Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 28

American Economic Association

Corruption and Development: A Review of Issues


Author(s): Pranab Bardhan
Source: Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35, No. 3 (Sep., 1997), pp. 1320-1346
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2729979
Accessed: 19/01/2010 04:19

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=aea.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal
of Economic Literature.

http://www.jstor.org
Journal of Economic Literature
Vol. XXXV (September 1997), pp. 1320-1346

Corruption and Development:


A Review of Issues

PRANAB BARDHAN
University of California at Berkeley

I afmgrateful for useful comments on earlier drafts from Jean-Claude Berthelemy, Andrew
Goudie, Mancur Olson, Dani Rodrik, Susan Rose-Ackermnan, and Andrei Shleifer The first
draft of the paper was wvritten for and presented at af meeting of the OECD Development
Center, Paris.

I. Introduction those who are concerned about it, there


can be and have been ways in which a
CORRUPTION IS an ancient problem. In a whole range of policy measures make a
treatise on public administration dating significant dent. In this paper, we start
back to the fourth century B.C. in India, Kau-
with a discussion of some of the alterna-
tiliya writes in his Arthasastra:
tive denotations of the problem of cor-
Just as it is impossible not to taste the honey ruption; we then consider the ways in
(or the poison) that finds itself at the tip of which the damaging consequences of
the tongue, so it is impossible for a govern- corruption operate in the economy,
ment servant not to eat up, at least, a bit of
the king's revenue. Just as fish moving under while not ignoring its possible redeem-
water cannot possibly be found out either as ing features in some cases; we pursue
drinking or not drinking water, so govern- the question of why corruption is per-
ment servants employed in the government ceptibly so different in different socie-
work cannot be found out (while) taking ties; and finally, we examine the feasi-
money (for themselves). (R. P. Kangle 1972,
p. 91)
ble policy issues that arise. Our
approach in this paper is primarily ana-
In a passage of characteristically re- lytical and speculative, given the inher-
markable precision Kautiliya states that ent difficulties of collecting (and hence
there are "forty ways of embezzlement" the nonexistence of) good empirical
and then goes on to enumerate these data on the subject of corruption; we
ways. refer in the Appendix to some subjec-
While corruption in one form or an- tive ordinal rankings of countries in
other has always been with us, it has terms of corruption that are available in
had variegated incidence in different the international media, for whatever
times at different places, with varying they are worth.
degrees of damaging consequences. In common usage the word "corrup-
While the tenacity with which it tends tion" is used to mean different things in
to persist in some cases easily leads to different contexts. Even if we choose to
despair and resignation on the part of confine ourselves only to the economic
1320
Bardhan: Corruption and Development 1321

context, staying away, for example, from bureaucrats of agencies meant to regu-
related issues of political corruption late them). Similarly, one should keep a
(i.e., where the ill-gotten gains are pri- distinction between "immoral" and
marily in terms of political power), "corrupt" transactions. When you pay a
there are alternative denotations of eco- blackmailer, you may consider him im-
nomic corruption. In a majority of cases moral, but you are paying to stop him
such corruption ordinarily refers to the from revealing some information which
use of public office for private gains, may be unpleasant for you but which
where an official (the agent) entrusted may be neither illegal nor corrupt. On
with carrying out a task by the public the other hand, one can think of in-
(the principal) engages in some sort of stances of corruption and bribery which
malfeasance for private enrichment some people may not regard as immoral
which is difficult to monitor for the (particularly those for whom end justi-
principal. There are, of course, many fies means), as when you bribe a police-
everyday cases of other kinds of corrup- man not to torture a suspect. Having
tion some of which may take place en- referred to these alternative meanings
tirely in the private sector. For exam- of even economic corruption, let me
ple, a private seller sometimes rations state that in this paper I shall mostly
the supply of a scarce good (instead of confine myself to the application of
using the price mechanism to clear the this term to imply the use of public
market), and we use various ways of office for private gain or the agency
bribing him or an agent to jump the problem referred to in the preceding
queue (paying a higher price to a paragraph.
"scalper" for a sold-out theater show or Even with this common use of the
a game, tipping a "bouncer" for entry term among economists, there are many
into a crowded nightclub, using "con- ambiguities. Does striving for private
nections," i.e., some form of long- gain include policies that are primarily
run gift exchange, to get a job, and so oriented to increasing the chances for
on). remaining in office? The distinction be-
Sometimes one invokes legality and tween political and economic corrup-
almost interchangeably uses the word tion can get blurred here. Then there
"corrupt" and "illicit" in describing a are problems in common comparative
transaction. But just as clearly not all use of the term in the obvious absence
illegal transactions are corrupt, nor are of any publicly available objective mea-
all instances of corruption or bribery il- sures. A particular African country may
legal1 (as when you tip the maitre d' to be in some sense more corrupt than a
get a better table at a restaurant than particular East Asian country, even
other customers, or in the much more though the actual amount of bribe
important cases of gift-giving by lobby- money exchanging hands may be much
ists to politicians, campaign contribu- larger in the latter; this may be simply
tions to Political Action Committees, or because rampant corruption may have
post-retirement jobs in private firms to choked off large parts of economic
transactions in the former. Then there
1 As Gordon Adams (1981, p 177) notes, the are cases where the bribe per unit of
U.S. Department of Defense directive 55007 al- transaction (and the consequent ineffi-
lows gratuities when they are a part of a "custom- ciency) may be higher (in the case of
ary exchange of social amenities between personal
friends and relatives when motivated by such rela- decentralized corruption, as we shall
tionships and extended on a personal basis." note later) than in situations of central-
1322 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (September 1997)

ized ("one-stop shopping") corruption ding by private firms for a government


where the inefficiency may be less, procurement contract, and the corrupt
even though the total amount of bribe official awards the contract to the high-
paid may be larger. est bidder in bribes, then allocation ef-
ficiency is maintained, as only the low-
II. Effects on Efficiency est-cost firm can afford the largest
bribe. (This, of course, assumes that
There is a strand in the corruption lit- other goals of the program are not vio-
erature, contributed both by economists lated: this bidding procedure is clearly
and noneconomists, suggesting that, in not acceptable in the case of University
the context of pervasive and cumber- admissions, for example.) That the pro-
some regulations in developing coun- ducer surplus lines the pocket of the
tries, corruption may actually improve bureaucrat and does not go to the pub-
efficiency and help growth. Economists lic treasury (as would have happened in
have shown that, in the second-best an open auction for the contract) does
world when there are pre-existing pol- not seemingly affect the allocation effi-
icy induced distortions, additional dis- ciency.
tortions in the form of black-marke- This argument, however, is more
teering, smuggling, etc., may actually complex when a briber does not have
improve welfare even when some re- full information about the cost levels
sources have to be spent in such activi- and therefore the bribing capacity of his
ties. The argument for efficiency-im- competitors, and when he has to take
proving corruption is a simple extension into account strategic considerations in
of this idea. As Nathaniel H. Leff making any particular offer of a bribe.
(1964, p. 11) puts it simply: "if the gov- But the situation can be modeled as an
ernment has erred in its decision, the n-person symmetric game with incom-
course made possible by corruption may plete information on the part of each
well be the better one." As nonecono- player and one can draw upon the the-
mists usually point out, corruption is ory of sealed-bid auctions. In such a
the much-needed grease for the squeak- context Paul J. Beck and Michael W.
ing wheels of a rigid administration. Maher (1986) and Donald H. D. Lien
Samuel P. Huntington (1968, p. 386) (1986) have shown that under the as-
states it bluntly: "In terms of economic sumptions of the model, the lowest-cost
growth, the only thing worse than a firm is always the winner of the con-
society with a rigid, over-centralized, tract, and thus bribery can reproduce
dishonest bureaucracy is one with a the efficiency consequences of competi-
rigid, over-centralized, honest bureauc- tive bidding procedures under imper-
racy. fect information. Inefficiency may, of
Even without pre-existing distortions, course, result if the official is influ-
one may look upon corruption as part of enced by considerations other than just
a Coasean bargaining process in which a the size of the bribe (for example, fa-
bureaucrat (who is in the illicit business voritism for a particular client or nepo-
of selling property rights to a public re- tism); or when the briber can get away
source in the form of issuing permits with supplying a low-quality good at a
and licences) and the private agent (the high-quality price, and the official lets
prospective buyer) may negotiate their in unqualified applicants with a high
way to an efficient outcome. If in a willingness to pay; or when bribery is
bribery game there is competitive bid- used to limit the competition (as in the
Bardhan: Corruption and Development 1323

case of bribing the police or tax inspec- vated by the same common factors. The
tors to harass rival firms).2 distortions are not exogenous to the sys-
Another efficiency argument in favor tem and are instead often part of the
of corruption is to look upon it as built-in corrupt practices of a patron-
"speed money" (for which there are dis- client political system. As we have indi-
tinct terms in different countries, like cated above, bidding procedures in such
lagay in the Philippines), which reduces a system may still end up in allocational
delay in moving files in administrative inefficiency.
offices and in getting ahead in slow- As for speed money, Gunnar Myrdal
moving queues for public services. (1968), citing the 1964 Santhanam
Queuing models which have received Committee on the Prevention of Cor-
some attention in the theoretical litera- ruption appointed by the Government
ture allow the possibility for the corrupt of India, has argued that corrupt offi-
bureaucrat to practice price discrimina- cials may, instead of speeding up, actu-
tion among clients with different time ally cause administrative delays in order
preference. In an interesting equilib- to attract more bribes.3 (I am told that
rium queuing model with some special in Russia there is a clear terminological
assumptions Francis T. Lui (1985) de- distinction between mzdoimstvo, taking
rives bribing functions where the size of a remuneration to do what you are sup-
the bribe (decided by the briber, not posed to do anyway, and likhoimstvo,
the server of the queue) is linked to the taking a remuneration for what you are
opportunity costs of time for the indi- not supposed to do.) Lui's equilibrium
vidual client and shows that the bribing queuing model is meant to question the
strategies will form a Nash equilibrium validity of Myrdal's hypothesis at the
of this noncooperative game that will theoretical level. But, as Jens C. Andvig
minimize the waiting costs associated (1991) points out, from the point of
with the queue, thereby reducing the view of imperfect information and stra-
inefficiency in public administration. tegic considerations queues as alloca-
(The model can also be useful in de- tion mechanisms are more complex and
signing schedules of incentive payments many-sided than has been recognized in
in the pay structure of civil servants.) the literature, and different ways of or-
One does not have to take a moralis- ganizing the queue may give rise to dif-
tic position on corruption to see that ferent outcomes on the average waiting
some of these arguments above in favor time. In Lui's otherwise very interesting
of the efficiency effects of corruption model, for example, both sides in the
are fraught with general problems, even corrupt transaction are honest in the
though in individual instances some re- sense that they stick to a deal, that no
deeming features of corruption may be new bribe offers are made by the wait-
present. For example, in the second- ing clients after the new entrants have
best case made above, it is usually pre- arrived, that there is no moral hazard
sumed that a given set of distortions are about the reliability of the sale by
mitigated or circumvented by the ef- the server of a priority in the queue,
fects of corruption; but quite often and so on. The model's results may not
these distortions and corruption are be robust to these kinds of considera-
caused or at least preserved or aggra- tions.
3 Abhijit Banerjee (1994) examines situations
2 For an account of many such harmful effects where bureaucrats create red tape and use it to
of corruption, see Rose-Ackerman(1996). screen clients of different types.
1324 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (September 1997)

This also suggests the problem with move a file faster, I am not sure if I can
looking upon bribes simply as side pay- help you; but if you want me to stop a
ments in a Coasean bargaining process file I can do it immediately." This abil-
between officials or politicians and ity to "stop a file" at multiple points (a
firms (even apart from the agency prob- system often installed to keep corrupt
lem that the bribee is not representing officials in check) may result in increas-
the interests of the principal, the pub- ing the inefficiency as well as the rate
lic). Of course, the briber and the of bribes. In general centralized corrup-
bribee may fail to agree on the appro- tion has less adverse consequences for
priate size of the bribe on account of efficiency than decentralized bribe-tak-
bargaining in a situation of asymmetric ing, because in the former case the
information and also, there are collec- bribee will internalize some of the dis-
tive action problems when several firms tortionary effects of corruption (assum-
have to get together to bribe a single ing similar powers at all levels to deter-
politician or bureaucrat. But more im- mine the overall rents in the system).
portant than these is the fact, empha- Shleifer and Vishny (1993) illustrate
sized by Maxim Boycko, Shleifer, and this point with an elementary model
Robert Vishny (1995), that corruption comparing a case of independent mo-
contracts are not enforceable in courts nopolists (where different public agen-
and there is many a slip between the cies provide complementary govern-
bribing transaction and the actual deliv- ment goods or services independently)
ery of the good or the service involved. with that of a joint monopolist agency
The control rights on the latter are providing the same goods or services.
often arbitrary and uncertain, leaving a Suppose a customer needs two permits
lot of leeway for the bribee to renege or two complementary inputs from two
on his understanding with the briber, or different agencies in the former case.
to come back and demand another Each agency as an independent monop-
bribe. (It used to be said of General olist will take the other agency's sales as
Noriega of Panama in his heyday that given and so the bureaucrat in charge of
he could not be bought, he could only it will set the bribe-inclusive price in
be rented.) Of course, the bribee may such a way that marginal revenue is
have to worry about his reputation in equal to the marginal cost, the bribe
the long run about keeping promises per unit of sale being the difference be-
(but many corrupt politicians have too tween the price and the monopolist's
short a time horizon), or sometimes the marginal cost (i.e., the official price of
briber can hire hoodlums to discipline the good supplied). The joint monopo-
the bribee (but the transaction costs for list, on the other hand, takes into ac-
such ways of enforcement can be high). count the effect of an extra unit sold on
the sales of the complementary good
A. Centralization of Bribery
and thus on the revenue from bribes
Sometimes the bribee cannot deliver from the other source as well, so that in
not because he wants to cheat, but be- equilibrium the marginal revenue in the
cause there is a multiple veto power supply of each good is less than the
system in operation, which makes cen- marginal cost. Thus the per unit bribe is
tralized collection of bribes in exchange higher and the supply of each good
of guaranteed favors very difficult. One lower in the independent monopolist
high official in New Delhi is reported to case 'than in the case of collusion. Of
have told a friend: "if you want me to course, the aggregate revenue from
Bardhan: Corruption and Development 1325

bribes is larger in the latter case, but performance by most accounts has been
the customer gets a larger supply of much better in Indonesia. Could it be
both inputs. The problem is made much that Indonesian corruption is more cen-
worse when complementarity can be ar- tralized (controlled largely by the first
tificially created (just when you think family and the top military leadership in
you have bribed two agencies to get cahoots with the ethnic Chinese-run
the required two permits, another in- conglomerates) and thus somewhat
dependent monopolist comes along and more predictable, whereas in India it is
tells you that you need a third permit a more fragmented, often anarchic, sys-
from him to get your business in tem of bribery?
place) and corruption opportunities stim- Centralization of the political ma-
ulate the entry of permit-dispensers chine also makes it possible to have a
armed with new regulations. Free entry system approximating "lump-sum" cor-
in this game allows the officials to ruption, without distorting too many de-
"overfish" in the "commons" or the cisions at the margin. It has been sug-
rental havens. gested, for example, that corruption in
Shleifer and Vishny would explain the countries like South Korea5 may have
increase in the inefficiency flowing been more in the form of lump-sum
from corruption in post-Communist contributions by the major business
Russia in comparison with Communist leaders to the president's campaign
Russia in these terms. Formerly, the slush fund, without taxing economic ac-
Communist Party used to centralize the tivity at the margin. The important
collection of bribes and effectively question here is how the ruler can
monitored (sometimes with the help of credibly promise to keep the contribu-
the KGB) deviations from agreed-upon tions lump-sum, and not come back
patterns of corruption. Now different again for individual quid pro quo deals
ministries, agencies, and levels of local at the margin. This ability to credibly
government all set their own bribes in- commit is a feature of "strong" states
dependently in a decentralized attempt that very few developing countries
to maximize their own revenue. It is have.
usually suggested that the regulatory The idea of the differential efficiency
state is at the root of the inefficiency effects of centralized versus decentral-
due to corruption spawned by the regu- ized corruption is akin to Olson's (1993)
lations; the above analysis suggests that idea of smaller distortionary effects of
a weak central government with its in- the tax impositions of the state as a "sta-
ability to stop the setting up of indepen- tionary bandit" (having thus an "encom-
dent corruption rackets (a kind of eco- passing interest" in the domain over
nomic warlordism) makes the problem which its rent-exacting power is exer-
of inefficiency particularly acute. This cised) as opposed to those of the "rov-
may be relevant in a comparison of cor- ing bandit." One may, however, point
ruption in, say, Indonesia with that in out that even centralized corruption is
India. Table 2 in the Appendix suggests more distortionary than taxation (not to
that in the perception of foreign busi- speak of the extra burden of taxes that
nessmen the two countries are about public revenue losses from corruption
equally corrupt;4 and yet the economic
5 It is interesting to note from Appendix Table 1
4 According to Table 1 in the that perceived corruption in Korea in the early
Aptendix, corrup-
tion in Indonesia was perceived to e much worse 1980s is not significantly different from that in
than in India in the early 1980s. Brazil or even India.
1326 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (September 1997)

may necessitate). This is because of the there have been models of barriers to
need to keep corruption secret, as entry in the rent-seeking sector (includ-
Shleifer and Vishny (1993) point out. ing models of dynamic games of moves
Efforts to avoid detection and punish- and counter-moves of the contending
ment cause corruption to be more dis- rent-seekers) and of the various transac-
tortionary than taxation. Because differ- tion costs and risks that the rent-seek-
ent activities have different chances of ers have to face. But what is still
detection for bribes, there will be some astonishing is the extremely small size
substitution effect following from cor- of the usual bribe compared to the rent
ruption by which corrupt officials will collected (Gordon Tullock, 1980, had
try to induce investment and transac- pointed this out quite early, and the
tions in the direction of lower-detection phenomenon is sometimes referred to
activities (or contractors who are less in the public choice literature as the
likely to squeal, even though they may "Tullock paradox"). The anecdotes are
be less efficient). Bureaucrats in poor endless. Tullock (1990) cites the case of
countries may, for example, opt for im- the New York Congressman Mario
ports of complex technology or goods Biaggi, who manipulated the federal
(where detecting improper valuation or government to save from bankruptcy an
overinvoicing is more difficult) in pref- enormous Brooklyn dockyard, for which
erence to more standardized, but possi- he received three Florida vacations
bly more appropriate, technology or worth $3,000. Spiro Agnew had to re-
goods. For similar reasons, allocating sign from the Vice Presidency of the
government funds in a few large de- Nixon Administration for continuing to
fense contracts may look more attrac- take bribes of an incredibly trifling
tive to the officials involved than spend- amount from an arrangement made ear-
ing the money in building numerous lier in his political career. Most such
small rural health clinics. To preserve anecdotes are from democratic polities.
the secrecy of deals, a small elite group On the other hand, there are anecdotes
may also try to raise entry barriers of corrupt income running to billions of
for outsiders, which in many situations dollars for authoritarian rulers in much
has the effect of discouraging the flow poorer countries, like Mobutu sese
of new ideas and innovations. Secret Seko in Zaire or Ferdinand Marcos in
payments, particularly by foreign com- the Philippines. This may point to a par-
panies, also tend to be accumulated ticular coordination problem in bribe
and spent not inside the country but collection in democratic polities that
abroad. Eric Rasmusen and Mark Ramseyer
(1994) have tried to model.
B. Bribes Relative to Rents
They use a coordination game among
Before we leave the subject of costs wealth-maximizing legislators to show
of corruption, it may be useful to com- that, if the latter cannot coordinate
ment on the magnitude of bribes in re- their actions, they may supply private-
lation to that of the rent they are sup- interest statutes for bribes even less
posed to procure for the briber. The than the costs they incur. Only when
early literature on rent-seeking, as in they can enforce agreements with one
Anne 0. Krueger (1974), assumed a another, solving a prisoner's dilemma
process of competitive bidding by the problem, will they come close to col-
rent-seekers which resulted in a com- lecting the full benefits of the statutes
plete dissipation of the rent. Since then they pass. Rasmusen and Ramsayer
Bardhan: Corruption and Development 1327

(1994) have a simple example to illus- It is often said that autocratic rulers
trate the difference between a demo- are more corrupt than democratic ones
cratic and an autocratic government in because the former do not have to
this context. Suppose that private-inter- worry about re-election. (This is not
est statute S14 would provide a benefit quite true as elections have become
of 14 for a lobbyist and would cost an very expensive, and to dispense favors
autocratic government 50 because of, in exchange for campaign contributions
say, an increased probability of public is a major source fof corruption in
discontent or even rebellion. The auto- democratic regimes.) In the example
crat will supply this statute only if of- above, the cost of corruption is deliber-
fered at least 50, which the lobbyist will ately kept the same for both autocratic
be unwilling to offer, so S14 will not and democratic governments, and yet
pass. Suppose that a second statute, the equilibrium bribe amount is larger
S80, would cost the autocrat 50 but under the former. The essential prob-
benefit the lobbyist by 80; the autocrat lem is due to an externality that each
will supply this statute for a bribe any- democratic legislator's vote potentially
where between 50 and 80. imposes on every other legislator, when
Now take a democracy where five they cannot coordinate their votes to
legislators vote on statutes S14 and S80. demand a bribe which compensates
For each statute, each legislator loses 5 them for that externality. In some ac-
by voting "yes" when the others vote tual democratic polities, of course, such
"no," but 10 if the statute passes. The coordination problems are reduced by
government thus loses (again in terms committee systems, disciplined factions
of public discontent) a total of 50 if a and party political machines.6 It is re-
statute passes, exactly the same cost as ported that in the past few decades Ja-
in the case of the autocratic govern- pan's Liberal Democratic Party (par-
ment. Take first the statute S14. If each ticularly its so-called Policy Affairs
legislator thinks that the others will Research Council, where important
vote "no," then all voting "no" will be policies were made and payoffs were
the equilibrium. The lobbyist could coordinated behind closed doors) has
overcome these expectations by offering been quite successful in centralizing
a bribe of 5 to three legislators, but that bribery and raking off billions of dol-
is too costly for him for a statute worth lars' worth in the process.
14. But if each legislator thinks the oth-
ers will vote "yes," then each may as III. The Growth Process
well vote "yes" for an infinitesimally
small bribe, because he will lose 10, no Corruption has its adverse effects not
matter how he votes (so that his mar- just on static efficiency but also on in-
ginal cost of voting "yes" is 0). Thus a vestment and growth. A payment of
democratic government may sell a pri- bribes to get an investment license
vate-interest statute at below cost when clearly reduces the incentive to invest
the autocratic government would not. (even apart from affecting the composi-
Consider now the statute S80. Here too tion of investment, in view of the con-
there is an equilibrium in which the siderations of secrecy and uncertainty
statute passes in the democratic legisla- alluded to in the previous section). One
ture with an infinitesimally small bribe, 6 Rose-Ackerman (1978) has noted that well-or-
when the autocrat would do it only for a ganized legislators may be able to extort larger
large bribe. amounts than disorganized legislators.
1328 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (September 1997)

might add that in the taxation system of dents7 in 70 countries in the early
many countries, negative profits (losses) 1980s, as reported in Table 1 in the Ap-
can be deducted from taxable invest- pendix, Paolo Mauro (1995) finds a sig-
ment income, but there is no corre- nificant negative association between
sponding loss offset in the case of the corruption index and the investment
bribes, so that the latter are particularly rate or the rate of growth (even after
harmful for risk-taking in the context of controlling for some other determinants
innovation. of the latter, and correcting for a possi-
Similarly, when public resources ble endogeneity bias in the data). A
meant for building productivity-enhanc- one-standard-deviation improvement in
ing infrastructure are diverted for poli- the corruption index is estimated to be
ticians' private consumption (cement associated with an increase in the in-
for public roads or dams used for luxury vestment rate by about 3 percent of
homes) growth rates obviously will be GDP.8 The negative relation seems to
affected adversely. Another growth ef- hold even in subsamples of countries
fect follows from the fact that higher where bureaucratic regulations are re-
bribes imply declining profitability on ported to be cumbersome, indicating
productive investments relative to rent- that corruption as a way of by-passing
seeking investments, thus tending to these regulations may not have been
crowd out the former. As Kevin Mur- very beneficial.
phy, Shleifer, and Vishny (1993) point Historians, of course, point to many
out, there are many reasons why there cases when a great deal of corruption in
are increasing returns to rent-seeking, dispensing licenses, or loans, or mining
so that an increase in rent-seeking low- and land concessions has been associ-
ers the cost of further rent-seeking rela- ated with (and may have even helped
tive to that of productive investment. In in) the emergence of an entrepreneurial
general when there is slow growth the class. In European history the latter
returns to entrepreneurship (particu- class grew out of the sales of monopoly
larly in production of new goods) fall rights, tax farms, and other forms of
relative to those to rent-seeking, and privileged access to public resources. In
the ensuing increase in the pace of the U.S. "gilded age" of 1860s and
rent-seeking activities further slows 1870s widespread corruption of state
down growth. Besides, innovators are legislatures and city governments by
particularly at the mercy of corrupt business interests and those seeking
public officials, because new producers franchises for public utilities is reported
need government-supplied goods like to have helped rather than hindered
permits and licenses more than estab-
7One problem with this data set is that it is
lished producers. In-any case, as Romer based on the perception of foreign businessmen
(1994) has suggested, corruption as a whose experience of corruption may be different
tax on ex post profits may in general sti- from what domestic businessmen face in a coun-
try. The former may have less insider knowledge
fle entry of new goods or technology about the intricacies of the indigenous bureauc-
which require an initial fixed cost in- racy and even less patience with its slow pro-
vestment. cesses. So they may end up paying much larger
bribes than what the latter settle for at the end of
Some of these growth effects have long negotiations and endless cups of coffee in fa-
been statistically corroborated from miliar terrain. This discrepancy may vary from
cross-country data. On the basis of cor- country to country and thus bias the results of sta-
tistical' analysis on the basis of this data set.
ruption rankings data assembled from 8 These results are confirmed in Mauro (forthcoming)
the Business International correspon- with a larger and more up to date data set.
Bardhan: Corruption and Development 1329

economic growth.9 More generally, cor- linearities in this relationship: in par-


ruption may have historically played ticular, in some countries with the pro-
some role in undermining the sway of cess of modernization and growth cor-
collective passions that used to fuel in- ruption may have got worse for some
ternecine group warfare. As Ronald time before getting better. What kind
Wraith and Edgar Simpkins (1963, p. of forces work toward possibly increas-
60) say of English history: "For two ing corruption at the earlier stages of
hundred and fifty years before 1688, economic growth? As the economy ex-
Englishmen had been killing each other pands and becomes more complex, pub-
to obtain power.... The settlements of lic officials see more opportunities for
1660 and 1688 inaugurated the Age of making money from their decisions,
Reason, and substituted a system of pa- which now go beyond simple functions
tronage, bribery, and corruption for the like maintaining law and order and col-
previous method of bloodletting." In lecting land revenue. As the markets in
this century, the highly corrupt system many new products are "thin" for quite
institutionalized in the PRI enabled some time, this gives scope for those of-
Mexico to transcend the decade of ficials to milk the process of granting
bloodletting that followed the Revolu- monopoly rights and franchises. In the
tion. Without denying the positive role process of transition from controlled to
that corruption may have played in his- market economy in Eastern Europe,
tory in some situations, in many devel- China, and Vietnam it has often been
oping countries today, however, corrup- observed that there are some special
tion is perceived to be so pervasive and factors increasing corruption even as in-
endemic that it is unlikely to have good come grows. For a considerable period
net effects, on grounds that we have of time the transition economy is on a
discussed earlier in this section and be- dual-track system: a part of output is
cause corruption tends to feed on itself still under obligatory delivery at con-
(as we shall discuss in the next section) trolled prices, while the rest is allowed
and it is impossible to confine corrup- to be sold at market prices. This creates
tion to areas, if any, of relative benefi- all kinds of new opportunities for cor-
cial effects. ruption. The process of privatization of
What about the effects of the growth state-owned enterprises in many coun-
process on the extent of corruption? Al- tries has also given rise to opportunities
though the requisite time-series evi- for public officials to get kickbacks
dence in terms of hard data is absent, from "crony capitalist" buyers of those
circumstantial evidence suggests that enterprises and contractors.
over the last 100 years or so corruption Yet, it is probably correct to say that
has generally declined with economic the process of economic growth ulti-
growth in most rich countries (and in mately generates enough forces to re-
some developing countries, like Singa- duce corruption. Rewards to entrepre-
pore, it is reported to have declined neurship and productive investment
quite fast in recent decades). While the relative to rent-seeking investment rise
historical relationship between eco- when there is sustained growth. A pros-
nomic growth and corruption is thus pering economy can also afford to pay
likely to have been negative in general, its civil servants well, reducing their
it is possible to envisage some non- motivation for corruption. And to the
extent prosperity in the long run brings
9 See Robin Theobald (1990) for a discussion. more demand, at least on the part of
1330 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (September 1997)

the middle classes, for democratic re- (based on the Business International
forms, the latter may install institutions survey data for the early 1980s), it can-
that check corruption. Not merely is the not explain why corruption is supposed
coordination problem in bribe-collec- to be so much more in Mexico than in,
tion among legislators rendered more say, South Korea or Taiwan in the early
difficult under democracy, as we have 1980s (when in the latter countries the
discussed at the end of the preceding state was not much less interventionist
section, but, more important, demo- than in Mexico).
cratic institutions build mechanisms of Another common explanation of dif-
accountability and transparency at dif- ferential corruption, popular among so-
ferent levels which make it difficult for ciologists, is that social norms are very
the networks of corruption to be sus- different in different countries. What is
tained for long. A qualifier to this argu- regarded in one culture as corrupt may
ment relates, as we have noted before, be considered a part of routine transac-
to campaign finance in democratic elec- tion in another. (Visiting Westerners
tions which leads to influence peddling are often aghast that an Asian or an Af-
on the part of politicians. Thus while rican will sometimes not carry out his
rich democracies have been quite suc- ordinary service without baksheesh or
cessful in better enforcement of laws, tips; the latter, on the other hand, finds
they have been in some cases less suc- the high degree of monetization even in
cessful in reducing the influence of personal transactions in advanced capi-
money on the process of enactment of talist countries somehow "corrupt.")
those laws. But a more important issue is involved.
It is widely recognized that in develop-
IV. Factors Behind Differential ing countries gift-exchange is a major
Incidence and Persistence social norm in business transactions,
and allegiance to kinship-based or clan-
We now turn to the question of why based loyalties often takes precedence
the incidence of corruption is so palpa- over public duties even for salaried
bly different in different countries and public officials. Under such circum-
the related question of why in some stances use of public resources to cater
cases corruption is so persistent. Lib- to particularistic loyalties become quite
eral economists, of course, have an easy common and routinely expected. At the
answer to this: it is the regulatory state same time, it will be wrong to suggest
with its elaborate system of permits and that concern about public corruption is
licences that spawns corruption, and peculiarly Western. In most of the same
different countries with different de- developing countries, public opinion
grees of insertion of the regulatory state polls indicate that corruption is usually
in the economy give rise to varying at the top of the list of problems cited
amounts of corruption. This explanation by respondents. But there is a certain
is no doubt valid to a large extent, but schizophrenia in this voicing of con-
inadequate. It cannot, for example, ex- cern: the same people who are most vo-
plain why corruption, in the judgment cal and genuinely worried about wide-
of many perceptive observers, may have spread corruption and fraud in the
increased in post-Communist Russia or public arena do not hesitate at all in
in China after the onset of the market abusing public resources when it comes
reforms in recent years. Comparing to helping out people belonging to their
across countries in Appendix Table 1 own kinship network. (It is a bit like the
Bardhan: Corruption and Development 1331
M Curve
A

NCurve \\l

Figure 1.

U.S. Congressmen who are usually livid favorable to corruption"). A more satis-
about the rampant pork-barrel politics factory explanation on these lines has to
they see all around them but they will go into how otherwise similar countries
fiercely protect the "pork" they bring to (or regions in the same country like
their own constituency.) Edward C. North and South in Italy) may settle
Banfield (1958) comments on the preva- with different social norms in equilib-
lence of what he calls "amoral familism" rium in, say, a repeated game frame-
in the Mezzogiorno in Italy, but Robert work, and how a country may some-
Putnam (1993) observes in his study of times shift from one equilibrium into
comparative civicness in the regions of another (as has happened in the case of
Italy that the amoral individuals in the today's developed countries in recent
less civic regions clamor most for history with respect to corruption).
sterner law enforcement. Mayfair Yang The idea of multiple equilibria in the
(1989) notes how people in China gen- incidence of corruption is salient in
erally condemn the widespread use of some of the recent economic theorists'
guanxi (connections) in securing public explanations. The basic idea is that cor-
resources, but at the same time admire ruption represents an example of what
the ingenuity of individual exploits are called frequency-dependent equilib-
among their acquaintances in its use. ria, and our expected gain from corrup-
A major problem with norm-based ex- tion depends crucially on the number of
planations is that they can very easily be other people we expect to be corrupt.
near-tautological ("a country has more At a very simple level the idea may be
corruption because its norms are more illustrated, as in Andvig (1991), with a
1332 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (September 1997)

so-called Schelling diagram shown in librium C; if the initial average corrup-


Figure 1. The distance between the ori- tion is low, the economy gravitates to-
gin and any point on the horizontal axis ward the honest equilibrium A. The dia-
represents the proportion of a given to- gram illustrates in an elementary way
tal number of officials (or transactions) how two otherwise similar countries
that is known to be corrupt, so that the (both in socio-economic structures and
point of origin is when no one is cor- in moral attitudes) may end up with two
rupt, and the end-point n is when every- very different equilibrium levels of cor-
one is corrupt. The curves M and N rep- ruption; also, how small changes may
resent the marginal benefit for a have a large impact on corruption if one
corrupt and an honest official respec- starts out at points close to B.
tively for all different allocations of the The problem with such simple dia-
remaining officials in the two catego- grams is that the mechanisms through
ries. The way the curve N is drawn, the which the economy reaches one or the
benefit of an honest official is higher other equilibrium are not fully spelled
than that of a corrupt official when very out. There are now several theoretical
few officials are corrupt, but it declines models in the literature which try to do
as the proportion of corrupt officials that rigorously, and also get away from
increases and ultimately becomes even the naive informational presumptions
negative when almost all others are implicit in the diagram. We shall briefly
corrupt. The M curve goes up at the touch upon the main ideas in a few of
beginning when more and more offi- them. Olivier Cadot (1987) has a model
cials are corrupt (for the marginal of corruption as a gamble, where every
corrupt official lower reputation loss time an official asks for a bribe in a bi-
when detected, lower chance of detec- lateral situation, there is a risk of being
tion, lower search cost in finding a reported to and sacked by a superior of-
briber, etc.), but ultimately declines ficer. The optimal Nash strategy of a
(when the size of bribe is bid down by corrupt official is derived under alterna-
too many competing bribers, for exam- tive assumptions about the information
ple), even though at the end-pont the structure. The comparative-static re-
pay-off for a corrupt official remains sults show that a higher time discount
positive. rate, a lower degree of risk-aversion,
In Figure 1 there are three equilib- and a lower wage rate will induce him,
rium points, A, B, and C. A and C are under certain conditions, to be more
stable, but B is not. At point A all are corrupt. Then Cadot goes on to intro-
honest and it does not pay to be cor- duce corruption also at the level of the
rupt. At C all are corrupt, and it does superior officer who can be bribed (be-
not pay to be honest. At B, any given yond a certain threshold) to cover up
official is indifferent (between being lower-level corruption. The interaction
corrupt and honest) but if only one of corruption at different hierarchical
more official is corrupt it pays to be- levels of administration leads to multi-
come corrupt; on the other hand, if one ple equilibria (one with only petty cor-
fewer is corrupt, the marginal official ruption and the other with more perva-
will choose to be honest. So initial con- sive corruption), as the probability of
ditions are important: if the economy being sacked diminishes with the gen-
starts with (or gets jolted into) a high eral level of corruption in the civil ser-
average level of corruption it will move vice, and corruption at each level feeds
toward the high-corruption stable equi- on the other. In the rent-seeking litera-
Bardhan: Corruption and Development 1333

ture also it has been pointed out by action is corrupt. Corrupt (noncorrupt)
Arye L. Hillman and Eliakim Katz agents would prefer meeting agents on
(1987) that there are extra social costs the other side of the transaction who
when there is a hierarchical structure are similarly corrupt (noncorrupt). For
such that a lowly customs official is each corrupt agent they meet, they will
obliged to pay a part of his take of revise upwards their subjective prob-
bribes to a superior. The usual pre- ability estimates of meeting corrupt
sumption of that literature-which is, as people, and are more likely to initiate a
we have seen, in any case question- corrupt act in the next period. This is
able-that bribes used in contesting a how beliefs about the nature of an eco-
rent do not entail a social cost because nomic environment one faces formed
they are only transfers, is seriously viti- on the basis of one's past experience of
ated when one takes into account multi- dealing with that environment feeds
tiered rent-seeking, with the official po- into the perpetuation of a culture of
sitions to which the bribes accrue are corruption. Again, there are multiple
themselves contested with real re- equilibria and two economies with an
sources. identical set of parameters can have sig-
Andvig and Karl 0. Moene (1990) in nificantly different levels of corruption;
their model assume, as in Cadot (1987), the particular steady state to which the
that the expected punishment for cor- economy settles is influenced by the
ruption when detected declines as more history of the economy preceding the
officials become corrupt, because it is steady state.
cheaper to be discovered by a corrupt Sah's model admits the possibility
rather than a noncorrupt superior. that sometimes there may be discrepan-
There is a bell-shaped frequency distri- cies between beliefs about corruption
bution of officials with respect to their frequency and its actual incidence.
costs of supplying corrupt services. On Philip Oldenburg's (1987) account of
the demand side the potential bribers' the land consolidation program in vil-
demand for corrupt services decreases lages in U.P. in Northern India provides
as the bribe size increases and as the an interesting case study in this context.
fraction of officials who are corrupt de- A land consolidation program involves a
creases (raising the search cost for a po- major reorganization of the mapping of
tential bribee). This model generates the existing cultivation plots, their valu-
two stable stationary equilibria of the ation and carving out of new plots in a
Nash type and highlights how the prof- village, and thus provides a lot of scope
itability of corruption is positively re- for corruption for the petty officials in
lated to its frequency and how tempo- charge. But Oldenburg's field investiga-
rary shifts may lead to permanent tions found very little evidence of ac-
changes in corruption. tual official corruption. Complaints of
Raaj Sah (1988) has a model of cor- corruption usually came from farmers
ruption with intertemporal behavioral who had not got precisely what they
externalities in the context of overlap- wanted, and did not understand the
ping generations and a Bayesian learn- process fully, and so assumed that other
ing process in belief formation. The bu- farmers who in their perception did
reaucrats and citizens both start off better must have bribed to get their
with a subjective probability distribu- way. Bribes were often paid to a mid-
tion which tells them how likely it is dleman, who pocketed the money while
that the agent they will meet in a trans- telling the villagers that it was primarily
1334 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (September 1997)

meant to bribe the Assistant Consolida- paign) may have no lasting effect: it
tion Officer. (He even made a show of may take a minimum number of periods
paying a visit to the Officer.) There may without corruption to return to a path
actually be more corruption in other leading to the low-corruption steady
cases, but Oldenburg makes a valid state.
point that the middlemen in general We have discussed in this section the
have a vested interest in spreading reasons for the persistence of corrup-
(dis)information that "nothing gets tion that have to do with frequency-de-
done without bribing the Officials," and pendent equilibria or intertemporal ex-
when everybody believes that, it may ternalities. Let us end it by referring to
even have the effect of inducing an offi- a simpler reason for persistence in the
cial to indulge in corruption, as he is case of some types of corruption. There
assumed to be corrupt anyway. This are many cases where corruption is mu-
is a familiar self-fulfilling equilibrium tually beneficial between the official
of corruption.10 (The middleman's and his client, so neither the briber nor
role in corruption is similar to what the bribee has an incentive to report or
Diego Gambetta (1988, p. 173) ob- protest, for example, when a customs
serves in his study of the Italian Mafia: officer lets contraband through, or a tax
"the mafioso himself has an interest auditor purposely overlooks a case of
in regulated injections of distrust into tax evasion, and so on. Shleifer and
the market to increase the demand for Vishny (1993) call it corruption with
the product he sells-that is, protec- theft (a better name may be collusive
tion.") corruption), to distinguish it from cases
In an overlapping generations frame- where the official does not hide the
work with dynamic complementarity be- transaction in which the client pays the
tween past and future reputation Jean requisite price, fee, or fine to the gov-
Tirole (1996) has argued that the per- ernment, but only charges something
sistence of corruption in a society may extra for himself, what Shleifer and
be explained partly by the bad collec- Vishny call corruption without theft.
tive reputation of previous generations: The former type is more insidious, diffi-
younger generations may inherit the cult to detect and therefore more per-
reputation of their elders with the con- sistent. One should add that this type
sequence that they may have no incen- also includes many cases of official re-
tive to be honest themselves. This laxation of quality control standards, in
means, if for some temporary reasons inspection of safety in construction of
(say, due to a war or some other disrup- buildings and bridges or in supplies of
tion in the economic system) corruption food and drugs, in pollution control,
in an economy increases, it has lasting etc.
effects: collective reputation once shat-
tered is difficult to rebuild. Similarly, a V. Policy Issues
one-shot reduction in corruption
(through, say, an anti-corruption cam- We now turn to policy issues arising
from our analysis above. We shall in
lo Myrdal (1968, pp 408-09) quotes Prime Min- general avoid paying much attention to
ister Nehru: "Merely shouting from the house- the policy positions taken by the "mor-
tops that everybody is corrupt creates an atmos- alists" and the "fatalists" on corruption,
phere of corruption. People feel they live in a
climate of corruption and they get corrupted even though it is sometimes tempting to
themselves." take their side. The "moralists"empha-
Bardhan: Corruption and Development 1335

size that without fundamental changes prohibited or controlled. As Klitgaard


in values and norms of honesty in public (1988) notes, when Hong Kong legal-
life-a kind of ethic cleansing through ized off-track betting, police corruption
active moral reform campaigns-no big fell significantly, and as Singapore al-
dent in the corrosive effects of corrup- lowed more imported products duty
tion is likely to be achieved. The "fatal- free, corruption in customs went down.
ists" are more cynical, that we have Sometimes, however, turning over a
reached a point of no return in many government agency's functions to the
developing countries, the corruption is market implies essentially a shift from a
so pervasive and well entrenched that public monopoly to a private monopoly,
for all practical purposes nothing much with a corresponding transfer of the
can be done about it. Our discussion in rent,1"but without much of an improve-
the last section on the history-depen- ment in allocational efficiency (except
dence of the high-corruption equilib- that due to a removal of the distortion
rium and the forces that tend to per- caused by secrecy discussed in Section
petuate it does point to the difficulties II).
of getting out of the rut, but there exist While regulations designed primarily
some examples of success in controlling to serve the patronage-dispensing
corruption even in the recent history of power of politicians and bureaucrats are
developing countries: Robert Klitgaard common, there are many regulations
(1988) cites several examples, of which which serve some other valued social
the cases of the Hong Kong Police De- objectives, and there may be a tradeoff
partment and the Singapore Customs between these objectives and that of re-
and Excise Department are the most ducing corruption through deregula-
successful, but in some sense the valiant tion. Suppose a scarce but essential
efforts by one tax commissioner to fight consumer good (like food) in a poor
pervasive corruption in the Bureau of country is currently rationed by the gov-
Internal Revenue and the substantial ernment so that the poor people can
impact he made in the 1970s in a hope- have some access to it. The rations are
lessly corrupt country like the Philip- administered by corrupt officials. What
pines under Marcos provide the most will be the welfare consequences for
striking case. Without minimizing the the poor of replacing this system by the
importance of moral exhortations in market?12 To simplify, let us assume
anti-corruption campaigns, our focus that the government is the only source
here will be on incentive structures that of food under the rationing scheme,
may induce even opportunists to forego that food obtained under ration cannot
corrupt practices and the general prob- be resold, and that corruption takes the
lems and prospects of implementing form of the official charging a price
them. higher than the stipulated ration price.
The first point that is commonly In Figure 2 the ration price p is given
made, no doubt with a great deal of jus- by the slope of AB and the consumer's
tification, is that regulations and bu- income by OA. The ration, x, is binding
reaucratic allocation of scarce public re-
11The histor of privatization in the last few
sources breed corruption, and so the yearsin manydevelopingcountriesis repletewith
immediate task is to get rid of them. In instancesof corrupttransfersto croniesof politi-
some sense the simplest and the most cians.
12Fora taxonomicanalysis
of differentcasesforthis
radical way of eliminating corruption is question,see PeterJ. Gordon(1994).The ideaof Figure
to legalize the activity that was formerly 2 is due to T. N. Srinivasan.
1336 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (September 1997)

Income I'

0 -

X C X X B Food

Figure 2.

in the sense that the consumer with his is driven to by the corrupt official as the
income OA and ration price p would ration is reduced from x to zero, be-
like to buy x which is more than Y. If cause at each point on the locus the
there were no corruption his rationed slope of the indifference curve repre-
consumption equilibrium will be at sents the maximum price the consumer
some point G on the line AB to the left is willing to pay for the associated ra-
of D. Suppose the alternative nonra- tion. As long as the ration exceeds x',
tioned market equilibrium is given by the consumer will prefer the corrupt ra-
point E, where the market price line, tion scheme to the market system. The
which is the slope of AC, is tangent to basic point is simple, although it can be
indifference curve F', and the consump- made with more complicated models,
tion is given by x'. As long as G is to the and should be brought to the attention
right of F (where the indifference curve of those who in their zeal for deregula-
through E intersects AB), the consumer tion and the market system with a view
prefers the uncorrupt ration scheme to to reducing corruption lose sight of
the market system. Now suppose the the social objective that the regulation
corrupt official charges a price higher was supposed to serve. (It is not an
than the ration price while distributing accident that getting rid of the corrupt
a stipulated total amount of food. The public distribution systems in food
broken curve in Figure 1 is the locus of under structural adjustment programs
points of tangency on the indifference in developing countries has been
map as the price line is rotated with A politically so unpopular.) In general
as its focus starting at AB and converg- the literature on corruption often
ing to the vertical axis. It is easy to see overlooks the distributional implica-
that this locus is also the locus of con- tions of corruption (apart from noting
sumption points to which the consumer that the poor do not have the resources
Bardhan: Corruption and Development 1337

or the "connections" to be able to bribe In case of legitimate business projects,


their way through). 13 however, this raises the multiple veto
One way of reducing bureaucratic power problem discussed in Section II.
corruption is to reduce the monopoly In some cases, on account of large
power of the bureaucrat when a client fixed costs, indivisibilities, and coordi-
faces her in trying to get a licence or nation problems, bureaucratic competi-
some subsidy or transfer. Rose-Acker- tion through overlapping jurisdictions is
man (1978) has suggested that, instead not feasible (nor desirable, if bargaining
of giving each official a clearly defined advantages are to be pressed), as in the
sphere of influence over which she has case of large defense contracts or when
monopoly control, officials should be the government buys in bulk in world
given competing jurisdictions so that a commodity markets (say, in petroleum)
client who is not well-served by one of- or expensive single items like aircrafts.
ficial can go to another. When collusion Not surprisingly, some of the major cor-
among several officials is difficult, com- ruption scandals in developing coun-
petition will tend to drive the level of tries (with substantial kickbacks from
bribes to zero. Of course, without an foreign contractors) involve politicians
appropriate incentive payment system, and bureaucrats in charge of such large
this can encourage laziness in some offi- procurement cases. On the bribe-givers'
cials, because clients who are tired of side it should be noted that when com-
waiting can turn to another official, in- petition among the foreign contractors
stead of complaining to the official's su- is intense, very few governments of in-
perior. Also, in cases of what Shleifer dustrially advanced countries discourage
and Vishny (1993) call corruption with the bribing of officials in the purchasing
theft, competitive pressure might in- countries (in fact tax-deductibility of
crease theft from the government (in- bribes by the companies often makes the
cluding relaxation of minimum quality tax-payers complicit in the payment of
standards) at the same time as it re- such bribes). Even in the exceptional
duces bribes. So in such cases, competi- case of the U.S. where there is the 1977
tion in the provision of government ser- Foreign Corrupt Practices Act forbid-
vices has to be accompanied by more ding American companies from making
intensive monitoring and auditing to payments to foreign officials, what are
prevent theft. Rose-Ackerman (1994) described as "grease payments" to speed
has suggested that multiple officials up transactionsare not ruled out. (In fact,
with overlapping jurisdictions may also the 1988 amendments to the Act expand
help in such cases, because the poten- the range of such payments allowed.)
tial briber has to face the prospect of Many countries launch periodic
"persuading" all the officials involved, "spring-cleaning" through anticorrup-
which raises costs and uncertainty for the tion campaigns. How effective are they?
corrupt project. (It has been reported It varies from situation to situation. To
that in the United States the overlap- be effective, they have to be credible
ping involvement of local, state, and and sustained. As suggested by the fre-
federal agencies in controlling illegal quency-dependent equilibrium models,
drugs has reduced police corruption.) a critical mass of opportunist individu-
als have to be convinced over a long
13 In some cases the poor may not be completely
enough period that corruption is not cost
left out. They get the rationed good after waiting
in line (unless the good is extremely scarce), while effective. But as has happened many
the rich bribe to jump the queue. times in the recent history of Africa or
1338 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (September 1997)

China, anticorruption campaigns are ments (using vouchers and competition


usually ad hoc, and targeted at political with private suppliers to serve a public
enemies or at best at small fry, exempt- need when customers can "vote" with
ing the big fish, or the important cro- their feet) and concentrating these
nies and accomplices of the political functions largely in areas where, on ac-
rulers. Short-lived campaigns and re- count of elements of natural monopoly
peated amnesties to offenders (de- or a public good or quality standards
signed to wipe the slate clean) only in- not easily discernible to the custom-
crease the cynicism about the next ers, a voucher plan is not an efficient
round and give out the wrong signals. way of providing the service; making su-
As we have discussed in connection pervisors answerable for gross acts of
with Tirole's (1996) intertemporal col- malfeasance by their subordinates; well-
lective reputation model, trust takes established procedures of encourag-
several periods to reestablish itself. What ing "whistle-blowers" and guaranteeing
is important is to institutionalize various their anonymity; authorization of peri-
kinds of accountability mechanisms (like odic probing of ostensible but "unex-
an independent office of public audit- plainable assets" of officials; working in
ing, an election commission to limit and teams (for example, in Singapore cus-
enforce rules on campaign contributions toms agents were asked to work in
in democratic elections, independent pairs) when lower bureaucrats face a
investigating agencies (like the Hong customer instead of one-on-one so that
Kong Independent Committee against there is some check in the bargaining
Corruption which directly reports to the process (this is a simpler form of the
Governor General), an office of local overlapping jurisdictions case discussed
ombudsman with some control over the above); well-defined career paths in
bureaucracy, citizens' watchdog commit- civil service that are not dependent on
tees providing information and monitor- the incumbent politicians' favor; peri-
ing services and pursuing public-inter- odic job rotation so that a bureaucrat
est litigation, a vigorous and independent, does not become too cosy with a cus-
even muckraking, press, less stringent tomer over a long period; a more elabo-
libel laws or laws protecting official se- rate codification of civil service rules
crecy, etc.).14 For the watchdog com- reducing the official's discretion in
mittees it is important not merely to un- granting favors; and so on. Of course, in
earth and publicize egregious cases of many of these cases one can also argue
public corruption, but also to highlight on the opposite side. Too many rules
credible cases where the automatic and rather than discretion may have the per-
cynical presumption of the local people verse effect of providing opportunities
that the officials are corrupt turns out for corruption simply to circumvent
to be gross exaggerations, thus cutting mindless inflexibilities. The practice of
down on the feedback effects of rumors frequent job rotation may provide an in-
and designs of middlemen. centive to officials for maximum loot'5
Many other measures of reform in the shortest possible time, discourage
within public administration have been
15 In Robert Wade's (1985) case study in South
suggested: cutting down on the prolifer- India, an Executive Engineer in charge of irriga-
ating functions of government depart- tion may pay as bribe up to 14 times his annual
salary. in order to obtain a two-year tenure at a
14 For a discussion of some of the "countervail- particular location. This suggests the lower bound
ing actions" that victims of corruption can under- of how much he expects to earn in bribes in two
take, see M. Shahid Alam (1995). years.
Bardhan: Corruption and Development 1339

learning on the job, and in general pro- the efficiency wage theory. The poten-
vide the politician (or the senior offi- tial cost of job loss (including the wage
cer) a weapon to transfer an honest offi- premium and seniority benefits) on de-
cial bent on rocking the boat of existing tection may stiffen official resistance to
patronage distribution. The opportunity temptation for corruption. International
to probe the private finances of an offi- agencies pushing for structural adjust-
cial is sometimes abused against rivals ment policies sometimes ignore that,
and political opponents. Working on teams while deregulation reduces opportuni-
in facing a customer may sometimes en- ties for corruption, another part of the
courage unnecessary delays or collusion same policy package aimed at drastic re-
in demands for larger bribes. And so on. ductions of public spending may result
in lower real wages for civil servants in-
VI. Incentive Payments for Civil creasing their motivation for corrup-
Servants tion. One should also keep in mind that
when today's rich countries had beaten
Let us now turn to the important pol- the worst of corruption in their history,
icy issue of an incentive pay structure in the average salary of an official was
public administration that is often cited many times that of what obtains in most
as one of the most effective ways of poor countries.
fighting corruption. In imperial China While the argument for incentive
under the Ch'ing dynasty district magis- payment is clear, the relationship be-
trates were paid an extra allowance tween public compensation policy and
called yang-lien yin ("money to nourish corruption can sometimes be quite
honesty"). Klitgaard (1988, p. 81) cites complex. This is because our objective
a quote from the historian Macaulay's is not merely to reduce corruption in an
account of Robert Clive's attempt to re- official agency but, at the same time,
duce the corruption rampant in the not to harm the objective for which the
British East India Company in 1765: agency was deployed in the first place.
"Clive saw clearly that it was absurd to Much of the theory of rent-seeking does
give men power, and to require them to not worry about this, because the pre-
live in penury. He justly concluded that sumption often is that government is
no reform could be effectual which nothing but organized theft and the less
should not be coupled with a plan for of it the better. But, as we have already
liberally remunerating the civil servants seen in the case of rationed distribution
of the Company." In recent times both of food to the poor, if we have another
Singapore and Hong Kong have fol- valued social objective, there may be
lowed an incentive wage policy for pub- cases where the corrupt administered
lic officials with a great deal of success. system is preferable to the market. We
Current reforms in tax enforcement in shall now discuss the compensation pol-
many countries, which include a bonus icy for corruptible enforcers of a regula-
to the tax officer based on the amount tion when the latter has a valued social
of taxes he or she collects, have often purpose. Let us take, for example, the
been associated with significant im- case of public inspectors charged with
provements in tax compliance (see, for monitoring pollution from a factory. We
example, Dilip Mookerjee 1995). In shall follow the theoretical model of
some cases (like in Singapore) a wage Mookherjee and I. P. L. Png (1995) to
premium above private sector salaries understand the nature of the tradeoff
has been found useful, consistent with among corruption, pollution, and en-
1340 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (September 1997)

forcement effort and consider the con- it takes a sufficiently large, discrete, in-
sequences of strategic interaction be- crease in the reward or the penalty to
tween the polluting factory and the cor- eliminate corruption (when the inspec-
ruptible inspector. tor's demand for bribe rises beyond the
Suppose the regulator can directly factory's willingness to pay). One way to
control neither the inspector's monitor- reduce the bribe, however, is to raise q,
ing effort nor his underreporting of the the penalty on the bribe-giver (making
factory's pollution for which he gets bribing more costly for him), while re-
bribed, a double moral hazard problem ducing the penalty p for the bribe-taker
in a principal-agent model. The regula- (so that the latter does not demand a
tor has three instruments: a rate of re- larger bribe): this contrasts with the
ward r for the inspector (a percentage typical practice of punishing bribe-giv-
commission based on the fines for pol- ers less severely than bribe-takers.
lution collected from the factory), a What effect does the compensation
penalty p (depending on the amount of policy have from the point of view of
underreporting of pollution) on the in- the primary objective of regulating pol-
spector when corruption is discovered, lution? A small increase in the reward
and a penalty q (a mark-up over the rate r, by raising the bribe and hence
usual fine for the evaded pollution ) on the price of pollution will lower the in-
the factory for bribing the inspector. centive for the factory to pollute. The
The probability that the inspector will larger bribe will increase the inspector's
unearth the factory's true pollution incentive to monitor, further deterring
level (assuming, of course, that he will the factory. The reduction in pollution,
not overreport) depends on the moni- on the other hand, will discourage the
toring effort exerted by the inspector. inspector from monitoring. In equilib-
There is also an exogenous probability rium the net effect is to reduce pollu-
that the inspector's underreporting and tion. By contrast, when the regulator
the bribe paid are discovered by the raises the penalty rate p on the inspec-
regulator. Given the regulator's policy tor, this will reduce his incentive to
package (r, p, q), the factory and the monitor; the reduction in monitoring
inspector simultaneously choose the can reduce the expected penalty for
pollution level and the monitoring in- pollution for the factory, and hence the
tensity respectively. The two parties result may be more pollution. Thus al-
(assumed risk-neutral) then jointly de- though the inspector is risk-neutral, the
termine the bribe, if any, as part of a carrot (reward for reporting pollution)
Nash bargaining solution. and the stick (penalty for taking a
Suppose the factory has polluted and bribe) can have opposite effects on the
the inspector has found out about it. If level of pollution. All this is not to dis-
bribery is going on, then small increases courage a suitable incentive payment
in r or p may merely raise the level of system in the context of corruption but
the bribe: a compensation policy to point to the nature of complexities
whereby the larger reward for the in- involved.16 The analysis also suggests
spector or a higher penalty for taking a
bribe, raises the cost borne by the in- 16 Timothy Besley and John McLaren (1993)
spector for underreporting pollution, show that in the case of tax collectors hetero-
and so the inspector demands and re- genous in their corruptibility, the revenue author-
ity may sometimes prefer a regime of corruption
ceives a larger bribe, and corruption in- among the tax collectors than paying them effi-
creases. Mookherjee and Png show that ciency wages.
Bardhan: Corruption and Development 1341

that the reward system should be more not enforce the laws and property rights
geared to the incidence of the primary that provide the minimum underpin-
harm that the regulator is supposed to nings of a market economy and thus lost
control. (This indicates that in the case respect; disrespect quickly led to disloy-
of controlling corruption in the Cus- alty and thievery among public officials.
toms department the value of paying re- The strong states of East Asia with their
wards to customs officials should be centralized rent-collection machinery
assessed by their effect on the open- and their dense "encompassing" net-
market price of the product subject to work with business interests stand in
import controls.) sharp contrast, even though by some
Finally, policy issues on corruption measures corruption has been quite
cannot be discussed without involving substantial. As we have emphasized in
the larger question of the nature of the our discussion of "lump-sum corrup-
state that is supposed to carry out the tion" in Section II, the ability to pre-
policies. This is too large a topic to be commit credibly may have been an im-
covered here,'7 but one may neverthe- portant feature of the "strength" of
less point out that to assume that all such states. This is not to deny that get-
states are predatory, as is customary in ting rid of many of the dysfunctional
much of the public choice literature in regulations remains a major first step in
the context of developing countries, anti-corruption policy, whatever the na-
does not help in understanding why cor- ture of the state. In addition, it is im-
ruption is more in some countries than perative to institutionalize the various
in others (even with similar extent of kinds of accountability mechanisms at
state intervention), and why countries different levels of the government (that
with similar over-all levels of corruption we have briefly discussed in Section V)
differ in its effect on productivity and as part of the agenda for any meaning-
growth. We have noted in Section III ful policy reform in this context.
that political competition can reduce
corruption (unless the transaction costs REFERENCES
in the political market, in the form, say, ADAMS, GORDON. The iron triangle: The politics
of campaign finances, are too large), of defense contracting. New Brunswick: Trans-
action Books, 1981.
but what is particularly important in de- ALAM, M. SHAHID. "A Theory of Limits on Cor-
ciding the economic consequences of ruption and some Applications," Kyklos, 1995,
corruption is the extent of centraliza- 46(43), pp. 419-35.
ANDVIG, JENS CHRISTOPHER. "The Economics of
tion in the rent-collection machinery. Corruption: A Survey," Studi Economici, 1991,
Weak and fragmented governments 43, pp. 57-94.
(even under authoritarian rulers) with ANDVIG, JENS CHR. AND MOENE, KARL, OVE.
"How Corruption May Corrupt," J. Econ. Be-
rampant economic warlordism can let hav. Organ., Jan. 1990, 13(1), pp. 63-76.
loose a regime of decentralized looting BANERJEE, ABHIJIT. "A Theory of Misgover-
that is particularly harmful for static nance." Working Paper. MIT Economics Dept.,
1994.
and dynamic efficiency. BANFIELD, EDWARD C. The moral basis of a
Some African states in recent history backward society. New York: Free Press, 1958.
became predatory in their rent-extrac- BARDHAN, PRANAB K. "The Nature of Institu-
tional Impediments to Economic Develop-
tion not because they were strong, but ment." Working Paper. Dept. of Economics, U.
because they were weak: the state could of California at Berkeley, Mar. 1996.
BECK, PAUL J. AND MAHER, MICHAEL W. "A
Comparison of Bribery and Bidding in Thin
17 For a discussion of the role of the state in the Markets,"Econ.Letters, 1986, 20, pp. 1-5.
context of development, see Bardhan (1996). BESLEY, TIMOTHY AND MCLAREN, JOHN. "Taxes
1342 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (September 1997)
and Bribery: The Role of Wage Incentives," OLSON, MANCUR. "Dictatorship, Democracy, and
Econ. J., Jan. 1993, 103(416), pp. 119-41. Development," Amer. Polit. Sci. Rev., Sept.
BOYCKO, MAXIM; SHLEIFER, ANDREI AND 1993, 87(3), pp. 567-75.
VISHNY, ROBERT. Privatizing Russia. Cam- PUTNAM, ROBERT D. Making democracy work:
bridge MA: MIT Press, 1995. Civic traditions in modern Italy. Princeton:
CADOT, OLIVIER. "Corruption as a Gamble," J. Princeton U. Press, 1993.
Public Econ., July 1987, 33(2), pp. 223-44. RASMUSEN, ERIC AND RAMSEYER, J. MARK.
GAMBETTA, DIEGO. "Mafia: The Price of Dis- "Cheap Bribes and the Corruption Ban: A
trust," in Trust making and breaking coopera- Coordination Game among Rational Legisla-
tive relations. Ed.: DIEGO GAMBETTA.Oxford: tors," Public Choice, Mar. 1994, 78(3-4), pp.
Blackwell, 1988, pp. 158-75. 305-27.
GORDON, PETER J. "Welfare of the Poor Given a ROMER, PAUL. "New Goods, Old Theory, and the
Corrupt Non-Market System." Working Paper. Welfare Costs of Trade Restrictions," J. De-
U. of West Indies, Jamaica, 1994. velop. Econ., Feb. 1994, 43(1), pp. 5-38.
HILLMAN, ARYE L. AND KATZ, ELIAKIM, "Hierar- RoSE-ACKERMAN, SUSAN. Corruption:A study in
chical Structure and the Social Costs of Bribes political economy. New York: Academic Press,
and Transfers," J. Public Econ., Nov. 1987, 1978.
34(2), pp. 129-42. . "Reducing Bribery in the Public Sector,"
HUNTINGTON, SAMUEL P. Political order in in Corruption & democracy: Political institu-
changing societies. New Haven: Yale U. Press, tions, processes and corruption in trasition
1968. states in East-Central Europe and in the former
KANGLE, R. P. The Kautiliya Arthasastra, Part II. Soviet Union. Ed.: DUC V. TRANG. Budapest:
Bombay: U. of Bombay, 1972. Institute for Constitutional & Legislative Policy,
KLITGAARD, ROBERT E. Controlling corruption. 1994.
Berkeley: U. of California Press, 1988. "When is Corruption Harmful?" Working
KRUEGER, ANNE 0. "The Political Economy of Paper. The World Bank, 1996.
the Rent-Seeking Society," Amer. Econ. Rev., SAH, RAAJ KUMAR. "Persistence and Pervasiveness
June 1974, 64(3), pp. 291-303. of Corruption: New Perspectives." Yale Eco-
LEFF, NATHANIEL H. "Economic Development nomic Growth Center Discussion Paper: 560,
through Bureaucratic Corruption," The Ameri- 48, Aug. 1988.
can Behavioral Scientist, Nov. 1964, 8(2), pp. SHLEIFER, ANDREI AND VISHNY, ROBERT W.
8-14. "Corruption," Quart. J. Econ., Aug. 1993,
LIEN, DONALD H. D. "A Note on Competitive 108(3), pp. 599-617.
Bribery Games," Econ. Letters, 1986, 22, pp. THEOBALD, ROBIN. Corruption, development, and
337-41. underdevelopment. Durham, NC: Duke U.
LUI, FRANCIS T. "An Equilibrium Queuing Model Press, 1990.
of Bribery,"J. Polit. Econ., Aug. 1985, 93(4), TIROLE, JEAN. "A Theory of Collective Reputa-
pp. 760-81. tions," Rev. Econ. Stud., Jan. 1996, 63(1), pp.
MAURO, PAOLO. "Corruption and Growth," Quart. 1-22.
J. Econ., Aug. 1995,11093), pp. 681-712. TULLOCK, GORDON. "Rent-Seeking as a Negative-
. "The Effects of Corruption on Growth, Sum Game," in Toward a theory of the rent-
Investment, and Government Expenditure," in seeking society. Eds.: JAMES M. BUCHANAN,
Corruption in the world economy. Ed.: KIM- ROBERT D. TOLLISON, AND GORDON TUL-
BERLY A. ELLIOTT. Washington DC: Institute LOCK. College Station: Texas A&M U. Press,
for International Economics, forthcoming. 1980, pp.16-36.
MOOKHERJEE, DILIP. "Reforms in Income Tax "The Costs of Special Privilege," in Per-
Enforcement in Mexico." IRIS-India Working spectives on positive political economy. Eds.:
Paper No.6. U. of Maryland, 1995. JAMES E. ALT AND KENNETH A. SHEPSLE.
MOOKHERJEE,DILIP AND PNG, I. P. L. "Corrupt- Cambridge and New York: Cambridge U. Press,
ible Law Enforcers: How Should They be Com- 1990, pp.195-211.
pensated?" Econ. J., Jan. 1995, 105(428), pp. WADE, ROBERT. "The Market for Public Office:
145-59. Why the Indian State Is Not Better at Develop-
MURPHY, KEVIN M.; SHLEIFER, ANDREI AND ment," World Devel., Apr. 1985,13(4), pp. 467-
VISHNY, ROBERT W. "Why Is Rent-Seeking So 97.
Costly to Growth?" Amer. Econ. Rev., May WRAITH, RONALD E. AND SIMKINS, EDGAR. Cor-
1993, 83(2), pp. 409-14. ruption in developing countries. London: Allen
MYRDAL, GUNNAR. Asian drama. Vol. II. New and Unwin, 1963.
York: Random House, 1968. YANG, MAYFAIR MEI-HuI. "The Gift Economy
OLDENBURG, PHILIP. "Middlemen in Third- and State Power in China," Comparative Stud-
World Corruption," World Politics, 1987, 39, ies in Societyand History, Jan. 1989, 31(1), pp.
pp. 508-35. 25-54.
Bardhan: Corruption and Development 1343

Appendix
TABLE1

Efficiencyof the
Countryin Indexof low Indexof low Indexof efficiency governance
descendingorderof corruption red tape of the legal system structure,average
GNP per capita (1) (2) (3) of (1)-(3)
Switzerland 10 10 10 10
Japan 8.75 8.5 10 9.08
Sweden 9.25 8.5 10 9.25
Denmark 9.25 9.5 10 9.58
Norway 10 9 10 9.67
United States 10 9.25 10 9.75
Germany 9.5 7.5 9 8.67
Austria 8 7.25 9.5 8.25
France 10 6.75 8 8.25
Finland 9.5 8.5 10 9.33
Belgium 9.75 8 9.5 9.08
Canada 10 9.5 9.25 9.58
Netherlands 10 10 10 10
Italy 7.5 4.75 6.75 6.33
United Kingdom 9.25 7.75 10 9
Australia 10 9.25 10 9.75
Singapore 10 10 10 10
Hong Kong 8 9.75 10 9.25
Kuwait 7.75 6.25 7.5 7.17
Spain 7 6 6.25 6.42
Israel 9.25 7.5 10 8.92
New Zealand 10 10 10 10
Ireland 9.75 7.5 8.75 8.67
SaudiArabia 4.75 5.25 6 5.33
Portugal 6.75 4.5 5.5 5.58
Greece 6.25 4 7 5.75
Korea 5.75 6.5 6 6.08
Argentina 7.66 6.66 6 6.77
Trinidad/Tobago 6.5 - 4 8 6.17
Mexico 3.25 5.25 6 4.83
Uruguay 8 6 6.5 6.83
Venezuela 5.75 4 6.5 5.42
Malaysia 6 6 9 7
Brazil 5.75 4 5.75 5.17
SouthAfrica 8 7 6 7
Chile 9.25 9.25 7.25 8.58
Iraq 10 3 6 6.33
Panama 5 7.25 6.75 6.33
Iran 3.25 1.25 2 2.17
Turkey 6 5.33 4 5.11
1344 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (September 1997)

TABLE1 (Cont.)

Efficiencyof the
Countryin Indexof low Indexof low Indexof efficiency governance
descendingorderof corruption red tape of the legal system structure,average
GNP per capita (1) (2) (3) of (1)-(3)
Thailand 1.5 3.25 3.25 2.56
Algeria 5 2.5 7.25 4.92
Jamaica 5 4 7.33 5.44
Colombia 4.5 4.5 7.25 5.42
Jordan 8.33 6.33 8.66 7.77
Ecuador 5.5 5 6.25 5.58
DominicanRep. 6.5 6 6.75 6.42
Morocco 5.66 5.33 6.66 5.88
Peru 7.25 5.75 6.75 6.58
Cameroon 7 6 7 6.67
Philippines 4.5 5 4.75 4.75
IvoryCoast 6 7.75 6.5 6.75
Indonesia 1.5 2.75 2.5 2.25
Egypt 3.25 3 6.5 4.25
Zimbabwe 8.75 7.75 7.5 8
SriLanka 7 6 7 6.67
Ghana 3.66 2.33 4.66 3.55
Pakistan 4 4 5 4.33
Nicaragua 8.75 4 6 6.25
Nigeria 3 2.75 7.25 4.33
Kenya 4.5 5 5.75 5.08
India 5.25 3.25 8 5.5
Haiti 2 2 2 2
Bangladesh 4 4 6 4.67
Liberia 2.66 5 3.33 3.66
Angola 8.66 5.33 4 6
Zaire 1 2.66 2 1.89

Source: Mauro(1995). The scale is 10 for no corruptionto 0 for maximumcorruption.The indices are based on
standardquestionnairesfilled in by Business Internationalcorrespondentsstationed in about 70 countries in
1980-83. It is likelythatthe indicesreflectwhatare faced by foreignbusinessmenin a country,not necessarilywhat
own citizensface.
Bardhan: Corruption and Development 1345
TABLE2
PERCEIVED CORRUPTION RANKING, 1996

Rank Country MeanScore Variance No. of SurveysUsed


1 New Zealand 9.4 0.39 6
2 Denmark 9.3 0.44 6
3 Sweden 9.1 0.30 6
4 Finland 9.1 0.23 6
5 Canada 9.0 0.15 6
6 Norway 8.9 0.20 6
7 Singapore 8.8 2.36 10
8 Switzerland 8.8 0.24 6
9 Netherlands 8.7 0.25 6
10 Australia 8.6 0.48 6
11 Ireland 8.5 0.44 6
12 U.K. 8.4 0.25 7
13 Germany 8.3 0.53 6
14 Israel 7.7 1.41 5
15 USA 7.7 0.19 7
16 Austria 7.6 0.41 6
17 Japan 7.1 2.61 9
18 Hong Kong 7.0 1.79 9
19 France 7.0 1.58 6
20 Belgium 6.8 1.41 6
21 Chile 6.8 2.53 7
22 Portugal 6.5 1.17 6
23 SouthAfrica 5.7 3.30 6
24 Poland 5.6 3.63 4
25 Czech Rep. 5.4 2.11 4
26 Malaysia 5.3 0.13 9
27 SouthKorea 5.0 2.30 9
28 Greece 5.0 3.37 6
29 Taiwan 5.0 0.87 9
30 Jordan 4.9 0.17 4
31 Hungary 4.9 2.19 6
32 Spain 4.3 2.48 6
33 Turkey 3.5 0.30 6
34 Italy 3.4 4.78 6
35 Argentina 3.4 0.54 6
36 Bolivia 3.4 0.64 4
37 Thailand 3.3 1.24 10
38 Mexico 3.3 0.22 7
39 Ecuador 3.2 0.42 4
40 Brazil 3.0 1.07 7
41 Egypt 2.8 6.64 4
42 Colombia 2.7 2.41 6
43 Uganda 2.7 8.72 4
44 Philippines 2.7 0.49 8
1346 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXV (September 1997)

TABLE 2 (Cont.)
PERCEIVED CORRUPTION RANKING, 1996

Rank Country Mean Score Variance No. of SurveysUsed


45 Indonesia 2.7 0.95 10
46 India 2.6 0.12 9
47 Russia 2.6 0.94 5
48 Venezuela 2.5 0.40 7
49 Cameroon 2.5 2.98 4
50 China 2.4 0.52 9
51 Bangladesh 2.3 1.57 4
52 Kenya 2.2 3.69 4
53 Pakistan 1.0 2.52 5
54 Nigeria 0.7 6.37 4

Source: Transparency International.The perceivedcorruptionscore is an averageof datafrom severalsurveys,the


respondentsof which are mostlypeople workingfor multinationalfirmsand institutions:it is a "pollof polls"(with
the variancein the score from different surveysgiven in column 4). The scale is 10 for no corruptionto 0 for
maximumcorruption.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi