Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 16

Concentrationin

Agribusinessand
61 Marketing:
ACaseStudyofArla
Foods
By:
DerekBakerand
KimmieGraberLtzhft

CASE STUDY #6-1 OF THE PROGRAM:


FOOD POLICY FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES: THE ROLE OF
GOVERNMENT IN THE GLOBAL FOOD SYSTEM
2007



Editedby:
PerPinstrupAndersen(globalfoodsystem@cornell.edu)andFuzhiCheng
CornellUniversity

Incollaborationwith:
SrenE.Frandsen,FOI,UniversityofCopenhagen
ArieKuyvenhoven,WageningenUniversity
JoachimvonBraun,InternationalFoodPolicyResearchInstitute

Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.


All rights reserved. This case study may be reproduced for educational purposes without express permission but must include
acknowledgement to Cornell University. No commercial use is permitted without permission.
ConcentrationinAgribusinessandMarketing:ACaseStudyofArlaFoods
BakerandGraberLtzhft

ExecutiveSummary

The modern food industry is characterized by and other large agribusiness firms. You will need to
fewer and fewer firms and the emergence of some assess the extent of market power exercised by
powerful international and global players. This case Arla and decide which stakeholders are likely to be
study of Arla Foods details that firms development affected by Arlas exercise of market power and in
from its origins in local dairy cooperatives to its which ways.
current position as a multinational food conglom-
erate. Its development has attracted scrutiny from
competition authorities for a variety of reasons, Background
and it raises questions about the role of farmer
cooperatives locally, nationally, and internationally. The number of food industry firms has declined
across most commodity sectors and in most coun-
Some technical terms are examined in support of tries of the world. This decline has been widely
the case study: consolidation, concentration, and associated with a presumed increase in the market
market power are often used interchangeably, but power of the largest firms and with the abuse of
from an economic and policy perspective they are that power. Owing to the public sentiments asso-
quite different and have a variety of origins. The ciated with such issues as the pursuit of profit, the
case study also outlines some current policy con- price and availability of food, rural and village life,
cerns about horizontal and vertical relationships in and farm incomes, market power in the food indus-
food marketing chains. Arla exhibits a range of try has been of considerable concern to policy
vertical and horizontal relationships with various makers. The connection between structural change
sets of stakeholders, and their actual and potential in the food industry and the possible development
interests are described and discussed in policy and abuse of market power is, however, complex.
terms. Arla dominates its supply of raw material This case study examines the forces at work, their
(milk), but its status as a cooperative would be potential impacts, and policy responses to them.
expected to protect its farmer-suppliers. As Arlas Arla Foods is a Scandinavian food industry firm
influence has crossed borders through exports and that has passed through various stages of growth
collaboration with other firms in processing and to enjoy near monopoly-monopsony status and
distribution, other farmers may suffer, along with attracted the attention of the evolving regulatory
the dairy-processing firms to which they sell. As environment in Scandinavia and Europe.
for other food processors, Arla faces powerful
trading partners among Europes retailers that have
ConsolidationandConcentration
themselves attracted attention from policy makers.
In many countries the number of food industry
In identifying and evaluating policy options, firms has declined and the average size of firms has
economists face a number of challenges, including increased in a process known as consolidation
variable definitions (of, for example, markets and (Baker 2003; Traill and Gilpin 1994; USDA 2002).
products), difficulties in empirical measurement As consolidation has proceeded, a few firms have
(particularly of market power), and modeling prac- increased market share more than the remaining
tices. Economic interests have shifted over time, firms through the process of concentration
and a channel orientation has developed in some (Rogers 2001). Economists assumption of many
food industries, changing the practices food indus- small, price-taking firms might be maintained in the
try firms use within those channels. Many such presence of some consolidation, as firms become
developments are difficult for policy to address, somewhat larger but each still has an equal and
and this issue has relevance for Arla Foods. negligible influence in the market. Concentration,
however, delivers a small subset of very large firms
Your assignment is to suggest policy recommenda- with the potential to exert greater influence over
tions for the various levels of government (local prices and trading conditions than their smaller
Danish and British governments, national Danish counterparts. Concentration has been shown to
and Swedish governments, and the European occur in both input markets and product markets
Commission) regarding the future of Arla Foods and at all stages of the food marketing chain.

Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.


All rights reserved. This case study may be reproduced for educational purposes without express permission but must include
acknowledgement to Cornell University. No commercial use is permitted without permission. 1
ConcentrationinAgribusinessandMarketing:ACaseStudyofArlaFoods
BakerandGraberLtzhft

Concentration is sometimes used interchangeably Misuse of market power is grounded in firms
with market power, whereas in fact neither term restricting traded quantities in order to raise sales
implies the other. prices or reduce purchase prices. This understand-
ing emerges from economic theory of monopoly
and oligopoly and is at the core of a set of empiri-
TheoreticalandEmpiricalIssues cal techniques that seek to detect the influence of
On the surface, measurement of consolidation may large firms decisions and actions on the market.
appear straightforward in that it entails tracking These techniques include direct approaches such as
numbers of firms, whereas measurement of concen- measuring or inferring differences between price
tration seems more challenging because market and marginal cost (P = MC in perfect competition)
shares must be derived. In fact, measurement of and finding a statistical association between market
both can be difficult for both product markets and volumes and price that otherwise violates the com-
for the often overlooked markets within which petitive model. More crudely, measures of profit
inputs are purchased. The first measurement prob- (or proxy measures) have been statistically asso-
lem concerns product and market definition: large ciated with market volumes and specific known cost
firms tend to purchase, produce, and sell many items. Less direct approaches involve observation of
different products in a variety of forms, formats, prices at different points in the food marketing
and quality levels. The emerging dominance of non- chain over time and examination of the timing and
specialized retail formats (Stensrud 1999) has extent of the transmission of price changes
exacerbated this problem. A second problem con- between stages. Observations of series of prices
fronts markets with significant volumes of interna- and market volumes have also been used in game
tional trade: calculating and interpreting a firms theoretic models. Most of these methods seek to
domestic market share is complex if the firm sells detect market power and its misuse at the market
in foreign markets or if the domestic market level rather than say anything about the actions of
features many products produced by foreign firms. the individual firm.
The third measurement problem involves inter-
actions between products: a concentrated market
for one product can have significant implications TheForcesatWork
for related products that involve the same, or dif- Technology. Consolidation is likely to be partly
ferent, firms. attributable to technological change, both internal
and external to the firm. Economies of scale often
A fourth measurement problem is the identification apply in cases of large investment items within the
of products within firms, and firms within markets. firm, like high-technology processing systems,
In the former case, vertical integration has the information technology (particularly those that are
effect of reducing marketing volumes because at bar codebased), packaging systems, logistics, and
one or more points in the marketing chain brand-based marketing. Economies of scale also
products are not traded but retained within a single apply to noninvestment-related items such as
firm. In the latter case, associations between small promotion and market research. Technological
firms may mimic the market powerrelated aspects forces external to the firm include the availability
of large firms, although the firms themselves each of reduced transport costs and rapid advances in
trade small volumes. A familiar example is the information technologies.
farmer cooperative, but equally significant is the
agglomeration of retailers and/or wholesalers into Policy has also interacted with technology in the
buyer groups for the purposes of negotiations food industry. Regulation of food safety, environ-
with suppliers (UK Competition Commission mental actions, and product labeling are likely to
2000). Finally, empirical measures of consolidation favor larger firms because they are better able to
and concentration have almost always been used exercise economies of scale (Siebert et al. 2000).
and interpreted with regard to product markets. These influences have increased market areas and
These two processes are equally important, how- reduced large firms unit costs relative to those of
ever, and perhaps even more influential, in input small firms. Many such advantages apply first and
markets. foremost at the firm level, rather than at the level
of the individual shop, processing plant, or ware-
house, thus providing the incentives for the

Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.


All rights reserved. This case study may be reproduced for educational purposes without express permission but must include
acknowledgement to Cornell University. No commercial use is permitted without permission.
2
ConcentrationinAgribusinessandMarketing:ACaseStudyofArlaFoods
BakerandGraberLtzhft

formation of chains without necessarily reducing globally or nationally well-known brands
the numbers of establishments (Marsden et al. without which no supermarket can
1998). operate.
The British model emphasizes retail
Consumer Habits. At the retail level, consumer power, exercised by restricted access to
shopping habits have changed to reflect changing supermarket shelf space, downward pres-
lifestyles and income, as well as transport avail- sure on prices paid to suppliers, and the
ability and changing dietary preferences (Kinsey use of retailers own-label brands in com-
and Senauer 1996). Changing consumer habits have petition with processors brands.
invoked changes in both the format and degree of
specialization of shops. In many countries spe-
cialized shops have given way to nonspecialized The implications of food convergence generally
stores, and mall-type retail clusters have appeared. arise from the smaller number of market partici-
With the growth in the importance of non- pants and their close vertical linkages in the food
specialized shops, the measurement of retail-level chain. Such linkages allow not only for supply con-
variables such as concentration, costs, and profits tracts, but also for provision of large amounts of
has become impossible for researchers and regula- information. This situation enables traceability and
tory authorities. differentiation of products according to issues such
as animal housing conditions or crops pesticide
Demand for information by consumers has led to history, and for specification of features such as
substantial pressure on food industry firms to packaging and timing for delivery.
create systems and services that can measure,
process, and deliver information to the consumer. Mergers. Mergers and acquisitions, which occur as
Labeling and test certification address the content firms that have increased their market share are
of foods, and identity preservation (traceability) purchased and combined with other winning
and process certification address the path taken by firms, have acted as driving forces in food industry
the product. In both cases, it is likely that large consolidation. Wrigley (2001) notes that merger
firms with large volumes can better serve the activity increased among food retailers in Britain in
customer than their smaller competitors. the 1980s and 1990s and followed in the United
States in the late 1990s. Wrigley (1997) rejects the
Channel Development. Consolidation and concen- concept of separate British and U.S. models of food
tration have fostered linkages downstream toward convergence. Instead, he identifies several factors
retailers and upstream toward farmers so that a determining the intercontinental difference,
smaller number of channels to the consumer are particularly the policy environment, the availability
available. The emergence of channels has led to new of venture capital, applications in information tech-
practices between agents in the food marketing nologies, and the entry of Wal-Mart into food
chain, particularly long-term contracts featuring retailing. Several commentators have noted the
rigorous application of privately specified standards increasing number of cross-border mergers in the
(Hughes 2002). In the context of market power, food industry (see, for example, UK Competition
channel practices may favor the emergence of Commission 2000), and this phenomenon is
chain captains (Connor 2003) who, although reflected in this case study of Arla.
they are active at just one stage of the chain, man-
age to control, and possibly exploit, agents at all Vertical Integration. Vertical integration in the
stages of the chain. The predisposing conditions food industry has been examined in many con-
for channel captaincy have been referred to as textsspecifically, farming and processing,
food convergence (Cotterill 1997) and have been processing and distribution, distribution and
recognized in two forms, both of which are asso- retailing, and processing and retailing. Reasons
ciated with the modern use of marketing tech- behind vertical integration include overcoming
niques that feature brands: difficulties in acquiring and processing information
(Hennessy 1996), reducing the cost or awkwardness
The U.S. model of food convergence of transactions (Azzam 1996), and enhancing the
features food processors as chain captains. compatibility of technologies and scale between
Market power is exercised by supply of

Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.


All rights reserved. This case study may be reproduced for educational purposes without express permission but must include
acknowledgement to Cornell University. No commercial use is permitted without permission.
3
ConcentrationinAgribusinessandMarketing:ACaseStudyofArlaFoods
BakerandGraberLtzhft

upstream and downstream stages of the food monopoly actions on the consumer. Real food
marketing chain. prices paid by consumers have continued to fall in
most developed markets, however, and little
Social Change. At the farm level, reduced numbers evidence of monopoly-related welfare loss to con-
of farms and increases in farm size have been sumers has appeared (Hyde and Perloff 1998;
accompanied by greater and more widespread Kinsey 2003; Park and Weliwheta 1996). A more
specialization and an increasing tendency for recent focus has been on the body of the food
farmers to be employed off the farm (Brouwer and chain, particularly the transactions between proces-
Bijman 2001). In general, consolidation of farms has sors, distributors, and retailers.
not been viewed as a competition-related issue. In
some commodity sectors, however, contracting and Retail Behavior. Retailers behavior toward suppliers
other transaction mechanisms have been used to has attracted considerable recent attention. A
effect significant local concentration and raise variety of tests have been employed for monop-
concerns about market access. In Western econo- sony action whereby retailers limit the volume they
mies, pork and poultry production provide exam- demand to drive prices downward. Economic
ples. In an African and Latin American context, modeling centered on methods developed in the
contract production of flowers and vegetables for new empirical industrial organization approach
multinational food industry firms has also been has yielded tests for monopoly and monopsony
criticized for dominating and marginalizing tradi- simultaneously (for a review see Digal and Ahmadi-
tional producers. Esfahani 2002). As already noted, such studies
employ market-level data and do not deal directly
Urban Location. Location of establishments has with single firms conduct.
played a role, as the growth in the size of retail
stores and processing plants has meant that an Specific actions by retailers toward suppliers have
increasing number of locations are capable of sus- come under scrutiny in the context of retailers as
taining just one establishment. Indeed, control of gatekeepers owing to their apparent control of
potential sites for retail food stores outside British the interface between consumers and the rest of
towns has itself become the subject of anti- the food industry (UK Competition Commission
monopoly action (UK Competition Commission 2000). There are many examples of such actions
2000). (see also McCorriston and Sheldon 1997; OECD
1999). Among other things, retailers
Innovation. Innovation is thought to be related to
market concentration, although opinions vary pass on to suppliers the costs of new retail
about the nature of the relationship. According to product introduction (such as initial adver-
some researchers and theorists, perfectly competi- tising costs);
tive markets would not offer sufficient returns to demand payments from processors for
firms to justify the costs incurred in innovation access to supermarket shelf space (known
(Braadland 2000). This view particularly refers to as slotting fees);
new product development in the context of price-
taking firms. The alternative view is that a price some basic products below cost to
monopoly provides no incentive for innovation increase sales of complementary high-
owing to lack of competition (Harris 2002). margin products (loss-leading);
Product differentiation and new product develop- require agreements with suppliers to be on
ment are apparent on the supermarket shelves, an all-or-nothing basis across a range of
although the extent to which this innovation is products (so-called de-listing threat);
greater or less than it would be in a non-concen- require compensation from suppliers for
trated food industry has not been adequately products commercial failure;
researched.
require suppliers to play technical roles
(such as physical stocking of shelves);
ManifestationsofMarketPower demand exclusive supply agreements; and
Economists approach to market power in the food require coordination with retailers use of
industry has traditionally focused on the impact of own-label brands.

Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.


All rights reserved. This case study may be reproduced for educational purposes without express permission but must include
acknowledgement to Cornell University. No commercial use is permitted without permission.
4
ConcentrationinAgribusinessandMarketing:ACaseStudyofArlaFoods
BakerandGraberLtzhft

Retailers use of own-label brands is not generally brands at all sites within the product space
thought of as a direct consequence of concentra- despite the non-profitability of most of those
tion, but it is clearly enabled by retailers scale and incumbent brands.
their desire to add value in terms of shoppers
desire for convenience. The extent to which Processors relations with retailers clearly vary from
retailers exploit food-processing firms that supply product to product. In the case of retail beer in
their own-label brand products is not clear. Britain, firms in the highly concentrated brewing
industry own a large proportion of the pubs. These
A key element of food retailers strategies is their pubs are commonly leased to agents under a set of
location within a catchment of customers. Several arrangements that have been criticized for their
locational trends have been observed, including pricing practices, exclusivity of product supply and
moves outside town centers and location within tying, and constraints on lessees management free-
shopping malls, often in combination. Owing to the dom (UK Monopolies and Mergers Commission
limited number of suitable (greenfield) sites, 1989).
retailers have the incentive to purchase or occupy
as many sites as possible, not only to open a store, The concept of exploitation of farmers by monop-
but also to prevent entry by a rival food retailer. sonistic food processors and buyers is an old
theme. Collusive arrangements have been portrayed
Processing. Most early studies of food processors as the main instrument of placing downward pres-
market power focused on the U.S. meat industry, sure on the prices received by farmers. Other
particularly the measurement of the market power potential instruments include
of processors and how they exercised it over
retailers on the one hand (for example, Morrison processor control of key inputs (like
2001) and feedlot owners on the other (for exam- water, transport, credit, seeds);
ple, Schroeter and Azzam 1990). tying of input supply to purchase of
products; and
According to the food convergence line of
reasoning, food processors must-stock brands are requirement for purchase of high-invest-
supplied to retailers under monopoly conditions. ment items on the farm (such as pipe sizes
The most obvious abuse of this position would be for milk collection that are not compatible
restriction of supply to drive up wholesale prices. with rival buyers equipment).
A range of other practices has been proposed,
however, including tying of must-stock brands to Farmer Cooperatives. One of the main justifications
other products the processor sells and exclusivity for farmer cooperation is the accumulation of
arrangements. countervailing market power against the potential
monopsonistic actions of processors and other
Logistics and distribution have also been employed buyers at the farm gate. The essential nature of a
in exercising market power. In some cases proces- cooperative is a consolidation of product (or input,
sors have supplied bulk containers, chillers and or service) from many farmer-members. The exclu-
freezers, and display cases to retailers with the sion of nonmember suppliers and the requirement
requirement that retailers use these items to that members sell exclusively to the cooperative has
handle, store, or display only that processors been interpreted in some contexts as anticompeti-
products. tive.

Researchers have examined the subject of brands as In the meat and dairy industries, many processors
an instrument of market power in some depth and are vertically integrated farmer cooperatives. These
detail for the case of breakfast cereals in the United cooperatives operate as large food processors and
States. Connor (1999) observes that the industry employ the full range of sophisticated processing
supplying such products is highly concentrated, and marketing techniques. In recent decades the
and the few firms in the market own a very large trend in most countries has been toward consolida-
number of brands. Connor argues that this situa- tion of cooperatives. In some cases single coopera-
tion is anti-competitive because it raises barriers to tives now approach 100 percent shares in milk and
entry, as potential new entrants face incumbent livestock purchases, perhaps spanning more than

Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.


All rights reserved. This case study may be reproduced for educational purposes without express permission but must include
acknowledgement to Cornell University. No commercial use is permitted without permission.
5
ConcentrationinAgribusinessandMarketing:ACaseStudyofArlaFoods
BakerandGraberLtzhft

one country. Aside from concerns about monop- As a result of rising imports of cheaper German
oly and monopsony behavior, such concentration milk, Arla's share of the Danish liquid milk market
presents a barrier to entry by other firms. Many of fell from 89 percent in 2003 to 80 percent in
these concerns have been raised with regard to 2006. It has been suggested that Arlas market
Arla Foods. share has also suffered owing to consumer reaction
to recent legal action over its abuse of dominant
Single Seller Desks. In some countries national-level market position (Food and Drink Europe 2006).
agencies have been assigned a state-authorized Arla still holds a large market share in Denmark for
monopoly in marketing export products. The most dairy products, including yogurt (75 percent),
objective is usually related to farm income, but the cheese (55 percent), and all organic dairy products
procedure faces criticism from some circles as a (75 percent). The United Kingdom, however, is the
market distortion. The argument runs that the groups biggest market, accounting for 33 percent
monopsony and monopoly status of these agencies of company sales, followed by Denmark (22
removes their incentive to supply products into percent) and Sweden (19 percent). Arlas UK sub-
differentiated markets. Obviously, the most sidiary (Arla Foods plc, formed in 2003 through a
strident opposition to single selling desks comes merger with Express Dairies) is that countrys
from independent traders that are excluded from largest supplier of liquid milk. Outside Denmark,
the market. Sweden, and the United Kingdom, Arla Foods
operates numerous subsidiaries, with production
Input Suppliers. Suppliers of farm inputs, animal facilities in Argentina, Brazil, Poland, and Saudi
feeds, and feed and food ingredients often operate Arabia and licensed production in Canada and the
in highly concentrated industries. The extent to United States.
which they exercise monopoly power over their
customers has not been studied in detail, but this Arla Foods spans the full range of dairy products,
concern lies at the heart of concerns over patent- including liquid milk (45 percent of turnover),
ing and other intellectual property attached to cheese (25 percent), powder and preserved milk
products or components based on living organisms. products (14 percent), and butter and spreads (11
percent). Strong brand names are employed,
including Lurpak (originally Danish, but now the
CaseStudy:ArlaFoods United Kingdoms leading butter brand),
Arla Foods is a cooperative owned by 10,000 Rosenborg mold cheeses, Buko cream cheeses, and
Danish and Swedish dairy farmers. Including its 84 DANO full-fat powdered products (with substantial
subsidiaries (as of September 2005), it is Europes market share in Asian and Middle Eastern markets).
second-largest dairy company, with milk purchases Through a number of subsidiary companies, Arla
of 8.4 billion kilograms and DKK 46 billion sales in markets fruit juices and other beverages, bacterial
fiscal year 2004/05 (Arla Foods 2006a, b). It was cultures, and food ingredients. In the United
formed in 2000 by the merger of two dairy coop- Kingdom, Arla Foods has a partnership with
eratives: MD Foods (Danish) and Arla (Swedish). Fonterra (a New Zealand dairy company, also coop-
The stated purpose of the merger was to match erative-based) for packaging and distribution of
and counter the size of the large international butter and other spreadables that uses Fonterras
retailing chains that were, and remain, its customer Anchor brand. For import and distribution on the
base. MD Foods had a long history of growth by Chinese market, Arla Foods has a joint venture
merger with other cooperatives as far back as 1970 with Mengnui (Chinas leading dairy company). In
and including the 1999 merger with the then addition to its branded product range, Arla
second-largest dairy cooperative, Klver Mlk. produces retailers own-label branded products.
Foreign acquisition was also a longstanding feature
of MDs strategy, beginning with the purchase of Both Arla Foods and its predecessor entities faced
Associated Fresh Foods (the United Kingdoms scrutiny from Swedish competition authorities
fifth-largest dairy company) in 1990. At the merger during the series of mergers that led to the current
in 2000, MD Foods purchased 90 percent of all corporate arrangements (Danish Competition
Danish cows milk, and Arla, some 65 percent of Authority 2000b; OECD 2004). The 1999 merger
Swedens. of MD Foods and Klver Mlk was subject to the
following requirements of the Danish Competition

Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.


All rights reserved. This case study may be reproduced for educational purposes without express permission but must include
acknowledgement to Cornell University. No commercial use is permitted without permission.
6
ConcentrationinAgribusinessandMarketing:ACaseStudyofArlaFoods
BakerandGraberLtzhft

Authority (Danish Competition Authority 1999, Arla Foods commitment to selling or buy-
2000a, 2004a, b): ing milk and cream to and from other
dairies.
Farmers level of choice was to be
enhanced by reducing the duration of the The merger between Arla Foods and Express
supply commitment and permitting Dairies was referred to the European Commission,
farmers to supply up to 20 percent to which concluded that the merger did not threaten
other buyers. to create, or reinforce, a dominant market position
All competitors were to be permitted to with regard to raw milk. The merger was also
purchase raw milk and cream from MD dependent on a general meeting of Express Dairies
Foods, and the company was obliged to shareholders in April 2003. The European Com-
buy excess milk from other Danish dairies. mission referred the matter to the competition
MD Foods was required to divest itself of authorities in seven countries in which the merger
annual processing capacity of 180 million may have threatened competition regarding
kilograms of milk (entailing sale of a processed dairy products (European Commission
specified subsidiary company to a Danish 2003). The UK competition authorities concluded
competitor). that there was no threat to the public interest, and
the deal was approved by the United Kingdoms
MD Foods was prohibited from real estate Office of Fair Trading. Notably, the UK regulator
arrangements that restricted entry by stated that the market power of retailers in the UK
prohibition of use of land or facilities in was sufficient to offset the effects of the merger
dairy processing. (UK Competition Commission 2003).
MD Foods was compelled to allow
competitors access to distribution In late 2006 Arla Foods acquired 30 percent of
facilities. the Finnish dairy company Ingman Foods, with an
option on the balance of shares. This action
Notably, the conditions imposed on MD Foods received approval from EU competition authorities
were not backed up by specified penalties for (Arla Foods 2007).
noncompliance. The Danish Minister for Commerce
and Industry imposed several restrictions on MD In 2002 EU competition authorities approved a
Foods and the new conglomerate Arla Foods but joint venture between Arla Foods packaging sub-
did not refer to case to European Union (EU) sidiary (Danapak), the Austrian Teich
Competition Authorities (Danish Competition Aktiengesellschaft Partnership, and Danish Corona
Authority 2000a). The summary of the situation Packaging. This joint venture created one of
given by the Organization for Economic Northern Europes largest manufacturers of flexible
Cooperation and Development (OECD) was that packaging (Arla Foods 2002). The European Com-
Denmark lacked an appropriate legal framework to mission concluded that because of the many end
deal with the case (OECD 2004). Although Swedish uses of flexible packaging (that is, not just for dairy
competition authorities had previously prevented products), there was no risk of emergence of a
Arlas mergers with other Swedish cooperatives dominant position for the new firm (European
(Eurofood 2000), they too gave an affirmative final Commission 2002).
judgment on the merger with MD Foods. The
following strictures were imposed (Danish In a Danish court decision of February 10, 2006,
Competition Authority 2004a): Arla Foods was fined DKK 5 million for abuse of a
dominant position in fresh milk and fermented
further MD Foods divestiture of products under the Danish Competition Act of
processing capacity to competitors; 2002 (Danish Competition Authority 2006a). Arla
had agreed to pay its (retailer) customer Metro to
Arla Foods provision for competitors
exclude the products of Arlas competitor Hirtshals
access to Arla Foods distribution system;
Andelsmejeri. Although Arla denies any wrong-
and
doing (Arla Foods 2006c), the court received
evidence that Metro revoked its contract with
Hirtshals in association with Arlas financial

Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.


All rights reserved. This case study may be reproduced for educational purposes without express permission but must include
acknowledgement to Cornell University. No commercial use is permitted without permission.
7
ConcentrationinAgribusinessandMarketing:ACaseStudyofArlaFoods
BakerandGraberLtzhft

contribution to Metros 40th anniversary celebra- antimonopoly policy targets firms pricing
tions. This decision marked the first time a Danish and practices that exercise market power;
court concluded that a company abused a domi- and
nant position. A later confidential settlement antitrust policy addresses relations among
between the two firms was reached, involving a firms, to prevent or punish mergers and
payment from Arla to Hirtshals (Arla Foods other forms of association that provide for
2006d). the exercise of market power.
Until 2004 Arla Foods charged new dairy supplier-
members an entry fee equal to 2 percent of the Increasing consolidation and concentration has led
value (at basic price) of milk to be supplied. Three to a shift in policy interest away from monopoly
Danish dairy farmers brought this matter to the and toward a balance of market power between
Danish court, alleging abuse of a dominant position. stages of the marketing chain. This shift is not new:
In August 2002 the Danish Competition Authority U.S. law has allowed farmers collusive actions (such
ruled that Arla Foods had abused its dominant as in a cooperative) to enable countervailing
position in procurement of Danish cows milk, on market power (relative to that of the large food
the grounds that the fee exceeded fair compensa- processors to whom the farmers sell) as far back as
tion to Arla for the costs of admission. In the Capper-Volstead Act of 1922. This vertically
November 2003 the Danish Competition Appeals oriented interest in bilateral market power has
Tribunal overturned the decision, finding that it recently extended to relationships between retailers
had not contained sufficient description and analy- and other stages of the food marketing chain.
sis of the salient facts. Furthermore, the Appeals
Tribunal stated that a high fee alone does not con- Policy concern about access to markets, which is
stitute evidence of abuse of a dominant position. traditionally protected by antitrust policy that pro-
The farmers took the case to the Danish High hibits collusion and exclusivity agreements, has
Court, which dismissed it in September 2006 been transformed into concern over access to
(Danish Competition Authority 2006b). channels. Food convergence means that fewer
channels are available to firms, and access to these
In 2004 the Danish Competition Authority con- channels is often predicated upon adherence to
cluded that the series of mergers between, first, quality standards, information provision, or other
Klver Mlk and MD Foods, and later MD Foods actions by suppliers. A further complicating feature
and Arla, had led to higher Danish milk prices than is that channel trade tends to be driven by con-
would otherwise have prevailed. The authority tracts rather than interactions in a transparent
stated that under the current legal regime the market. This situation limits the extent to which
mergers would probably not have been permitted policy agencies can monitor trading conditions.
(Danish Competition Authority 2004b, 284). Fur-
ther concerns have arisen over Arlas market power To the extent that channel access and food conver-
as a supplier to retailers and as a distributor of gence require and result in specialization on the
other firms products to retailers (Danish Competi- farm, then concentration can be associated with
tion Authority 2004b, Chapter 5), but in several farmers risk management. The ageless risk-related
instances Arla was found not to have abused its practice of diversification must then be abandoned,
dominant position, particularly with regard to and policy makers must ensure that alternative
pricing and marketing support in dealing with re- mechanisms are available.
tailers (Danish Competition Authority 2002).
Channel access requisites such as standards,
product descriptions, food safety, information pro-
PolicyIssues vision, certification, labor arrangements, animal
welfare, and political (and even religious) commit-
ments are to one degree or another parallel
GeneralComments
requirements to those of most governments. They
The primary policy concerns provoked by concen- are defined and imposed by private agents, how-
tration in the food industry are the protection, ever, which challenges traditional thinking about
promotion, and preservation of competition. Most the role of government and private enterprise.
countries feature two forms of policy: Currently there are few indications of which, if any,

Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.


All rights reserved. This case study may be reproduced for educational purposes without express permission but must include
acknowledgement to Cornell University. No commercial use is permitted without permission.
8
ConcentrationinAgribusinessandMarketing:ACaseStudyofArlaFoods
BakerandGraberLtzhft

within-channel practices actually discourage entry and supplant domestic suppliers or force lower
or otherwise exclude entry by farmers on a non- price regimes onto them.
competitive basis. While farmers that gain channel
access can certainly benefit from it, they have the In all countries, farmer cooperatives operate under
incentive to minimize the number of other farmers selective policies that provide certain advantages
that benefit alongside them. over other agribusiness firms. Commercial advan-
tages include allowing income to be treated as non-
The gatekeeping role of retailers gives rise to taxable until distributed to members and exempting
several concerns. First, as the controllers of super- transactions between suppliers and the cooperative
market shelf space, retailers effectively determine from most taxes. In terms of competition policy,
the range and form of products on sale. In addi- cooperatives are commonly allowed to approach
tion, retailers own-label brands compete for shelf monopoly status in raw material purchase, product
space and in most countries have steadily accumu- sales, and export supplies. At the farm level, this
lated market share. Consumer groups have raised monopoly status is implemented through supplier
concerns over the possible decline in product contracts featuring exclusivity clauses that would
variety, specifically a reduced number of brands on be illegal in other commercial settings. It should be
sale and the disappearance of local or traditional noted that such treatment of cooperatives is not
brands from the market. That tendency is exacer- necessarily the preserve of so-called cooperative
bated by supermarkets increasing sales of nonfood law, as many countries featuring a powerful coop-
items and ready-to-eat foods, which are recognized erative movement lack any such a law. In such cases
as the fast-growing market segments. Many authors the laws governing commerce can accommodate
have observed the decline of second-tier brands, the cooperative business model.
possibly as a consequence of these trends.
The role played by food processing and other agri-
As old brands and products disappear from shop business in rural society is an area of current
shelves, a second set of gatekeeping concerns research. There is a widespread belief that agribusi-
addresses the appearance of new ones. Several ness is a significant employer in rural areas and a
authors have made the case that some actions of means of retaining added value in the region in
retailers hamper new product introduction. In the which it is added. Concentration means that fewer
view of some, slotting fees (and other costs of firms are making fewer decisions about where to
product introduction that are passed back by locate, so that much of relevant rural development
retailers) are simply barriers to entry. Still, a plausi- policy is now concerned with presenting and pro-
ble economic argument can be made that such moting potential locations to agribusiness firms. In
costs are compensation to retailers for the risk turn, this effort to promote location of agribusi-
taken when a new, and possibly unsuccessful, nesses in certain areas interfaces with policies such
product takes shelf space from an existing product as transport and local taxation (which might
of known performance. encourage location) and preservation of rural land-
scapes, residents protection from smells and noise,
In many countries, policy makers resolve to sup- and heavy transport bans (which are designed for
port, assist, and promote small and medium-sized the opposite effect).
firms. Some food-related policies are less demand-
ing of small firms than large ones, but many Protection of the countryside from retail greenfield
instruments of other policies (like food safety and development finds some common cause with small
environmental protection policies) demand high business owners in the high streets of towns and
levels of capital and specialist labor, which large small cities. Retail facilities outside small towns take
firms are clearly more able to provide than small business, and businesses, away from these tradi-
ones. Where policies address the firm rather than tional locations. Where powerful retail firms have
the individual factory or site, then the case has already purchased suitable land areas, then zoning
been made that regulation encourages concentra- and municipal planning responses may (1) be too
tion by way of merger and acquisition. The fact late and (2) support the implied market power by
that some mergers and acquisitions cross borders restricting other firms location options.
accentuates the concern that new entrants, partic-
ularly retailers, will bring their suppliers with them

Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.


All rights reserved. This case study may be reproduced for educational purposes without express permission but must include
acknowledgement to Cornell University. No commercial use is permitted without permission.
9
ConcentrationinAgribusinessandMarketing:ACaseStudyofArlaFoods
BakerandGraberLtzhft

PolicyIssuesSurroundingArlaFoods Arla exerts limited market power over retailers,
despite its substantial market share.
Arla Foods operates as a near monopoly, and a
near monopsony, in Denmark and Sweden and
maintains a dominant position in Britain. It has Stakeholders
achieved this position through a process of
mergers among cooperatives (in the Scandinavian In the context of concentration in the food indus-
countries) and joint ventures, partnerships, and try, stakeholders obviously include the members of
mergers with other organizations elsewhere. Com- the food marketing chain, consumers, and tax-
petition authorities have, at various stages in Arlas payers, who fund and benefit from the regulatory
development, reviewed these various mergers, part- process. Within the food marketing chain, several
nerships, and acquisitions to ensure that societys spectra of interests exist that span ownership (as
best interests were being preserved. In practice this opposed to employment), sentiment, tradition, and
oversight has involved examining merger plans and ethics.
requiring certain actions of the parties to the
merger that would maintain competition.
Less obvious connections extend to rural residents,
Because Arla is a cooperative and is, to some users of shared resources (such as roads and water
extent, vertically integrated, some of the supplier- supplies), and pressure groups with a single agenda
buyer policy issues do not arise. A cooperative is (such as antigenetic modification or pro-organic)
required, however, to operate according to its con- or multiple ones (such as quality of rural life or
stitution, which usually means farmer-member various animal welfare concerns).
governance and influence over strategy, as well as
generation of benefits to member-suppliers. Some A number of stakeholders are associated with Arla
Arla members have brought actions against Arla Foods. Consumers in many countries are stake-
concerning its entry fees (which are now discon- holders in any change in Arla Foods competitive
tinued). The policy issue is whether or not Arla position. This situation particularly applies to
employs its near monopsony status to extract Denmark and Sweden, where few alternatives to
higher entry fees than would be possible were a Arlas products exist; the position in the United
number of competing buyers of milk available. Kingdom is somewhat less extreme.

Close associations with a supplier of auxiliary Scandinavian dairy farmers are stakeholders in
services (packaging) have also come under scrutiny. Arlas development. Farmers within Arla have a
The policy issue is the extent to which Arlas own- financial stake in Arlas profitability, no matter
ership and control of dominant auxiliary firms what means are used to bring it about. Arlas
prevent other firms from accessing similar existing members also have a stake in defending
products. their benefits, so that if volumes of sales were
static, they would have an incentive to prevent
Arla is reported to have been found guilty of other farmers from joining. Farmers who are not
imposing exclusivity on a retail customer, at the suppliers to Arla have a stake in maintaining com-
expense of a rival supplier. Here, the policy issue is petition because they require continued access to
that the consumers interest is best served by processing firms and to retail buyers of processed
having products from numerous dairy processors products. Farmers wishing to join Arla have a stake
on the shelves of as many retail shops as possible. in ensuring that no barriers to entry exist.
Arlas actions not only prevented that outcome,
but also deprived a competitor of a market for its Farmers in foreign countries have seen their own
products, thus inflicting financial damage on its dairy-processing operations (whether cooperative
farmer-suppliers. or private) face competition from Arla, with the
likely consequence of damage to milk prices. As
It is notable that Arla produces own-label branded one consequence, local dairy processing firms may
products for retail customersparticularly in the be forced out of production of the most profitable
United Kingdomalongside its own heavily brand- dairy products and left with less lucrative alterna-
oriented marketing activities. This fact suggests that tives.

Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.


All rights reserved. This case study may be reproduced for educational purposes without express permission but must include
acknowledgement to Cornell University. No commercial use is permitted without permission.
10
ConcentrationinAgribusinessandMarketing:ACaseStudyofArlaFoods
BakerandGraberLtzhft

Retail buyers of dairy products have a stake in arrangements (requiring supply of one product
secure access to high-quality products at competi- with another), exclusivity of infrastructure and
tive prices. In addition, retailers would prefer to hardware, collaborative pricing arrangements, and
offer consumers a choice from their shelves. other issues between Arla and its retail customers.
Such policies may prove difficult to implement
Rural communities are stakeholders in agro- because compliance is difficult to ensure.
industrial change. Small, independent processing
firms (including cooperatives) provide different In the past, large, vertically integrated cooperatives
kinds of employment and economic contributions have justified their size and influence as a counter-
than do large, vertically integrated organizations weight to large and powerful retailers. Any policy
such as Arla. Given that Arla has supplanted almost steps taken to reduce Arlas ability to act as a
all small dairy-processing plants in Denmark, that counterweight to retailers would (1) face some well-
countrys rural communities have had to adjust, founded and popular opposition and (2) require
and that adjustment has produced winners and compensation of farmers that might exceed bene-
losers. fits to consumers.

Another approach may be to prohibit Arla from


PolicyOptions operating in markets related to the ones in which it
has achieved dominance. Arla might be excluded,
The most obvious policy option available to regu- for example, from markets for protein fractions, ice
lators of Arla is scrutiny, entailing monitoring of cream, or milk powder. Such an approach would
require sales of Arlas by-products to competing
mergers, takeovers, acquisitions, and joint firms, which would then be able to maintain a
ventures; presence in the dairy industry in order to challenge
pricing; Arla in the future.
complaints and legal actions; and In an extreme response, policy makers might
adherence to the cooperative constitution require Arla to be broken up into separate and
and relevant laws. competing firms. This approach would be a tech-
nical challenge and would need to be formulated
In dealing with such a persistent, dominant market and implemented in a manner that did not disrupt
force, policy makers might move to limit Arlas supplies from farms and processors. The breakup
market share in the event of any new proposed might be regional, vertical (for example, involving
mergers and acquisitions. Such a step would require separation of stages of processing and distribution),
legislators to define a maximum allowable market or market-by-market in a product sense.
share and then defend that definition. Several com-
plicating factors would also arise: Should market Arlas dominance in Denmark and Sweden is
share be defined over the EU as a whole (it is strongest as a buyer of raw milk: it is a virtual
politically defined as a single market) or just for monopsonist. This outcome has largely arisen, and
the three markets in which dominance is clear? been tolerated, because Arla is a cooperative.
Should market share be defined over all dairy Future policy will need to examine whether cooper-
products or just certain ones? atives should be allowed to become monopsonists
(which then eases their progress toward monopoly).
If Arla manages to increase its market share by At present, policy treatment of cooperatives is
increasing sales, without mergers and acquisitions, poorly equipped to deal with such problems:
regulators have few options. An alternative, how- Denmark has no cooperative law as such but makes
ever, lies in the regulation of retailers. Retailers are provisions for cooperatives through their
already prohibited from exercising exclusivity in adherence to aspects of their own constitutions.
sourcing, and this prohibition may provide an Policies could, however, restrict the length of Arlas
opportunity to constrain Arlas market share, contracts with suppliers or remove its exclusivity
particularly if Arla is prohibited from acquiring with individual farmers. The EU has not yet
competing firms. Contracts and other transactions developed a policy or legal construct for dealing
might be regulated to prohibit product-tying with market dominance by cooperatives. Most

Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.


All rights reserved. This case study may be reproduced for educational purposes without express permission but must include
acknowledgement to Cornell University. No commercial use is permitted without permission.
11
ConcentrationinAgribusinessandMarketing:ACaseStudyofArlaFoods
BakerandGraberLtzhft

arguments in favor of cooperatives as defenders of market power exercised by Arla, and decide which
farmers break down when the cooperative markets stakeholders are likely to be affected by Arlas
its products across borders to the detriment of exercise of market power in which ways.
foreign farmers.
More general policy options are also available to AdditionalReadings
encourage rivalry with Arla. These options include
supporting or subsidizing innovation, local On developments in Danish and EU competition
employment, product promotion and market law and institutions, including application to
research and investing in value-adding activities. merger and treatment of cooperatives
These instruments largely fall within regional
OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation
development policy or support to science and
and Development). 2005. Denmark: Report on
industrial development. It should be noted that
competition law and institutions (2004).
Arla cannot generally be excluded from taking
DAF/COMP (2005). Paris: OECD, Directorate
advantage of such incentives, which may have the
for Financial and Enterprise Affairs, Com-
effect of reinforcing its dominant position. A
petition Committee.
possible exception is in policies targeted at small
and medium-sized enterprises or those located in On empirical modeling methods used to measure
specified locations. Such an exception would be market power
effective in countering Arlas dominance only
Digal, L., and F. Ahmadi-Esfahani. 2002. Market
where (1) a subsidiary of Arla was not eligible and
power analysis in the retail food industry: A
(2) the eligible firms had sufficient size to take
survey of methods. Australian Journal of Agri-
advantage of the opportunities offered on a
cultural and Resource Economics 46 (4): 559
national scale.
584.
Governments are significant buyers of dairy On patterns of development and behavior in the
products through their ownership of hospitals, dairy industry
schools, prisons, and other state facilities. Govern-
Blayney, D., and A. Manchester. 2000. Large com-
ments could encourage competitors to Arla by
panies active in changing dairy industry. Food
awarding supply contracts to them instead of to
Review 23 (2): 813.
Arla. Implementing such a policy would require
support from local authorities, many of whom
operate competitive tendering arrangements and
would be loathe to favor a high-priced bid over a References
low one. In rural areas, local state facilities like hos-
pitals and schools serve the families of farmers who Arla Foods. 2002. EU approval for packaging
may be suppliers to Arla and so object to its partnership. News release, September 5.
exclusion from their local market. In the long run, http://www.arlafoods.com/appl/HJ/HJ202CO
such farmers might be viewed as potential sources M/HJ202D01.NSF/O/475EE9C237E34DCDC12
of milk for competing firms, but defections from 57068003E842E.
Arla are not likely to occur in regional blocs that
. 2006a. Arla Foods: A brief presentation,
would provide a competitor with easy market
2006.
entry.
http://www.arlafoods.dk/appl/HJ/HJ201AFD/
HJ201CFG.NSF/AllGraphics/HBLL6SRG6U/$F
Assignment ILE/Arla_KortPraes_2006_GB.pdf.
. 2006b. Arla Foods website.
Your assignment is to suggest policy recommenda- http://www.arlafoods.dk/appl/HJ/HJ201AFD/
tions for the various levels of government (local HJ201D01.NSF
Danish and British governments, national Danish
and Swedish governments, and the European
Commission) regarding the future of Arla and
other large agribusiness firms. Assess the extent of

Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.


All rights reserved. This case study may be reproduced for educational purposes without express permission but must include
acknowledgement to Cornell University. No commercial use is permitted without permission.
12
ConcentrationinAgribusinessandMarketing:ACaseStudyofArlaFoods
BakerandGraberLtzhft

. 2006c. The charge against Arla in Danish Competition Authority. 1999. Documents
Denmark. Press release, February 10. for 1999: Aftale mellem MD Foods AMBA og
http://www.arlafoods.com/APPL/HJ/HJ202C KS. April 21.
OM/HJ202D01.NSF/O/086A59F01CB45B22C1 http://www.ks.dk/publikationer/konkurrence/
257111003558EF. publikationer-1999/19990421-fusionen-mellem-
md-foods-og-kloever-maelk/aftale-mellem-md-
. 2006d. Hirtshals Cooperative Dairy and
foods-amba-og-ks/
Arla Foods have reached a settlement in the
dispute between the two companies. Press . 2000a. Aftalen: Fusionen mellem MD
release, February 28. Foods og Arla. January 24.
http://www.arlafoods.com/APPL/HJ/HJ202C http://www.ks.dk/presserum/presse-
OM/HJ202D01.NSF/O/E727B41EDF68FB16C12 2000/fusionen-mellem-md-foods-og-arla/
57123004CCFDC.
. 2000b. Bilag 1: Fusionen mellem MD
. 2007. Arla Foods purchase of Finnish Foods og Arla. January 24.
Ingman Foods approved. News release, January http://www.ks.dk/publikationer/konkurrence/
16. publikationer-2000/20000124-fusion-mellem-
http://www.arlafoods.com/APPL/HJ/HJ202C md-foods-og-arla/bilag-1-fusionen-mellem-md-
OM/HJ202D01.NSF/O/B2455D232C516447C1 foods-og-arla/
2572650035E06B.
. 2002. Konkurrencent. Arla har ikke ydet
Azzam, A. 1996. Testing the monopsony-ineffi- konkurrenceforvridende rabatter. December 8.
ciency incentive for backward integration. http://www.ks.dk/publikationer/konkurrencen
American Journal of Agricultural Economics yt/k-nyt-2002/konkurrencenyt-nr-8-
78 (3): 585590. december/arla-har-ikke-ydet-
konkurrenceforvridende-rabatter/
Baker, A. D. 2003. The Danish food marketing
chain: Developments and policy choices. . 2004a. Documents for 2004: Fusionerne
Rapport No. 154. Copenhagen. Danish Institute mellem MD Foods /Klver Mlk og Arla /
for Food and Resource Economics. MD Foods.
http://www.ks.dk/publikationer/redegoerelser
Braadland, T. 2000. Innovation in the Norwegian
/dok-for-2004/fusionerne-mellem-md-foods-
food system. Oslo STEP Programme,
kloever-maelk-og-arla-md-foods/
Norwegian Research Council.
. 2004b. Konkurrenceredegrelse 2004.
Brouwer, F., and J. Bijman. 2001. Dynamics in crop
http://www.ks.dk/publikationer/redegoerelser
protection, agriculture, and the food chain in
/2004-06-17-konkurrenceredegoerelse-
Europe. The Hague, the Netherlands: Agricul-
2004/kr2004pdf/
tural Economics Research Institute.
(p. 283, see table 9.4)
Connor, J. M. 1999. Breakfast cereals: The extreme
. 2006a. Arla idmt bde for misbrug af
food industry. Agribusiness 15 (2): 247260.
dominerende stilling. Press release, February 10.
. 2003. The changing structure of global http://www.ks.dk/presserum/presse-
food markets: Dimensions, effects, and policy 2006/arla-idoemt-boede-for-misbrug-af-
implications. Paper presented at conference dominerende-stilling/
Changing Dimensions of the Food Economy:
. 2006b. Anker Lftstedt vs. Arla Foods: A
Exploring the Policy Issues, The Hague,
dominant undertakings demand of a high fee
Netherlands 6-7 February.
for entering the cooperative society.
Cotterill, R. W. 1997. The food distribution system September 29.
of the future: Convergence toward the US or http://www.ks.dk/english/competition/nationa
UK model? Agribusiness 13 (2): 125139. l-judgments/national-judgments-2006/2006-
09-29-anker-loeftstedt-vs-arla-foods-a-
dominant-undertakings-demand-of-an-high-fee-
for-entering-the-cooperative-society/

Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.


All rights reserved. This case study may be reproduced for educational purposes without express permission but must include
acknowledgement to Cornell University. No commercial use is permitted without permission.
13
ConcentrationinAgribusinessandMarketing:ACaseStudyofArlaFoods
BakerandGraberLtzhft

Digal, L., and F. Ahmadi-Esfahani. 2002. Market Kinsey, J. 2003. Emerging trends in the new food
power analysis in the retail food industry: A economy: Consumers, firms, and science. Paper
survey of methods. Australian Journal of Agri- delivered at OECD Conference on Changing
cultural and Resource Economics 46 (4): 559 Dimensions of the Food Economy: Exploring
584. the Policy Issues, The Hague, the Netherlands,
6-7 February.
Eurofood. 2000. Arla/MD merger will not be
referred to Commission - MD Foods. February Kinsey, J. B., and R. Senaur. 1996. Consumer Trends
17. and Changing Food Formats. American Journal
http://www.findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_m0 of Agricultural Economics 78 (5): 11871191.
DQA/is_2000_Feb_17/ai_59870869.
Marsden, T., M. Harrison, and A. Flynn. 1998.
European Commission. 2002. Commission clears Creating competitive space: Exploring the
flexible packaging joint venture between social and political maintenance of retail power.
Denmark's Danapak and Teich of Austria. Press Environment and Planning 30 (3): 481498.
release, August 30.
McCorriston, S., and I. Sheldon. 1997. Vertical
http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do
restraints and competition policy in the US and
?reference=IP/02/1252.
UK food marketing systems. Agribusiness 13
. 2003. Case No. COMP/M.3130 - ARLA (2): 237252.
FOODS/EXPRESS DAIRIES Document No
Morrison, P. C. 2001. Market and cost structure in
303M3130. Notification of 16.04.2003 pur-
the U.S. beef packing industry: A plant-level
suant to Article 4 of Council Regulation No.
analysis. American Journal of Agricultural
4064/89. Brussels.
Economics 83 (1): 6476.
Food and Drink Europe. 2006. Consumers snub
OECD (Organization for Economic Cooperation
Arla's Mini30 milk. July 6.
and Development). 1999. Buying power of
http://www.foodanddrinkeurope.com/news/ng
multi-product retailers. DAFFE/CLP(99)21.
.asp?id=68947.
Paris: OECD, Directorate for Financial, Fiscal,
Hamann, K., and D. Baker. 2004. Review of policies and Enterprise Affairs, Committee on Com-
impacting the Danish food marketing chain. petition Law and Policy.
Working paper no. 07/2004. Copenhagen.
. 2004. Denmark: Report on competition
Danish Institute for Food and Resource Eco-
law and institutions. Paris: OECD, Directorate
nomics.
for Financial and Enterprise Affairs, Competi-
Harris, J. M. 2002. Food manufacturing. In J. M. tion Committee.
Harris, P. Kaufman, S. Martinez, and C Price, http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/51/16/3442544
The U.S. food marketing system, 2002. Agri- 7.pdf.
cultural Economic Report No. 811. Washington,
Park, T., and A. Weliwheta. 1996. Competitive
DC: Economic Research Service, U.S. Depart-
behaviour in the food retailing industry.
ment of Agriculture.
University of Georgia Faculty Series No. F.S.
Hennessy, D. 1996. Information asymmetry as a 96-23. Athens, GA.
reason for food industry vertical integration.
Rogers, R. 2001. Structural changes in U.S. food
American Journal of Agricultural Economics
manufacturing, 19581997. Agribusiness 17 (1):
78 (6): 10341043.
332.
Hughes, D. 2002. Grocery retailing in Europe and
Schroeter, J. R., and A. Azzam. 1990. Measuring
emerging routes to the consumer. Eurochoices
market power in multi-product oligopolies: The
1 (3): 1217.
U.S. meat industry. Applied Economics22 (10):
Hyde, C., and J. Perloff. 1998. Multimarket power 13651376.
estimation: The Australian retail meat sector.
Applied Economics 39 (5): 11691176.

Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.


All rights reserved. This case study may be reproduced for educational purposes without express permission but must include
acknowledgement to Cornell University. No commercial use is permitted without permission.
14
ConcentrationinAgribusinessandMarketing:ACaseStudyofArlaFoods
BakerandGraberLtzhft

Siebert, J. W., R. M. Nayga, and N. Hooker. 2000.
Dimensions of food safety risk mitigation
strategies adopted by meat processors: The
case of HACCP. Paper delivered at World
Food Forum, Chicago, IL. June 2425.
Stensrud, J. 1999. Food retailing in Europe. Statistics
in Focus, Theme 429/1999. Statistical Office
of the European Communities (Eurostat).
Luxembourg.
Traill, B., and J. Gilpin. 1994. Changes in size distri-
bution of EU food and drink manufacturers:
1980 to 1992. Agribusiness 14 (4): 321329.
UK Competition Commission. 2000. Supermarkets:
A report on the supply of groceries from
multiple stores in the United Kingdom. Report
to the Secretary of State for Trade and Indus-
try. London.
. 2003. Arla Foods amba and Express
Dairies plc: A report on the proposed merger.
http://www.competition-commis-
sion.org.uk/rep_pub/reports/2003/483arlaex
press.htm#full.
UK Monopolies and Mergers Commission. 1989.
The supply of beer: A report on the supply of
beer for retail sale in the United Kingdom.
Report to the Secretary for Trade and Indus-
try. London.
USDA (U.S. Department of Agriculture). 2002.
U.S. food industry structural data. Annex to J.
M. Harris, P. Kaufman, S. Martinez, and C
Price, The U.S. food marketing system, 2002.
Agricultural Economic Report No. 811.
Washington, DC: Economic Research Service,
U.S. Department of Agriculture..
Wrigley, N. 1997. Exporting the British model of
food retailing to the U.S.: Implications for the
EU-U.S. food systems convergence debate.
Agribusiness 13 (2): 137152.
. 2001. The consolidation wave in U.S. food
retailing: A European perspective. Agribusiness
17 (4): 489514.

Cornell University, Ithaca, New York.


All rights reserved. This case study may be reproduced for educational purposes without express permission but must include
acknowledgement to Cornell University. No commercial use is permitted without permission.
15

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi