Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 1

ICES Journal of Marine Science, 59: 649.

2002
doi:10.1006/jmsc.2002.1299, available online at http://www.idealibrary.com on

Food for Thought


ITQs and the economics of high-grading
Michael C. S. Kingsley

Kingsley, M. C. S. 2002. ITQs and the economics of high-grading. – ICES Journal of


Marine Science, 59: 649.

Received 11 June 2001; accepted 11 December 2001.


Michael C. S. Kingsley: Greenland Institute of Natural Resources Nuuk, Greenland
[e-mail: mcs@natur.gl]

Individual Transferable Quota (ITQ) are now used as a getting big fish is b, and (1-b) of getting another catch of
management tool in many fisheries. ITQ permit an indi- small fish. The net return on quota used up after
vidual the freedom to allocate resources so as to maximize catching a replacement tonne of fish is therefore the
net return within an individual constraint on catch. The expected value of sales minus the expected costs:
constraint imposed by a collective TAC is an expected
bL + (1-b)S  D  HF  Q
duration of fishing opportunity, and the incentive that
results is to conserve time; under this constraint, resources But a decision to land the small fish already in the hold
would be differently, and perhaps less efficiently, allo- incurs no discard cost and no extra fishing cost, and the
cated. However, as ITQ impose instead an incentive to net return therefore becomes:
conserve quota units they might be expected to increase
SQ
the reward from discarding low-value catches.
Making quota freely negotiable, so they can be Therefore the marginal interest in discarding is:
bought and sold at a price agreed between buyer and
b(L-S)  (D+HF).
seller, gives an additional dimension of freedom and
flexibility to the fishing community. However, I was The first term in this expression is the expected return
recently astonished to be confidently assured by two from high-grading, the second is the expected cost of
experienced fishery scientists that this further step is doing so. Thus, the incentive for high-grading depends
detrimental in that it hugely increases the fisherman’s on the probability of replacing small fish with large, the
incentive to high-grade. price differential, the cost of discarding, and the cost of
The argument advanced to support this view was as the necessary extra fishing; but not on the price paid for
follows: suppose the price paid for quota was $10 kg  1. the quota (Q). This is merely an expression of the
Effective return must be calculated on marginal profit, economic truism that the amount of a sunk cost does not
and so if small fish are worth $12 kg 1 and large $18 affect the relative benefits of future courses of action.
kg 1, the marginal profits are $2 kg 1 and $8 kg 1: large According to this simple model, negotiable ITQ do
fish are worth four times as much as small. Hence, the not increase the marginal benefit of high-grading catch.
incentive to high-grade is powerful and will increase as the This is not to say that ITQ do not give an incentive to
profit margin on small fish decreases. If small fish become high-grade catches; merely that this incentive does not
worth less than the price paid for the quota, the incentive depend on the negotiability or cost of quota.
to high-grade becomes a compulsion: one would be losing In practice, people act on their beliefs, which may be
money by selling fish at such a price. This argument is erroneous. The fallacious reasoning described earlier is
fallacious, according to the following analysis: simple and compelling, and if fishers believe that having
A fisher has caught 1 t of small fish, and must decide paid so much for their quota gives them an overriding
whether to discard it, in the hope of replacing it with reason for high-grading catches, they may do so. However,
more valuable large fish, or land it at the going price. the effects are not necessarily beneficial either to the fish-
The quota cost $Q t 1, small fish at the dock are worth able resource or to their own bank accounts. This problem
$S t 1, and large fish are worth $L t 1. Discarding could be easily addressed by distributing correct infor-
incurs a cost of $D t 1. If the present catch is discarded, mation; but is only aggravated if fishery scientists continue
it will take an estimated H hrs of fishing, at a cost of $F to propagate a fallacy by depreciating the principle of
hr 1, to replace it with another tonne; the chance of negotiable ITQ.

1054–3139/02/080649+01 $30.00/0  2002 International Council for the Exploration of the Sea. Published by Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi