the roots of war in Angola and Mozambique. London:
crime, overpopulation and disease are threatening Zed Books.
the social fabric of our planet. Atlantic Monthly, 44 Moore, B. (1967). Social origins of dictatorship and
74. democracy: lord and peasant in the making of the
Keane, J. (1996). Reections on violence. London: Verso. modern world. London: Penguin.
Keen, D. (1994). The benets of famine. Princeton: Moore, D., Nabudere, D., & Kibasambi, R. (2001). Notes
Princeton University Press. on the political economy of the DR Congo War.
Keen, D. (2001). Disqualifying grievance? A response to Mimeo, Institute for Global Dialogue, Johannesburg.
the Collier/Hoeer model as an explanation for Nafziger, E. W. (1996). The economics of complex
civil war. Presented to CODEP Conference, School humanitarian emergencies: preliminary approaches
of Oriental and African Studies, London, June 18 and ndings. WIDER Working Paper No. 119,
20. UNU/WIDER, Helsinki.
Keynes, J. M. (1920). Economic consequences of the Ndikumana, L. (1998). Institutional failure and ethnic
peace. London: Macmillan. conicts in Burundi. African Studies Review, 41(1),
Keynes, J. M. (1978). How to pay for the war. In 2947.
The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, Neary, H. M. (1997). A comparison of rent-seeking
XXII. models and economic models of conict. Public
Khan, M. (1995). State failure in weak states: a critique Choice, 93, 351373.
of new institutionalist explanations. In J. Harriss, J. Pagano, U. (1999). Is power an economic good? notes on
Hunter, & C. M. Lewis (Eds.), The new institutional social scarcity and the economics of positional
economics and third world development. London: goods. In S. Bowles et al. (Eds.), The politics and
Routledge. economics of power. London: Routledge.
Klein, M. (1997). Envy and gratitude. London: Vintage. Pizzorno, A. (1986). Some other kinds of otherness: a
Kriger, N. J. (1992). Zimbabwes guerrilla war: peasant critique of rational choice theories. In A. Foxley
voices. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. et al. (Eds.), Development, democracy and the art of
Lange, O. (1970). The role of planning in a socialist trespassing: essays in honor of Albert Hirschman.
economy. In Papers on Economics and Sociology. Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press.
New York: Pergamon Press. Prest, A. R. (1948). War economics of primary producing
Lawson, T. (1997). Economics and reality. London: countries. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Routledge. Pritchett, L. (1997). Where has all the education gone?
Leamer, E. (1983). Lets take the con out of economet- Policy Research Working Paper No. 1581, World
rics. American Economic Review, 73, 3143. Bank, Washington DC.
Le Billon, (2001). The political ecology of war: natural Reno, W. (1996). The business of war in Liberia.
resources and armed conicts. Political Geography, Current History, May.
20, 561584. Richards, P. (1996). Fighting for the rainforest: war,
Lemarchand, R. (1994). Burundi: ethnic conict and youth and resources. London: International Africa
genocide. Washington DC, Cambridge: Woodrow Institute with James Currey.
Wilson Center Press and Cambridge University Riddell, R. (1990). Manufacturing Africa: performance
Press. and prospects in seven Sub-Saharan African countries.
Levi, P. (1986). The periodic table. London: Sphere. London: James Currey.
Lindqvist, S. (1998). Exterminate All the Brutes. Lon- Sapir, J. (1990). Leconomie mobilisee: essai sur les
don: Granta. economies de type sovietique. Paris: La Decouverte.
Lumpe, L. (Ed.) (2000). Running guns: the global black Schierup, C.-U. (1992). Quasi-proletarians and a patri-
market in small arms, NISAT/PRJO. London: Zed archal bureaucracy: aspects of Yugoslavias re-
Books. peripheralisation. Soviet Studies, 44(1), 7999.
Mann, M. (1999). The dark side of democracy: the Schierup, C.-U. (1993). Prelude to the inferno: economic
modern tradition of ethnic and political cleansing. disintegration and the political fragmentation of
New Left Review, 235, 1845. Yugoslavia. Balkan Forum, 1(2), 89119.
Marchal, R., & Messiant, C. (2001). Une lecture Scott, J. (1976). The moral economy of the peasant:
symptomale de quelques theorisations recentes des rebellion and subsistence in Southeast Asia. New
guerres civiles. Working Paper, CERI/CNRS, Paris. Haven and London: Yale University Press.
Mayer, T. (1993). Truth versus precision in economics. Sen, A. (1986). Rationality, interest and identity. In
Aldershot: Edward Elgar. A. Foxley et al. (Eds.), Development, democracy and
1864 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

the art of trespassing: essays in honor of Albert American data. Working Paper 409, IBRD, Wash-
Hirschman. Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame ington DC.
Press. Tilly, C. (1992). Coercion, capital and european states,
Snyder, J. (2000). From voting to violence. New York: AD 19901992. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell.
Norton. Turton, D. (Ed.) (1997). War and ethnicity: global
Stewart, F. (1993). War and underdevelopment: can connections and local violence. Rochester, NY: Ro-
economic analysis help reduce the costs. Journal of chester University Press.
International Development, 5(4), 357380. Wallensteen, P., & Sollenberg, M. (1998). Armed con-
Stewart, F. (2000). Crisis prevention: tackling horizontal ict and regional conict complexes, 198997. Jour-
inequalities. QEH Working Paper Series 33. Queen nal of Peace Research, 35(5), 621634.
Elizebeth House, Oxford. Wolf, E. (1969). Peasant wars of the twentieth century.
Stewart, F., & Fitzgerald, V. (2000). War and underde- New York: Harper and Row.
velopment: the economic and social consequences of Yeats, A. (1990). On the accuracy of economic obser-
conict, Vol. 1. Oxford: Oxford University Press. vations: do sub-Saharan trade statistics mean any-
Storey, A. (1998). Economics and ethnic conict: struc- thing. World Bank Economic Review.
tural adjustment in Rwanda. Development Policy Zarovski, M. (2000). The rational choice generalization
Review, 17, 4363. of neo-classical economics reconsidered: any theo-
Szekely, M., & Hilgert, M. (1999). Whats behind the retical legitimation for economic imperialism. Socio-
inequality we measure: an investigation using latin logical Theory, 18(3), 448471.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi