Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 7

Trends in investment and labour inputs with economic development Page 1

Trends in Investment and Labour Inputs With Economic Development as Shown in the
Data of Jorgenson and Vu

By John Ross, 22 August 2010

Key Trends in Globalisation has published two articles on: (i) the contribution of capital
investment to GDP growth in developed and developing economies,1 (ii) differing patterns
of labour inputs in developed and developing economies.2 These are based on analyses of
the major database on international growth published by Jorgenson and Vu (Jorgenson & Vu,
2007b). The reason for such detailed analysis is both the importance of the issues involved
and a relation to long standing research topics. The present article introduces these papers.

The most fundamental issue involved is that of the tendency of the contribution of
investment to economic growth to increase with economic development. This trend was
first analysed by Adam Smith and affirmed by other economists including Keynes. 3 However,
it was rejected in analyses of economic growth put forward by various mid 20th century
theorists. The latter asserted, against the analysis flowing from Adam Smith, that the
division of the economy between investment and consumption remained constant with
economic development – this is, of course, a central assumption of the widely employed
Cobb-Douglas production function, of the economic growth model put forward by Solow

1
(Ross, 2010a)
2
(Ross, 2010b)
3
In The Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith analysed that the role of capital and intermediate inputs, which he
jointly termed ‘stock’, would increase as an economy developed. Smith noted: ‘As the accumulation of stock
must, in the nature of things, be previous to the division of labour, so labour can be more and more subdivided
in proportion only as stock is previously more and more accumulated… As the division of labour advances,
therefore, in order to give constant employment to an equal number of workmen, an equal stock of provisions,
and a greater stock of materials and tools than what would have been necessary in a ruder state of things must
be accumulated beforehand.’ (Smith, 1999, p. 372) Keynes, arrived at the same conclusion of an increasing
role of capital investment in economic development via a somewhat different chain of reasoning related to
savings behaviour: ‘the richer the community, the wider will be the gap between its actual and its potential
production… For a poor community will be prone to consumer by far the greater part of its output, so that a
very modest measure of investment will be sufficient to provide full employment; whereas a wealthy
community will have to discover much ampler opportunities for investment if the saving propensities of its
wealthier members are to be compatible with the employment of its poorer members.’ (Keynes, 1983, p. 31)
For a wider discussion see (Ross, 'The Asian and Chinese economic growth models - implications of modern
findings on economic growth', 2009).
Trends in investment and labour inputs with economic development Page 2

(Solow, 1957), and continues to be repeated in many4, although no longer all5, economic
textbooks.

As discussed in detail elsewhere (Ross, 2009), the present author from the early 1970s
concluded, on the basis of the long term historical data on growth that was then beginning
to be published, than Adam Smith and those who followed his analysis were clearly correct.
Despite the fact that the theories of Solow et al of a constant contribution of investment to
GDP growth were the prevailing orthodoxy they were contradicted by the historical data.
Jorgenson has outlined more general reasons for the breakdown of such econometric
models. (Jorgenson D. W., 2009) The theory that the proportion of the economy devoted to
investment remained constant, rather than rose with economic development, was
erroneous and classical economics was correct.

Initial statistical unclarity in this discussion was undoubtedly aided by the fact that the US is
untypical in that, unlike the great majority of other economies, the proportion of the US
economy devoted to fixed investment has indeed not risen for the approximately 150 year
period for which reliable statistical data exists. (Ross, 2008a) (Barro & Sala-i-Martin, 2004).6
Analyses based on generalisations from the US, therefore, arrived at the erroneous
generalisation of a constant, rather than rising, share of investment in GDP. 7

4
Romer for example asserts ‘The growth rates of output and capital has been about equal (so that the capital-
output ratio has been approximately constant).’ (Romer, 2006, p. 17) Blanchard asserts: ‘the savings rate does
not appear to systematically increase or decrease as a country becomes richer.’ (Blanchard, 2006, p. 226)
5
It is clearly rejected, as noted below, in (Barro & Sala-i-Martin, 2004)
6
The initial data on which the present author arrived at the conclusion of confirmation of a rising share of
investment in GDP was based on calculations from (Deane & Cole, 1967), (Feinstein, 1972), (Mitchell, 1980),
(Economist, The, 1982), (Lister, 1989). Barro and Sala-i-Martin note: ‘For the United States, the striking
observation… is the stability over time of the ratios for domestic investment and saving… The United States is,
however, an outlier with respect to the stability of its investment and saving ratios; the data for the other
seven countries *analysed+ show a clear increase in these ratios over time… The long-term data therefore
suggest that the ratios to GDP of gross domestic investment and gross national savings tend to rise as an
economy develops, at least over some range. The assumption of a constant gross savings ratio, which
appears… in the Solow-Swan model, misses the regularity in this data.’ (Barro & Sala-i-Martin, 2004, p. 15)
Baro and Sala-i-Martin do not, however, draw out all the implications of this.
7
Similar assertions were, however, also made by those who were centred on the UK economy - despite the
fact that the UK economy showed a clear tendency for the proportion of investment in GDP to rise with time.
Kaldor for example, in a widely cited paper, claimed as one of his ‘stylised facts’ on economic growth: ‘Steady
capital-output ratios over long periods; at least there are no clear long term trends, either rising or falling, if
differences in the degree of utilisation of capacity are allowed for. This implies, or reflects, the near identity in
Trends in investment and labour inputs with economic development Page 3

A consequence of the difference between the pattern in the US economy and the general
international trend of a rising share of investment in GDP, is that the US share of fixed
investment in GDP, which was above the international average in the 19 th and first half of
the 20th century, has now fallen below the international average – in particular the US level
of investment in GDP has fallen below the level of rapidly growing Asian economies. This
contributes to the slow growth of the US economy compared to Asian competitors, the US
balance of payments deficit with Asia, and present international financial developments.
(Ross, 2008b)

The question of whether the role of fixed investment in economic growth rises with
economic development, or remains constant, has numerous practical economic implications.
The key pieces of evidence demonstrating the rising contribution of fixed investment to GDP
growth with economic development, prior to the publication of the database of Jorgenson
and Vu, included:

1. Trends in leading international growth economies. The analysis of leading growth


economies, in successive historical periods of economic development from the 18 th century,
carried out by the present author from the 1970s onwards, showed that each such leading
economy – in chronological succession the UK, the US, West Germany, Japan, South Korea
and now China – was characterised by a higher percentage of fixed investment in GDP than
the preceding lead growth economy. This trend is shown in Figure 1.

the percentage rates of growth of production and the capital stock – i.e. that for the economy as a whole, and
over long periods, income and capital tend to grow at the same rate.’ (Kaldor, 1961, p. 178)
Trends in investment and labour inputs with economic development Page 4

Figure 1

Gross Domestic Fixed Capital Formation


% of GDP
45%

40%

35%

30%

25% UK
US
20%
Germany
15%
Japan
10% South Korea
5% China

0%

Source: Calculated from Deane and Cole British Economic Growth 1688-1959, The Economist 100 Years of
Economic Statistics and IMF International Financial Statistics

2. The comprehensive comparative analyses, published by Angus Maddison, of economic


growth in developed economies since World War II, including his Phases of Capitalist
Development (Maddison, 1982) and Dynamic Forces in Capitalist Development (Maddison,
1991), demonstrated that capital investment was the largest contributor to post-World War
II GDP growth in a wide range of advanced economies. Maddison demonstrated, over a
longer time frame than the post-World War II period, that both non-residential fixed
investment rates and savings rates, which were correlated with fixed investment rates, rose
with time in most advanced economies – the US, as already noted, being an exception and
not a rule. (Maddison, 1992)
Trends in investment and labour inputs with economic development Page 5

3. Studies by Jorgenson and his co-authors demonstrated that capital investment was the
largest single contribution to GDP growth in the US, the G7 and a number of developed
economies.8

While these studies analysed a wide range of developed, and a number of leading
developing, economies they were however not entirely comprehensive in coverage – in
particular they did not include a comprehensive range of developing economies. The
publication by Jorgenson and Vu (Jorgenson & Vu, 2007b) of a comprehensive growth
accounting base for up to 122 economies, constituting more than 95% of world GDP,
therefore provides an opportunity to fill this major gap.

A striking trend that may be analysed in its data, in addition to those drawn attention to by
Jorgenson and Vu themselves, is that GDP growth in developed economies is capital-
intensive while GDP growth in most developing economies is labour- intensive. The path of
economic development is therefore a transition from labour intensive growth to capital
intensive growth. The East Asian developing economies may be seen as an intermediate
group between the majority of developing economies and the developed economies.

Such a pattern is, of course, consistent with the other evidence showing the rising
contribution of investment to GDP growth with economic development. However, such a
comprehensive database for evaluation of these trends has not previously been available –
in particular it allows an integration of trends in developing economies with those in
developed economies. It is for this reason that these three analyses of trends in the data of
Jorgenson and Vu for capital and labour inputs in different stages of economic development
have been published.

Summary

It is clear on the basis of the above data that there is overwhelming evidence of a tendency
for the contribution of investment to GDP growth to rise with economic development. In
light of such clear evidence it is evident that the assertion that the contribution of
investment to GDP growth remains constant with time, rather than rising, is erroneous.

8
See for example (Jorgenson & Yip, 2001), (Jorgenson D. W., 2003). Other authors have, of course, also noted
the rising proportion of investment in GDP growth – see for example (Jones, 1995) and (De Long & Summers,
1992).
Trends in investment and labour inputs with economic development Page 6

Economic models and theories therefore must take into account that the contribution of
investment to GDP growth increases with economic development - Adam Smith and those
who followed him on this issue were correct.

The implications of this for economic theory and practice of such a trend are numerous as
has been analysed elsewhere (Ross, 2008a).

The normal disclaimer must, of course, be made that while these papers utilise calculations
based on data produced by Jorgenson and Vu they do not bear responsibility for the
conclusions drawn.

* * *
Since this analysis was carried out Jorgenson and Vu have extended their data to 2008.
(Jorgenson & Vu, 2010) The new data does not alter the main trends analysed above. A
detailed analysis from the angle of approach in this article will be published.

Bibliography

Barro, R. J., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (2004). Economic Growth. Cambridge, Massachusetts, US: MIT Press.

Blanchard, O. (2006). Macroeconomics. Upper Saddle River: Pearson Prentice Hall.

De Long, J. B., & Summers, L. H. (1992, revised October 1992). Equpment investment and economic growth. Retrieved August 22, 2010,
from http://j-bradford-delong.net/pdf_files/Brookings_Equipment.pdf

Deane, P., & Cole, W. (1967). British Economic Growth 1688-1959. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Economist, The. (1982). World Business Cycles. London: The Economist.

Feinstein, C. H. (1972). Statistical Tables of National Income, Expenditure and Output of the UK 1855-1965. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.

Jones, C. I. (1995). Time series tests of endogenous growth models. The Quarterly Journal of Economics , 110 (2), 495-525.

Jorgenson, D. W. (2003). 'Information technology and the G7 economies'. World Economics , 4 (4), 139-169.

Jorgenson, D. W. (2009). 'Introduction'. In D. W. Jorgenson (Ed.), The Economics of Productivity (pp. ix-xxviii). Cheltenham, UK: Edward
Elgar.

Jorgenson, D. W., & Vu, K. M. (2009). ‘Growth accounting within the International Comparison Programme’. The ICP Bulletin , 6 (1).

Jorgenson, D. W., & Vu, K. M. (2007b). 'Information technology and the world growth resurgence - updated tables'. Retrieved from Dale
Jorgenson: http://www.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/jorgenson/recent_work_jorgenson

Jorgenson, D. W., & Vu, K. M. (2010). Potential growth of the world economy. Journal of Policy Modeling
(doi:10.1016/j.polmod.2010.07.011).

Jorgenson, D. W., & Yip, E. (2001). 'Whatever happened to productivity growth'. In C. R. Hulten, E. R. Dean, & M. J. Harper (Eds.), New
Developments in Productivity Analysis (pp. 509-540).
Trends in investment and labour inputs with economic development Page 7

Kaldor, N. (1961). Capital Accumulation and Economic Growth. Retrieved August 22, 2010, from
http://www.fep.up.pt/docentes/joao/material/macro2/Kaldor_1961.pdf

Keynes, J. M. (1983). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: MacMillan.

Lister, T. (1989). One Hundred Years of Economic Statistics. London: The Economist.

Maddison, A. (1992). 'A long run perspective on saving'. Scandanavian Journal of Economics , 94 (2), 181-196.

Maddison, A. (1991). Dynamic Forces in Capitalist Development. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

Maddison, A. (1982). Phases of Capitalist Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Mitchell, B. R. (1980). European Historical Statistics 1750-1975. London: MacMillan.

Romer, D. (2006). Advanced Macroeconomics. Boston: McGraw-Hill Irwin.

Ross, J. (2008b, September 25). Fundamental driving forces of the financial crisis. Retrieved August 22, 2010, from Key Trends in
Globalisation: http://ablog.typepad.com/keytrendsinglobalisation/2008/09/it-is-superfluous-to-note-on-this-blog-that-the-world-
economy-ispassing-through-the-most-severe-financial-crisis-since-1929.html

Ross, J. (2010b, August 22). Labour inputs in stages of economic development – trends revealed in the data of Jorgenson and Vu. Retrieved
August 2010, 2010, from Key Trends in Globalisation:
http://ablog.typepad.com/keytrendsinglobalisation/2010/08/labour_inputs.html.html

Ross, J. (2009, September 8). 'The Asian and Chinese economic growth models - implications of modern findings on economic growth'.
Retrieved from Key Trends in Globalisation: http://ablog.typepad.com/keytrendsinglobalisation/2009/09/the-issue-of-whether-chinas-
economic-stimulus-package-and-the-asian--growth--model-in-general-is-correct-and-therefore-its.html

Ross, J. (2010 August, August). 'The Transition From Labour-Intensive to Capital-Intensive Growth During Economic Development – Trends
Revealed in the Data of Jorgenson and Vu'. Retrieved from Key Trends in Globalisation.

Ross, J. (2010a, August 22). 'The transition from labour-intensive to capital-intensive growth during economic development – trends
revealed in the data of Jorgenson and Vu. Retrieved August 22, 2010, from Key Trends in Globalisation:
http://ablog.typepad.com/keytrendsinglobalisation/2010/08/capital_intensive_growth.html.html

Ross, J. (2008a, September 17). Why Asia will continue to grow more rapidly than the US and Europe - a historical perspective. Retrieved
August 22, 2010, from Key Trends in Globalisationi: http://ablog.typepad.com/keytrendsinglobalisation/2008/09/data-on-long-term-
trends-in-investment-and-economic-growth--this-post-deals-with-the-historic-trend-of-investment-and-econo.html

Smith, A. (1999). The Wealth of Nations. London: Penguin.

Solow, R. M. (1957). 'Technical change and the aggregate production function'. Review of Economics and Statistics (3), 312-320.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi