Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 24

* Academy of Management Baview

1996. Vol. 23, No. 4, 773-79S.

MULTINATIONAL SUBSIDIARY EVOLUTION:


CAPABILITY AND CHARTER CHANGE IN
FOREIGN-OWNED SUBSIDIARY COMPANIES
JULIAN BIRKINSHAW
Stockholm School of Economics

NEIL HOOD
University of Strathclyde

In this article we develop a model ol subsidiary evolution io shed light on the


processes that drive changes in a subsidiary's activities and its underlying capabil-
ities. We see subsidiary evolution as (1) the enhancement/depletion of capabilities in
the subsidiary, coupled with (2) an explicit change in the subsidiary's charter. Build-
ing on this definition, we analyze the interaction between capability and charter
change and identify five generic subsidiary evolution processes, developing propo-
sitions around the underlying drivers for each process.

There has been a profound evolution in established typologies that suggest very differ-
thinking about multinational corporations ent roles and responsibilities for the population
(MNCs) during the past 10 years. Traditionally, of subsidiaries (e.g., Bartlett & Ghoshal, 1986;
in academic models researchers assumed that larillo & Martinez, 1990; White & Poynter, 1984).
ownership-specific advantages were devel- What is missing, we believe, is an understand-
oped at the corporate headquarters and lever- ing of how subsidiaries change roles. Is there a
aged overseas through the transfer of technol- predictable evolution process toward, for exam-
ogy to a network of foreign subsidiaries ple, greater specialization in terms of product,
(Dunning; 1981; Vernon, 1966). As these over- market, or technology? What are the factors pro-
seas subsidiaries grew in size and developed moting and/or suppressing such a shift? What
their own unique resources, however, it be- are the underlying managerial processes that
came apparent to many researchers that cor- make such a shift possible?
porate headquarters was no longer the sole
source of competitive advantage for the MNC. These questions are made more complex by
Scholars developed models such as the heter- the enormous variety of multinational subsid-
archy (Hedlund, 1986) and the transnational iaries in existence. For example, subsidiary can
(Bartlett & Ghoshal, 1989) to reflect the critical refer to the totality of the MNCs holdings in a
role played by many subsidiaries in their cor- host country or to a single entity, such as a
porations' competitiveness, and research at- manufacturing or sales operation. Subsidiaries
tention began to shift toward understanding are established for a variety of motives (e.g.,
the new roles played by subsidiaries. resource seeking, market seeking, or efficiency
Implicit in this shift in research attention has seeking) and through a variety of modes (e.g.,
been the concept of subsidiary evolution. We greenfield, acquisition, or joint venture). The re-
specify later in this article a precise definition of lationship of the subsidiary to the parent com-
subsidiary evolution, but, for the moment, it can pany can be anything from legal holding com-
be understood broadly as the process of accu- pany to fully integrated. And recent shifts
mulation or depletion of resources/capabilities toward regional free trade have led to interna-
in the subsidiary over time. There is already tional divestments, rationalizations, mergers,
widespread acknowledgment that subsidiaries and acquisitions—all of which lead to further
evolve over time, typically through the accumu- changes in the make-up of the MNCs subsidiar-
lation of resources and through the development ies. The reality is that a single evolution process
of specialized capabilities (Hedlund, 1986; Pra- for subsidiaries cannot be readily identified.
halad & Doz, 1981). There are also a number of Subsidiaries contract or die out, as well as be-
773
774 Academy o/ Management fleview October

come larger or more specialized, and there are hardt, 1996). We elaborate on this definition later
many different factors that can influence the in the article, but, for the moment, it is important
processes. In this article we therefore put for- to recognize that changes to the subsidiary's
ward a number of generic processes that are stock of capabilities and its charter are closely
appropriate under certain conditions. We also tied to the subsidiary's ability to add value.
draw extensively from the empirical literature to There is some danger, when considering sub-
ensure that the ideas we present are grounded sidiary evolution, that one will develop a nor-
in the available evidence. mative bias toward the accumulation of re-
We organize this article into two parts. The sources and specialized capabilities (i.e.,
first part is a systematic review of the literature subsidiary development), both because it is
on subsidiary evolution. This literature is frag- more commonly reported and because develop-
mented, but we identify three broadly defined ment is an intrinsically more attractive phenom-
schools of thought on the processes underlying enon to study than decline. We are careful in
subsidiary evolution. The second part of the ar- this article to avoid such a stance, partly be-
ticle is theoretical development. Building on cause development is just one side of the story
foundations provided by the resource-based and partly because it is clearly possible that
view of the firm, we define subsidiary evolution subsidiary development is not always desirable
in terms of capability and charter change and from the MNCs perspective. Host country laws
then put forward five generic subsidiary evolu- or customer requirements may force the MNC to
tion processes. For each one we develop propo- undertake activities in that country that it would
sitions linking various antecedent conditions to rather do elsewhere, and subsidiary manage-
subsidiary evolution. ment may take certain actions to develop the
We feel it is important to be clear on the subsidiary for the benefit of their country or for
boundaries of this study from the outset. We are themselves (i.e. "empire building"). Our prefer-
concerned with those processes that occur once ence, then, is to model the generic processes of
the MNC has made its initial foreign direct in- subsidiary evolution in positivist terms—that is,
vestment in the host country; hence, we do not with regard to what the literature and experi-
consider issues of market entry (Johanson & ence tells us actually happens—and to ensure
Vahlne, 1977}. We are concerned primarily with that our definition of subsidiary evolution ac-
dominantly owned or wholly owned subsidiar- counts for the possible lack of alignment be-
ies, because the literature addressing the phe- tween subsidiary and parent company goals.
nomenon of subsidiary evolution has focused on
such cases. Nonetheless, our expectation is that
many of the processes we discuss in this article LITERATURE REVIEW
could be adapted to other forms of subsidiary, There exists a substantial body of literature
such as international joint ventures and alli- concerned with various aspects of multinational
ances. subsidiary management (for reviews, see Birkin-
We define subsidiary as a value-adding entity shaw & Morrison, 1995, and Jarillo & Martinez,
in a host country. This definition reflects the 1989). In the past 10 years the focus of such
reality that a given host country will sometimes research has been on the different roles taken
have several subsidiaries (of the same parent) by subsidiaries (e.g., Bartlett & Ghoshal, 1986;
that are independent of one another and that, Gupta & Govindarajan, 1991, 1994; White &
consequently, will have a separate evolutionary Poynter, 1984). Strangely, little explicit attention
path. A subsidiary can perform a single activity has been given to the question of how a partic-
(e.g., manufacturing) or an entire value chain of ular subsidiary's role might shift over time (mi-
activities. Finally, subsidiary evolution refers to nor exceptions are Jarillo & Martinez, 1990; Pa-
the enhancement or atrophy of subsidiary capa- panasstasiou & Pearce, 1994; and White &
bilities over time and the establishment or loss Poynter, 1984). In part, this lack of attention re-
of the commensurate charter (Galunic & Eisen- flects the cross-sectional nature of the research,
but it also appears to emanate from an assump-
tion that the subsidiary's role is "assigned" to it
' Hence lies our decision to focus on subsidiary evolution
by the parent company according to such factors
rather than subsidiary development. as the perceived capabilities of the subsidiary
1998 Birkinshaw and Hood 775

and the strategic importance of the local market Head-Oifice Assignment


(Bartlett & Ghoshal, 1986).
Head-office assignment of roles is a critical Two theoretical perspectives shed light on the
determinant of subsidiary evolution, but in our head-office-driven process of subsidiary evolu-
reading of the literature, it is just one of three tion: (1) the product life cycle (PLC) model
broad mechanisms that are responsible for driv- (Vernon, 1966) and (2) the internationalization
ing the process. The second we refer to as sub- process (Johanson & Vahlne, 1977). Both work on
sidiary choice, which reflects the decisions the assumption that the subsidiary is an instru-
taken by subsidiary management to define for ment of the MNC and, consequently, that it acts
themselves the role of their subsidiary. The third solely with regard to head-office-determined im-
we refer to as locaJ environment deteiminism. in peratives. In Table 1 we summarize these two
that the role of the subsidiary can be understood theoretical perspectives, along with the other
as a function oi the constraints and opportuni- three perspectives that we subsequently dis-
ties in the local market. Our basic understand- cuss.
ing of subsidiary evolution is that the three Vernon's (1966) PLC model is well known. In
mechanisms interact to determine the subsid- the first stage the MNC manufactures and sells
iary's role at any given point in time. The sub- in its home market and also exports to certain
sidiary's role subsequently impacts the deci-
foreign markets. As the product matures, low-
sions made by head-office managers, the
decisions made by subsidiary managers, and cost production becomes important and foreign
the standing of the subsidiary in the local envi- competition a threat, so the MNC establishes
ronment. This creates a cyclical process through production overseas. This production is directed
which the subsidiary's role changes over time. primarily toward the host country, but, as qual-
Figure 1 illustrates the process. We underscore, ity improves, it may also be exported back to the
however, that this framework is simply a means home country. Finally, once the host country ad-
of organizing the literature review that follows. vances to a stage where its costs are uncompeti-
In the second part of the article we provide a tive, production is shifted to a lower-cost host
more detailed specification of the evolution pro- country (see also Mullor-Sebastian, 1983, and
cess, as we see it. Norton & Rees, 1979).

HGURE 1
Organizing Framework for Subsidiary Evolution

Head-office assignment
Decisions made by head-office
managers regarding the allocation
of activities to the subsidiary

Subsidiary's lole
Subsidiary choice Measured in terms of the
Decisions made by subsidiary specific business, or elements
managers regarding the activities oi the business, the
undertaken by the subsidiary subsidiary undertakes and
for which it has responsibility

i.ocai environment deteiminism


Influence of environmental factors
on decisions made by head-office and/
or subsidiary managers regarding the
activities undertaken by the subsidiary
776 Academy of Management Beview October

TABLE 1
Summary of Different Perspectives on Subsidiary Evolution
Drivers of Subsidiary Role oi Subsidiary in Role of Subsidiary in
Perspective Theoretical Roots Evolution MNC Host Country

Product life cycle Economics; Economic development Subordinate entity; Manufactures and sells
transaction cost of host country; recipient of technology products in local
theory transfer ol technology transfers market; exploitative
from parent to role
subsidiary
Internationalization Cognitive and Cognitive limitations of Subordinate entity; Learns about local
process behavioral HQ management; recipient of investment market; builds
theory incremental increase on basis of market experience and
in commitment to experience transfers it back to HQ
foreign market
Network Sociology; Growth oi resources Node in a network; "Embedded" in local
perspective resource through organic potential source of network, which can be
dependency process; allocation of ownership-specific a source of influence
theory responsibilities on advantages and equal vis-d-vis HQ
basis oi relative power partner with HQ
Decision process "Managerial" Development of Role is function of Not discussed
theory of the structural context that subsidiary's structural
firm allows subsidiary context; may be
management to subordinate or equal
develop organically partner with HQ
Regional Economic Local environment Subsidiary provides Participates in local
development geography; growth and upgrading access to local industrial cluster; may
trade theory stimulates subsidiary learning, which is be an active
development disseminated through contributor to local
corporation economic development

The PLC model helps us to understand the Building from a more micro perspective than
development process as subsidiaries' roles shift the PLC model, authors of the infernafionaiiza-
toward high value-added activities—from ser- tion process literature begin with assumptions
vicing the local market to "adapting" the tech- about the cognitive limitations and behaviors of
nology to local specifications, then exporting individual managers (Cyert & March, 1963) and
back to the home country, and, eventually, to seek to understand how firms move beyond their
contributing to product development (Harrigan, national borders (e.g., Agarwal & Ramaswami,
1984; Vernon, 1979). However, it is limited in two 1992; Aharoni, 1966; Cavusgil, 1980; Johanson &
ways: (1) the subsidiary is always subordinate to Vahlne, 1977; Li, 1995). In their model, Johanson
the center, and (2) the possibility of subsidiary and Vahlne (1977) explain this process in terms
decline is not considered. There are, however, a of the reciprocal relationship between (1) levels
number of contributions from the same eco- of knowledge about, and existing commitment
nomic paradigm that begin to address both of to, the foreign market and (2) decisions regard-
these shortfalls. Some acknowledgment has ing further commitment to the market.
been made of the greater role that the subsid- This model can be readily applied to the case
iary can play in the MNC network (e.g. Dunning, of established subsidiaries. For example, the
1993; Rugman & Verbeke, 1992) but still to a decision to enhance the manufacturing opera-
lesser degree than the subsidiary choice per- tion in a subsidiary represents a "commitment
spectives we discuss below. Also, the foreign decision," based on an appreciation of the sub-
divestment process has been modeled to under- sidiary's current strengths and weaknesses (i.e.,
stand the factors that precipitate the closure or maiket knowledge) and a desire to increase the
sale of a foreign subsidiary (Boddewyn, 1979, quality of investment in that country (i.e., market
1983). commitment). That decision, thus, leads to in-
1998 Birkinshaw and Hood 777

creased commitment, greater understanding of plicitly models subsidiary growth as a sequen-


the local business environment, and the possi- tial process of resource commitment and capa-
bility of a further investment in the future. Sub- bility building. There have also been occasional
sidiary development, then, is achieved through studies from other parts of the world indicating
the cyclical interaction between investment and the importance of head-office assignment as the
learning.^ Again, though, there are limitations driver of subsidiary development (e.g., Jarillo &
as to how applicable the theory is to the generic Martinez, 1990; Malnight, 1995, 1996).
issue of subsidiary evolution—the most promi- Researchers have also given subsidiary de-
nent being that it is more effective at modeling cline some attention. Boddewyn (1979, 1983) un-
development than decline. Given that market dertook a comprehensive review of foreign di-
knowledge and commitment must increase the vestment and concluded that poor financial
longer the subsidiary is operating in its host performance was the primary cause, followed
market, the decision to reduce commitment or by lack of strategic iit and various organization-
exit a country has to be interpreted as an exog- al problems, such as poor relationships between
enous input to the model. To be useful as a parent and subsidiary. More recently, research
generic model, some modifications would ap- undertaken in the United Kingdom on the Eu-
pear to be necessary. rope-wide rationalization sparked by free trade
In terms of the empirical literature, there ex- has shown that the dynamics of internal compe-
ists a large body of work in which scholars ex- tition between subsidiaries are a critical deter-
amine various aspects of subsidiary evolution minant of which subsidiaries survive (Almor &
from a headquarters assignment perspective. Hirsch, 1995; Sachdev, 1976; Young, McDermott,
The most comprehensive evidence comes from & Dunlop, 1991).
researchers in the United Kingdom, who have, Three important implications can be drawn
over a 30-year period, tracked the successive from this review. First, head-office assignment
waves of U.S., European, and Japanese invest- is not the sole determinant of subsidiary evolu-
ment into the United Kingdom. This research tion. As the U.K. studies have shown, the
shows that, in aggregate, there has been a clear changes in subsidiary roles were dictated by
development process—from "miniature replica" head office but motivated, in large part, by the
subsidiaries (White 8E Poynter, 1984) in the 1950s changing economic conditions in the United
and 1960s to rationalized manufacturers and Kingdom and Europe. They were also, to a large
product specialists in the 1970s and 1980s (Hood degree, driven by the track record of the subsid-
& Young, 1983; Young, Hood, & Hamill, 1988)—in iary companies in question, especially during
a manner that is consistent with both the PLC the recent phase of plant rationalization in Eu-
and internationalization models. rope. Second, most of the evolution documented
Evidence for the head-office assignment pro- (development and decline) was at the low value-
cess also can be found in the case of foreign- added end of the scale. Very few had "world
owned subsidiaries in the United States, al- mandates" (Roth & Morrison, 1992) or product
though not in the same detail as in the United development responsibilities. This leads to the
Kingdom. Much has been written, for example, observation that head-office assignment may be
about the growth of Japanese manufacturing the driver of subsidiary evolution in the early
operations in the United States (e.g., Hamel & stages of the process, when the level of re-
Prahalad, 1985; Lincoln, Olson, & Hanada, 1978; sources and capabilities in the subsidiary is not
Sugiura, 1990), but the evidence simply indi- too advanced. Third, theoretical perspectives
cates that these subsidiaries have grown and, to have not been very helpful for understanding
some extent, have adapted to the local environ- some of the higher-order value-adding activity
ment. More fruitfully, research by Chang (1985, that has emerged in subsidiaries, nor for under-
1996) and Rosenzweig and Chang (1995a,b) ex- standing the process of subsidiary decline (how-
ever, see Boddewyn, 1979, for the one exception).
^ Madhok (1997) makes the point that the emphasis on
knowledge accumulation in this mode] makes it essentially Subsidiary Choice
part of the organizafionai capabilities school that defines
the firm on the basis of its proprietary capabilities rather Two theoretical perspectives shed light on the
than market failure considerations. subsidiary choice view of subsidiary develop-
778 Academy of Management Review Qctober

ment: (1) the network model of the MNC and (2) plete control of its own destiny (Pfeffer & Salan-
the decision process perspective. The network cik, 1978; Prahalad & Doz, 1981).
model of the MNC, in contrast to the PLC model The second theoretical approach involves the
discussed earlier, allows the subsidiary to move decision process in large, complex organiza-
from a position of subordination (vis-a-vis head tions (Bower, 1970; Burgelman, 1983a, 1991, 1996;
office) to one of equality, or even leadership. In Noda & Bower, 1996; Prahalad, 1976). Like the
terms of core assumptions, the network model internationalization process perspective, the
recognizes that ownership-specific advantages body of literature on the decision process per-
do not have to be tied to the home country (Rug- spective begins with assumptions of bounded
man & Verbeke, 1992) but can, instead, be ac- rationality on the part of individual managers.
quired or developed by the subsidiary itself. In This literature has provided much of the foun-
addition, the MNC is modeled as an "interorgan- dations for the network model of the MNC, and
izational network" (Ghoshal & Bartlett, 1991) of various aspects of subsidiary management
loosely coupled entities, rather than a hierarchi- have also been studied from this perspective
cal monolith. This loose coupling gives the sub- (Bartlett & Ghoshal, 1986; Prahalad & Doz, 1981).
sidiary the necessary freedom to develop its Surprisingly, though, subsidiary evolution has
own unique resource profile. received only limited attention. Only Prahalad
Much of the contemporary thinking on MNC and Doz (1981) explicitly have considered sub-
organization conforms to these basic assump- sidiary growth, and their concern was with how
tions, without an explicit network conceptual- the head office could continue to exert control
ization (e.g. Bartlett & Ghoshal, 1989; Hedlund, over its subsidiaries, rather than with the bene-
1986; White & Poynter, 1984). More recently, fits of growth per se.
scholars have attempted to model more formally Of greater interest, in terms of this article, is
the relationships between entities in the MNC the work of Burgelman (1983a,b), who studied
according to their relative power (Forsgren, internal corporate venturing using an extension
Holm, & Johanson, 1992; Forsgren & Pahlberg, of Bower's (1972) resource allocation model. His
1992; Ghoshal & Bartlett, 1991). This latter stream key contribution was a recognition that strategic
of research has built on the concepts of network behavior often occurs below top management
analysis developed in the fields of industrial levels and sometimes in ways that are not ac-
marketing (Johanson & Mattson, 1988) and organ- tively encouraged by top management. He
izational theory (Emerson, 1962; Pfeffer & Salan- termed this autonomous hehavior. Regarding
cik, 1978; Thompson, 1967). It is important to note the MNC subsidiary, the concept of autonomous
that the resource-based view of the firm (Barney, behavior is important, because it suggests a
1991; Penrose, 1959; Wernerfelt, 1984) has a lot in process of internal growth that is only loosely
common with the network model, once one rec- controlled by head-office directives. The idea
ognizes that resource development can occur at that subsidiaries take the initiative to win world
the level of the subsidiary, rather than at the product mandates, for example, is very consis-
level of the MNC as a whole. tent with Burgelman's theory (Birkinshaw, 1995;
The network model provides a very valuable Crookell, 1986).
perspective on subsidiary evolution, because it In sum, both theoretical perspectives give us
reflects the reality that many subsidiaries have considerable potential for understanding sub-
specialized capabilities on which the rest of the sidiary evolution. The network perspective pro-
MNC is dependent. Evolution here is an organic vides important insights into the role of the un-
process, built around the growth and decline of derlying capabilities of the subsidiary and
valuable and distinctive resources in the sub- emphasizes that the subsidiary is part of a net-
sidiary. Subsidiary growth, in particular, is con- work—not just a dyadic relationship with a par-
strained by the natural rate of growth of re- ent company. The decision process perspective
sources (Penrose, 1958) and also by the actions of provides us with a way of understanding auton-
other entities (notably the parent company) who omous action on the part of subsidiaries.
use their relative power to enforce their will on The empirical literature that draws on the
the subsidiary. As the subsidiary increases its subsidiary choice perspective is mostly from
stock of distinctive resources, it lessens its de- Canada, but smaller contributions come from
pendence on other entities and takes more com- Sweden, Ireland, and the United Kingdom. Can-
1998 Birkinshaw and Hood 779

ada appears to have been an attractive setting ment of resources and capabilities. Second,
for research on subsidiary choice because of the head-office support appears to be a necessary
consistently high levels of foreign ownership of but not sufficient condition for subsidiary-driven
industry (Safarian, 1966) and the deliberate pol- development. Many of the failed cases of initia-
icy of governments in the 1970s and 1980s to tives in the Canadian literature appear to have
encourage foreign MNCs to grant their Cana- been the result of weak parent-subsidiary rela-
dian subsidiaries "world product mandates" tionships or a somewhat ethnocentric attitude
(Hatch Report, 1979). A landmark study by the among parent managers (Birkinshaw, 1997;
Science Council of Canada (1980) documented Perlmutter, 1969).^ Third, subsidiary decline gets
case studies of subsidiaries that had won such essentially no consideration in either the theo-
mandates, typically achieved through develop- retical or the empirical literature. Clearly, it is
ment of specialized capabilities and strong re- meaningless to suggest that subsidiary manag-
lationships with the parent company. Subse- ers might orchestrate their own demise, but we
quent studies by Bishop and Crookell (1986) and can certainly envision a process in which inac-
Birkinshaw (1995) drew similar conclusions. tion by subsidiary managers leads to the atro-
Thus, while the macro changes in the Canadian phy and eventual demise of the subsidiary and
business environment, and the strategic re- its resources.
sponses to those changes by parent company
management, shaped the broad shift toward
subsidiary specialization, there is strong evi- Local Environment Determinism
dence that specific subsidiaries' development In much of the mainstream organization the-
paths were also swayed by the entrepreneurial ory literature, scholars view organizational ac-
actions of their managers. tion as constrained or determined by the envi-
Although Canadian researchers are alone in ronment in which it occurs (Hannan & Freeman,
emphasizing subsidiary initiative as the driver 1977; Meyer & Rowan, 1977; Pfeffer 8r Salancik,
of development, there has been some discussion 1978). MNC researchers have adapted this per-
of the concept for U.K. (Papanasstasiou & spective by proposing that each subsidiary of
Pearce, 1994), Scottish (Young, Hood, & Peters, the MNC operates in its own unique task envi-
1994), and Irish (Delaney, 1996) subsidiaries, and ronment, which constrains or determines the ac-
Gupta and Govindarajan (1994) have discussed tivities of that subsidiary (Ghoshal & Bartlett,
it as well. In research on international R&D lab- 1991; Ghoshal & Nohria, 1989; Rosenzweig &
oratories, scholars have offered similar conclu- Singh, 1991; Westney, 1994). The argument, in
sions (Behrman & Fischer, 1980; Hdkanson & essence, is that each subsidiary operates under
Zander, 1986; Pearce, 1989; Ronstadt, 1977)— a unique set of conditions to which it has to
namely, that over time R&D laboratories tend to adapt in order to be effective. The nature of the
evolve through their own initiative toward local environment, as defined by customers,
higher value-added R&D work. Finally, a num- competitors, suppliers, and government bodies,
ber of Swedish researchers working from a thus has an important influence on the activities
head-office perspective have pursued the same undertaken by the subsidiary.
themes in a rather different way. Their overall Although the static relationship between the
approach has been one of organizational devel- subsidiary and its local environment has been
opment, but the evidence of subsidiaries build- studied (e.g., Andersson & Johanson, 1996;
ing specialized resources and gaining recogni- Ghoshal & Nohria, 1989; Rosenzweig & Nohria,
tion for their distinctive abilities is compelling 1995), there has been less consideration of the
(Forsgren et al., 1992, 1995; Forsgren & Pahlberg, dynamic question—that is, the relationship be-
1992; Ghauri, 1992; Holm, Johanson, & Thilenius, tween local/regional development and subsid-
1995).
This evidence points to a number of implica-
tions for the subsidiary evolution process in
general. First, autonomous subsidiary behavior Note that there are cases of subsidiaries "assuming"
charters (Hagstrom. 1994) without head-office support, but
(Burgelman, 1983b) appears to be a potent force our argument is that these do not constitute part ol the
for subsidiary development because it leads to subsidiary development process. We return to this point in
the planned—rather than fortuitous—develop- the theory development section.
780 Academy of Management Review October

iary evolution (Young et al., 1994).'* In the litera- 1986). There is, however, an increasing acknowl-
ture that does exist, scholars have, for the most edgment of the importance of inward invest-
part, not explicitly considered the foreign- ment agencies, such as Scottish Enterprise,
owned sector. One important line of thinking is whose role is not only to attract greenfield in-
the various "stages" models of economic growth vestments but also to help existing subsidiaries
that explicitly recognize the importance of for- upgrade their activities (Hood, Young, & Lai,
eign direct investment (FDI) by MNCs as a driver 1994).
oi the process. These include Ozawa's "dynamic In sum, there is strong evidence that the sub-
paradigm of FDI-facilitated development" (1992) sidiary development process is influenced by
and Dunning's investment development cycle the local environment, through both (1) the
(1981, 1986). In both, the MNC subsidiary plays a broadly defined dynamism and attractiveness
critical role as a conduit for technology and skill of the local business context and (2) the specific
development in the local economy. incentive programs offered by development
Implicitly, the subsidiary itself also develops, agencies. But, as with many oi the other per-
in that it becomes capable of adopting and ap- spectives, it is the early stages of subsidiary
plying increasingly sophisticated levels of the development that scholars best understand,
MNCs technology. Porter (1990) proposes a while later-stage development and decline get
stages model of growth based on his "diamond little attention.
of competitive advantage," but he sees the role
of the MNC subsidiary as primarily one of "se-
lective tapping" (of ideas), rather than active Integrating the Three Perspectives
development. The exception, he argues, is the In this review we took a broad approach in
few subsidiaries in leading-edge clusters that identifying any theoretical or empirical re-
go on to become the MNCs home base for a search that potentially shed light on the process
particular business area. of subsidiary evolution. In order to move for-
We should briefly mention the theoretical ra- ward, however, it is important to take a position
tionale for linking regional development to sub- and develop one line of thinking in detail. Our
sidiary evolution. The heart of the issue is the preference is to build upon the subsidiary
argument that certain aspects of knowledge choice perspective. We fully embrace the net-
transfer occur more effectively between local work conceptualizations of the MNC by model-
firms (wholly owned or subsidiaries) than be- ing the subsidiary as a semiautonomous entity,
tween parent and overseas subsidiary, because capable of making its own decisions but con-
of geographical proximity and cultural similar- strained in its action by the demands of head-
ity (Kogut & Zander, 1992; Krugman, 1991; Porter, office managers and by the opportunities in the
1990; Solvell & Zander, 1998). Subsidiary evolu- local environment. We also borrow heavily from
tion, thus, is driven by the dynamism of the local the decision process perspective, notably the
business environment (cf.. Porter's diamond), as work of Burgelman (1983b) on autonomous be-
well as by the subsidiary's ability to access re- havior.
sources from the MNC. We draw on the other perspectives to a lesser
The evidence for local environment-driven degree. The PLC model offers important lessons
subsidiary evolution is rather limited. Both the in the early stages of subsidiary development,
U.K. and Canadian literature we discussed ear- but it does not allow for autonomous action on
lier make it clear that local environment char- the part of the subsidiary. The internationaliza-
acteristics factor into the decision to invest in or tion process, likewise, has implications for ear-
upgrade a subsidiary, but, typically, it is the ly-stage development but is rooted in a head-
subsidiary company or head-office managers office perspective on MNC management. The
who drive the process (e.g.. Bishop & Crookell, local environment perspective has clear impli-
cations for subsidiary development, but in its
pure form it is fundamentally opposed to the
* There is also a large body of literature originating from subsidiary choice perspective (Child, 1972). It is
the field of economic geography, in which authors look at the also less developed than the other perspectives.
spatial distribution of the MNC and its relationship with
regional economic development (e.g., Clarke, 1985; Dicken, The theory part of this article can be described
1976; McNee, 1958). as a "dynamic capabilities" approach to subsid-
1998 Birkinshaw and Hood 781

iary evolution. We draw heavily on recent ad- An important point to underscore here is that
vances in thinking about organizational capa- the subsidiary's capabilities are, to some extent,
bilities (Kogut & Zander, 1992; Madhok, 1997; distinct from the capabilities of the headquar-
Teece, Pisano, & Shuen, 1993), but we do so with ters operation and its sister subsidiaries. In
an important distinction—namely, a focus on other words, the particular geographical setting
the subsidiary, rather than the entire firm, as the and history of the subsidiary are responsible for
unit of analysis. Our approach is, of course, con- defining a development path that is absolutely
sistent with the network conceptualizations of unique to that subsidiary, which, in turn, results
the MNC, but it also raises a number of new in a profile of capabilities that is unique (Teece
challenges. et al., 1997). There are also, of course, shared
capabilities between subsidiaries, such as
those codified in company manuals or blue-
THEORETICAL DEVELOPMENT prints. The evidence, however, indicates that the
Toward a Definition of Subsidiary Evolution transfer of capabilities between units of the
same firm is iar from trivial and is a function of
Following Amit and Schoemaker (1993), we de- the codifiability of the capability in question
fine resources as the stock of available factors (Zander, 1994), the motivations of the receiving
owned or controlled by the subsidiary and ca- units, and a host of contextual variables (Szu-
pabilities as a subsidiary's capacity to deploy lanski, 1996).^ Capabilities, simply stated, are
resources, usually in combination, using organ- "sticky," and they cannot be easily transferred
izational processes to effect a desired end. Sub- from one subsidiary to the next, even when the
sidiary capabilities can be specific to a func- transfer is undertaken willingly.
tional area—for example, flexible production,
research into iiber optics, or logistics manage- Related to the stickiness of subsidiary capa-
ment— or they can be more broadly based—for bilities is their path dependence.^ Capabilities
example, total quality management, systems in- are not easily transferred and not readily dissi-
tegration, innovation, or government relations. pated. They develop over time as a result of past
experiences and are subsequently applied to
Subsidiary evolution, we argue, is the result of new or related areas of business. To some ex-
an accumulation or depletion of capabilities tent, new capabilities are always being devel-
over time.'^ In this respect, we are very close to oped, but they typically emerge at the margin of
the dynamic capabilities perspective of Nelson existing capabilities in response to competitive
and Winter (1982), Dierickx and Cool (1989), demands (see below). As a result, it is possible
Kogut and Zander (1992), and Teece et al. (1997), to think in terms of path-dependent trajectories
in that we are concerned with the "mechanisms of capabilities that gradually evolve over time.
by which firms accumulate and dissipate new Large-scale grafting of new capabilities onto
skills and capabilities" {Teece et al., 1997: 19). To the subsidiary's existing stock of capabilities
some extent, capabilities are accumulated and also can be achieved through merger or acqui-
stored as organizational routines (Nelson & Win- sition (Huber, 1991; Madhok, 1997), although such
ter, 1982) that have emerged over time, but the a process has been shown in the postacquisition
process also can be strongly influenced by var- integration literature to be far from trivial
ious subsidiary, corporate, and local environ- (Haspeslagh & Jemison, 1991).
ment factors, many of which we discussed ear-
lier.
^ Of course, there is also a transaction cost argument
here, in that there are costs asscx;iated with transacting with
other units, even if they are part oi the same firm. This
* Note that the accumulation of capabilities is very differ- reduces the likelihood oi transfer, which adds to the sticki-
ent Irom the accumulation of resources. A resource- ness oi the capabilities in question.
accumulating subsidiary may just be "fat," as a reviewer 'Bamey (1991) and others have also elaborated on many
pointed out. whereas a capability-accumulating subsidiary other dimensions of capabilities, such as rarity, causal am-
is putting together new combinations of resources and de- biguity, and tacitness. These characteristics have important
ploying them in creative ways. This is an important depar- implications when it comes to combining a subsidiary's
ture irom normal usage in the decision process and product capabilities with those of other subsidiaries and of protect-
life-cycle traditions, in which resource accumulation and ing capabilities from competitor imitation, but we believe
capability accumulation are not distinguished. they are not central to a discussion oi subsidiary evolution.
782 Academy of Management Review October

The visible manifestation of the subsidiary's internal competition is both for existing charters
role in the MNC is its charter, defined as the (where one subsidiary "steals" a charter from
business^or elements of the business—in another) and for new charters (where two or
which the subsidiary participates and for which more subsidiaries "bid" against one another).
it is recognized to have responsibility within the We find the best evidence for internal charter
MNC (Galunic & Eisenhardt, 1996). The term competition in the recent work of Galunic and
chaiter has implications for the organization's Eisenhardt (1996) and Galunic (1996), who stud-
mission (Thompson, 1967) and for its institu- ied the processes through which divisions of
tional legitimacy (DiMaggio & Powell, 1983; Omni corporation gained and lost charters from
Scott & Meyer, 1994), but our focus here, in keep- one another. Charter competition is also men-
ing with Galunic and Eisenhardt (1996), is to tioned in several studies of Canadian subsidiar-
focus on business activities and the underlying ies (Birkinshaw, 1996; Crookell, 1986).
capabilities through which they are implement- The idea that charters might shift from one
ed.^ Thus, we can define charter in terms ot subsidiary to another appears strange at first,
markets served, products manufactured, tech- given that we have just argued that each sub-
nologies held, functional areas covered, or any sidiary has a unique capability profile. How-
combination thereof. The charter is typically a ever, in many cases subsidiaries will have sim-
shared understanding between the subsidiary ilar, although not identical, capability profiles.
and the headquarters regarding the subsid- Take, for example, the case of a large silicon
iary's scope of responsibilities. chip manufacturer, which will typically have 10
The relationship between the subsidiary's or more fabrication plants in various sites
charter and its underlying capabilities is not a around the world. These plants all have the ba-
simple one. In the case where the subsidiary's sic capability to manufacture chips, but, at the
charter does not change for a long period of same time, they do so with rather different tech-
time, subsidiary managers are likely to steer nologies and different levels of quality control,
resource deployment and capability accumula- cost, process enhancement, and so on. In all of
tion efforts toward the fulfillment of that charter these plants there is an ongoing process of in-
so that, eventually, the subsidiary's capability ternal benchmarking and capability upgrad-
profile is a reflection of its charter. However, if ing,^ because a new investment can potentially
there is a high level of change in the subsid- be made at any one of the existing plants.
iary's resource base (e.g., through merger and Not all charters are "contestable" in this fash-
acquisition), in its charter, or in the markets that ion. Some charters are country specific and so
the charter is directed toward, then at any given are linked inextricably to the local subsidiary
point in time, there are likely to be mismatches operation: others are tied to large, immobile as-
between the subsidiary's capability profile and sets (e.g., an auto plant) so they cannot easily be
its official charter. The point here, which we shifted to another location. Many more, how-
elaborate on further in the next section, is sim- ever, are readily contestable, especially when
ply that the concept of subsidiary evolution must the underlying resources on which they are
take into account both the chaiter ot the subsid- based are mobile. It is, we believe, the latent
iary and its underlying capabilities. It is danger- mobility of charters and the competition be-
ous to assume that the two simply move to- tween subsidiary units for charters that is one of
gether. the fundamental drivers behind the subsidiary
One final line of reasoning regarding subsid- evolution process.
iary charters and capabilities needs to be men- The importance of internal competition for
tioned here—namely, that in most corporations charters can be shown in another way. Porter's
there is internal competition for charters. The (1980, 1990) thinking on competitive advantage
suggests that it is exposure to demanding cus-
^ It should be recognized that an institutional definition of
the subsidiary's charter will not necessarily covary with the ^ An interesting side issue here is why competing manu-
activity/capability-based definition. Thus, an interesting facturing units choose to help one another to improve. The
area for future research would be to examine divergences evidence suggests that they do. implying that managers are
between institutional- and capability-based charter defini- motivated more by their long-term allegiance to the corpo-
tions in subsidiaries. ration than by the short-term gain of a new charter.
1996 Biikinshaw and Hood 783

tomers, leading-edge competitors, and high- developed above. Our objective here is to put
quality suppliers that pressures firms to up- forward five generic processes of subsidiary
grade their capabilities. In the case of the evolution and to use the theoretical insights in-
subsidiary company, we can identify a compet- dicated above (and earlier in the article) to pro-
itive environment with both external and inter- pose a series of causal relationships linking cer-
nal components. The external elements are cus- tain contextual factors to each of the five
tomers, competitors, and suppliers in the local processes.
environment; the internal elements are other In Figure 2 we indicate the possible combina-
corporate units that buy from or sell to the fo- tions oi capability change and charter change in
cal'° subsidiary and sister subsidiaries that are the subsidiary. As we noted earlier, it seems
competing for new and existing charters. Our extremely unlikely that the subsidiary's charter
argument is that internal competitive forces— will mirror exactly the subsidiary's capability
when they are released—are as critical to the profile. Instead, the capability change will ei-
capability enhancement process as external ther lead or lag the charter change.
competitive forces. In some MNCs there is no In situation 1 the charter extension leads, sub-
internal competitive environment, because all sequently, to an enhancement oi the subsid-
sourcing relationships and charter allocations iary's capability profile. Given that charter as-
are centrally planned by head-office managers, signment is the parent company's responsibility
but, increasingly, MNCs are making use of in- and that the capabilities are not already in ex-
ternal market mechanisms to foster the compet- istence, we designate this process parenf-driven
itive dynamics we are describing here (Halal, investment (PDI). Although subsidiary managers
1994). may have some influence over the process (no-
In summary, subsidiary evolution is defined tably, through high performance), they are typi-
in terms of (1) the enhancement/atrophy of cally actively competing for the charter with
capabilities in the subsidiary and (2) the estab- other subsidiaries, so the development of the
lishment/loss of the commensurate charter. commensurate capabilities begins only once the
Subsidiary development consists of capability charter has been assigned.
enhancement and charter establishment; sub- In situation 2 the capability enhancement
sidiary decline consists oi capability atrophy leads, subsequently, to an extension to the sub-
and charter loss. Capability change may lead or
lag the change in the commensurate charter, FIGURE 2
but, for evolution to have occurred, the charter Subsidiary Evolution As a Function of
must eventually reflect the underlying capabil- Capability and Charter Change
ities of the subsidiary. Note that this definition
deliberately excludes cases oi self-serving or Change in charter
empire-building behavior, in which the subsid- Loss No change Grain
iary develops capabilities that are not aligned
with the strategic priorities oi the MNC. Our
argument is that the process oi assigning a
charter to the subsidiary is an explicit acknowl-
edgment by corporate management that the un-
derlying capabilities are valued. If the capabil-
ities are not valued, there is no charter change,
and evolution has not occurred.
CI

Generic Subsidiary Evolution Processes a


o
We now can reconsider the phenomenon of
subsidiary evolution using the theoretical ideas

'°We use local subsidiary to reier to the hypothetical Note: Numbers refer to the live generic processes we dis-
subsidiary at the center of our analysis. cuss in the text.
784 Academy 0/ Managemeni Review October

sidiary's charter. In essence, it represents a stra- of conceptual and operational clarity, we must
tegic move by subsidiary managers, who see the work at the lower level of analysis. Second, we
opportunity to gain a new or enhanced charter if should be clear that we see the five processes as
they can demonstrate that they have the neces- comprehensive and mutually exclusive so that
sary capabilities. However, charter change in every case of subsidiary evolution can be clas-
this case is not guaranteed—for example, if the sified as belonging to one of the five. Whether
capabilities in question are not deemed by cor- this also means that the five generic processes
porate management to be valuable. We desig- constitute a type is more debatable, because the
nate this process subsidiary-driven charter ex- processes lack comparability in certain key di-
tension (SDE). mensions. Moreover, some have argued that the
Situations 4 and 5 are the reverse of situations term typology should be used in a very precise
1 and 2. The former is paren^driven divestment manner to retain its value for theory building
(PDD), where the subsidiary loses its charter for (Doty & Glick, 1994: 232), so our preference here
a certain product, technology, or market and is to avoid claiming that a type exists, even
then, gradually, the commensurate capabilities though in certain respects it could probably be
atrophy. The latter is atrophy through subsidiary labeled as such.
neglect (ASN), where the subsidiary's capabili- Two questions follow from the categorization
ties gradually wither away over time, the sub- indicated in Figure 2. First, what do these five
sidiary's performance (for that charter) suffers, processes look like (in terms of action-outcome
and, eventually, the parent company takes relationships)? Second, what contextual factors
away the charter. are responsible for promoting or suppressing
Finally, situation 3 is subsidiary-driven char- them? In the remainder of the article, we ad-
tei leinfoicement (SDR), which refers to the sit- dress these two questions, using Table 2 as a
uation in which the subsidiary sharpens or framework. We consider each process in tum,
strengthens its existing capabilities and main- with regard to the major actions undertaken by
tains its charter. One could argue that this is not parent management, subsidiary management,
a pure case of subsidiary evolution, but we in- and any other actors involved, and the antici-
clude it to account for the situation in which the pated outcomes. We then look at the contextual
subsidiary opts to deepen its capabilities in one factors listed in Table 2 and consider the impact
specific area (i.e., its current charter), rather that each is predicted to have—if any—on the
than seek out new charters. As part of a long- five generic processes. Note that we identified
term strategy of subsidiary development, char- the contextual factors from the existing litera-
ter reinforcement is probably an important ture or during theoretical development.
phase for the subsidiary to go through, because Parent-driven investment (PDI). This process
it ensures that the subsidiary has leading-edge consists of one clearly defined event—that is,
capabilities vis-d-vis both internal and external the decision to enhance the subsidiary's char-
competitors. Note, however, that in such a case it ter—preceded by a period of negotiation and
is harder (although not impossible) to identify deliberation by the parent and the subsidiary
when evolution has occurred, because the char- and followed by a period of capability enhance-
ter is maintained rather than enhanced. ment by the subsidiary in order to deliver satis-
Two further observations should be made at factorily on the new charter. The action taken by
this stage. First, each process represents a dis- parent management typically is an evaluation
crete phase that, in our experience, may take of the relative merits of various locations for the
anything from a few weeks to a few years to planned investment, followed by the decision to
complete. Over a longer period of time, one make the charter change (or not) in the focal
would expect to see multiple phases of develop- subsidiary. The action taken by subsidiary man-
ment, including positive and negative steps, as agement is typically lobbying parent managers
well as subsidiary- and parent-driven ones. The to persuade them to decide in that subsidiary's
unit of analysis under investigation here, thus, favor. In most cases the process involves the
is the single period of one charter change and a commitment of considerable resources to the
commensurate change in capabilities. Subsid- subsidiary—for example, through the establish-
iary evolution, broadly conceived, also can refer ment of a new factory or through creation of a
to aggregate changes over time, but, for the sake research and development group. However, it is
1998 Bitkinsbaw and Hood 785

TABLE 2
Five Generic Subsidiary Evolution Processes
Contextual Facton Action Outcome
PDI
Parent company factors Parent: Decision to make investment; -* Establishment of new charter in
• Competitive internal evaluation of various locations subsidiary (CC); gradual
resource allocation Subsidiary: Lobbying development of commensurate
• Decentralization ol decision capabilities (CB)
making
• Ethnocentrism ol parent SCE
management Subsidiary: Identification oi new —» Extension of charter in subsidiary
opportunities; building capabilities (CC)
(CB); proposal to parent
Subsidiary factors
Parent: ludgment on subsidiary
• Track record of subsidiary
proposal
• Credibility of subsidiary
management SCR
• Entrepreneurial orientation Subsidiary: Competitiveness-driven -• Reinforcement of existing charter in
of subsidiary employees search; upgrading of existing subsidiary
capabilities (CB)

PDD
flost country factors Parent: Decision to divest; evaluation of —• Loss or diminution of charter (CC) in
• Strategic importance of various locations subsidiary; atrophy cf existing
country Subsidiary: Lobbying capabilities (CD)
• Host government support
• Relative cost of factor inputs ASN _ 1
• Dynamism of local business Subsidiary: Inaction; atrophy of -^ Loss or diminution ot charter in
environment capabilities (CD) subsidiary (CC)
Parent: ludgment on subsidiary's lack of
competitiveness

Key: CC, charter change; CB, capability building; CD, capability depletion.

also possible that the decision will simply be Subsidiary-driven charter extension (SDE).
one of charter change in the subsidiary—for ex- This involves a long and often slow process of
ample, the extension of market responsibility capability building, followed by an extension to
from the United Kingdom to Europe. the subsidiary's charter. The process essentially
The process is driven by the parent company's is one of corporate entrepreneurship (Birkin-
desire to select, according to whatever criteria it shaw, 1997; Burgelman, 1983b) on the part of
deems appropriate, the optimum location for an subsidiary management, in that it represents a
investment. Some MNCs use a formalized re- conscious effort by the subsidiary to seek out
quest-for-proposal procedure in such cases, and develop new business opportunities and
whereby proposed corporate-level investments then put them forward to parent company man-
are opened up to all interested subsidiary oper- agers. On the assumption that parent company
ations and allocated on the basis of the "bids" managers are inherently risk averse in their de-
that are received. In other cases the process is cisions about which subsidiaries should have
less structured and may involve a variety of responsibility for which charters, the logic here
boundediy rational decision-making procedures is that subsidiary management builds the re-
(Cyert & March, 1963; Mintzberg, Raisinghani, & quired capabilities first and seeks the charter
Theoret, 1976), such as localized search or polit- extension only once the subsidiary can demon-
ically motivated decision criteria. In both cases strate those capabilities.
there is at least an implicit competition between The process involves three distinct steps by
locations for the new investment, which typi- subsidiary managers: (1) an initiative-driven
cally leads to active lobbying by various subsid- search for new market opportunities in both the
iaries and host governments. subsidiary's local market and within the corpo-
786 Academy oi Management Review October

rate system (Birkinshaw, 1997; Kirzner, 1973), ized. Such a scenario can be triggered by a need
(2) the pursuit of a specific market opportunity to cut costs or by the desire for greater strategic
and the development oi the appropriate capa- focus on core activities. The fate of the subsid-
bilities to iuliill it, and (3) a proposal to the iary, therefore, may be closure, sale to another
parent company that the subsidiary's charter be company, or spinoff as a separate entity.
enhanced. For the parent company, the only ac- The evaluation process is influenced by a host
tion required is a judgment on whether to grant of factors, including the existing capabilities of
the subsidiary its requested charter enhance- the subsidiary relative to others and the attrac-
ment. In many cases the parent company will be tiveness of the host country market, according to
informed of the subsidiary's initiative through- a number of criteria. Subsidiary managers and
out the process, whereas in other cases the sub- host country governments will sometimes have
sidiary will have deliberately undertaken the the opportunity to lobby against closure, but
process without the parent company's knowl- more often the decision will be presented as a
edge (Birkinshaw & Ridderstrdle, in press). In all fait accompli by parent company management.
situations, however, we see the SDE process as The final decision results in a charter loss for
fairly "political," in that it relies to a great de- the focal subsidiary. This may include the sale
gree on the subsidiary-level champion gaining or closure of all associated activities (e.g., when
support at the head office through his or her a plant is shut down). In such a case the subsid-
personal contacts. Our reasoning here is simply iary's capabilities are immediately lost at the
that parent company managers will naturally same time. Equally likely is the case where a
treat an initiative irom a peripheral part of the charter is lost but the subsidiary as a whole
corporation with suspicion, unless they know continues to exist (Galunic & Eisenhardt, 1996).
the individual promoting it. In this case the capabilities that were associ-
Subsidiary-driven charter reinforcement ated with the old charter will gradually be lost
(SDR). As with the previous process, this one is as employees are reassigned to new roles and
driven entirely by the actions of subsidiary man- develop new skills. However, it is possible that
agers. It is triggered by concerns about the sub- the remaining capabilities are actually rede-
sidiary's competitiveness vis-d-vis both sister ployed toward the development oi a new charter
subsidiaries (Morrison & Crookell, 1990) and ex- (i.e., an SDE process as described above). This
ternal competitors. The competitors provide spe- process has been labeled chartei renewal
cific cues to subsidiary management regarding (Birkinshaw, 1996).
their relative strengths and weaknesses, which Atrophy through subsidiary neglect (ASN), The
leads to attempts to enhance the relevant set of final process is one in which the subsidiary's
capabilities. This process may or may not also capabilities gradually atrophy while the charter
involve external benchmarking and internal is still retained. The argument here reverses
transfers of best practice (Szulanski, 1996). The that suggested in the SDE and SDR processes.
net result, assuming the process has been effec- Essentially, we see subsidiary management's
tive, is lower costs and/or quality and service lack of attention pushing this process along. The
improvements and, thus, a reinforcement oi the subsidiary becomes less and less competitive
subsidiary's existing charter. There may be no over time. This can be simply a case of poor
head-office involvement in this process per se, management, but it is more likely to stem from a
given that no oificial change to the charter is lack oi competition. Ii, for example, the subsid-
being suggested, but the capability reinforce- iary has guaranteed internal contracts for its
ment process will lead to a stronger subsidiary products and the corporation as a whole is mak-
performance and, hence, an enhanced level oi ing money, the pressure to reduce costs or im-
credibility and visibility vis-a-vis head-office prove service is likely to be low.
managers. ASN occurs through two somewhat different
Parent-driven divestment (PDD). This is the processes. In the first, the subsidiary continues
mirror image of PDI. The typical scenario is that to fulfill its charter but on the basis of capabil-
the parent company has made the decision to ities that are not leading edge and that gradu-
rationalize its international operations and/or to ally atrophy over time through lack of attention.
exit certain businesses but that the decision re- Eventually, this situation comes to the attention
garding which ones to divest has not been final- of head-oifice managers, either because it is
1996 Birkinshaw and Hood 787

negatively impacting the competitiveness of the Corporate-level factors. Central to our earlier
entire MNC or because internal performance discussion on capabilities was the notion of in-
measures indicate the sub-par performance of ternal competition for charters among subsid-
the focal subsidiary. Depending on the urgency iary units. Here, we develop the idea of compe(-
of the change that is demanded of head-office itive internal resource allocation, which means
managers, the subsidiary may be given the op- a corporate-wide system that promotes internal
portunity to turn things around itself, or it can competition, either by allowing bids for new in-
lose its charter immediately." The second sce- vestments or by creating a system through
nario, given the discussion about SDR, is one in which existing charters can be "challenged" by
which the subsidiary is doing a satisfactory job other units (Galunic & Eisenhardt, 1996; White &
of maintaining its capabilities, but, when faced Poynter, 1984). A competitive internal resource
with a global rationalization program, it be- allocation system has substantial implications
comes apparent that other subsidiaries have up- for subsidiary evolution, because it legitimizes a
graded their capabilities more effectively. Char- process by which subsidiaries can both gain
ter loss follows simply because the focal and lose charters. It also increases awareness of
subsidiary's capabilities are weaker than those the relative capabilities among subsidiaries
of its sister subsidiaries. Atrophy, in this sense, and provides a motivation for them to continu-
refers to the level of the capabilities relative to ally upgrade their capabilities. In contrast, in
other subsidiaries, rather than in an absolute the absence oi such a competitive system, re-
sense. source allocation decisions are made by head-
office decision makers through a central plan-
ning process, which typically means favoring
Contextual Factors Impacting the Generic investment locations with which the decision
Processes makers are familiar and maintaining charters
over long periods of time. According to this
In the literature review and in the preceding logic, it will be the subsidiary-driven, rather
description, we touched on a large number of than the parent-driven, processes that are fa-
factors at the corporate, subsidiary, and host vored by competitive internal resource alloca-
country level, which, scholars have argued, tion. Therefore, we argue that both PDI and PDD
have an impact on the presence of the five ge- will be negatively impacted, and SDE, SDR, and
neric processes. In this section we take a much ASN will be positively impacted.
more systematic look at these iactors (listed in ASN is a particularly interesting case. The
Table 2) and put forward specific propositions core argument is that the number of cases of
relating the levels of the contextual factors to charters lost to internal competitors is likely to
the extent to which the five processes occur. We increase, because charters are more mobile and
make one point of clarification here—namely, because sister subsidiaries are more proac-
that the factors identified are not a comprehen- tively developing their own capabilities. How-
sive list; they represent the main factors that ever, there is also likely to be a mitigating fac-
previous researchers have identified, and, as tor—namely, that faced with such competitive
such, there may well be other factors that also pressure, the number oi cases of atrophying ca-
impact the occurrence of the five subsidiary evo- pabilities should decrease. ASN, therefore, will
lution processes. We also acknowledge that our occur through relative—not absolute—capabil-
focus on three contexts (corporate, subsidiary, ity depletion. To summarize:
and host country) means that we have set aside
several others, such as the parent company's Proposifion J; A compefifive internal
industry environment or other subsidiaries resource allocation mechanism in the
within the corporation, that could potentially im- MNC will have a positive impact on
pact subsidiary evolution. the likelihood of SDE, SDH, and ASN
and a negative impact on the likeli-
hood of PDI and PDD.

'' Frequently, the charter loss process is rather more grad- A second important corporate-level factor is
ual than this, in that the subsidiary finds itseli with increas- the level of decenfraiizafion of decision making
ingly unimportant charters. (i.e., the autonomy granted to subsidiaries).
788 Academy of Management Beview October

MNC researchers have given a lot of attention to level of ethnocentrism will negatively impact
the issue oi subsidiary autonomy, both as a the likelihood of significant investments being
cause and a consequence of certain behaviors made outside the MNCs home country, thus lim-
and operational characteristics in subsidiaries iting the prospects of subsidiary evolution. This
(e.g.. Gates & Egelhoff, 1986; Prahalad & Doz, we expect to be true not only for SCE but also for
1981). Here, we argue that decentralized deci- PDI, because many such investments can poten-
sion making will provide subsidiary managers tially be made in the home country. SCR, by
with the degrees of freedom necessary to take contrast, is driven purely by the subsidiary and
autonomous action, as well as will empower is therefore unlikely to be impacted one way or
them to take charge of the destiny of their own the other by parent management ethnocentrism.
units, both of which should positively impact the For the divestment cases (ASN and PDD), the
likelihood of the three subsidiary-driven pro- situation is a little more complex. Some of the
cesses—SDE, SDR, and ASN—while having a elements of ethnocentrism (e.g., uncertainty and
corresponding negative impact on the parent- ignorance about a foreign country) are likely to
driven processes—PDI and PDD. be ameliorated once the subsidiary investment
This point is, in some ways, very obvious, but is in place, but an ethnocentric parent company
it is worth further scrutiny. The idea is that for is still likely to be very receptive to signals, even
SDE, and to a lesser degree SDR, subsidiary weak ones, that suggest that the subsidiary re-
managers need a critical amount of autonomy, ally does not have the necessary capabilities to
below which they will be unable to put their fulfill its charter. Thus, ASN and PDD will be
development plans into action. Access to seed positively impacted by the existence of parent
money, for example, is a critical precondition to management ethnocentrism. In summary:
building new capabilities, but it may not be
available in centrally controlled subsidiaries. Proposifion 3; An ethnocentric attitude
ASN is also likely to occur more often when among parent company managers
decision making is decentralized, because the will have a positive impact on the
subsidiary can become isolated relatively eas- likelihood of PDD and ASN, a negative
ily from the rest of the corporation and thus be impact on (he likelihood of PDI and
unaware of its competitive position vis-d-vis SDE, and no impact on SDR.
other subsidiaries. PDI and PDD, however, can Subsidiary-level factors. In terms of the at-
probably be undertaken more effectively when tributes of the subsidiary itself, the most critical
the subsidiary is tightly integrated into the cor- factor affecting subsidiary evolution is its (racic
porate system, because the level of knowledge record—that is, the extent to which it has deliv-
of the subsidiary's capabilities by parent com- ered, over the years, results at or above the
pany managers is much higher. PDI and PDD, expectations of the parent company. The impor-
thus, do not require a significant level of sub- tance of a strong track record is immediately
sidiary autonomy. Therefore, in summary: apparent when one does fieldwork in this area,
and it is consistently mentioned in the literature
Proposition 2: A decenfraJizafion of
as a critical parameter (e.g., Delaney, 1996; Hood
decision making in the MNC will have
et al., 1994; Morrison & Crookell, 1990). The logic,
a positive impact on the likelihood of
from the parent company's perspective, is that
SCE. SCR. and ASN and a negative
any investment decision is uncertain. By decid-
impact on the likelihood of PDI or
ing in favor of a subsidiary that has already
PDD.
been successful in the past, parent management
Finally, as we noted in the literature review, is reducing the extent of that uncertainty,
the attitude of parent company managers to- thereby providing a strong justification for its
ward foreign investment is very important in decision should it prove, in retrospect, to be
subsidiary evolution. Here, we use the well- poor. Both PDI and SCE are therefore likely to be
established concept of parent management eth- positively impacted by a strong track record,
nocentrism (Perlmutter, 1969), which represents whereas PDD and ASN are likely to be nega-
a preoccupation with their own national identity tively impacted. In the case of SCR, the process
and a belief in its superiority over others (Gage is not actively controlled by parent manage-
Canadian Dictionary, 1983). Simply put, a high ment, but one can argue that the development of
1998 Biikinshaw and Hood 789

a track record in the subsidiary is itself part of tween subsidiary management and decision
the charter reinforcement process. The proposi- makers in the parent company become critical.
tion is obvious: If the relationship is good, the subsidiary man-
ager may convince the people at headquarters
Proposition 4: A strong track record that he or she deserves another chance or that
will have a positive impact on the another subsidiary should take the hit. Finally,
likelihood of PDI SCE, and SCR and a SCR will not be impacted because it does not
negative impact on the likelihood ol involve the parent company.
PDD" and ASN,
Proposition 5: A high-quality parent-
Earlier, we also identified the quality of
subsidiary relationship will have a
paxent-subsidiary relationships a s another
positive impact on the hkelihood of
important factor impacting the evolution
PDI and SCE, a negative impact on the
process. This term refers to the informal ties
likelihood of PDD and ASN. and no
between key decision makers in the parent com-
impact on SCR.
pany and senior managers in the subsidiary.
Often, subsidiary managers will be expatriates The enfrepreneuriaJ orientation of subsidiary
or people who have spent a period at the head employees refers to the predisposition of em-
office and will therefore have built up a strong ployees throughout the subsidiary to be alert
network of relationships at a personal level with and responsive to new opportunities (Kirzner,
parent company managers. Such networks rep- 1973). Here, we argue that entrepreneurial sub-
resent a social control system that can be an sidiary employees are on a constant lookout for
effective means of holding the MNC together new ways to add value and that their ideas will
{Bartlett & Ghoshal, 1989; Ouchi, 1980). be brought forward, first to subsidiary manage-
The quality of parent-subsidiary relationships ment and then to corporate management, for
will have a very strong impact on SCE, because active consideration (Birkinshaw, 1997). Entre-
it is entrepreneurial in nature. As researchers preneurial orientation, thus, becomes a neces-
consistently have shown, initiatives are evalu- sary, although not sufficient, condition for the
ated more on the qualities of the individual put- SCE and SCR processes, in that they cannot
transpire unless the new ways of adding value
ting them forward than on their technical merits
are put forward. Using the reverse logic, we pre-
(Bower, 1970; Day, 1994). Thus, where the individ-
dict that the absence of an entrepreneurial ori-
ual is well known to parent company decision entation in subsidiary employees will breed an
makers, it follows that the initiative he or she is environment in which capabilities atrophy and,
championing will be far better received than therefore, that an entrepreneurial orientation
one put forward by a relatively unknown man- will have a negative impact on ASN. PDI and
ager. By the same logic, the quality of the PDD, in contrast, we predict to be relatively un-
parent-subsidiary relationship will also have a affected by the entrepreneurial orientation of
positive impact on PDI, although we should note subsidiary employees, because they are initi-
that the magnitude of this effect is likely to be ated by the parent company. ^^
rather less than the impact of the subsidiary's
track record on SCE. Proposition 6: The entrepreneurial ori-
The quality of parent-subsidiary relationships entation of subsidiary employees will
is likely to have a correspondingly strong neg- have a positive impact on the likeli-
ative impact on the two processes of subsidiary hood of SCE and SCR, a negative im-
decline (PDD and ASN). Our reasoning here is pact on the likelihood of ASN, and no
that decisions to close or divest operations inev- impact on PDl and PDD.
itably become politically charged, and during
such periods the personal relationships be- Host-country-level factors. Propositions 7
through 10 involve the various characteristics of
'^ There is one mitigating factor here—namely, that a very
poorly performing subsidiary cannot easily be sold, whereas '^ Again, though, it is possible to suggest counterex-
a strong performer will fetch a high price. Thus, a very weak amples, such as a parent company that invests in a subsid-
pertormer may actually be fixed rather than sold, depending iary because it thinks subsidiary management will run
on a host of other factors. a high-risk/high-reward venture.
790 Academy of Management Review October

the host country market. The dynamism of the We argue that host government support is
local business environment refers to the extent likely to have a very strong impact in the case of
and quality of the interaction between compet- PDI, primarily because most large, job-creating
ing and complementary firms in that environ- investments are of this type, and it is them that
ment. Using Porter's (1990) diamond framework, local politicians care most about. It will have an
we define the dynamism of the local business equally strong but negative impact in cases of
environment in terms of demand conditions, the subsidiary decline (PDD and ASN), in that gov-
existence of related and supporting industries, ernment representatives will lobby hard with
strong factor endowments, and competition.^^ the MNC to reverse or ameliorate the decision to
Our argument is that a dynamic local business divest a subsidiary (even though, in our experi-
environment provides the stimuli for upgrading ence, such efforts rarely do more than delay the
the subsidiary's capabilities in much the same inevitable).
way that internal competition does, for the sub- In the cases of SCE and SCR, we see host
sidiary reacts to competitive moves by other governments having a lesser, but not trivial,
companies and sharpens its capabilities in line role. These processes are not contestable to the
with the expectations of local customers and same extent that new investments are, but the
suppliers. increasing effort that many investment agencies
As a result, we see SCE and SCR positively are putting into after-care programs is evidence
impacted by local dynamism, whereas ASN is that many host governments believe they can
likely to occur through a lack of local dynamism. influence SCE and SCR. Thus, we predict a
The parent-driven processes—PDI and PDD— small positive impact for SCE and SCR.
are likely to be impacted rather less directly by
the dynamism of the local business environment Proposition 8; The support of the host
because such stimuli are, by their nature, local government will have a positive im-
(Solvell & Zander, 1998). However, it seems likely pact on the likelihood of PDI, SCE, and
that there will be a small effect on the parent SCR and a negative impact on the
company that is transmitted through the subsid- likelihood of PDD and ASN.
iary so that PDI will be positively impacted by Finally, we consider together two further as-
the dynamism of the local business environment pects of the host country: the strategic impor-
and PDD will be negatively impacted. tance of (he country to the MNC and the relative
cost of factor inputs. In a global business envi-
Proposition 7: The dynamism of the la- ronment MNCs weigh—at least implicitly—the
cal business environment will have a relative pros and cons of a large number of
positive impact on the likelihood of possible locations for major investments and di-
PDI, SCE, and SCH and a negative im- vestments. The above are two of the critical fac-
pact on the likelihood of PDD and tors in any such decision. Strategic importance
ASN, refers to the extent to which a competitive posi-
The extent of host government support has a tion in that country affects the MNC's worldwide
substantial impact on subsidiary evolution, as competitive position. Relative cost of factor in-
the literature review indicated. Even in today's puts is simply an assessment of all the major
almost free-trade world, host governments are cost elements of the investment that are locally
still able to offer direct financial incentives for sourced.
foreign investment, as well as a host of indirect In the case of PDI, then, strategic importance
incentives, such as soft loans, personnel train- and relative cost of factor inputs are critical
ing, and infrastructural support. In addition, factors so that a new investment will tend to
host government agencies can help MNCs to gravitate, ceteris paribus, toward the more stra-
identify and evaluate potential sites and intro- tegically important country and the country with
duce prospective partners. lower factor input costs. Equally, the case of
PDD will likely include a consideration of the
same set of factors. For SCE and ASN, however,
'^Porter (1990) was concerned primarily with leading- the situation is more equivocal. One could argue
edge industry clusters, but we note that these four sets oJ
factors can be used to assess the dynamism of any business that SCE and ASN will nof be impacted substan-
environment. tially by these two sets of factors, in that they
1998 Birkinshaw and Hood 791

represent judgments on the subsidiary's man- based view of the firm—namely, its lack of con-
agement and their existing capabilities and not sideration of the internal workings of the large
on the country per se, but, at the same time, it firm. We are not suggesting that the resource-
seems likely that such factors will inevitably based view needs to be modified as such, be-
find their way into the parent company manag- cause the subsidiary unit can be modeled
ers' assessments and, hence, their decisions on readily in the same way that the firm is, but it
whether to extend or reduce the subsidiary's seems clear that much more attention needs to
charter. be paid in future to the ways that capabilities
Thus, we predict a positive impact for both on are developed at a subfirm level and then dis-
SCE and negative impact for both on ASN. SCR, seminated or transferred within the firm, rather
however, because it does not involve parent than just focusing on firm-level capabilities.
company management in any significant way, Some researchers have already begun to ad-
is unlikely to be impacted one way or the other dress these issues (e.g., Kogut & Zander, 1992;
by the strategic importance of the country or the Szulanski, 1996).
relative cost of factor inputs. To summarize: We see two principal limitations to our theo-
retical development. First, the model does not
Proposition 9: The strategic impor- deal explicitly with merger and acquisition. If
tance of the host country will have a we take a case such as the Asea-Brown Boveri
positive impact on the likelihood at merger, it is clear that the assignment of char-
PDI and SCE, a negative impact on the ters within the merged company was a one-time,
likelihood of PDD and ASN, and no top-down process that was undertaken with re-
impact on SCR. gard to a host of strategic and political factors,
Proposition 10: The relative cost of fac- as well as a consideration of where the appro-
tor inputs in the host country will have priate capabilities were. This fits broadly within
a positive impact on the likelihood of the head-office-driven investment process, but it
PDD and SCE, a negative impact on represents an unusual case, because new capa-
the likelihood of PDI and ASN, and no bilities are "appended" to the subsidiary rather
impact on SCR. than grown incrementally along an existing tra-
jectory. Second, we have focused on wholly
owned subsidiaries, rather than hybrid cases,
CONCLUDING COMMENTS such as joint ventures. The critical difference
In this article we had three broad objectives. between the two cases, obviously, is that a joint
The first was simply to document and organize venture has two parents, so it would be poten-
the rather fragmented body of literature on sub- tially quite easy to apply the same principles of
sidiary evolution, the second to examine the capability development and charter change to
phenomenon of subsidiary evolution using a dy- joint venture companies. Indeed, from our read-
namic capabilities perspective, and the third to ing of the literature, it is apparent that joint
put forward five generic processes of subsidiary ventures go through parent-driven and subsid-
evolution and identify those contextual factors iary-driven phases of development that are typ-
expected to impact each one. ically part of an overall process of evolution
The dynamic capabilities perspective on sub- toward higher-value-added activities (Doz, 1996;
sidiary evolution raises two important theoreti- Ring & Van de Ven, 1994). It is also likely that the
cal issues that should be briefly addressed. analytical approach adopted here could be ap-
First, it implies a much more fluid system than plied to specific units or divisions within the
that suggested by traditional models of the firm, rather than thinking in terms of foreign
MNC, in that charters are mobile and subsidiary subsidiaries as a special case.
companies are competing for them in an inter- What are the managerial implications of this
nal market system. This approach is consistent study? At this stage of theory development, it is
with the network perspective of Ghoshal and inappropriate to be too specific about the man-
Bartlett (1991) and Hedlund (1986), but it also agerial consequences of our thinking, but a few
takes things further by specifying the processes issues can be highlighted nonetheless. For sub-
through which charter changes occur. Second, it sidiary managers, the primary message is that
hints at one of the weaknesses of the resource- attention should be paid to the capabilities of
792 Academy of Management Heview October

the subsidiary. Capabilities need to be sharp- Aharoni, Y. 1966. The /oreign investment decision process.
ened and upgraded in the face of competition Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
from other subsidiaries as well as external Almor, T., & Hirsch, S. 1995. Outsiders' response to Europe
firms, and new opportunities need to be proac- 1992: Theoretical considerations and empirical evi-
dence, /oumai oi International Business Studies, 26: 223-
tively sought out in areas that are close to the
239.
existing strengths of the subsidiary and that are
Amit, R., & Schoemaker, P. 1993. Strategic assets and organ-
aligned with the priorities of the MNC as a
izational rent. Strategic Management/oumai, 14: 33-46.
whole. A second message is that the subsidiary
Andersson, U., 8E Johanson, J. 1996. Subsidiary embedded-
appears to need a certain level of decision-
ness and its implications for integration in the MNC.
making autonomy to be able to pursue charter- Proceedings ol the European International Business As-
enhancing and -reinforcement initiatives. This sociation: 235-256.
autonomy has to be earned through a strong
Barney. 1. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive
track record and relationships with parent com- advantage./oumai of Management. 17: 99-120.
pany managers—not taken unilaterally. For
Bartlett, C. A., & Ghoshal, S. 1986, Tap your subsidiaries for
head-office managers, the message is that com- global reach. Harvard Business Beview, 64(6): 87-94.
petitive resource allocation procedures and the
Bartlett, C. A., & Ghoshal, S. 1989. Managing across borders:
locus of decision making should be considered
The transnational solution. Boston: Harvard Business
carefully as mechanisms for improving the School Press.
MNC's ability to allocate charters to the appro-
Behrman, J. N., & Fisher, W, A. 1980. Overseas B&D activities
priate subsidiaries. There are also interesting ol transnational companies. Cambridge, MA: Oelge-
implications in terms of the mix of subsidiary schlager, Gunn and Hain.
managers (e.g., entrepreneurs versus risk- Birkinshaw, J. M. 1995. Entrepreneurship in mu/tinafional
averse managers) that the parent company corporations: The initiative process in Canadian subsid-
should select to keep the subsidiary's options iaries. Unpublished doctoral dissertation. Western Busi-
open in the future. We are a long way from ness School, University ol Western Ontario, London, On-
prescribing any particular courses of action, but tario.
this article highlights the questions that need to Biikinshaw, J. M, 1996. How subsidiary mandates are gained
be asked. and lost. Journal of International Business Studies. 27:
467-496.
In conclusion, we believe that the phenom-
Birkinshaw, J. M. 1997. Entrepreneurship in multinational
enon of subsidiary evolution has considerable
corporations: The characteristics of subsidiary initia-
potential as an area for future research. There tives. Strategic Management Journal, 18: 207-229.
is a need for clinical studies of subsidiary
Birkinshaw, ]. M., & Morrison, A. 1995. Configurations of
evolution and more detailed examination of strategy and structure in subsidiaries of multinational
various aspects of the phenomenon, such as corporations. Journal oi International Business Studies,
the interplay between parent and subsidiary 26: 729-754.
management and the impact of host country Birkinshaw, J. M., & Ridderstrdle, J. In press. Fighting the
policies on subsidiary evolution. Finally, there corporate immune system: Peripheral initiatives in
may also be important theoretical implica- large and complex organizations, /ntemotionai Business
tions for the concepts developed here, both in Review.
terms of the role of the subsidiary in the MNC Bishop, P., & Crookell, H. H. 1986. Specialization in Canadian
and for the theory of the MNC itself. Although subsidiaries. In D. G. McFetridge (Ed.), Canadian indus-
try in transition: 305-385. Toronto: University of Toronto
it is too soon to predict how such extensions
Press.
will transpire, our hope is that this article pro-
vides a grounding of theoretical perspectives , J. 1979. Foreign divestment: Magnitude and fac-
and a framework of ideas around which sub- tors. Journal of International Business Studies, 10(3): 21-
28.
sequent studies can be built.
Boddewyn, J. 1983. Foreign and domestic divestment and
investment decisions: Like or unlike? /oumai of Interna-
tional Business Studies, 14(3): 23-35.
REFERENCES Bower, J. L. 1970. Managing tiie resource aiiocation process.
Homewood, ILi Irwin,
Agarwal, S., & Ramaswami, S. 1992. Choice oi foreign market
entry mode: Impact of ownership, location and internal- Burgelman, R. A. 1983a. A process model of internal corpo-
ization factors./oumai of/ntemationai Business Studies, rate venturing in the diversified major firm. Administra-
23: 1-28. tive Science Quarterly, 28: 223-244.
1998 Birkinshaw and Hood 793

Burgelman, R. A. 1983b. A model of the interaction oi strate- Dunning. J. H. 1993. i^fuitinafionai enterprises and the global
gic behavior, corporate context and the concept ai strat- economy. Wokingham, England: Addison-Wesley.
egy. Academy of Management Review, 8: 61-70. Emerson, R. M. 1962, Power-dependence relations. American
Burgelman, R. A. 1991. Intraorganizational ecology oi strat- Sociological Review, 27: 31-41.
egy making and organizational adaptation: Theory and Forsgren, M., Holm, U., & Johanson. J. 1992. Internationaliza-
ileld research. Organization Science, 2: 239-262. tion of the second degree: The emergence oi European-
Burgelman. R. A, 1996. A process model of strategic business based centres in Swedish firms. In S. Young & J. Hamill
exit: Implications for an evolutionary perspective on (Eds.j, Europe and tiie muitinationais: 235-253. London:
strategy. Strategic Management Journal. 17: 193-214. Edward Elgar,
Cavusgil, S. T, 1980, On the internationalization process oi Forsgren, M., Holm, U., & Johanson. J. 1995. Division head-
the firm. European i?esean:h, 8: 273-281. quarters go abroad—A step in the internationalization
Chang, S.-J. 1995, International expansion strategy of Japa- of the multinational corporation. Journal of Management
nese firms: Capability building through sequential en- Studies, 32:475-491.
try. Academy of Management Journal. 38: 383-407. Forsgren, M., & Pahlberg, C. 1992. Subsidiary influence and
Chang, S.-J. 1996. An evolutionary perspective on diversifi- autonomy in international firms, internationai Business
Review. 1(3): 41-51.
cation and corporate restructuring: Entry, exit and eco-
nomic performance during 1981-1989. Strategic Manage- Gage Canadian Dictionary. 1983. Toronto: Gage Educational
ment/ournai, 17:587-612, Publishing Company.
Child, J, 1972. Organization structure, environment and per- Gralunic. D. C. 1996. Recreating divisional domains: Intracor-
formance: The role oi strategic choice. Socioiogy, 6: 1-22. porate evolution and the muUibusiness firm, In B. Keys
Clarke, I. 1985. Tiie spatial organization of multinationai & L, N, Dosier (Eds.). Proceedings of the Academy of
corporations. London: Croom Helm. Management: 219-224.

Crookell, H. H. 1986. Specialization and international com- Galunic. D, C, & Eisenhardt, K. M. 1996. The evolution of
petitiveness. In H. Etemad & L. S. Dulude (Eds.), Manag- intracorporate domains: Divisional charter losses in
ing the multinational subsidiary: 102-111. London: high-technology, multidivisional corporations. Organi-
Croom Helm. zation Science, 7: 255-282.

Cyert, R., & March, J. G. 1963. A beiiaviorai tiieoiy of the firm. Gates, S. R., & Egelhoff, W. G. 1986, Centralization in head-
Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, quarters-subsidiary relationships. Journal of Interna-
tional Business Studies, 17: 71-92.
Day, D. 1994. Raising radicals: Different processes for cham-
pioning innovative corporate ventures. Organization Ghauri. P. 1992. New structures in MNCs based in small
Science, 5: 148-172. countries: A network approach, European Management
Journal 10: 357-364.
Delaney, E. 1996. Strategic development of multinational
subsidiaries in Ireland. In J. Birkinshaw 8i: N. Hood (Eds.), Ghoshal, S., & Bartlett. C. A. 1991. The multinational corpo-
iVfuitinationai corporate evoiution and subsidiary devei- ration as an interorganizational network. Academy o/
opment: 239-267, London: Macmillan. Management Review, 15: 603-625.

Dicken, P. 1976. Geographical perspectives on United States Ghoshal. S., & Nohria, N. 1989. Internal differentiation within
investment in the United Kingdom. Environment and multinational corporations. Strategic Management Jour-
Planning, 8: 685-705. nal 10: 323-337.

Dierickx, I., & Cool, K. 1989. Asset stock accumulation and Gupta, A. K., & Govindarajan, V, 1991. Knowledge ilows and
sustainability oi competitive advantage, iWanagemenf the structure of control within multinational corpora-
Science, 35: 1504-1S13, tions. Academy of Management Review. 16: 768-792.

DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron cage revisited: Gupta, A. K., & Govindarajan. V. 1994, Organizing for knowl-
Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in edge within MNCs. internationai Business Review, 3:
organizational fields. American Socioiogicai iTeview, 48: 443-457.
147-160. Hagstrcim, P. 1994, Tiie 'wired' MNC. Stockholm: Institute of
Doty, D, H., & Glick, W. H. 1994. Typologies as a unique form International Business.
of theory building: Toward improved understanding and Hdkanson, L., & Zander, U. 1986, iWanaging intemationai
modeling. Acodemy of Management Review, 19: 230- researcii and deveiopment. Stockholm: Sveriges Mekan-
251. forbund.
Doz, Y. L. 1996. The evolution of cooperation in strategic Halal, W. 1994. From hierarchy to enterprise: Internal mar-
alliances: Initial conditions or learning processes? Stra- kets are the new foundation oi management. Academy
tegic Management Journal, 17: S&-83. of Management Executive. 8(4): 69-83.
Dunning, J, H. 1981. internationai production and the muiti- Hamel, G.. & Prahalad, C, K. 1985, Do you really have a
nationai enterprise. London: Allen & Unwin. global strategy? Harvard Business Aeview, 63(4); 139-
Dunning, J. H. 1986. The investment cycle revisited. 145.
Weitwirtscha/tiiches Archiv, 122: 667-677. Hannan, M., & Freeman, J. 1977. The population ecology of
794 Academy of Management Review October

organizations. American /oumai of Socioiogy, 82: 929- Malnight, T. 1996. The transition from decentralized to net-
964, work-based MNC structures: An evolutionary perspec-
Harrigan, K. R. 1984, Innovation within overseas subsidiar- tive./oumai o/intemationai iSusiness Studies, 27: 43-66.
ies. Journal of Business Strategy, 5: 47-53. McNee. R. B. 1958. Functional geography of the firm with an
Haspeslagh, P, C, & Jemison, D, B. 1991. Managing acquisi- illustrative case study from the petroleum industry. Eco-
tions: Creating value through corporate renewal. New nomic Geograpiiy, 34: 321-337.
York: Free Press. Meyer, J, W., & Rowan, B. 1997, Institutionalized organiza-
Hatch Report. 1979. Strengthening Canada abroad. Industry, tions: Formal structure as myth and ceremony. Ameri-
trade and commerce. Ottawa, Ontario: Export Promotion can Journal of Sociology. 83: 340-363.
Review Committee. Mintzberg, H., Raisinghani. D., & Theoret, A, 1976, The struc-
Hedlund, G. 1986, The hypermodern MNC: A heterarchy? ture of unstructured decision processes. Administrative
Human Resource Management. 25: 9-36. Science Quarterly, 21: 246-274.
Holm, U., Johanson, J., & Thilenius, P. 1995. Headquarters' Morrison, A., & Crookell, H. 1990. Subsidiary strategy in a
knowledge of subsidiary network contexts in the multi- free-trade environment. Business Quarterly. 55(2): 33-39.
national corporation, internationai Studies ol iWanage- MuUor-Sebastian, A. 1983. The product life cycle theory: Em-
ment and Organization. 25(1-2): 97-120. pirical evidence. Journal of International Business Stud-
Hood, N., & Young, S. 1983. i^fuitinationai investment strate- ies. 14(Winter): 95-105.
gies in tiie British Isles. London: Her Majesty's Stationery Nelson, R., & Winter. S. 1982. An evolutionary theory of eco-
Office (HMSO). nomic change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Hood, N.. Young, S., & Lai, D. 1994, Strategic evolution within Press.
Japanese manufacturing plants in Europe. UK evidence.
Noda, T., & Bower, J. L. 1996. Strategy making as iterated
infernationai Business Review, 3(2): 97-122.
processes of resource allocation. Strategic Management
Huber, G. 1991. Organizational learning: The contributing Journal 17: 159-192.
processes and the literatures. Organization Science, 2:
Norton, R. D., & Rees, J. 1979. The product cycle and the
88-115.
spatial decentralization oi American manufacturing.
larillo, J.-C, & Martinez, J. 1. 1990. Different roles for subsid- i?egionai Studies, !3: 141-151.
iaries: The case ol multinational corporalions. Strategic
Management Journal. 11: 501-512. Ouchi, W. G. 1980. Market, bureaucracies and clans. Admin-
istrative Science Quarterly, 25: 124-141,
Johanson, J., & Mattson, L. G. 1988. Internationalisation in
industrial systems—A network approach. In N. Hood & Ozawa, T. 1992, Foreign direct investment and economic
I. E. Vahlne (Eds.), Strategies in global competition: 287- development. Tran sncrfi on ai Corporations. 1: 27-54.
314. London: Croom Helm, Papanasstasiou, M., & Pearce, R. 1994. Determinants of the
Johanson, J., & Vahlne, J.-E. 1977. The internationalization market strategies of US companies. Journal oi the Eco-
process of the firm—A model oi knowledge development nomics of Business. 2: 199-217.
and increasing foreign market commitments. Journal oi Pearce. R, D. 1989, The internationalization of research and
International Business Studies, 8: 23-32. development by multinational enterprises. New York: St
Kirzner, I. 1973, Compefition and entrepreneurship. Chicago: Martin's Press.
University of Chicago Press. Perlmutter, H. 1969. The tortuous evolution of the multina-
Kogut. B., & Zander. U. 1992. Knowledge of the firm, combi- tional corporation, Coiumbia /oumai of World Business,
native capabilities and the replication oi technology. 4: 9-18.
Organization Science, 3: 383-397. Penrose, E. T. 1959. Tiie theory of the growth of the firm.
Krugman, P. 1991. Gfeograpiiy and trade. Cambridge, MA: Oxiard, England: Basil Blackwell.
MIT Press. Pieffer, J, R,, & Salancik, G, R, 1978, The external control of
Li, J. T. 1995, Foreign entry and survival: Eifects oi strategic organizations. New York: Harper & Row.
choices on performance in international markets. Stra- Porter, M. E. 1980. Competitive strategy. New York: Free
tegic Management Journal. 16: 637-655. Press,
Lincoln, J. R., Olson, J., & Hanada, M. 1978. Cultural effects on Porter, M, E. 1990. The competitive advantage of nations. New
organizational structure: The case oi Japanese firms in York: Free Press.
the United States. American Socioiogicai Review, 43:
829-847. Prahalad, C. K, 1976. Tiie strategic process in a muitinationai
corporation. Unpublished doctoral dissertation. Harvard
Madhok, A, 1997, Cost, value and ioreign market entry mode:
University, Boston.
The transaction and the firm. Strategic Management
Journal 18: 39-61. Prahatad, C. K.. & Doz, Y. L, 1981. An approach to strategic
control in MNCs. Sioan Management Review. 22(Sum-
Malnight. T, 1995, Globalization of an ethnocentric firm: An
evolutionary perspective. Strategic Management Jour- mer): 5-13.
nal 16: 119-141. Ring, P. S., 8c Van de Ven, A. 1994, Development processes of
1998 Biikinshaw and Hood 795

cooperative interorganizational relationships. Academy The dynamic firm: The role of technology, strategy, or-
oi Management Review, 19: 90-118. ganization and regions: 402-416. Oxford, England: Ox-
Ronstadt, R. C. 1977. Research and deveJopment abroad by ford University Press.
U.S. multinationals. New York: Praeger. Sugiura, H. 1990. How Honda localizes its global strategy.
Rosenzweig, P., & Chang. S.-I. 1995a. An evo/u(ionary model Sloan Management Review. 3UFall): 77-82.
ol the multinational corporafion. Paper presented at the Szulanski, G. 1996. Exploring internal stickiness: Impedi-
annual meeting oi the Academy oi International Busi- ments to the transfer oi best practices within the firm.
ness, Seoul. Korea. Strategic Management Journal. 17(Special Issue): 27-44.
Rosenzweig, P., 8E Chang, S.-J. 1995b. Sequential direct in- Teece, D. J., Pisano, G., & Shuen. A. 1997. Dynamic capabili-
vestment of European and Japanese firms in the U.S. ties and strategic management. Strategic Management
Paper presented at the annual meeting oi the Academy Journal, 18: 509-534.
oi International Business, Seoul, Korea.
Thompson, J. D. 1967. Organizations in action. New York:
Rosenzweig. P.. & Nohria. N. 1995. Ioiluences on human re- McGraw-Hill.
source management practices in multinational corpora-
tions. Journal of International Business Studies, 25: 229- Vemon, R. 1966, International investments and international
252. trade in the product cycle. Quarterly Journal of Econom-
ics, 80: 190-207.
Rosenzweig, P., & Singh, J. 1991. Organizational environ-
ments and the multinational enterprise. Academy of Vernon, R. 1979. The product cycle in the new international
Management Review. 16: 340-361. environment. The Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Sta-
tistics, 41: 255-267.
Roth. K.. 8f Morrison, A. 1992. Implementing global strategy:
Characteristics of global subsidiary mandates. Journal Wernerielt, B. 1984. A resource based view oi the firm. Stra-
ol International Business Studies, 23: 715-736. tegic Management Journal, 5: 171-180.
Rugman, A., & Verbeke. A. 1992. A note on the transnational Westney, D. E. 1994. Inatitutionalization theory and the mul-
solution and the transaction cost theory oi multinational tinational corporation. In S. Ghoshal 8r D. E. Westney
strategic management. Journal of International Business (Eds.), Organization theory and ihe multinational corpo-
Studies. 23; 761-772. ration: 53-76. New York: St Martin's Press,
Sachdev. J. C. 1976. A framework for (he planning of divest- White. R. E., & Poynter. T. A, 1984. Strategies for ioreign-
ment policies tor multinational companies. Unpublished owned subsidiaries in Canada. Business Quarterly,
doctoral dissertation. University of Manchester, 49(Summer}: 59-69.
England. Young, S., Hood, N., & Hamill, J. 1988, Foreign mu/tinationals
Safarian, E. 1966. Foreign ownership of Canadian industry. and the British economy. London: Routledge.
Toronto: McGraw-Hill. Young, S., Hood, N., & Peters, E. 1994. Multinational enter-
Science Council of Canada. 1980. Multinationals and indus- prises and regional economic development, Regionai
(riai strategy. The role of world product mandates. Studies. 28: 657-677.
Ottawa, Ontario: Science Council oi Canada, Young, S., McDermott, M,, & Dunlop, S. 1991, The challenge of
Scott. R.. & Meyer. ]. 1994. Institutional environments and the single market. In B. Burgenmeir & I. L, Mucchelli
organizations: Structural complexity and individualism. (Eds.), MuJtinationals and Europe: 121-143. London:
Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. Routledge.
Solvell, 0., & Zander, I. 1998. International diffusion of Zander, I. 1994. The tortoise evoiufion of the muJtinationai
knowledge: Isolating mechanisms and the role of the corporation. Doctoral dissertation. Institute oi Interna-
MNE, In A. D. Chandler, P. Hagstrom, & O. Sdlvell {Eds.), tional Business, Stockholm School oi Economics.

Julian Birkinshaw is an assistant professor at the Institute of International Business,


Stockholm School oi Economics. He received his Ph.D. from the Richard Ivey School oi
Business, University of Western Ontario. His current research is concemed with the
strategy and internal organization oi large multinational firms.
Neil Hood is Professor oi Business Policy and Director of the Strathclyde International
Business Unit at the University of Strathclyde in Glasgow. His research concerns the
strategy of multinational enterprises, globalization, and public policy issues sur-
rounding inward investment.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi