Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 36

“Marketing Strategy Meets Wall Street”:

A Research Proposal for MSI-EmoryBI

“The Effect of Brand Acquisition and Disposal on Stock Returns”

Michael Wiles*
Indiana University

Neil A. Morgan
Indiana University

Lopo L. Rego
University of Iowa

*Please address all correspondence concerning this project to:


Michael Wiles
Kelley School of Business
Indiana University
1309 East Tenth Street
Bloomington, IN 47405-1701

Phone: (812) 855-5530


Fax: (812) 855-6440
E-mail: mwiles@indiana.edu
“The Effect of Brand Acquisition and Disposal on Stock Returns”

Abstract
Firms operating in consumer markets generally manage portfolios of brands and make
corporate-level investment decisions regarding additions to and subtractions from their portfolio
through brand acquisition and disposal. While a commonly observed phenomenon, we know
little about the performance effects of firm decisions to acquire or dispose of brands. Here, using
the resource-based view as a theoretical lens and an event study methodology, we examine stock
market reactions to firms’ brand acquisition and disposal announcements in the consumer
packaged goods industry. Initial findings on a sample of 188 brand acquisitions and 128 brand
disposals over the period 1994 through 2006 suggest that firms disposing of brand assets enjoy
abnormal stock returns while firms acquiring brands do not. Drawing on strategic factor market
theory and the diversification literature in strategic management, we identify a number of
boundary conditions under which firms may benefit from acquiring brands and benefit more or
less from disposing of brands.

Introduction

In seeking to better understand the relationship between marketing and firm performance,

a fundamental question is the effect that strategic marketing investments have on shareholder

wealth (Day and Fahey 1988 Rust et al. 2004). A firm’s market value reflects the discounted

value of the firm’s expected future cash flows (e.g., Rappaport 1997). Marketing activities which

affect channels of distribution and consumers in ways which impact the firm’s cash flows

therefore affect shareholder value (e.g., Gruca and Rego 2005). The marketing-finance literature

provides a well-developed theoretical rationale detailing how market-based assets such as brands

can impact firms’ market value by (1) increasing cash flow levels, (2) accelerating cash flows,

(3) decreasing cash flow vulnerability, and (4) increasing the firm’s residual value (Srivastava,

Shervani, and Fahey 1998). These conjectures are supported by a growing body of empirical

evidence (e.g., Barth et al. 1998; Kerin and Sethuraman 1998; Madden, Fehle, and Fournier

2006; Rao, Agarwal, and Dahlhoff 2004) linking brands with competitive advantage for the

firms that own them. As a result, it is increasingly widely accepted that brands are important

1
intangible assets that can significantly contribute to firm performance (e.g., Ailawadi, Lehman,

and Neslin 2001; Keller and Lehman 2006; Sullivan 1998).

Most firms operating in consumer markets have a portfolio comprising multiple brands

(e.g., Aaker 2004; Hill, Ettenson, and Tyson 2005). In managing these portfolios firms often buy

or sell brands (e.g., Capron and Hulland 1999; Laforet and Saunders 2005). For example, in 2000

Unilever embarked on a brand portfolio trimming strategy, and by 2003 had sold off several

hundred brands — including well-known brands such as Elizabeth Arden perfumes and Golden

Griddle syrup. Similarly, over the past eight years, Procter & Gamble has disposed of over 1,000

brands. At the same time, other firms have aggressively grown their brand portfolios through

brand acquisitions. For example, following a corporate strategy shift in 2000 ConAgra has built a

portfolio of 48 major brands, only 3 of which were developed in-house. Similarly, Nestle has

purchased a large number of brand assets over the past decade. However, in spite of the active

market in both the acquisition and disposal of brand assets, we have little understanding of this

important phenomenon (Bahadir, Bharadwaj, and Srivastava 2006). In particular, little is known

about whether and how firms benefit from buying and/or selling their brand assets (e.g.,

Varadarajan, DeFanti, and Busch 2006).

We address this significant knowledge gap in this research proposal and provide some

initial empirical insights using a preliminary data set that we have already assembled. More

specifically, we seek to address three questions that are of particular theoretical importance and

managerial interest: (1) do firms enhance their performance by purchasing brands from others?;

(2) if brands are valuable market-based assets, will investors reward or punish firms that dispose

of brand assets?; and (3) can we identify brand, firm, transaction, and strategic factors which

2
significantly affect the returns to buying and selling brands? Figure 1 outlines the broad research

framework we adopt in our initial empirical work addressing these questions.

This research proposal addresses provides new insights in each of the four priority areas

laid out in the MSI-EmoryBI “Marketing Strategy Meets Wall Street” call for proposals. For

example, in terms of priorities #1 and #4 we provide preliminary evidence that investors react to

the disposal of brands and show that stock prices are informed with regard to the acquisition and

disposal of brand assets. We also uncover an interesting asymmetry in how investors appear to

value complementary marketing resources (brands and channel relationships) that requires

further investigation. Relevant to priority #2, we show that the buy-side strategic factor market

for brands is relatively efficient, which provides an important source of information (and initial

support) for brand valuation approaches that projecting cash flows attributable to brands

forwards and discounting them using “multiples” (e.g., Interbrand). In terms of priority #3, we

provide evidence that some of the biggest single marketing investments firms ever make – the

purchase of an existing brand – generally do not produce abnormal stock returns but we also

identify some conditions in which it can.

Theory Framework

The marketing strategy literature linking brand assets with firm performance draws on the

resource based view of the firm (RBV) as its primary theory lens. From this perspective, strong

brands are rare and non-substitutable assets that allow firms to conceive of and execute

inimitable value-creating strategies (e.g., Barney 1991). An important, but often overlooked

foundation of RBV explanations of firm performance is the existence of strategic factor markets

(e.g., Chi 1994; Dierickx and Cool 1989). Strategic factor markets exist whenever firms acquire

the resources required for the implementation of a particular strategy (Makadok and Barney

3
2001). The extent to which these strategic factor markets are competitive (efficient) will affect

the likely returns to any strategy that is implemented using acquired resources. This is the result

of competitive markets valuing such resources in ways that reflect the discounted present value

of cash flows that will accrue from implementing the strategy for which they are acquired (e.g.,

Barney 1986; Woolridge and Snow 1990). This is consistent with price systems theory in

classical economics which posits that even when knowledge about the value of a resource in all

potential uses does not exist (as is the case in strategic factor markets), prices which emerge from

a competitive equilibrium will reflect the value of a resource in its best use (Koopmans 1957).

The strategic management literature indicates three key elements that impact the

existence and relative efficiency of strategic factor markets. First, consistent with models of

perfect competition in classical economics, the existence of an efficient market implies multiple

buyers and/or sellers of the strategic factor. This allows bargaining to occur and ensures that the

price mechanism reflects the value of the strategic factor. Second, the availability and

equivalence of information about the value of the strategic factor in use is an important

determinant of strategic factor market efficiency. Perfectly competitive strategic factor markets

require perfect information regarding the strategic factor and its expected value in all possible

alternative uses among and between buyers and sellers. Third, the existence of heterogeneous

resources and capabilities among firms, and the relationship between these idiosyncratic firm

resources and capabilities and the strategic factor under consideration has a significant effect on

strategic factor market efficiency. Strategic factor markets are perfectly competitive when all

buyers and sellers have equivalent resources and capabilities which are equally related to the

productive use of the strategic factor.

4
From this perspective, if strategic factor markets are competitive then the full value of the

firm strategies they enable will be reflected in the price paid for the resource(s) and firms will

not be able to obtain abnormal returns from strategies executed using acquired resources. Views

on the existence and efficiency of strategic factor markets vary in the strategic management

literature (Lippman and Rumelt 2003). For example, Barney (1986) maintains that reasonably

competitive (albeit imperfect) markets for strategic resources exist and that a firm can therefore

benefit from strategic resource acquisition only by being better informed about the future value

of strategies requiring the resource in question for their implementation. The more accurate the

expectations of the future value of strategies that can be executed using the resource in question,

the more likely the firm is to avoid overpaying (winners curse) and to be able to spot

undervalued resources (bargains) (Barney 1986). Meanwhile, Denrell, Fang, and Winter (2003)

argue that Barney’s logic may be correct but that most complex resources are so idiosyncratic

that they make accurate valuation difficult, if not impossible, and “imply thin, highly imperfect

markets for strategic resources when indeed there are markets at all.”

Irrespective of these different viewpoints on how efficient strategic factor markets are in

general, RBV theory suggests that firms should only be able to benefit from buying and selling

resources when they can create or exploit imperfections in the relevant strategic factor market

(Barney 1986). Two broad elements in strategic factor market inefficiency that firms may create

and/or exploit have received attention in the theoretical literature: information asymmetry; and,

idiosyncratic asset complementarities. Information asymmetry may exist between a buyer and a

seller and/or among buyers in a strategic factor market with regards to the availability and

accuracy of information regarding the value in use of the strategic factor (e.g., Barney 1986;

1989; Lippman and Rumelt 2003). Asset complementarities involve the idiosyncratic pre-

5
existing resources and capabilities of a firm that affect the value in use of a strategic factor,

leading to different valuations between firms for the same strategic factor (e.g., Chi 1994;

Makadok 2001). Barney (1988) describes this in an acquisition context as “when a target is

worth more to one bidder than it is to any other bidders.”

Drawing on these theoretical viewpoints of strategic factor markets suggests that firms

should only benefit from buying and selling brands when the market for brands is (or can be

made) inefficient. Further, strategic factor market theory indicates that (i) information

advantages regarding the accuracy with which buyers and sellers can forecast the value in use of

brands, and (ii) idiosyncratic firm resources and capabilities that are complementary to the brand

and affect the brand’s value in use are likely to be important determinants of whether or not

firms benefit from the acquisition and disposal of brands. Below, we detail how these factors

may be expected to impact the returns to buying and selling brand assets.

Hypotheses

Most of the strategic factor market literature focuses on conditions under which buyers

may be able to generate abnormal returns from acquiring a resource. From this perspective, there

are five factors that may be particularly important in determining the extent to which a firm can

enjoy superior performance as a result of purchasing a brand.

First, information asymmetries between the buyer and the seller and/or between buyers

which affect the accuracy with which the expected value of the brand in use can be forecast

create a factor market inefficiency that can be exploited (Lippman and Rumelt 2003). This is the

“resource-picking” mechanism for creating economic rents where superior knowledge of the

value of the brand allows a firm to purchase the brand for less than its marginal productivity

when used in combination with the firm’s stock of other resources and capabilities (Makadok

6
2001). As the brand’s owner, the seller has been able to observe the brand in use in conjunction

with its other resources and capabilities, while prospective brand acquirers have not had this

opportunity. Under most conditions the seller of a brand will therefore have a systematic

information advantage over potential buyers regarding the likely future value of the brand to the

seller. Thus, applying strategic factor market theory to the market for brands suggests that,

absent luck (which is by definition not systematic) a buyer should not be able to succeed in

profiting at all from purchasing a brand (Barney 1986; Denrell, Fang, and Winter 2003).

Second, asymmetries in complementary assets between the buyer and the seller and/or

between buyers can also affect the accuracy with which the expected value of the brand in use

can be forecast, creating a strategic factor market inefficiency (Barney 1986; Conner 1991).

From this perspective, marketing capabilities and channel relationships have been identified as

complementary assets that may that enhance the value in use of brands (e.g., Amit and

Shoemaker 1993). Such complementary assets are nontradeable and are the result of firms’

idiosyncratic investments in different activities over time (Dierickx and Cool 1989; Barney

1989). Complementary assets such as marketing capabilities and channel relationships cannot

therefore simply be acquired by other potential bidders for the brand in question. Makadok

(2001) shows analytically how firm-specific capabilities (such as marketing and brand

management) and resources (such as channel relationships) lead to differential value

expectations from the same acquirable resources among potential acquirers.

Third, diversification research in strategic management suggests that firms benefit from

diversification only when there is a strong marketing or technology link between the businesses

in which the firm is engaged (e.g., Palich, Cardinal, and Miller 2000). Applying this logic to the

acquisition of a brand suggests that the more closely a (non-redundant) brand is related to the

7
buying firm’s existing brand portfolio, the more the buying firm should benefit from acquiring

the brand. The economic logic for this expectation concerns the existence of synergies between

closely-related brands that are not available to unrelated brands and is closely allied to the above

arguments concerning complementary assets (e.g., Barney 1988). For example, purchasing a

brand in a category that is similar to that of the firm’s existing brands can enable the acquired

brand to be sold through the firm’s existing distribution channel producing synergistic savings

that will not be available if the firm purchased a brand in an unrelated category.

Finally, an important element in efficient markets is a large number of buyers and sellers.

As brands are idiosyncratic assets (a characteristic that adds to their value for consumers and

therefore for their owners), we would not expect there to be many occasions in which there may

be qualitatively similar brands for sale from multiple sellers in a strategic factor market. From a

buyer’s perspective, however, the greatest danger lies in the existence of multiple interested

buyers for a single brand asset, since limited supply and many buyers will lead to competition

that will likely bid up the value of the brand to a level that is equivalent of its highest expected

value in use. At which point, it becomes impossible for any firm to obtain positive returns form

purchasing the brand. Thus when there is an “auction”, i.e. multiple potential buyers are

approached to gauge their interest in purchasing the brand, we would expect the ultimate buyer

to be less able to enjoy superior performance as a result of the purchase.

More formally, the above arguments suggest that:

H1: Brand acquisitions are not associated with firms’ abnormal stock returns
H2: Brand acquisitions will be more positively (negatively) associated with firms’ abnormal
stock returns when:
(a) the acquired brands provide new distribution resources to the firm
(b) the buying firm has superior (inferior) brand-related marketing resources and
capabilities

8
(c) the acquired brands are more closely (distantly) related to the firm’s existing business(es)
(d) there are a smaller (larger) number of potential buyers

Resource sellers have not been the subject of as much attention as buyers in the strategic

factor market literature. However, drawing on strategic factor market theory we suggest that

there are four factors that may be important in determining the extent to which a firm can enjoy

superior returns from disposing of a brand.

First, as outlined above in the context of buying brands, information asymmetries

between the buyer and the seller which affect the accuracy with which the expected value of the

brand in use can be forecast creates a factor market inefficiency that can be exploited (Lippman

and Rumelt 2003). The “resource-picking” mechanism for creating economic rents suggests that

such information asymmetries can be valuable in enabling the firm to know what assets not to

invest in as well as those assets that should be acquired (Makadok 2001). The selling firm should

have an information advantage relative to any purchaser concerning detailed non-public

knowledge of the brand and its performance prospects (e.g., Denrell, Fang, and Winter 2003).

Perhaps more importantly, with complete information regarding the brand asset in use in

combination with the firm’s existing stock of other resources and capabilities, the selling firm is

able to more accurately assess the value of owning the brand than any firms who may consider

purchasing the brand (Makadok and Barney 2001). Thus, sellers of brand assets should

systematically have an information advantage relative to buyers. Buyers may sometime be lucky

but this is not systematic (Barney 1986).

Second, armed with this information advantage, if a firm is willing to sell a brand at a

given price then the brand must have a more valuable alternative “next best use” (Peteraf 1993).

That is, managers in the selling firm must believe that another firm (the buying firm) has

9
superior brand-related resources and capabilities such that the buyer will pay a market price for

the brand and not lower their returns by doing so (cf. Barney 1986). By selling the brand,

managers in the selling firm also signal to investors that the resources freed up by disposal of the

brand in question will deliver a greater return if they are deployed on other projects, activities,

brands, etc. (e.g., Carlotti, Coe and Perry 2004; Varadarajan, DeFanti, and Busch 2006). For

example, a firm may dispose of a brand because it believes that the returns from paying down its

debt are greater than those of owning the brand – the reason Levi’s announced for selling its

Dockers brand.

Third, the brand portfolio literature suggests that reducing the size of a brand portfolio

may result in efficiencies that lower costs (e.g., Knudsen et al. 1997; Laforet and Saunders

1999). For example, following its portfolio slimming strategy announcement in 2000 and the

selling off of more than 100 businesses and several hundred brands in the following three years,

procurement standardization and improved product mix led Unilever to improve its operating

margins from 11.2 percent to close to 15 percent (Pierce and Moukanas 2002). Thus any sale of

brand assets may increase the efficiency with which the firm may manage its remaining brand

portfolio.

Finally, the diversification literature in strategic management suggests that firms that

dispose of brands which are unrelated to their core business should enjoy stronger positive

abnormal returns. The intuition is that brands that are unrelated to the firm’s core resources and

capabilities are unlikely to enjoy any significant synergistic economic benefits (a “parenting

advantage”) from being owned by the firm (e.g., Campbell, Goold, and Alexander 1995). There

is therefore likely to be both a higher value in use for the brand in the portfolio of another firm

10
which should lead to a higher market price being paid for the brand, and also to be higher returns

available for the funds generated from selling the brand by investing in other brands.

More formally, the above suggests that:

H3: Brand disposals are associated with firms’ abnormal stock returns
H4: Brand disposals will be more (less) positively associated with firms’ abnormal stock
returns when:
(a) the selling firm has inferior (superior) brand-related resources and capabilities
(b) the selling firm signals (does not signal) that it has identified higher return investments
for the funds generated by the disposal of the brand
(c) the brand(s) sold significantly reduce the size of the selling firm’s brand portfolio
(d) the brand(s) sold are more distantly (closely) related to the firm’s existing business(es)

Research Method

We use the event study methodology to assess the impact of unexpected information on

the firm’s stock price. Finance theory asserts that a stock price reflects all public information

about the firm, so only unexpected information can change the price of a stock (Fama et al.

1969). Thus, if the new information causes investors to expect that the firm will garner lower

(higher) future cash flows, then the firm’s stock price drops (rises) in reaction to the new

information. The stock’s abnormal return, the difference between the stock’s actual return and its

expected return based on general market movement, is a measure of the event’s effect on the

firm’s market value. We follow the standard protocols for the short-term event study method,

and excellent summaries of this method currently exist in the literature (e.g., Srinivasan and

Bharadwaj 2004). When events are confined to a single industry, cross-sectional dependence in

the returns biases the standard deviation estimate downward (MacKinlay 1997), inflating the

associated test statistics. We correct for this bias using the Jaffe (1974) portfolio method.

Sample

11
We selected the companies included in the American Customer Satisfaction Index

(ACSI) as our sampling frame for three reasons. First, the ACSI is designed to be representative

of the consumer sector of the US economy, and includes the largest firms in each of 40 different

industries (representing 70% or more of the sales in these industries and collectively representing

more than 42% of US GDP), which should minimize generalizability concerns (see Fornell et al.

1996). Second, since consumer spending represents more than 70% of US GDP and brands

occupy a more central role in the business models of consumer as opposed to business-to-

business focused companies, a sample of large consumer companies is more appropriate for the

topic of our study. Third, most of the firms in the ACSI are publicly-traded which is required for

us to be able to assess stock returns as required in an event study. We focused in our initial data

collection efforts on seven of the largest industries in the ACSI: Apparel; Athletic Shoes and

Sportswear; Beverages; Cigarettes; Beer; Food/Pet Food; and, Personal Care. Eliminating private

companies resulted in an initial sample of 29 firms (see Appendix 1)1. Our sample includes all

brand acquisitions and disposals for these firms from Jan 1, 1994 through December 31, 2006.

Our disposal event is the announcement of a sale or a pending sale of a brand, identified

through a Factiva search of company news releases and press reports. Our acquisition event is

the announcement that an agreement has been reached to acquire a brand. When earlier press

reports mentioned that the firm was negotiating to purchase the brand, the announcement that the

firm was negotiating to purchase the brand was considered to be the event. We compiled our list

of brands that were acquired and disposed through four sources. First, we searched the SDC

Platinum database to construct an initial list of the acquisitions and disposals for each firm.

1
Our sample size is comparable with many other event studies. For example, Aaker and Jacobson (1994) and Lane
and Jacobson (1995) each had a sample of 34 firms, with a much smaller number of events over a shorter time
period than in our data set and Agrawal and Kamakura (1995) had a sample of 35 firms and 110 events over a
similar time period.

12
Second, we read the firms’ annual reports over the sample period to identify additional brand

acquisitions and disposals. Third, we examined all of the firms’ press releases and investor

relations material posted on their websites. Finally, we also conducted a Factiva search for brand

acquisitions and disposals, centering our search on those terms. Brand disposals mandated by

government regulators following an acquisition were not included in our sample.

Overall, we found 394 brand acquisitions and 270 brand disposals. After removing brand

acquisitions and disposals in non-G7 countries (e.g., Poland, Argentina, Turkey) and those

involving brands focused on the non-consumer foodservice channel, we were left with 238 brand

acquisitions and 199 brand disposals. Events where we found contaminating information

pertaining to earnings announcements, stock splits, key executive changes, unexpected stock

buybacks, or changes in the dividend within the two trading day window surrounding the release

of the letter were removed from the sample. Sixty-eight events had to be eliminated due to the

presence of confounding information. An additional 53 events had to be dropped due to limited

data availability about the event (e.g., we could not locate a four digit SIC code for the brand or

we were unable to determine the brand’s yearly revenues), leaving 188 announcements of brand

acquisitions and 128 announcements of brand disposals2.

Variable Operationalization

Dependent variable. Abnormal stock returns were obtained using the Eventus® software

program on WRDS. An abnormal stock return is computed as detailed above.

Independent and control variables. These were operationalized using both information

coded from the announcements we collected and also from secondary databases such as

2
In only 17 observations were the purchase and disposal events matched in our two databases suggesting that the 29
large companies in our sample rarely swap brand assets. In only 10 of these matched pairs did we find no
confounding information and include these in our analyses.

13
COMPUSTAT. Details of the variable operationalization are contained in Appendix 2. A content

analysis of the announcements was conducted. A coder recorded the data in the announcements

using a standardized coding scheme. We plan to use a second coder for all events to allow an

assessment of inter-coder agreement that will provide additional confidence in the quality of

coded data (see future research plans). Descriptive statistics for all variables are reported in

Table 1 and correlations among the variables in the brand acquisition and disposal samples are

reported in Tables 2 and 3 respectively.

[Insert Tables 1, 2 & 3 Here]

PRELIMINARY ANALYSES AND RESULTS

Event Study Analysis and Results

Daily stock returns were gathered from the University of Chicago’s Center for Research

in Security Prices (CRSP), and parameters of the market model were estimated over a 90 trading

day estimation window, ending 6 days prior to the event. The daily and cumulative average

abnormal returns for windows surrounding the event date are presented in Table 4. All statistical

tests are two-tailed. To allow for uncertainty over when the information was available to

investors, common event study practice is to determine the event window empirically (Agrawal

and Kamakura 1995; Brown and Warner 1985). For the disposals, results are strongest for the

event day, but for the acquisitions we observe no significant abnormal return on any of the days

surrounding the event. We find no evidence that information leaks to the market before the

announcement of the acquisition or sale of the brand. Motivated by the strength of the results for

the (0,0) window for the disposals, as well as the idea that investors should react swiftly to these

material firm events, we focus our analysis on the (0,0) window.

(Insert Table 4 here)

14
Supporting H1, we find that the announcement of brand acquisitions is not associated

with a significant stock price move, with an abnormal return of -.18 on average during the [0,0]

window, supporting H1 (tJaffe portfolio test = -0.53, p > .10), and confirming that investors neither

reward nor punish firms for buying brand assets. On the event date, 89 of the 188 abnormal

returns were positive (tgeneralized sign test = -0.26; p > .10). Further, the Wilcoxon signed rank test, a

more powerful nonparametric test incorporating the sign and magnitude of the abnormal returns,

was also insignificant (ZWilcoxon = -542.00, p > .10), suggesting outliers did not overly influence

our insignificant results (McWilliams and Siegel 1997)3.

In contrast, we find that the announcement of brand disposals is associated with a

significant stock price increase of .49% on average during the [0,0] window, supporting H3 (tJaffe

portfolio test = 2.80, p < .01), with 78 of the 128 abnormal returns being positive (tgeneralized sign test =

2.65, p < .01). Further, the Wilcoxon signed rank test was also significant (ZWilcoxon = -1056.00, p

< .01), suggesting outliers did not overly influence our results (McWilliams and Siegel 1997).

The disposal announcement was associated with an average gain of $141 million dollars in

shareholder value.

Cross-sectional Regression Results

We tested H2 and H4 regarding the impact of different firm, transaction, brand, and

strategic characteristics on the abnormal stock returns to the acquisition and disposal of brand

assets through a regression of the [0,0] cumulative abnormal return on the independent variables

and the controls. The cross-sectional results are presented in Tables 5 and 6.

[Insert Tables 5 and 6 here]

3
Sensitivity analysis indicated that the negative abnormal return is robust with respect to other market model benchmarks and
statistical tests. The significance of [0,0] abnormal return is unaffected by using a value-weighted market portfolio. Results for
the [0,0] window are also significant using Brown and Warner’s (1980) crude dependence adjustment test statistic.

15
Brand Acquisitions

Table 5 reveals that our cross-sectional regression has significant explanatory power

(Adjusted R2 of .17). Among the control variables, we find that the abnormal returns to acquiring

a brand are positively associated with purchases of Canadian (p<.10) and French (p<.05) brands,

and negatively associated with the relative size of the acquisition (p<.001). Surprisingly, neither

announcements concerning the expected effect of the brand acquisition on the firm’s earnings or

analyst perceptions of the relative price paid for the brand had a significant relationship with

abnormal stock returns.

In terms of H2, we find support for H2(a) with a positive coefficient (p<.05) when the

acquired brand brings new distribution resources to the acquirer firm. We also find some support

for H2(b), with a marginally significant (p<.10) positive coefficient on the Tobin’s Q variable

(our proxy for a firm’s marketing capabilities). With a non significant coefficient for the un-

relatedness and auction variables we find no support for either H2(c) or H2(d). Beyond the

hypothesis tests we also included an interaction of Tobin’s Q and whether or not the brand was

being purchased at auction. As seen in Table 4, we found a significant negative interaction

between these two variables in predicting abnormal stock returns to brand acquisitions.

Brand Disposals

Table 6 reveals that our cross-sectional regression of the abnormal returns to brand

disposals has good explanatory power (Adjusted R2 of .32). Among the control variables we find

stronger positive returns to disposals of brands that are primarily geographically strong in France

(at the p<.10 level). We also find that announcements concerning an expected positive effect of

the disposal on the selling firm’s earnings (p<.05) and analyst perceptions of the price realized in

16
selling the brand (p<.05) were both positively associated with abnormal stock returns to brand

disposals.

In terms of H3, we find mixed support for H3(a) with an insignificant coefficient on the

Tobin’s Q variable (our proxy for a firm’s marketing capabilities) but a strong positive

coefficient on the sale of brands for which the selling firm has inferior distribution resources

(p<.01). We find no support for H3(b). In fact we observe that when the selling firm identifies

higher return uses for the cash released in disposing of the brand, this is either not significantly

associated with abnormal stock returns, or in the case of investing in more profitable brands

(p<.10) and reducing debt (p<.10), investors tend to react negatively rather than positively. We

find some support for H3(c), since the sale of relatively larger brands (implying a larger

opportunity for efficiency savings through the reduction in the selling firm’s brand portfolio) is

positively associated with greater abnormal stock returns (p<.001). With a marginally significant

positive coefficient (p<.10) for the un-relatedness variable we also find some support for H3(d).

DISCUSSION AND IMPLICATIONS

Our study reveals no significant abnormal returns associated with the acquisition of brand

assets. This does not suggest that brand assets are not valuable. Rather, in line with strategic

factor market theory, our results indicate that the buy-side market for brand assets is relatively

efficient in valuing brands. This contrasts with the “winners curse” phenomenon noted in the

acquisitions literature in strategic management and economics which shows that acquirers

consistently pay too high a premium when purchasing other firms (e.g., Varaiya 1988). Thus, our

results suggest that acquirer expectations of the future returns from the purchase of a single asset

(a brand) are more accurate than when purchasing a collection of different types of assets (an

entire firm). The relative efficiency of the buy-side factor market for brands provides some

17
support for valuation mechanisms such as those used by Interbrand that use the prices paid for

brand assets in recent market transactions in a particular sector as an important determinant of

the “multiple” used to compute the value of specific brands.

However, the results of our test of H2(d) indicate that it is not the presence of multiple

prospective bidders for a brand that drives the insignificant returns from brand purchase (and by

inference the efficiency of the strategic factor market for brands). We further explored this result

by examining whether or not this finding is moderated by an interaction with the firm’s

marketing capabilities (Tobin’s Q). The significant negative interaction suggests that brand

acquirers with lower marketing capabilities may be better rewarded in an auction situation than

those with higher capabilities. One possible explanation is that this result may be driven by firms

acquiring brand management teams as well as the brand(s) on which they work and being

rewarded by investors as a result – a possibility we will explore as we further develop our

database and analyses.

The cross sectional regression results provide some support for suggestions that when

buying brands, acquirers with stronger marketing capabilities (those with higher Tobin’s Q’s

scores) may be rewarded (or less punished) when they purchase brand assets. This result is in

contrast to Bahadir, Bharadwaj, and Srivastava (2006) who find acquirer marketing capabilities

do not affect the value placed on brands in the context of whole company acquisitions. The

regression results also indicate that when buying brands, acquirers that have the ability to use the

purchased brand’s channel relationships to expand the distribution of their existing brand

portfolio are rewarded when they purchase brand assets. However, this is not true of using the

acquirer’s existing channel relationships to expand distribution of the purchased brand. A

subsequent split group analysis revealed that brand acquisitions which bring new distribution

18
relationships to the acquirer produce a .96% positive abnormal return on average during the [0,0]

window (tJaffe portfolio test = 4.04, p <.01) with 13 of 14 abnormal returns being positive (tgeneralized sign

test = 3.35, p < .01). In contrast, brand acquisitions designed to leverage the acquirer’s existing

channel relationships produce a -.55% abnormal return on average during the [0,0] window (tJaffe

portfolio test = -0.46, p >.10) with 10 of 18 abnormal returns being positive (tgeneralized sign test = .56, p

>.10).

This suggests an interesting asymmetry – leveraging the acquirer’s existing brands

through new channels is rewarded while leveraging newly acquired brand(s) through the

acquirer’s existing channels is not. Theoretically, this suggests that the channel relationships

associated with a brand may be undervalued by firms in strategic factor markets. It also suggests

that investors believe that firms have the opportunity to further leverage their brand assets into

new channels. It is also possible that it is the relative size of the two opportunities that drives

these results. The average size of the acquired brands in our sample is around 5% of the

acquirer’s total sales revenue, so it is possible that the absolute returns of leveraging the

acquirer’s larger brand portfolio into a new channel are greater than those possible from selling

the newly acquired brand(s) through the firm’s existing distribution network. This possibility

will be investigated in our future analyses.

While the regression results indicate that the degree of diversification implied in the

purchase of the brand (un-relatedness) does not drive abnormal returns, this is a very coarse

grained variable which does not allow us to compare our findings with those of the

diversification literature in strategic management. We therefore did some post-hoc analyses with

a finer grained set of variables where we coded each brand in terms of whether it was in the same

19
industry and market segment, in the same industry in an adjacent market segment, or in an

unrelated industry. Split group analysis of the acquisition sample indicate that investors are

unmoved by purchases within the same market segment with a -.07% on average during the [0,0]

window (tJaffe portfolio test = -.44, p >.10) with 20 of 42 abnormal returns being positive (tgeneralized sign

test = -.00, p > .10). This may indicate that investors see any relatedness (synergy) benefits from

acquiring brands in the same market segment as being offset by overlap or “redundancy”

between the acquired brand and the brands that are already in the acquirer’s portfolio which can

reduce price premiums and weaken manufacturing and distribution economies (e.g., Pierce and

Moukanas 2002; Varadarajan, DeFanti, and Busch 2006).

We also found that consistent with the diversification literature in strategic management

investors reward purchases in an adjacent market segment to the firm’s existing business, and

tend towards punishing acquisitions in unrelated industries. Our split group analysis of the

acquisition sample indicate that brand acquisitions in adjacent market segments produce a .58%

positive abnormal return on average during the [0,0] window (tJaffe portfolio test = 2.33, p <.05) with

22 of 34 abnormal returns being positive (tgeneralized sign test = 1.81, p < .10). In contrast, brand

acquisitions in unrelated industries produce a -.45% abnormal return on average during the [0,0]

window (tJaffe portfolio test = -1.42, p >.10) with 47 of 112 abnormal returns being positive (tgeneralized

sign test = -1.33, p >.10).

On the sell-side our results reveal a significant, positive abnormal return associated with

the sale of brand assets, indicating that firms are rewarded when investors become aware of a

pending sale of brand assets. This is consistent with strategic factor market theory regarding

information asymmetry and our conjecture that because sellers have more knowledge and

information regarding the brand they have more accurate expectations about the brand’s value in

20
use. Theoretically, this is a strategic factor market imperfection which seller firms can exploit

and our results suggest that investors are aware of this benefit to sellers of brands.

The positive abnormal returns to the sale of a brand are even more positive when selling:

non-core business brands; larger brands; and brands that are primarily French. The enhanced

positive returns when selling a non-core business brand is consistent with Varadarajan, DeFanti,

and Busch’s (2006) conjecture that firms will do so if the brands are likely to fetch a premium in

the marketplace. The enhanced positive returns from selling larger brands mirrors the negative

returns from buying bigger brands in the acquisition sample. Brand disposals that contribute

positively to earnings and those that realize a higher price than analysts may have expected are

also associated with abnormal positive returns in our analyses which is consistent with a

“shareholder value maximization” perspective on investor behavior (Woolridge and Snow 1990).

There are two other interesting results revealed in our regression analyses of the positive

abnormal returns to selling brands. First, we find that selling brands for which the selling firm

had limited distribution resources relative to other firms is positively related to abnormal returns.

In RBV terms this is suggestive of a “better use” available in a strategic factor market for the

brand asset and an absence of a “parenting advantage” for the seller (e.g., Peteraf 1993;

Campbell, Goold, and Alexander 1995). For a tradable asset such as a brand, this should result in

the expected value of ownership of the brand being higher to another firm with superior

distribution resources, resulting in a higher valuation for the brand (Barney 1986; 1989). Perhaps

most interesting here is that this result is not mirrored in the brand acquisition findings.

Second, we find that announcements detailing the strategic logic of the disposal (i.e. the

use to which the proceeds of the sale will be put) do not enhance the positive abnormal returns

and in the case of announcements of investing in more profitable brands and reducing debt, the

21
effect may even be negative. Our speculation for this result is that investors may view paying

down debt or investing in more profitable (but not necessarily faster growing) brands as an

indicator that the firm’s managers do not see significant growth opportunities that may provide

better returns.

LIMITATIONS

One caveat of the event study methodology is that it does not identify the mechanism for

explaining why any abnormal return occurs (Johnson and Tellis 2007). We assumed that

investors’ response would be predicated by the variables thus far examined, but surveys of

investors will be useful to confirm this assumption.

Further, we need to more systematically examine the purchase process when the acquirer

firm competes in an auction. There are a number of stages in this process: (1) firms are rumored

to bid, (2) firms bid, (3) one firm becomes a front-runner, (4) a firm enters into talks, and (5) an

agreement is reached. Currently we have used stage #4 as our event, but results may change if a

different stage is used. Further, if #2 is used, this could expand our sample by including more

firms that bid but did not buy.

22
Appendix 1
Companies and Industries Included in Complete Case Analysis Data Set
COMPANIES
Anheuser-Busch General Mills Reebok
Cadbury Schweppes HJ Heinz Reynolds American
Campbell’s Soup Hershey Reebok
Clorox Jones Apparel Reynolds American
Coca-Cola Kellogg’s Sara Lee
Colgate-Palmolive Kraft Foods Quaker Oats
ConAgra Foods Liz Claiborne Tyson Foods
Dial Molson Coors Unilever
Del Monte Nike VF Corporation
Dole Food Pepsi Co

INDUSTRIES
Apparel Beverages - Soft drinks Personal Care Products
Athletic Shoes Food Processing
Beverages - Beer Tobacco - Cigarettes

26
Appendix 2
Operationalization of Independent and Control Variables
Type of Variable Operationalization
Variable
Brand-Level Un-relatedness If the 4 digit SIC code for the acquirer and target in the transaction
Factors provided by SDC Platinum differed in their first 2 digits
Relative size Prior year sales of the brand / prior year sales of the firm
Geographic presence The main countries within the G7 that the brand operated in were
of the brand coded from press reports of the transaction
Disposed brand has Whether the firm decided to sell because the brand’s distribution
inferior distribution resources were inferior to its competitors, as coded from press
resources (D) reports of the transaction
Firm-Level Tobin’s Q Calculated following Chung and Pruitt (1994) and Srinivasan
Factors (2006)
Market Value Closing price X shares outstanding from CRSP
Transaction Stated earnings Whether the acquisition/disposal would have an accretive (1),
Factors impact dilutive (-1), or no impact (0) on earnings, coded from press
reports of the transaction
Perception of brand’s Whether price was deemed high (1) or low (0) by market
price observers, coded from press reports.
Brand was purchased Coded using the terms “auction”, “bid”, and “bidders”, coded
in an auction (A) from press reports.
Distribution Acquired brand When the brand was acquired in part to allow the firm to sell in
Factors provides new-to-the- new channels or geographies, as coded from press reports (i.e.,
firm distribution Campbell Soup buying France’s Liebig).
resources (A)
Target bought to When the acquiring firm stated that a reason for the acquisition
leverage acquirer’s was to be able to expand the brand’s sales by leveraging the firm’s
distribution resources distribution strengths (e.g., P&G’s purchase of Tambrands)
(A)
Strategic To focus on faster If firm identified this as a rationale for the disposition, as coded
Logic growing brands (D) from press reports.
To focus on more If firm identified this as a rationale for the disposition, as coded
profitable brands (D) from press reports.
To focus on core If firm identified this as a rationale for the disposition, as coded
brands (D) from press reports.
To reduce debt (D) If firm identified this as a rationale for the disposition, as coded
from press reports.
To buy back shares If firm identified this as a rationale for the disposition, as coded
(D) from press reports.

27
Figure 1
Outline Research Model

• Outside of the firm’s major industry


(2-digit SIC)
Brand-Level • Relative size (brand sales/firm sales)
Factors • Disposed brand has inferior distribution
resourcesD
• Geographic presence of brand (U.S.,
Canada, U.K., France, Germany, Italy)

Firm-Level • Tobin’s Q
Factors • Market value

• Brand purchased in an auctionA


Transaction • Auction X Tobin’s Q interactionA Abnormal
Factors • Stated earnings impact Return for
• Perception of brand’s price Brand
Acquisition /
• Acquired brand provides new-to-the-firm Disposal
Distribution distribution resourcesA
Factors • Target bought to leverage acquirer’s
distribution resourcesA

• To focus on faster growing brandsD


Strategic • To focus on more profitable brandsD
Logic • To focus on core brandsD
• To reduce debtD
• To buy back sharesD A – applies only to brand acquisitions
D – applies only to brand to disposals
Control variables

28
Table 1
Descriptive Statistics

Acquisition Sample
Std.
Variable Mean Dev. Max. Min.
(0,0) Abnormal return (in percent) -.18 2.52 -11.39 15.87
Un-relatedness (outside of the firm’s major 2 digit SIC industry) .22 .41 .00 1.00
Relative size of acquisition (acquired brand’s sales / acquirer’s sales) .05 .16 .00 1.92
Acquirer bought entire firm .60 .49 .00 1.00
Geographic presence: USA .76 .43 .00 1.00
Brand-Level
Factors Geographic presence: Canada .08 .27 .00 1.00
Geographic presence: U.K. .12 .33 .00 1.00
Geographic presence: France .11 .31 .00 1.00
Geographic presence: Germany .06 .25 .00 1.00
Geographic presence: Italy .05 .23 .00 1.00
Firm-Level Tobin’s Q 2.22 1.23 .43 9.91
Factors Market value (in billions $) 28.50 39.86 .14 192.91
Acquisition has accretive/dilutive earnings impact .10 .48 -1.00 1.00
Transaction
Factors Perception of price paid (high price: 1, low price: -1) .08 .33 -1.00 1.00
Brand was purchased in an auction .13 .34 .00 1.00
Distribution Acquired brand provides new distribution resources to the firm .07 .26 .00 1.00
Factors Target bought to leverage acquirer’s distribution resources .10 .30 .00 1.00

Disposal Sample
Std.
Variable Mean Dev. Min. Max.
(0,0) Abnormal return (in percent) .49 1.83 -3.01 10.86
Un-relatedness (outside of the firm’s major 2 digit SIC industry) .34 .47 .00 1.00
Disposed brand’s percent of prior year firm sales .02 .04 .00 .31
Disposed brand has inferior distribution resources .05 .21 .00 1.00
Geographic presence: USA .65 .48 .00 1.00
Brand-Level
Geographic presence: Canada .22 .42 .00 1.00
Factors
Geographic presence: U.K. .17 .38 .00 1.00
Geographic presence: France .13 .34 .00 1.00
Geographic presence: Germany .14 .35 .00 1.00
Geographic presence: Italy .13 .34 .00 1.00
Firm-Level Tobin’s Q 2.32 .93 .89 5.51
Factors Market value (in billions $) 28.24 36.50 .07 141.38
Transaction Disposal has accretive/dilutive earnings impact -.02 .31 -1.00 1.00
Factors Perception of price received (good: 1, poor: -1) -.01 .20 -1.00 1.00
To focus on faster growing brands .33 .47 .00 1.00
To focus on more profitable brands .15 .36 .00 1.00
Strategic
To focus on core brands .67 .47 .00 1.00
Logic
To reduce debt .08 .27 .00 1.00
To buyback shares .02 .15 .00 1.00

29
Table 2
Correlations of Variables in the Acquisition Sample

Variable Correlations
(0,0) Abnormal return (in percent) 1.00
Outside of the firm’s major industry (2 digit SIC) .10 1.00
Relative size (acquired brand’s sales / acquirer’s sales) -.38 -.08 1.00
Acquirer bought entire firm -.02 .17 .03 1.00
Geographic presence: USA -.07 .08 .08 .28 1.00
Brand-Level
Factors Geographic presence: Canada .09 .03 .15 -.04 -.16 1.00
Geographic presence: U.K. .06 -.04 .08 -.26 -.55 .13 1.00
Geographic presence: France .24 -.10 -.04 -.18 -.57 .03 .24 1.00
Geographic presence: Germany .21 -.03 -.01 -.05 -.41 .08 .23 .47 1.00
Geographic presence: Italy .23 -.01 -01 -.05 .37 .11 .20 .53 .52 1.00
Firm-Level Tobin’s Q .04 -.11 -.06 .03 -.05 -.02 .06 .10 -.03 -.06 1.00
Factors Market value (in billions $) .02 .02 -.09 -.04 -.05 -.07 .03 .13 .05 .04 .64 1.00
Acquisition has accretive/dilutive earnings impact .16 .00 -.03 .03 .01 -.02 .13 .04 .08 .05 -.14 -.17 1.00
Transaction
Factors Perception of price paid (high price: 1, low price: -1) -.14 -.01 .14 -.00 .06 .17 .01 -.03 .00 .01 .09 .11 -.29 1.00
Brand was purchased in an auction -.00 -.02 .33 -.06 .11 .17 .14 -.08 -.04 -.02 -.01 -.02 -.01 .24 1.00
Distribution Acquired brand provides new distribution resources to the firm .13 -.05 -.02 .07 .06 -.08 -.04 .03 -.07 -.07 -.07 -.14 .16 -.07 .07 1.00
Factors Target bought to leverage acquirer’s distribution resources -.05 .05 -.02 .23 .14 -.03 -.07 -.11 -.08 .00 .14 .14 -.10 -.02 .-.07 -.09 1.00

Note: correlations with an absolute value ≥ .14 have a p-value < .05.

30
Table 3
Correlations of Variables in the Disposal Sample

Variable Correlations
(0,0) Abnormal return (in percent) 1.00
Outside of the firm’s major industry (2 digit SIC) .13 1.00
Brand-Level Disposed brand’s percent of prior year firm sales .41 .01 1.00
Factors Disposed brand has inferior distribution resources .36 .08 .02 1.00
Geographic presence: USA -.08 .14 .06 .01 1.00
Geographic presence: Canada -.05 .10 -.05 .06 .19 1.00
Geographic presence: U.K. .05 -.06 .10 -.00 -.49 -.04 1.00
Geographic presence: France .15 .01 .12 -.09 -.39 -.04 .31 1.00
Geographic presence: Germany .22 .05 .12 .12 -.41 .00 .35 .44 1.00
Geographic presence: Italy .05 .06 .04 .02 -.39 .02 .43 ..39 .37 1.00
Firm-Level Tobin’s Q -.03 .06 -.15 -.09 -.03 -.02 -.06 .06 .07 -.01 1.00
Factors Market value (in billions $) .01 .15 -.15 -.03 .17 -.16 -.15 .00 -.14 -.01 .41 1.00
Transaction Disposal has accretive/dilutive earnings impact .01 .09 -.15 -.11 .02 .09 .02 .02 .02 .17 .08 .03 1.00
Factors Perception of price received (good: 1, poor: -1) .18 -.14 -.03 .20 -.11 .12 .12 .02 .13 .13 -.01 -.06 -.13 1.00
Strategic To focus on faster growing brands .16 .03 .12 .08 -.04 .15 .03 .07 .05 .07 .05 -.15 -.07 .20 1.00
Logic To focus on more profitable brands -.08 -.02 .05 .01 .08 .15 .04 .03 -.11 .03 .01 .07 .02 -.09 -.01 1.00
To focus on core brands .15 .07 -.01 .08 -.13 -.07 .05 .18 .14 .08 .10 .09 .07 .06 .17 .06 1.00
To reduce debt -.04 .04 .23 .07 .03 -.01 .02 .14 .05 -.03 -.20 -.08 -.18 .16 -.08 -.12 -.11 1.00
To buyback shares .05 -.00 .09 -.03 -.10 -.08 .07 .09 -.06 -.06 -.10 .09 .01 .01 .00 .08 -.11 .34 1.00

Note: correlations with an absolute value ≥ .18 have a p-value < .05.

31
Table 4
Abnormal Returns and Test Statistics for Windows Surrounding the Event Day

Acquisition Sample
Jaffe (1974) Wilcoxon
Abnormal # Positive Generalized
Event Window Portfolio t- Signed Rank
Return (%) (Total) Sign test
statistic test
-1, 0 -.06 -.40 96 of 188 .76 145.00
0, 0 -.18 -.53 89 of 188 -.26 -542.00
0, 1 -.23 -.73 96 of 188 .76 -529.00

Disposal Sample
Jaffe (1974) Wilcoxon
Abnormal # Positive Generalized
Event Window Portfolio t- Signed Rank
Return (%) (Total) Sign test
statistic test
-1, 0 .58 2.51** 71 of 128 1.41 940.00**
0, 0 .49 2.80*** 78 of 128 2.65*** 1056.00**
0, 1 .50 2.47** 69 of 128 1.06 691.00

32
Table 5
Cross-Sectional Regression Results on the Standardized Abnormal Return for the Event
Day for the Brand Acquisitions (0,0) [In Percent]

Brand-Level, Firm-Level,
Transaction, and
Distribution-Level Factors
Parameter
Independent Variable Estimate t-value
Intercept -.65 -1.40

Brand-Level Factors
Un-relatedness (brand is outside of the firm’s major industry) .29 .96
Relative size of acquisition (acquired brand’s sales / acquirer’s sales) -6.14*** -4.68
Acquirer bought entire firm -.26 -1.10
Geographic presence: USA .41 1.06
Geographic presence: Canada .74* 1.71
Geographic presence: U.K. -.24 -.59
Geographic presence: France 1.13** 2.42
Geographic presence: Germany .75 1.59
Geographic presence: Italy .15 .26

Firm-Level Factors
Tobin’s q .20* 1.67
Market value -.00 -1.37

Transaction Factors
Acquisition expected to have an accretive/dilutive earnings impact .10 .38
Perception of price paid (high price: 1, low price: -1) -.37 -.90
Brand was purchased in an auction .10 .25
Auction X Tobin’s Q interaction -.75** -2.27

Distribution Factors
Acquired brand provides new distribution resources to the firm .89** 2.25
Target bought to leverage acquirer’s distribution resources -.12 -.27

Observations 188
R2 .25
Adjusted R2 .17
F-value 3.37
F-probability < 0.01
*** p < .01
** p ≤ .05
* p ≤ .10

33
Table 6
Cross-Sectional Regression Results on the Standardized Abnormal Return for the Event
Day for the Brand Disposals (0,0) [In Percent]

Brand-Level, Firm-Level,
Transaction, and Strategic
Logic Factors
Parameter
Independent Variable Estimate t-value
Intercept -.60 -1.42

Brand-Level Factors
Un-relatedness (brand is outside of the firm’s major industry) .51* 1.81
Disposed brand’s percent of prior year firm sales 20.20*** 5.65
Disposed brand has inferior distribution resources 2.22*** 3.74
Geographic presence: USA .22 .75
Geographic presence: Canada -.17 -.59
Geographic presence: U.K. .05 .14
Geographic presence: France .73* 1.70
Geographic presence: Germany .44 1.10
Geographic presence: Italy -.45 -1.11

Firm-Level Factors
Tobin’s Q .08 .55
Market value .00 .30

Transaction Factors
Disposal expected to have an accretive/dilutive earnings impact .90** 2.19
Perception of price received (good: 1, poor: -1) 1.48** 2.46

Strategic Logic
To focus on faster growing brands .23 .91
To focus on more profitable brands -.59* -1.87
To focus on core brands .07 0.28
To reduce debt -1.01* -1.75
To buyback shares .78 1.16

Observations 128
R2 .41
Adjusted R2 .32
F-value 4.25
F-probability < .01
*** p < .01
** p ≤ .05
* p ≤ .10

34
REFERENCES
Aaker, David A. (2004) Brand Portfolio Strategy, New York: Free Press.
---- (1991), Managing Brand Equity, New York: Free Press.
---- and Kevin Lane Keller (1990), “Consumer Evaluations of Brand Extensions,” Journal of
Marketing, 54 (1), 27-41.
---- and Robert Jacobson (1994), “The Financial Information Content of Perceived Quality,” Journal
of Marketing Research, 31 (May), 191-201.
Agrawal, Jagdish and Wagner A. Kamakura (1995), “The Economic Worth of Celebrity
Endorsers: An Event Study Analysis,” Journal of Marketing, 59 (July), 56-62.
Ailawadi, Kusum L., Donald R. Lehman, and Scott A. Neslin (2001), “Revenue Premium as an
Outcome Measure of Brand Equity,” Journal of Marketing, 67 (4), 1-17.
Anderson, Eugene W., Claes Fornell, and S. Mazvancheryl (2004), “Customer Satisfaction and
Shareholder Value,” Journal of Marketing, 68 (4), 172-185.
Bahadir, Cem, Sundar G. Bharadwaj, and Rajendra K. Srivastava (2006), “Financial Value of Brands
in Mergers and Acquisitions: Is Value in the Eye of the Beholder?” ZIBS Technical Report, Zyman
Institute of Brand Science: Atlanta, GA.
Barney, Jay B. (1986), “Strategic Factor Markets: Expectations, Luck, and Business Strategy,”
Management Science, 32 (10), 1231-1241.
---- (1988), “Returns to Bidding Firms in Mergers and Acquisitions: Reconsidering the Relatedness
Hypothesis,” Strategic Management Journal, 9 (1), 71-78.
---- (1989), “Asset Stocks and Sustained Competitive Advantage: A Comment,” Management Science,
35 (12), 1511-1513.
Barth, Mary, Michael Clement, George Foster, and Ron Kasznik (1998), “Brand Values and Capital
Market Valuation,” Review of Accounting Studies, 3, 41-68.
Boulding, William and Richard Staelin (1995), “Identifying Generalizable Effects of Strategic
Actions on Firm Performance: The Case of Demand-Side Returns to R&D Spending,” Marketing
Science, 14 (3), 222-234.
Brown, Stephen J. and Jerold B. Warner (1980), “Measuring Security Price Performance,”
Journal of Financial Economics, 8 (September), 205-58.
---- and ---- (1985), “Using Daily Stock Returns: The Case of Event Studies,” Journal of
Financial Economics, 14 (March), 3-31.
Campbell, Andrew, Michael Goold, and Marcus Alexander (1995), “Corporate Strategy: The Search
for Parenting Advantage,” Harvard Business Review, March-April, 120-132.
Capron, Laurence and John Hulland (1999), “Redeployment of Brands, Sales Forces and General
Marketing Management Expertise Following Horizontal Acquisitions: A Resource-Based View,”
Journal of Marketing, 63 (2), 41-54.
Carlotti, Stephen J., Mary Ellen Coe, and Jesko Perry (2004), “Making Brand Portfolios Work,”
McKinsey Quarterly, 4, 26-36.

35
Chi, Tailan (1994), “Trading in Strategic Resources: Necessary Conditions, Transaction Cost
Problems, and Choice of Exchange Structure,” Strategic Management Journal, 15, 271-290.
Connor, Kathleen R. (1991), “A Historical Comparison of Resource Based View and Five
Schools of Thought Within Industrial Organization Economics: Do We Have a New Theory of
the Firm?” Journal of Management, 17, 121-154.
Day, George S. and Liam Fahey (1988), “Valuing Market Strategies,” Journal of Marketing, 52
(3), 45-57.
Denrell, Jerker, Christina Fang, and Sidney G. Winter (2003), “The Economics of Strategic
Opportunity,” Strategic Management Journal, 24, 977-990.
Dierickx, Ingemar and Karel Cool (1989), “Asset Stock Accumulation and Sustainability of
Competitive Advantage,” Management Science, 35 (12), 1504-1511.
Fama, Eugene F., Lawrence Fisher, Michael C. Jensen, and Richard Roll (1969), “The
Adjustment of Stock Prices to New Information,” International Economic Review, 10 (1), 1-21.
---- and Kenneth R. French (1993), “Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds,”
Journal of Financial Economics, 33 (1), 3-56.
Finskud, Lars, Egil Hogna, Trond Riiher Knudsen, and Richard Törnblom (1997), “Brand
Consolidation Makes a Lot of Economic Sense,” McKinsey Quarterly, 4, 189-93.
Fornell, Claes, Michael D. Johnson, Eugene W. Anderson, Jaesung Cha, and Barbara Bryant
(1996), “The American Customer Satisfaction Index: Description, Findings, and Implications,”
Journal of Marketing, 60 (4), 7-18.
Grant, Robert M. and A. P. Jammine (1988), “Performance Differences between the
Wrigley/Rumelt Strategic Categories,” Strategic Management Journal, 9 (4), 333-346.
Greene, William H. (2003), Econometric Analysis, 5th Edition, Prentice Hall: Englewood Cliffs,
NJ.
Hill, Sam and Chris Lederer (2001), The Infinite Asset: Managing Brands to Build New Value,
Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press.
----, Richard Ettenson, and Dane Tyson (2005), “Achieving the Ideal Brand Portfolio,” Sloan
Management Review, 46 (2), 85-90.
Jaffe, Jeffrey F. (1974), “Special Information and Insider Trading,” The Journal of Business, 47
(3), 410-28.
Johnson, Joseph and Gerard J. Tellis (2007), “The Value of Quality: Stock Market Returns to
Published Quality Reviews,” Marketing Science, forthcoming.
Kallapur, Sanjay and Sabrina Y. S. Kwan (2004), “The Value Relevance and Reliability of Brand
Assets Recognized by UK Firms,” The Accounting Review, 79 (1), 151-172.
Kapferer, Jean-Noel (1994), Strategic Brand Management, New York: Free Press.
Keller, Kevin Lane (1993), “Conceptualizing, Measuring, and Managing Customer-Based Brand
Equity,” Journal of Marketing, 57 (1), 1-22.
Kennedy, Peter (2003), A Guide to Econometrics. 5th Ed. MIT Press: Cambridge, MA.

36
Keller, Kevin Lane and Donald R. Lehmann (2006), “Brands and Branding: Research Findings
and Future Priorities,” Marketing Science, 25 (6), 740-759.
Koopmans, T. C. (1957), Three Essays on the State of Economic Science, New York: McGraw-
Hill.
Knudsen, Trond R., Lars Finskud, Richard Törnblom, and Egil Hogna (1997), “Brand
Consolidation Makes a Lot of Economic Sense,” McKinsey Quarterly, 4, 189-93.
Kumar, Nirmalya (2003), “Kill a Brand, Keep a Customer,” Harvard Business Review, December,
86-95.
Laforet, Sylvie and John A. Saunders (2005), “Managing Brand Portfolios: How Strategies Have
Changed,” Journal of Advertising Research, 45 (3), 314-327.
---- and ---- (1999), “Managing Brand Portfolios: Why Leaders Do What They Do,” Journal of
Advertising Research, 39 (1), 51-66.
Lane, Vicki and Robert Jacobson (1995), “Stock Market Reactions to Brand Extension
Announcements: The Effects of Brand Attitude and Familiarity,” Journal of Marketing, 59 (1), 63-
77.
Lippman, Steven A. and Richard P. Rumelt (2003), “A Bargaining Perspective on Resource
Advantage,” Strategic Management Journal, 24, 1069-1086.
MacKinlay, A. Craig (1997), “Event Studies in Economics and Finance,” Journal of Economic
Literature, 35 (March), 13-39.
Madden, Thomas J., Frank Fehle, and Susan M. Fournier (2006), “Brands Matter: An Empirical
Investigation of Brand Building Activities and the Creation of Shareholder Value,” Journal of the
Academy of Marketing Science, 34 (2), 224-235.
Makadok, Richard (2001), “Towards a Synthesis of the Resource-Based View and Dynamic-
Capability Views of Rent Creation,” Strategic Management Journal, 22 (4), 387-401.
---- and Jay B. Barney (2001), “Strategic Factor Market Intelligence: An Application of
Information Economics to Strategy Formulation and Competitor Intelligence,” Management
Science, 47 (12), 1621-1638.
McWilliams, Abagail and Donald Siegel (1997), “Event Studies in Management Research:
Theoretical and Empirical Issues,” Academy of Management Journal, 40 (June), 626-657.
Palich, Lind E., Laura B. Cardinal, and Chet C. Miller (2000), “Curvilinearity in the
Diversification-Performance Linkage: An Examination of over Three Decades of Research,”
Strategic Management Journal, 21 (2), 155-174.
Pierce, Andrew and Hanna Moukanas (2002), “Portfolio Power: Harnessing a Group of Brands
to Drive Profitable Growth,” Strategy & Leadership, 30 (5), 15-20.
Rao, Vithala R., Manoj K. Agarwal, and Denise Dahlhoff (2004), “How Does Branding Strategy
Affect the Intangible Value of a Corporation?” Journal of Marketing, 68 (4), 126-141.
Rappaport, Alfred (1997), Creating Shareholder Value: A Guide for Managers and Investors.
New York: The Free Press.

37
Rust, Roland T., Tim Ambler, Gregory S. Carpenter, V. Kumar, and Rajendra K. Srivastava
(2004), “Measuring Marketing Productivity: Current Knowledge and Future Directions,” Journal
of Marketing, 68 (October), 76-89.
Srinivasan, Raji (2006), “Dual Distribution and Intangible Firm Value: Franchising in Restaurant
Chains,” Journal of Marketing, 70 (3), 120-135.
---- and Sundar Bharadwaj (2004), “Event Studies in Marketing Strategy Research,” in Assessing
Marketing Strategy Performance, Christine Moorman and Donald R. Lehmann, eds. Cambridge,
MA: Marketing Science Institute, 9-28.
Srivastava, Rajendra K., Tasadduq A. Shervani, and Liam Fahey (1998), “Market-based Assets and
Shareholder Value: A Framework for Analysis,” Journal of Marketing, 62 (1), 2-18.
Strong, Norman (1992), “Modeling Abnormal Returns: A Review Article,” Journal of Business,
Finance & Accounting, 19 (4), 533-53.
Sullivan, Mary W. (1998), “How Brand Names Affect the Demand for Twin Automobiles,”
Journal of Marketing Research, 35 (May), 154-165.
Varadarajan, P. Rajan, Mark P. DeFanti, and Paul S. Busch (2006), “Brand Portfolio, Corporate
Image, and Reputation: Managing Brand Deletions,” Journal of the Academy of Marketing
Science, 34 (2), 195-205.
Varaiya, Nikhil P. (1988), “The ‘Winner’s Curse’ Hypothesis and Corporate Takeovers,
Managerial and Decision Economics, 9 (3), 209-219.
Woolridge, J. Randall and Charles C. Snow (1990), “Stock Market Reaction to Strategic
Investment Decisions,” Strategic Management Journal, 11, 353-363.

38

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi