Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 18

Environment International 29 (2003) 105 – 122

www.elsevier.com/locate/envint

Review
Progress in renewable energy
Robert Gross *, Matthew Leach, Ausilio Bauen
Imperial College Centre for Energy Policy and Technology (ICCEPT), Department of Environmental Science and Technology,
Imperial College London, 4th Floor RSM, Prince Consort Road, London SW7 2BP, UK
Received 1 August 2002; accepted 18 October 2002

Abstract

This paper provides an overview of some of the key technological and market developments for leading renewable energy technologies—
wind, wave and tidal, photovoltaics (PV) and biomass energy. Market growth, innovation and policy are closely interrelated in the
development of renewables and the key issues in each area are explored for each of the main types of renewable energy technology. This
enables the prospects for future development and cost reduction to be considered in detail. Key issues for policy are outlined.
D 2002 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Renewable energy; Technological development; Market growth

1. Introduction than 3% of global electricity and 2% of primary energy.


There is no doubt that the potential scale of their
Governments around the world are placing considerable contribution is very large, but sustained growth will be
faith in renewable energy as important technologies for needed, in the face of lower cost and often more con-
reducing energy related environmental problems, particu- venient alternatives.
larly CO2 emissions. Most OECD countries have ambitious This paper reviews progress in some key technologies
plans and targets, with particularly strong support in and considers the challenges for the future. The relationship
Europe—recently reinforced by the EU Renewables Direc- between technological progress and policy mechanisms is
tive and in the policies of several states—and in the US. discussed and conclusions drawn with a view to policy
There is policy support in several developing countries priorities for the coming decades.
(notably China, India and Brazil).
Support is focused upon the so-called ‘new’ renew-
ables such as wind energy, modern1 biomass and solar 2. Renewable energy resources and technology options
photovoltaics (PV). Some of these technologies have
made strong progress—with substantial cost reductions One of the most notable features of renewable forms of
and rapid market expansion—others are remote from energy is the diversity of technologies and resources.
commercial viability and require more development. But There is little doubt that the ultimate size of the renewable
all are coming from a very low base; excluding large energy resource is large and could, in principle, make a
hydro and traditional2 biomass, renewables contribute less very substantial contribution to world energy demands—
easily exceeding current world electricity supply for exam-
ple (see Table 2). An overview of the leading resources
* Corresponding author. Tel.: +44-20-7549-9324. and the technologies for harnessing them is provided in
E-mail address: Robert.gross@ic.ac.uk (R. Gross). Table 1.
1
Sustainable biomass resources used for the production of modern
energy vectors such as electricity and a variety of liquid and gaseous fuels,
2.1. Current status
using advanced technologies.
2
Biomass used for domestic heating and cooking, mainly in developing
countries, based on the collection and combustion of wood and dung in crude Despite the scale of the potential, the current contribu-
stoves/fireplaces. tion of renewables to world energy supplies is modest.

0160-4120/02/$ - see front matter D 2002 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved.
PII: S 0 1 6 0 - 4 1 2 0 ( 0 2 ) 0 0 1 3 0 - 7
106 R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122

Renewables are estimated to supply around 17% of world Table 2


Installed capacities and output of ‘new’ renewables
primary energy, but most of this is from large hydroelectric
schemes and the use of traditional biomass and agricultural Capacity Approx. annual
(MW)a outputb (TW h/year)
waste in developing countries—these supply 3% (18% of
electricity) and 14% of primary energy, respectively (IEA, Biomass (modern) 35,000 185
Wind 20,000 50
2000a). Both can lead to considerable local environmental
Geothermal 8200 44
problems and the potential for sustainable expansion of Small hydro 3000 15
both is limited. The ‘new’ renewables such as solar, Solar PV 1200 1
modern biomass and wind power contribute a much Solar thermal 350 0.2
smaller proportion of energy needs at present—around Total 68,550 356
3% of electricity and 2% of primary energy (IEA,
2000a). Current installed capacities and energy outputs Capacity (GW) Output (TW h/year)
are shown in Table 2, which also provides an estimate
Current world electricity 3,000,000 15,000
of current world electricity capacity and supply. Yet these a
Sources: UNDP/WEC (2000) and Wind Power Monthly (2001).
technologies offer large potential for growth and signifi- b
Authors’ estimates, except geothermal UNDP/WEC (2000), based
cant environmental benefits. upon capacity factors of 60% for biomass and small hydro, 60% for solar
thermal, 30% for wind and 10% for PV.
2.2. Regional differences and a diversity of applications
tion in tropical regions 3 times that of temperate latitudes.3
The aggregated figures for both potential and current Marine resources are rather obviously most readily
installations belie considerable regional differences. Solar accessed from coastal regions, with considerable variation
potential varies considerably, with average annual insola- in wave and tidal regimes. Geothermal energy and micro-
hydro are even more location specific. Whilst biomass
resources are more widely available, land use and climatic
constraints result in significant differences in the scale of
the potential resource and the type of application.4 Wind
Table 1
energy is also widely distributed but wind regimes differ
Global renewable energy resources
significantly both within and between regions, and modest
Resource Scale of technical Energy conversion options
variations in wind speed can have a profound effect on
potential (useful energy
output)a (TW h/year) energy output.
As a result, renewables potential tends to be geograph-
Direct solar 12,000 – 40,000 Photovoltaics
Solar thermal power generation ically diverse. Moreover, the diversity of technology options
Solar water heaters for exploiting renewable resources also offers a wide range
Wind 20,000 – 40,000 Large scale power generation of types of application. Renewables are able to provide
(onshore) Small scale power generation energy in various forms—heat, fuels, electricity—and at a
Water pumps
range of scales. In electricity generation this ranges from
Wave 2000 – 4000 Numerous designs
Tidal >3500 Barrage large-scale grid-connected technologies to the provision of
Tidal stream small amounts of power for remote villages or telecommu-
Geothermal 4000 – 40,000 Hot dry rock, hydrothermal, nications. Similarly, the opportunities to use renewable fuels
geopressed, magma (only ranges from small niche markets to large scale blending with
hydrothermalcurrently viable)
conventional fuels.
Biomass 8000 – 25,000 Combustion, gasification,
pyrolysis, digestion, for bio-fuels, The approach here is to focus on key technologies and
heat and electricity their development in leading markets rather than attempting
a
These figures are illustrative of the energy that could be usefully to assess resources and technologies on a region by-region
extracted using known technologies and allowing for physical constraints. or application by-application basis. However, it is notable
Such figures are inevitably approximate and depend upon assumptions that scenarios of future energy supplies suggest that future
about conversion efficiencies, competing land-use and so on. Figures energy systems will be characterised by more renewables
derived from various primary sources cited in UNDP/WEC (2000) and are
based upon conservative estimates of land availability and/or accessibility.
and much greater diversity—both in terms of regional
Where required, the authors have converted data on resource into resource use and scale and type of technology application
technical potential—figures for solar based upon PV at 10% conversion (Shell, 1995).
efficiency, geothermal for power generation at 20% efficiency and for
wave and tidal 20% efficiency. Wind power figure is for large grid
3
connected machines only. Note also that limited data are available on 2500 and 900 kW h/m2, respectively.
4
global wave and tidal resources and these figures could be substantial Oil and sugar-based crops generally better suited to bio-fuel
underestimates. Figures will increase as technology improves. However, production, based on current technology, tend to be more viable in warmer
the resources that are economically viable are much smaller, given the climates, whilst woody fuels currently better suited to electricity generation
current technologies. and heat markets may be grown in a wider range of climatic conditions.
R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122 107

35
2.3. Key technologies 30
30

Cost US cents/kWh
25
Understanding progress and future potential requires
close attention to the technologies themselves. The technol- 20

ogies that have experienced the most rapid developments 15


9
and/or appear to offer the greatest scope for more extensive 10 7 6 5 5
and widespread utilisation include solar PV, wind power, 5 3

wave and tidal energy and modern biomass technologies— 0


and this paper focuses on these. This is not to suggest that

)
V)

T)
)

er

l
d
ild
re

oa
in

G
(P

ow
ho

bu

C
the other options5 and applications do not have a role to play

C
r

rp
rs

(C
la

w
ea
So

ne

fo

as
(n
or are unlikely to experience further development. But for

r(

G
as
e

a
av

le

om
the most part they either offer more limited scope for

uc
w

Bi
N
widespread application or are closer to technological matur-
ity, or both, and concentrating on a limited number of Fig. 1. Typical costs for electricity generation.
technologies allows us to explore the key issues for these
‘exemplars’ in depth. Most of the leading technologies are
suited to a range of applications—fuels, heat and power in place them on a spectrum that ranges from ‘mature’ to
the case of biomass, on and off-grid in the case of wind and ‘emerging’. In simple terms, mature technologies are those
PV. But markets for grid connected electricity from renew- that are well established and near the limit of incremental
ables have expanded rapidly in the last 10 years and we technological development. Emerging technologies, by
explore these markets in detail. contrast, are those with considerable potential for further
One of the most important issues for the continued development and cost reduction through innovation.
growth of most renewable options is their relative cost.
Many technologies are currently more expensive than the 2.6. Learning curves
least-cost fossil fuel alternative, some markedly so (see
Fig. 16). Costs are intimately bound up with the develop- The main alternative to engineering assessment for
ment of markets and technical progress—and hence policy. assessing cost reductions is so-called learning, learning by
In the sections that follow we explore progress with doing, or experience, curves. Evidence from a very wide
renewables in terms of the relationship between these range of technologies and sectors demonstrates a clear
factors. relationship between production and cost; put simply, in
most cases as cumulative production increases, costs fall.
2.4. Assessing cost reduction potential This relationship has been assessed in depth for energy
technologies (IEA, 2000b; McDonald and Schrattenholzer,
Evidence on cost reduction potential for different renew- 2001; Grubler et al., 1999).
able options is discussed below. This is generally based If cumulative production and unit costs are plotted on a
upon two approaches to the assessment of future costs: the log/log scale the learning curve appears as a straight line,
first may be termed ‘engineering assessment’, the second this gives us the relationship between cumulative production
the ‘learning curve’ approach. and cost, which may be presented in a number of ways. The
measure that is often quoted is the ‘learning rate’—the
2.5. Engineering assessment percentage cost reduction that occurs with every doubling
of cumulative production. Learning rates vary by technol-
This approach is based upon detailed expert assess- ogy and at different stages of development of a given
ments of technology status and potential for further devel- technology—tending to be ‘faster’ in the early stages.
opment. Typically, such assessment of technologies may However, typically, for industrial products, the learning rate
is in the range 10 to 30%, which means that for each
doubling of cumulative production, costs fall by between
5
Geothermal, micro-hydro, solar thermal, tidal barrage. 10% and 30%.
6
Costs for all technologies vary considerably according to local This ‘simple’ relationship should not be interpreted as
conditions and resources. Costs for CCGT, wind and coal are ‘average’
costs for countries with well-developed gas grids, good access/infra-
underplaying the complexity of the factors that drive cost
structure for coal and moderate wind regimes. PV costs represent ‘best reduction. Learning rates chart only the empirical relation-
case’ in higher insolation countries but neglect offset costs (see below). ship between market size and cost and do not provide an
Biomass costs are typical of conventional combustion of forestry and insight into the drivers of cost reduction. However, the core
agricultural by-products. Nuclear costs are estimated costs of new build conclusion is that most ‘learning’ and cost reduction come
based upon existing technologies (no new build has taken place in
liberalised markets) and wave costs are projections (sources DTI, 1998;
through production and market experience.
Pearson and Pena-Torres, 2000; PIU, 2002; Thorpe, 1999; UNDP/WEC, Both engineering assessment and learning curves pro-
2000). vide valuable insights into the potential for continued cost
108 R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122

18000

Installed Capacity at year


16000
14000

end (MW)
12000
10000
8000
6000
4000
2000
0 91

92

93

94

95

96

97

98

99

00
19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

19

20
Fig. 2. Growth in world wind turbine installed capacity.

reduction, and the relationship between this and innovation modern AC wind turbine was built in Denmark at the end
and market growth. Learning curves can provide robust cost of the 1950s. The 200 kW Gedser wind turbine was a three-
reduction projections, where market data are available. bladed, upwind machine, with an electrically operated yaw
However, engineering assessments are particularly useful mechanism and asynchronous generator. This ‘Danish Con-
for emerging technologies that have yet to gain sufficient cept’ became the blueprint for many subsequent wind
market experience for the construction of a learning curve. turbine developments.
They can also provide an insight into potential discontinu- The OPEC oil price hikes of 1973 and 1979 redoubled
ities in development that imply caution in the interpretation interest in wind power. Large aerospace companies and
of past trends. In short, the techniques are complements, and electricity utilities designed megawatt turbines, but none of
we therefore use sources that draw upon both. these research programmes resulted in commercially viable
concepts. At around the same time small developers started
developing and manufacturing much smaller machines,
3. Progress with key technologies based on the Danish Concept. These began to go into
commercial application in the 1980s, and developed along
3.1. Wind power the path of gradual increase in size to what are now the
current commercial megawatt turbines. Over this period
In many respects, wind power is the great success story there has been immense achievement:
of renewables development. Grid connected wind power,
from ‘large’ turbines7 has seen rapid market growth in the  Over the last 15 years, the annual energy output per
period from 1991. Total installed capacity worldwide has turbine has increased 100-fold.
increased from 2 GW to more than 20 GW (Wind Power  Turbine rated capacity (for typical commercial machines)
Monthly, 2001) and capacity factor (output per unit of has increased from 55 kW to 1 MW or more.
capacity installed) has also improved. Market growth has  In the last 5 years, the weight of wind turbines per kW
averaged 22% per year in this period, accelerating to installed power has halved.
around 30% per year in the period from 1997 and as a  In the last 3 years, the sound level has halved.
result an important new industry has developed—world-  In the last 10 years, installed capacity has increased 10-
wide investment in wind energy topped US$4 billion last fold.
year (BTM Consult, 2001). The historical trend in cost
reduction has been similarly impressive. These factors have played a major role in reducing the
capital costs of wind energy. Wind turbines have become
3.1.1. Historical trends and drivers cheaper to produce, more efficient and more reliable. As the
The first electricity generation by wind energy was industry has matured, learning has reduced design, planning
achieved around the end of the 19th century. The first and installation costs and market growth has brought
economies of scale. The perceived risk of investment in
7
wind power has also decreased, leading to a lower cost of
Today’s designs of commercial turbines for grid connected power financial capital (discount rate) and longer amortisation
generation have installed capacities in the range 600 kW to 2.0 MW. The
term ‘large’ turbine is used to distinguish such turbines from the much
periods (Wind Power Monthly, 2000).
smaller units of a few kW up to 100 kW used for off-grid and leisure Progressively larger machines have brought significant
applications. scale economies, in terms of both the cost per unit of
R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122 109

25

20

cECU/kWh
15

10

80 8 2 84 86 88 90 92 9 4 96 98
19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19 19
year

Fig. 3. Price of electricity from wind, Denmark.

installed capacity ‘at the turbine’ and in terms of balance of by better siting—despite opportunities for re-powering older
plant and electrical integration. A 500-kW machine is less sites with larger, better located turbines, this would also
than 5 times the cost of a 100-kW machine and costs of appear unlikely to be entirely repeatable. In addition, costs
land, electrical connections, installation and maintenance, fell due to scale economies as turbine sizes increased
often increase little as turbine size and capacity rises. Tools tenfold, this also appears unlikely to be repeatable.
for optimising turbine location have improved. This suggests that cost reductions may be on a declining
Taken together these factors have resulted in a rapid and trajectory. However, this does not imply that further cost
sustained fall in the cost per unit of electrical output. Costs reductions will not be forthcoming. In fact, wind appears
fell fourfold in the 1980s, and halved in the 1990s. likely to become one of the lowest cost renewable generat-
Figs. 2 and 38 illustrate growth in wind installations and ing options. Recent work for the UK government Energy
cost reductions in wind generation.9 Review10 suggested costs for onshore wind are likely to fall
These figures above are indicative of a trend, rather than to less than 2.0 p (3.0 US$c)/kW h in sites with good to
absolute for all installations. Costs are sensitive to wind moderate wind regimes, PIU (2001a). This work, repro-
speed, discount rate and other variables and there is a wide duced in Fig. 4, combined the evidence of historical learning
range in existing wind farms. It is particularly important to and market growth rates with engineering assessment. It
note that cost falls rapidly with wind speed because power allows both declining market growth rates and a slow-down
output from wind turbines rises with the cube of the wind in the learning rate for wind energy as the technology
speed. For this reason, wind farms at the windiest sites are matures.11
already close to cost competitive with the average costs of Clearly, some market growth must take place if costs are
conventional power. to fall to levels that will ensure competitiveness with the
lowest cost fossil fuel alternatives. Despite the impressive
3.1.2. Future development progress outlined above, wind energy remains a small player
There appears to be considerable scope for continued on the global energy scene. Wind energy generated world-
innovation in site optimisation, blade and generator design wide in 2000 was around 37 TW h—equivalent to around
and in grid connection using power electronics (De Vries, 10% of UK electricity supply—with around 9 GW of new
2001). However, it appears possible that the pace of cost plant installed. By contrast, worldwide electricity generation
reductions will tend to decline as the technology matures. was around 15,000 TW h and around 170 GW of new
According to some assessments, wind energy capital costs conventional capacity was installed (FT, 2001). There is, in
are expected to decrease by 50– 75% in the next 20 years principle, very substantial potential for continued onshore
(EU, 1998), which is probably lower than the historical development in many parts of the world. Should market
trend. Moreover, historical cost reductions were also driven growth rates seen in the previous 10 years continue for a

8 10
Based upon data from EU (1998) and UNDP/WEC (2000). The lead author was co-author of PIU (2001a) and undertook the
9
Figures for price reduction for Denmark in the period to 2000 are supporting analysis.
11
used as a proxy for cost reduction, as market and policy conditions have Market growth rates were assumed to decline progressively from the
been relatively stable in Denmark—at least until recently; the impact of current rate of 25% to 10% by 2015. The historic learning rate for wind of
recent changes to the policy environment in Denmark upon costs and prices 18% was assumed to decline to 10% once cumulative production reaches
are not yet clear. 1000 TWhs—likely to occur around 2008.
110 R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122

100000 100.000
mean that turbines can spin faster—which increases output
Cumulative Production (TWh)

10000 for a given size of machine, and reduces blade size and

Cost p/kWh(2000)
10.000
loadings on bearings and structures relative to onshore
1000 machines of similar capacity. Larger turbines, variable speed
DC drives, and improved cabling and forecasting techniques
100 are also expected to reduce costs.
1.000
If potential cost reductions are to be realised, developers
10
must gain economies of scale in the manufacture of dedi-
1 0.100 cated offshore turbines, components and mountings, and the
1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 benefits of ‘learning by doing’ for all aspects of offshore
wind engineering. The successful completion of the plans
Production Lowest cost Highest cost
for the first phase of offshore wind development will be key.

Fig. 4. Projections of wind energy costs based on growth in global capacity 3.1.4. Key issues
with reduced learning as technology matures (source PIU, 2001a).
Wind has demonstrated the potential for innovation and
market growth to reduce costs and is now a proven and
further 15 years, installed capacity would still be less than effective technology with the potential to become a fully
10% of the global technical potential.12
competitive generation option, but continued market growth
However, it appears likely that for several years markets
will be needed to keep driving down costs. The key
will continue to expand most rapidly in OECD countries challenges are to expand the growth of wind beyond its
with supportive policies, notably Europe. There is some traditional ‘homes’ in the US and EU, and to ensure that the
evidence that development in Europe is beginning to be first wave of offshore technology gets built.
affected by availability of suitable sites. As this is the region
that has seen the highest growth in the last 10 years and has 3.2. Photovoltaics (PV)
the most supportive policy environment for wind energy,
continued development is also likely depend upon the
Like wind power markets, PV markets have seen rapid
success of offshore wind.
growth and costs have fallen dramatically. However, mar-
kets for PV, and the total capacity installed, are much
3.1.3. The move offshore smaller than those for wind energy; cumulative installed
To a large extent progress onshore has set the stage for capacity is of the order of 1 GW, with around 250 MW
developments offshore. The technology is now suitable— shipped last year.
large turbines are essential to the economics of offshore PV remains at least 6 –10 times the cost of grid elec-
wind—and there is a skills base and adequately resourced tricity, even allowing for avoided transmission and distri-
industry in place. However, at present very little offshore
bution costs. In locations remote from conventional
wind capacity is installed anywhere in the world. As with
onshore developments during the 1990s, Europe is the lead,
with all of the world’s operating offshore capacity and
ambitious plans for future development (Table 3). A large
resource has been identified (Study of Offshore Wind Table 3
Offshore wind progress and plans in Europe
Energy in the EC. Final Report of Joule I contract JOUR-
0072, 1995 cited in Gaudiosi, 1996; Cockerill, 2001) and Country Built (MW) Planned/proposed
offshore wind is expected to reach around 2 GW installed UK 4 Existing development at Blyth only
capacity by 2005 and grow at around 800 MW/year there- two turbines close to shore; however,
the recently auctioned Crown Estates
after (BTM Consult, 2001).
sites would, if successfully developed,
Offshore wind currently delivers electricity at a cost of 6 lead to 1000 – 1500 MW by 2010
to 9 cents/kW h13—around twice the cost of onshore wind Denmark 52 750 MW by 2008 (utility obligations,
in good sites. Installing wind turbines in the sea obviously four sites), long-term aim 4 GW
incurs additional costs—engineering, installation, power Germany Plans to secure 25% of electricity from
offshore wind by 2030, sites equivalent
connection and maintenance. However, engineering studies
to 10 GW identified. Initial plans
suggest that there is considerable potential for other factors (sites with permits) 3 GW. 500 MW
to offset these costs. Wind regimes are generally higher and expected to come on stream in 2003
more stable offshore and the absence of noise constraints Sweden 22 175 MW under development, long-term
potential f 3 GW
12
Technical potential is>7000 GW, 25% growth per year over 15 years Netherlands 19 1500 MW by 2020, 240 MW well
would result in 570 GW. advanced
13
Based upon projections in DTI (1998) and Danish data for existing Ireland 500 MW+ (plans for farms at Dublin
sites, Danish Energy Ministry (1999). Bay and Arklow Banks)
R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122 111

35.0 16
electricity grids, PV is often able to meet modest demands
for electricity at a lower cost than either grid extension or

Efficiency of commercially available


30.0 14
small-scale diesel generation.
12
25.0
3.2.1. Historical trends and drivers

Price (1998 $/Wp)


Photovoltaics have their origins in the US space pro- 10

modules (%)
20.0 Price (1998$/Wp)
gramme and were first utilised in the 1960s to power
Efficiency (%) 8
satellites. They still fulfil this role. The other early driver
15.0
of market expansion was niche applications for very small 6
amounts of power such as calculators, and remote small-
10.0
scale applications such as telecommunications. However, 4
supportive policies in several countries have played an
5.0 2
important role in expanding markets for PV for both grid
and off-grid electricity supply in recent years. Market
0.0 0
growth in PV shipments has averaged 15% since mid
1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998
1980s, in the last 5 years this increased to around 30%
per year, with growth approaching 40% in the last 2 years. Fig. 6. Price and conversion efficiencies for PV modules (source IT Power).
This growth has been associated with the development of
progressively larger dedicated manufacturing plant; PV has contrast, thin film modules produced by the deposition of a
moved from the specialist laboratory to specialised factories. thin layer of semi-conducting material onto a glass substrate
This has brought economies of scale and increasing auto- are likely to offer the potential of inherently lower costs, and
mation and standardisation of the manufacturing processes. are more amenable to mass production. However, at least
Capital costs of modules have fallen from several hundred until recently, thin film cells based upon silicon have suffered
dollars per peak Watt (Wp) in the early seventies, to less than from poor long-term reliability as the photosensitive layer
6 (Anderson, 1998). In addition, the conversion efficiency of degrades. These problems are now largely solved and thin
the best commercially available modules has risen steadily, film silicon is increasing market share.
from under 10% in 1980, to around 14% (Figs. 5 and 6). In the very long term, a ‘third generation’ of PV
materials, currently at the laboratory stage, may be able to
3.2.2. Future developments deliver even more radical reductions in cost—semi-conduct-
Manufacturing remains very small scale in comparison ing polymers are one example.
with both other forms of electricity generation and with The potential for profound innovation sits alongside
many other silicon semi-conductor applications. In addition, continued improvements and scale economies in existing
many commercial PV panel designs are currently based module types. Both will yield cost reductions. This makes
upon modules assembled from a number of individual the future for PV difficult to read. A direct comparison
crystalline silicon cells. One of the key issues for the future between engineering assessments and learning curves
of PV is the extent to which crystalline silicon will give way (UNDP/WEC, 2000) found that the historical learning curve
to so-called ‘thin film’ designs for power generation appli- for PV provides less ambitious cost reduction projection
cations, both on and off-grid. than recent engineering assessments. If PV may soon go
Production of crystalline silicon cells requires sophisti- through a technological transition to inherently cheaper thin
cated techniques and is considered to be inherently high cost. film technologies will this fundamentally change the learn-
Assembling modules is also a relatively complex process. By ing rate? Learning rates of up to 30% are not untypical in the
semi-conductor industries.
300
The 18 –20% historical learning rate of the last 15 years
250 may prove conservative14 and projecting costs on the basis
Capacity (MW)

200 of historic learning rate and market growth rate may under-
state the potential of PV. Nevertheless, the Energy Review
150
team found that there would be very significant cost
100 reductions over the period to 2025 if a 20% rate of learning
50 is extended into the future, and if PV installations continue
to grow at an average 25% p.a. This is illustrated in Fig. 7,
0
which also shows the assumed growth in installed capacity.
90 92 94 96 98 00
19 19 19 19 19 20
year
14
A recent review of learning rates (McDonald and Schrattenholzer,
Fig. 5. World PV module shipments 1990 to 2000 (sources Jackson and 2001) presents evidence that the rate for PV modules is 20% rather than the
Oliver, 1999; UNDP/WEC, 2000). 18% reported by the IEA (2000b).
112 R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122

100.00 1000

100

Module Cost US$(1992)/Wp

Installed Capacity (GW)


10
10.00
1

0.1
1.00
0.01

0.001

0.10 0.0001
1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030

Cost Capacity

Fig. 7. Illustrating the growth in capacity and reduction in costs for solar PV assuming a learning rate of 20% (PIU, 2001a).

It is important to note that the learning curves above are around 5 times the cost of electricity supplied to domestic
for installed capacity and reflect capital costs. Costs per unit consumers. This is in addition to 50% capital subsidies for
of output (kW h) are likely to follow a slightly different purchase of PV equipment.
trajectory due to improved conversion efficiencies, efficien- Clearly the purpose of such policies is to rapidly reduce
cies in balance of system components for grid integration, costs by expanding markets vigorously. Some analysts have
reduced installation costs and improved siting, as well as argued that a ‘step-change’ in manufacturing capacity is
cost reductions in balance of system equipment. However, required in order to reduce costs and create a virtuous circle
allowing for a modest increase in efficiency and neglecting of expanding markets and further reduced costs (KPMG,
other additional learning, with a 20-year lifetime and at an 1999). The danger with this approach is that it could entail
8% discount rate, the projections suggest that PV could ‘lock-in’ to current module technologies and hinder inno-
deliver electricity at around 15 cents/kW h by 2020, falling vation and cost reduction in the longer term.
to 10.5 cents/kW h by 2025 in the UK. In sunnier climates, The challenge for policy is to continue to drive market
these figures are reduced to around 6 cents and 3 cents/kW expansion whilst minimising this risk. Offset costs may prove
h. Additional learning in balance of systems installation and highly significant to growth in the use of BIPV, particularly in
other costs, if possible, could reduce these figures further. the commercial building sector where there is significant
potential for expensive cladding to be replaced with PV.
3.2.2.1. Offset costs? It is possible for PV to replace
conventional cladding materials—building integrated PV 3.3. Wave and tidal stream energy
(BIPV) may be designed to form part of the walls, or roof,
of buildings. This can have a dramatic effect on the By comparison to wind and PV, wave energy and tidal
economics, as only the incremental costs of PV—over and stream are very much in their infancy. Currently, around 1
above the costs of alternative cladding—need be factored MW of wave energy devices is installed worldwide, mainly
into the cost equation. A number of purpose designed from demonstration projects. There is currently no large-
products are entering the market; PV roof tiles are already scale tidal stream capacity operating, though prototypes are
commercially available for example. In some instances, planned for the near future (DTI, 2002).
where relatively expensive materials are displaced, BIPV However, the potential resource world-wide is very large
is already at or close to being commercially viable (able to as the energy per metre of wave front is substantial along
deliver electricity at less than the cost of grid electricity to large reaches of oceanic coastline and wave energy machines
the end user) (ETSU, 1998). are typically able to convert 60 – 80% of available wave
power into useful energy (Thorpe, 1999). A great deal
3.2.3. Key issues depends upon assumptions about site availability, and the
Policy support for PV is both ambitious in several global technical potential has not been studied in great detail.
countries and, on a per kW h basis and compared to other More detailed studies have explored some regions; the
renewables, expensive. In Germany, for example, the rate at accessible resource (which takes account of constraints on
which legislation obliges local utilities to buy output from available sites for a wide variety of reasons) in the waters
small-scale PV installations is around US$0.50/kW h— around the UK for example is very large—700 TW h/year,
R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122 113

almost double electricity consumption. The extent to which to drive a hydraulic motor in order to extract wave
this will prove practical to harness will depend upon suc- energy.
cessful development of both nearshore and deep water
technologies, as a result technical potential is more difficult Some of leading designs are listed in Box 1.
to estimate—a range of perhaps 70– 140 TW h, representing
10 –20% of the accessible resource, would appear reasonable
as prima-facie estimate, but this is highly speculative at Box 1. Some wave and tidal energy designs and
present. There are very limited data on global tidal stream devices.
potential.
Though intermittent, electrical output from wave energy is Shoreline OWCs (Oscillating water column)
. Limpet (UK) other devices in Sri Lanka, Australia,
more predictable than wind power output, as sea states
(waves) are inherently more predictable than wind. This is China, India, Japan, Norway
because waves, once created, continue to transmit energy for Nearshore OWCs
. Osprey(UK), Sperbouy (multi-chambered) (UK),
some time and distance—around 8 h is the typical period of
certainty within which sea state can be predicted accurately. Mighty Whale (floating) (Japan)
Tidal currents flow according to a predictable diurnal pattern. Spillover devices
. Tapchan (Norway), Wave Dragon, Wave Plane

3.3.1. Historical trends and drivers (Denmark) and Floating Wave Vessel (Sweden)
The first patent for a wave energy device was filed in Pneumatic devices
. Sea Clam pneumatic bag-type device
Paris in 1799, and by 1973 there were 340 British patents
for wave energy devices. The number continues to rise. Float-based devices
. Danish Wave Power Device (Denmark), Bristol
Considerable research and development was initiated in
several countries following the second oil price shock and Cylinder (UK) Hosepump (Sweden), Archimedes
numerous prototype devices have been developed. How- Wave Swing, IPS Buoy (Sweden) Sloped IPS (UK)
ever, enthusiasm gave way to some skepticism because of Moving body devices
. McCabe Wave Pump (UK), Pelamis (UK)
the high cost estimates associated with early prototypes.
. Edinburgh Duck (UK), PS Frog (UK)
Despite this, considerable progress was made during the
1990s. Several companies are developing and deploying Tidal stream
. Marine current turbines (UK)
new devices that represent a significant improvement over
. RV Venturi (UK)
older concepts. Projected costs of leading designs have
fallen considerably in recent years and installed capacity is
widely predicted to grow exponentially over the next few
years, rising to around 6 MW by around 2005. To date, 3.3.2. Cost estimates
however, the only truly commercial success has been wave Commercial scale wave energy is yet to become a reality
power for navigation buoys. and as such empirical evidence on costs does not exist.
Wave and tidal energy is largely at the R&D and Nevertheless, wave energy devices under development in
prototype stage. A very large number of designs for wave the UK have been subject to rigorous and independent
energy devices have been proposed. A much smaller num- assessments of probable capital and generation costs should
ber appear promising at present, but the ‘best’ device is yet commercial scale development be realised (Thorpe, 1999),
to be identified. Devices can be classified as shoreline, these are explored below. It has not been possible to secure
nearshore and offshore. They may be further classified by data on devices under development in other countries,
generic technology type, though there is some overlap however there is no reason to presume that costs and trends
(Duckers, 1998). The classifications include: differ substantially.
Of those devices that have been deployed, for the most
n pneumatic devices, such as the oscillating water column part near-shore and shoreline devices, costs are in the region
(OWC), which use wave motion to compress and decom- of 7 – 9 cents (4.5 – 6 pence)/kW h. As a result several
press air, from which energy is extracted; devices are economically viable with the relatively modest
n float-based devices which utilise a buoyant float moving support offered by renewables support schemes. The Lim-
with the waves, reacting against a reference point such as pet, OSPREY and Pelamis have secured support from the
a sea bed anchor in order to harness energy; Irish and Scottish renewables obligations, but most devices
n spillover devices which utilise wave height to replenish a will require considerable further development before reach-
reservoir of sea water which then runs a turbine; ing this stage.
n raft type devices which use the relative motion of adjacent
rafts or pontoons to harness wave energy; 3.3.3. Future development
n moving body devices which actually articulate in the Learning curves cannot be used to assess wave and tidal
water in some way, inducing motion which may be used energy as there is little or no market experience and hence
114 R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122

100 3.4. Biomass


Cost of Electricity (p/kWh)
Energy from biomass resources presents, in many
respects, a more complicated picture than the technologies
10 discussed above. This is because there are a wide variety of
feedstocks and conversion technologies, and progress has
been more pronounced in some areas than others. Biomass
may also provide energy for a diversity of applications,
including domestic and industrial heat, transport fuels and
1 electricity. This variety of uses and technologies is illus-
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 trated in Fig. 10.
Year of Design Space does not permit us to do full justice to develop-
ments in the plethora of biomass feedstocks, or indeed to
Edinburgh Duck Bristol Cylinder
discuss conversion technologies in detail. For this reason,
SEA Clam PS Frog
we confine ourselves to an overview of developments in
McCabe Wave Pump Sloped IPS Buoy
markets, in the leading conversion technologies and of some
Fig. 8. Evolution of predicted electricity costs for offshore devices (Thorpe,
of the issues for the future of biomass.
1999).
3.4.1. Historical trends and drivers
no data. Engineering assessments provide some indication Current biomass use for energy is estimated to be around
of the likely range of future costs, at least for wave energy— 14% of world primary energy, most of this is used in
upon which we concentrate in this subsection. A parametric developing countries, where biomass accounts for up to 1/
cost estimation model has been developed for the UK 3 of energy needs (Bauen and Kaltschmitt, 1999). By
government (Thorpe, 1999). The latest estimates suggest contrast, biomass provides at most 3% of energy in indus-
that once commercial scale deployment is achieved, costs of trialised countries. The current utilisation of biomass com-
offshore devices are likely to lie in the range 7 –12 cents/kW pared to an estimate of practical sustainable potential is
h, with some of the nearshore devices likely to be below 7.5 illustrated in Fig. 11.
cents/kW h (Thorpe, 1999).15 As Fig. 11 illustrates, the amount of biomass utilised
Figs. 8 and 9 illustrate how projected costs have fallen in around the world is much lower than its potential in most
successive costing studies, as designs have improved. As yet regions. However, use appears to exceed sustainable con-
it is not clear how long it will take for such costs to be sumption in some regions, notably Asia. Expanding the
realised—if at all in some cases. In general, it appears likely utilisation of modern biomass therefore has two major
that the nearshore options will achieve these kind of cost drivers:
levels in the near future (within 5 years or so), whilst a great
deal more uncertainty surrounds the offshore devices. – in developing countries, efforts need to be directed to
As the number and variety of full scale demonstration more modern and sustainable biomass uses;
schemes increases, confidence in cost estimates will
improve. The UK Government has recently signalled an
increased willingness to support wave and tidal schemes
through the demonstration phase that precedes the ‘pre-
commercial markets phase’ where renewables become com-
mercially viable through generic renewables support poli-
cies (such as the UK’s Renewables Obligation) alone (DTI,
2002; PIU, 2001b).

3.3.4. Key issues


Overall, there is considerable uncertainty surrounding the
economics of wave energy, reflecting the relatively immature
status of the technology and market. Nevertheless, there is
clear evidence that the (theoretical) economics are steadily
improving as RD&D progresses, and significant cost reduc-
tions have been achieved. Wave is now leaving the laboratory
and entering a large-scale demonstration phase. Active and
well-targeted policies are likely to be central to success.
15
Figures based upon 8% discount rate. Fig. 9. Evolution of predicted costs for OWC Devices (Thorpe, 1999).
R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122 115

Bi om as s

Storage, T ran sp ort, Pre-treatm en t

Thermo-chemical conversion Physico-chemical conversion Biological conversion

Charcoal Pressing/Extraction Fermentation/ Anaerobic


Combustion Pyrolysis Gasification
production Hydrolysis digestion

Esterification

Solid fuel Liquid fuel Gaseous fuel

Transport fuels

Boiler Engine, gas turbine Fuel cell

Heat Steam turbine

Electricity

Fig. 10. Biomass feedstocks and conversion technologies.

– more modern and sustainable biomass uses can alleviate – furthermore, in both developing and industrialised
local environmental problems—including the severe countries, modern biomass can bring numerous envi-
health implications of exposure to biomass combustion ronmental and other benefits, these are summarised in
products; Box 2.

Fig. 11. Biomass use and potential around the world (Bauen and Kaltschmitt, 2001).
116 R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122

Despite the potential, there are a number of issues that the other renewable technologies, the focus of the rest of this
need to be addressed in the development of biomass to section is on biomass combustion and gasification technol-
energy fuel cycles. Biomass is often perceived as a fuel that ogies for electricity generation.
is inconvenient, requires excessive land-use, leads to high
energy costs and is questionable in terms of environmental
benefits. Whilst these issues have more to do with percep-
tions (or misconceptions) of modern biomass, the technol-
ogies and practices discussed below, together with good Box 3. Biomass conversion options.
management of biomass resources, do much to ameliorate
many concerns. Biomass direct combustion
Biomass can be burned in small-scale modern boilers
Box 2. Benefits of biomass fuels. for heating purposes, or in larger boilers for the
generation of electricity or combined heat and power
 biomass is far more widely available than fossil (CHP). Most electricity generation is based on the
fuels, and a variety of wastes (e.g. forest and agro- Rankine (steam turbine) cycle.
industry waste) can provide a significant short-term Biomass combustion systems are in commercial use
biomass resource often in need of disposal around the world, using disparate technology. Dedi-
 biomass provides a renewable source of fuel cated combustion plants can burn a wide range fuel,
provided good management practices are followed including wastes. Co-combustion of biomass and coal
 there are good prospects for biomass to be using pulverised fuel (PF) and (circulating) fluidised
economically converted to a variety of energy bed ((C)FB) conversion technologies may also be an
carriers (e.g. heat, electricity, methanol, ethanol, option.
hydrogen) in an environmentally viable manner Biomass gasification
 the conversion of renewable biomass results in no Biomass gasification converts biomass to a low to
net CO2 emissions to the atmosphere, and modern medium calorific value gaseous fuel. The fuel can be
biomass fuel chains may present other environ- used to generate heat and electricity by direct firing in
mental benefits compared to fossil fuel chains engines, turbines and boilers after suitable clean up.
 social benefits (of particular significance to devel- Alternatively, the product gas can be reformed to
oping countries) include: produce fuels such as methanol and hydrogen, which
 reduced fuel imports could then be used in fuel cells or microturbines, for
 diversification in agricultural activities example. Gasification-based systems may present
 enhanced rural development and employment advantages compared to combustion in terms of econo-
 incentive to recover deforested and degraded mies of scale and clean and efficient operation.
lands Hundreds of small-scale fixed bed gasifiers are in
operation around the world, in particular in developing
countries. Recent gasification activities, in industrial-
ised countries in particular, have focused on fluidised
bed systems, including circulating fluidised bed sys-
Modern biomass for heat and electricity production tems. Larger systems coupling combined cycle gas and
contributes around 4% of US primary energy, 11% in steam turbines to gasifiers (biomass integrated gas-
Austria, 20% in Finland, 17% in Sweden. Biomass for ification combined cycle, BIG/CC) are at the demon-
district heating and CHP is also well established in Den- stration stage. BIG/CC systems could lead to electrical
mark and Germany (UNDP/WEC, 2000; Bauen, 2001). efficiencies of about 50%.
Cumulative electricity production from commercial bio- Gasification is becoming an increasingly popular
mass is in excess of 100 TW h—biomass already has means of treating municipal solid waste, and a signifi-
significantly more market experience than any other cant part of new waste-to-energy plants will be based
emerging renewable option (IEA, 2000b). Its use has on gasification technology.
expanded considerably in several countries in the last Biomass pyrolysis
decade, largely as a result of supportive policy frame- Biomass pyrolysis produces a liquid fuel which can be
works. The production of biomass liquid fuels for blending transported and stored, and allows for de-coupling of
with conventional vehicle fuels is well established in the fuel production and energy generation stages. The
Brazil and the US (UNDP/WEC, 2000). fuel can be used to generate heat and electricity by
The main technologies for biomass conversion are out- combustion in boilers, engines and turbines. Products
lined in Box 3. The issues facing each are different and other than liquid fuels can be obtained from pyrolysis;
complex, both in terms of technology and market drivers. To such as charcoal and fuel gas.
illustrate some of the issues, and to enable comparison with
R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122 117

Box 3 (continued) (UNDP/WEC, 2000), and expansion is envisaged in several


other OECD countries, including the UK. Cost reductions
Anaerobic digestion and the continued development of biomass electricity is
Anaerobic digestion is a biological process which closely related to technological developments, in both crops
converts solid or liquid biomass to a gas. The gas and combustion technologies.
consists mainly of methane and carbon dioxide and Conventional combustion technologies for biomass fuels
contains various trace elements. are closely related to coal fired combustion technologies and
Anaerobic digestion is used in the treatment of wastes as such the technology may be considered ‘mature’. State of
of industrial, agricultural and domestic origin. It is also the art combustion plants for biomass electricity generation,
used in sewage treatment plants to reduce sludge running on agricultural and forestry wastes, currently deliver
volumes and produce a gas for heat and electricity. energy at around 5 to 6 cents/kW h (UNDP/WEC, 2000).
Farm-based facilities are common, in particular in The learning rate for electricity production from biomass
countries such as China and India, at household or (using conventional combustion) has been estimated at
village-scale, for cooking, heating and lighting. Over around 15% (IEA, 2000a).
600 plants treating farm wastes, and often co-digesting Although a learning rate for biomass electricity produc-
wastes from a variety of sources, are in operation in tion using conventional combustion is available, detailed
North America and Europe. Anaerobic digestion is cost reduction projections based upon this learning rate, for
increasingly used in sewage treatment facilities, in conventional combustion technologies alone, are not appro-
treating the organic fraction of municipal solid waste priate. The reasons for this are as follows:
(MSW) and in treating industrial organic waste. The
 Development of larger and more efficient replacement
solid and liquid residues from the anaerobic digestion
process can be used as compost and fertilisers. plants underpins some of the 15% learning rate seen in
Landfill gas recent years. Whilst this is an important aspect of
Landfill gas (LFG) is a product of anaerobic and learning and the trend towards larger plant may continue,
aerobic digestion processes and generally consists of modern conventional combustion plants are already
up to 50% methane. Only 30-40% of the landfill gas is approaching theoretical limits on conversion efficiency.
 Potential for continued efficiency gain is a key driver of
normally collected, with the remainder of the gas
escaping to the atmosphere. The collected gas can be interest in gasification technologies and it would seem
cleaned and burned in engines or turbines to produce inadvisable at this stage to assume that the historic
heat and electricity. learning rate for conventional combustion technologies
Physical– chemical conversion can be applied to gasification technologies—for reasons
The physical – chemical conversion route applies to discussed below.
 Whilst considerable expansion of biomass electricity
biomass from which vegetable oil can be obtained,
and consists of pressing and extracting oil from the (primarily CHP) is planned in Denmark, Finland, Sweden
biomass. Vegetable oils can be used in special engines and the USA (UNDP/WEC, 2000), technology-specific
or in diesel engines after an esterification step to the detailed market growth data are not available.
 Biomass fuel costs may be expected to continue to fall.
produce oil methyl ester. Biofuel from oilseed rape is
produced in several European countries, the largest However, the potential for this is uncertain (see below)
production being in Germany. and fuel cost reduction alone is unlikely to be sufficient
Fermentation and hydrolysis to sustain a 15% learning rate.
Ethanol production from biomass provides a high qual-
ity fuel for transport. The bioethanol production process All these factors suggest that overall cost reduction
depends on the type of biomass considered. Sugars can potential in biomass combustion technology over the time
be fermented by various organisms. Starch and cellulo- horizon of interest here cannot be assessed without
sic biomass need first to be broken down by acidic or attention to advanced conversion technologies, and to
enzymatic hydrolysis. Progress is being made in the fuel costs.
development of technologies aimed at efficiently con-
verting cellulosic biomass. Breakthrough in this field 3.5. Biomass integrated gasification combined cycle
would provide greater opportunities for ethanol because
of increased efficiency and feedstock flexibility. Gasification of biomass feedstocks offers the potential of
higher conversion efficiencies and reduced atmospheric
emissions compared to conventional combustion technolo-
3.4.2. Future developments in biomass electricity and gies, as well as a reduced dependency on economies of
combined heat and power (CHP) scale. Integrated gasification and combined cycle gas tur-
Considerable expansion of biomass electricity (primarily bine plants (BIGCC) offer high efficiencies at a relatively
CHP) is planned in Denmark, Finland, Sweden and the USA small scale (f 30 –50 MW), which makes them suitable for
118 R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122

decentralised generation—of particular interest due to the There is some evidence that the infrastructure and exper-
distributed nature of biomass crops and the relatively high tise for growing and marketing dedicated energy crops is a
costs of transporting biomass material. In the longer term it long way from maturity at present. Confidence building
is possible that BIGCC will give way to gasification for use measures may be required in order to bring growers and
in fuel cells. generators together in an effective marketplace (PIU, 2001b).
BIGCC is currently at the pre-commercial demonstration The PIU team explored these issues using several sce-
stage. Pilot projects are operating and being developed in narios for market growth and learning in both capital and
the UK, Sweden, the US and Brazil (UNDP/WEC, 2000). fuel costs. The analysis suggests that biomass electricity-
With such a small number of operating projects, learning based upon BIGCC could deliver energy in the cost range
rates are not available. However, detailed engineering cost 2.5– 4.0 p (3.75 – 6.0 cents)/kW h in within a 20-year time-
assessment of the Swedish and UK plants has been under- frame (PIU, 2002).
taken (Bauen, 2000). The Swedish plant (a CHP scheme)
delivers energy at a cost of around 7 cents/kW h and the UK 3.5.1. Key issues
plant (electricity only) at around 11.5 cents/kW h.16 Engi- There are many challenges and obstacles to the develop-
neering assessment suggests that capital costs could be ment of biomass fuels for different applications and in
reduced by half through replication and economies of scale different parts of the world—it is not possible to do full
once BIGCC plants enter early commercial application justice to all of these here. However, the key challenges
(Bauen, 2000), this would reduce energy costs to 2.3 to facing biomass for electricity generation are to commercialise
4.5 and 5.2 to 9 cents/kW h for the Swedish and UK plants, high efficiency generating plant and to secure sustainable
respectively.17 supplies of relatively low cost fuel. This is likely to require
It should be noted that these costs are estimates of the more extensive demonstration of gasification technology and
first ‘commercial’ applications—that is where the technol- support for the development of energy crop markets.
ogies move beyond one-off demonstration projects plants
and begin to be installed in larger numbers. Further cost 3.6. Grid and electrical integration issues
reduction would be expected as market size expands. How-
ever, it is notable that the gasification process accounts for Renewable sources of energy give rise to a number of
just 19% of total capital costs, whilst combustion technol- differences in the way in which power is fed into existing
ogy costs account for around 35% (Bauen, 2000). It is not electricity networks and in which networks are operated,
clear how much scope for cost reductions in turbines—a compared to the current approach, which is dominated by
much more mature technology—may be expected. Learning large and often remote ‘central station’ power generation
rates for CCGT technologies are less than 10% (IEA, feeding directly into the high voltage grid.
2000b), and turbines for BIGCC application would repre- Renewables provide three important challenges for elec-
sent only a very small amount of existing turbine markets. tricity system operators:
Overall, whilst it is clear that considerable cost reduction for
BIGCC should be expected once the technology progresses – Intermittency,
beyond the early pilot stage, the long-term trajectory of cost – Decentralisation of generation,
reductions is uncertain. – Remoteness of some generation options.
Once capital costs are reduced to ‘early commercialisa-
tion’ levels, sensitivity to fuel cost and capital cost reduc- 3.6.1. Intermittent generation
tions become largely the same—energy costs are reduced by With the exception of biomass, renewable generation is
10% for each 20% reduction in fuel costs or capital costs both intermittent and, to a greater or lesser extent, unpre-
(Bauen, 2000). If capital costs are reduced further then dictable. The technical issues for well-developed grid sys-
sensitivity to fuel costs will increase. Considerable uncer- tems in absorbing intermittent generation were explored by
tainty surrounds the potential to lower fuel costs—partic- utilities in several countries, and by independent analysts, in
ularly in dedicated energy crops. Agricultural and forestry the early 1990s (see PIU, 2001c) for an overview). Inputs to
wastes offer a low cost fuelling option (Bauen and Kaltsch- the UK Energy Review from the UK’s grid operator, NGC,
mitt, 2001)—but this is limited to those countries with supported these conclusions from the UK perspective.
sufficient forestry and/or appropriate agricultural activity. This work suggests that:
In the UK, for example, this resource is relatively small
(DTI, 1998).  intermittency is unlikely to require major changes to the
operation of the grid (such as building additional storage
16
Bauen quotes costs in 1995 Euros, all costs have been converted at capacity, upgrading transmission lines) until the pene-
1995/Euro exchange rate (0.83) and inflated to 2001 prices (2.5% PA tration of intermittent renewables approaches 20% of
inflator) and converted into dollars at current 2002 rates. The lower cost of
the Swedish plant results largely from the utilisation of heat energy
peak supply;
available through CHP mode operation, raising overall efficiency.  at low penetrations (around 5%) intermittents are
17
The cost range reflects sensitivity to discount rate (8% and 15%). essentially invisible to the system operator, because their
R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122 119

output fluctuations are insignificant compared to the Of course, the interaction of these manifold factors is
normal fluctuations in demand; complex and it is not appropriate to conclude either that
 in the 10– 20% region it will be necessary to schedule intermittency poses an insurmountable obstacle or is never a
small amounts of additional spinning reserve, but the cost problem in every case.
impacts of this will be very small as a proportion of Finally, it is important to note that the technical costs of
generating costs (PIU, 2001c). dealing with intermittency may be at some variance with
commercial considerations when despatch of power is
Analysis undertaken for the Review also came to the managed through a competitive bidding arrangement, as is
conclusion that the costs of building additional storage or the case in most liberalised systems. The extent to which
peaking plants to enable penetration of renewables above such systems can ‘unfairly’ penalise intermittency (because
20% and up to 50% would remain small compared to total price signals are not cost reflective) has been the subject of
generation costs (PIU, 2001c, 2002). some debate and many argue that the system recently
These conclusions are based upon the assumptions that introduced in the UK does indeed introduce unfair penalties.
renewables are spread over a wide geographical area (such However, unless renewables are completely exempted
that short-term and rapid fluctuations, e.g. in wind-speed, from conventional competitive arrangements for despatch,
are evened out for the aggregated renewable input), with a intermittency is important to potential competitiveness. This
well-developed and geographically dispersed grid, and that is because the prices paid for electricity vary widely
renewable output and demand are not inversely correlated according to what point on the electricity demand curve
(such that maximum demand always occurs at minimum or suppliers are able to bid into. Prices paid for baseload
zero renewable output). Many of the studies considered generation are around 1 US cent per kW h, whereas at peak
well-dispersed wind generation. demand prices rise to up to 15 cents. In most instances
If these conditions are not met, then the problems caused intermittent generators cannot bid in at the premium end of
by intermittency may be more severe at lower penetrations. the market. As a result, low cost storage or peaking plant
Conversely, if the conditions are right, these thresholds may could make a big difference to the commercial proposition
be increased. offered by renewables. The advantage of storage technolo-
The following can reduce costs and/or increase the gies in this respect is obvious—external fuel inputs are not
capacity of a network to cope with intermittency: required and ‘excess’ renewable generation may used more
efficiently—this has the potential to improve both the
– Increased interconnection and/or larger geographical size economics and the environmental performance of renewable
of grid areas. Denmark is able to cope with large energy.
penetrations of renewables (up to 50% in places) by Overall, and given the current small contribution of
making extensive use of high capacity interconnection intermittent renewables to generation in almost every coun-
with other Scandinavian countries and Germany. try, intermittency is in general unlikely to present a problem
– Larger geographical dispersion of intermittent inputs and in the immediate future. However, as (and if) the penetration
lower correlation between variations from different of intermittent renewables expands, and in regions with less-
renewable sites. developed grids, it appears likely that the potential for
– A diversity of types of intermittent generation with output renewables will come to depend increasingly upon the costs
that varies independently. It can be shown that inter- and viability of a range of options for coping with inter-
mittents that vary independently of one another increase mittency—increased interconnection, demand management
system resilience to variations (Grubb, 1991). techniques, peaking plant and storage technologies.

The following add to costs: 3.6.2. Decentralisation


Several important options, most notably BIPV, but also
– Large penetrations in small geographical areas, what holds smaller wind developments and biomass generation, are
for the grid of an entire country may mask considerable small scale and decentralised. They supply power direct to
localised difficulties. local distribution networks, close to demand. Large numbers
– Localised grid limitations. Large penetrations of wind of such generating units would fundamentally change the
energy have already required the upgrading of local grid way in which electricity networks have been operated for
infrastructure in some regions, notably in Spain (Wind many decades in most countries—where power flow is ‘one
Power Monthly, 2000). way’ from large generating stations through a high voltage
– Strong inverse correlation between high demand and grid down to the multiple and varied loads connected to the
low renewable output. For example, large penetrations local distribution network. Increased amounts of decentral-
of PV in a country like the UK, where peak demands ised generation would require much more active manage-
occur in winter and at night, would be expected to ment of local networks, to ensure that demand and supply
require more substantial changes to system (such as remain in balance, and may require the development of new
more storage). control techniques.
120 R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122

Renewables are not the only emerging technologies 4.1. Principles and mechanisms
likely to increase the proportion of generation from decen-
tralised sources—the economic proposition offered by A number of considerations provide a basis for policy
micro-turbines and fuel cells for combined heat and power support, and this is reflected in the policies of many
(CHP) is also improving rapidly. Many analysts predict a countries. The main reasons often cited include:
significant move away from the proportion of electricity
supplies that are provided by centralised generation.  Environmental considerations; renewables provide low
pollution energy which can help meet international
3.6.3. Remote options commitments.
Renewables do not just have implications for a decentral-  Market and technology development which promise cost
isation of generation. However, the offshore options in effective low pollution energy in the future, for which
particular are both potentially large scale and remote from policy support can provide the stimulus.
both existing grid infrastructure and demands. This is likely  Security of supply; most renewables are an ‘indigenous’
to result in an increasing requirement for the development of resource.
new transmission capacity; the issues may be well illustrated  Employment and rural development; renewable energy
with reference to the UK. may create jobs, often in rural regions.
Offshore wind resources are well distributed around
the UK coast, and this means that it is feasible, at least at In most parts of the world electricity supply is being
first, to develop resources that are in close proximity to privatised and liberalised to a greater or lesser extent and in
areas where local distribution networks are well devel- a variety of ways. Direct state investment through national-
oped and robust. In addition, it is feasible for offshore ised utilities is therefore excluded from further considera-
power to be landed at existing grid supply points— tion. The extent and nature of privatisation and liberalisation
feeding energy straight into the high voltage grid. The also affects who may benefit from policy intervention (for
sites recently auctioned by the UK government fit this example independent power producers rather than regional
pattern. However, in the longer term it appears likely that utilities). A number of general options exist to support the
substantial resources in more remote areas—particularly development of renewable energy, these include:
relatively shallow waters to the north east of Scotland—
could not be exploited without substantial improvements  Public funding for R&D and dissemination programmes
to local networks and the capacity of the system to  Public Procurement
deliver power from north to south.  Direct state subsidy—this may target either capital
If the development of wave and tidal energy devices is investment in renewable plant, through direct subsidy
successful, infrastructural changes considerably more pro- for investors, or electrical output, where generators and/
found than those for offshore wind will be required. The or utilities/suppliers receive a subsidy based upon the
best resources are to the far west and northwest—where, in quantity of electricity supplied/purchased from wind
Scotland at least, there is currently no high voltage grid at generators. Few countries continue to use public funds
all. The UK’s recent investigation of an offshore power line for direct subsidy of renewable energy.
illustrates the range of options for how such problems could  Fiscal incentives—again these may target either capital
be tackled based upon conventional electricity transmission. investment in plant—for example through accelerated
Another long-term option would be to use some vector other depreciation or other tax relief on investment—or be
than electricity to transport the energy—the possibility of based upon the quantity of electricity supplied/purchased
using marine renewables to make hydrogen from seawater is from renewables generators—for example through rebate
an oft-cited example. of carbon taxes. Incentives on capital investment alone,
which fail to incentivise production, have caused prob-
lems. In California in the 1980s, and more recently in
4. Policy and progress India, this has contributed to the development of poorly
designed and unproductive wind farms (Rajeskar et al.,
The relationship between policy and progress to date is 1999).
unquestionable—policy is key to the successes above and is  Statutory obligations on electricity suppliers—this type
likely to remain so. Those countries with the most suppor- of mechanism may take a number of forms, all of which
tive policies are more successful in exploiting their renew- differ substantively. A number of variations on this theme
able resources and in developing new industries. But it is have been utilised with considerable success, particularly
also clear that policy environments differ substantively in Europe and the USA. Details differ, but a number of
between countries and that some measures have been a key options may be identified:
great deal more successful than others. Moreover, different – ‘Fixed price plus obligation to buy’, often referred to
technologies and applications require different kinds of as ‘feed-in laws’: An obligation is placed upon utilities
policies. to accept all renewably generated power, provided
R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122 121

technical criteria are met. The power producers are cussed above suggest that some of the renewables offer
paid a guaranteed price for their power-fixed accord- good prospects for becoming a cost-effective way to reduce
ing to technology type. This may be financed through carbon emissions and gain carbon permits, and hence may
subsidy, a levy on electricity, or borne by the utility no longer need more targeted support. However, those
and passed onto consumers. This system has proved options further from commercial viability may well continue
highly effective as a market stimulus, but provides to need additional support—both financial and institutional.
limited incentives for driving down price. It is also, The main reason for continued additional support for renew-
arguably, anti-competitive in the context of growing ables is to create new low carbon options for the long term;
international trade in electricity, as it favours domestic investment does not just deliver emissions reductions in the
suppliers. short term but also has an ‘option value’, helping to drive
– ‘Competitive bidding’, or ‘NFFO type18 schemes: innovation and deliver new options for reducing emissions
Renewable energy developers are invited to bid for in the long run. As discussed above, renewables also have a
contracts to sell electricity at a fixed premium price for number of non-carbon related benefits which may justify
a fixed term. The premium price emerges from the additional support.
competitive bidding process—the most competitive The relationship between innovation, product develop-
bidders being awarded contracts. In the schemes run in ment and market structure is complex and multifaceted
the UK and Ireland, the price premium was funded (Utterback, 1997). Understanding the relationship between
through a levy on conventional generation. The the innovation process and policy is also far from straight-
NFFO’s competitive nature appears to help drive cost forward. In addition to price support, it is important that
reductions. Unfortunately, in the UK at least, it has policy targets a variety of market barriers and structural
proved much less effective in driving market growth; issues that can impede the development of promising new
whether this is attributable to the system itself or to technologies (Anderson et al., 2001).
other factors specific to the UK is less clear.
– ‘Renewables Portfolios Standards’ (RPS) or obligation
based schemes: A number of countries19 are moving 5. Conclusions
away from the above two schemes in favour of a
simple obligation on electricity suppliers to source a Wind power is well-developed, with a rapidly expanding
proportion of their power from renewables. This global market and substantial technological advances over
involves a target level of renewable generation, to be the last decade. As a result, costs at the best sites onshore are
met at some point in the future, usually combined with already close to competitive with fossil fired alternatives.
tradable certificates for green electricity. Tradable There is some evidence to suggest that the rate of cost
certificates allow flexibility on the part of suppliers to reduction could slow down over the next 10 –20 years, but
either directly purchase/generate renewable electricity, considerable further cost reductions are widely predicted.
or to purchase the equivalent certificates—which The key challenge for policy is to facilitate continued
creates a competitive market for renewable power. market expansion and ensure that cost reductions are deliv-
ered. If this succeeds then there is good reason to expect that
4.2. Issues for policy wind will indeed converge with fossil fuelled alternatives,
but this is likely to require both developments offshore and
Overall, a supportive policy environment looks set to considerable expansion into parts of the world that have, as
continue for the foreseeable future. Most existing schemes yet, seen little wind energy deployed.
guarantee a supportive framework for investors for at least Photovoltaics are well established in a number of
5 –10 years and many governments have targets for the next important niche markets, many of which are likely to
10 –20 years. It appears probable that policy support will continue to expand. Policy support for grid connected,
move towards ‘RPS’ schemes, already being adopted in building integrated PV has provided one of the most
many countries, and generally considered to be more important areas for growth. As yet this support is rela-
amenable to moves to open up markets to international tively high cost, reflecting the substantial cost differential
competition. between PV and grid electricity. PV appears to offer
In the longer term, it appears likely that policies to price tremendous potential for long-term cost reduction through
carbon emissions will come into operation, particularly market growth and innovation over the next 10 –20 years
through the Kyoto Protocol, most likely in the form of and there is good evidence to suggest that the number of
tradable carbon ‘permits’. The trends and projections dis- applications where it will become cost competitive with
conventional options will expand considerably. Within this
18 timeframe, PV is likely to become cost competitive in
Non Fossil Fuel Obligation, the UK scheme introduced in the mid
1990s, now superseded by the Renewables Obligation, an RPS scheme (see
grid connected applications where solar insolation is high
main text below). and/or where it can offset the costs of building materials.
19
E.g. Denmark, the Netherlands, the UK, the US. The challenge for policy is to help provide the niche
122 R. Gross et al. / Environment International 29 (2003) 105–122

markets that allow rapid learning by doing as well as De Vries B. A turn for the better? Innovative concepts for wind energy.
Renew Energy World, April 2001;42 – 50.
supporting more research driven R&D activity into new
DTI. Renewable energy in the UK. Prospects for the 21st century. Support-
materials, etc. ing analysis for the renewables obligation consultation. London: DTI;
Wave and tidal energy are very much in their infancy, 1998. Crown copyright.
with many competing designs and, as yet, little large scale DTI. Wilson gives boost to tidal power. Press release on tidal stream P/
demonstration. However, these technologies are now leav- 2002/014, 10 January, 2002.
ing the laboratory and entering full-scale trials in several Duckers P. Wave energy. Open University teaching pages. www.
openuniversity.edu/studentweb/265/update.htm.
countries. The key challenge for policy is to provide for ETSU. The value of electricity from photovoltaic systems in buildings.
proving and testing (and in some cases failure) of promising ETSU report for the DTI, 1998.
designs. EU. Wind energy—the facts. Brussels: EC Directorate General for Energy;
Biomass energy faces multiple challenges—reflecting the 1998.
diversity of fuelling options and applications around the FT. Financial times survey. Power Gener, June 2001.
Gaudiosi G. Offshore wind energy in the world context. Renew Energy
world. Biomass for electricity generation illustrates some of 1996;9(1 – 4):899 – 904.
the issues; policy is likely to be required that supports both Grubb M. The integration of renewable electricity sources. Energy Policy
advanced conversion technologies and the development of 1991;670 – 87.
appropriate expertise and market infrastructure in dedicated Grubler A, Nakicenovic N, Victor D. Dynamics of energy technologies and
energy crop production. global change. Energy Policy 1999;27:247 – 80.
IEA . World energy outlook 2000. Paris: International Energy Agency;
Overall, renewable technologies are diverse in terms of 2000a.
both commercial and technological maturity. Some are close IEA. Experience curves for energy policy assessment. Paris: International
to competing with fossil fuels and may be cheaper if Energy Agency; 2000b.
environmental externalities are included, but others are Jackson T, Oliver D. The market for solar photovoltaics. Energy Policy
much further from market viability. Appropriate policies 1999;27:371 – 85.
KPMG. Solar energy—from perennial promise to competitive option.
are needed that allow those options and applications that are KPMG Consultants report for Greenpeace, 1999.
close to commercial viability to flourish, whilst ensuring McDonald A, Schrattenholzer D. Learning rates for energy technologies.
that options which hold promise for the longer term are Energy Policy 2001;29:255 – 61.
nurtured through their early stages. Pearson P, Pena-Tores H. Carbon abatement and new investment in liber-
alised electricity markets: a nuclear revival in the UK? Energy Policy
2000;28(2):115 – 35.
PIU. Working paper on generating technologies: potentials and cost re-
References ductions to 2020 by Rob Gross and Jake Chapman. UK Cabinet Of-
fice, 2001a. http://www.cabinet-office.gov.uk/innovation/2002/energy/
workingpapers.shtml.
Anderson D. The economics of photovoltaic technologies. In: Archer M.,
PIU. Renewable energy in the UK-building the future for the environment.
Hill R., editors. Clean electricity from photovoltaics. London: Imperial
UK Cabinet Office. http://www.cabinet-office.gov.uk/innovation/2001/
College Press; 1998. p. 741 – 71. Ch. 17.
energy/Renewener.shtml. Crown copyright, 2001b.
Anderson D, Clark C, Foxon T, Gross R, Jacobs M. Innovation and the
PIU. Working paper on penalties for intermittent sources of energy
environment: options and challenges for UK policy. ICCEPT/Fabian
by David Milborrow. UK Cabinet Office, 2001c. http://www.
Society report. London: ICCEPT; 2001. ISBN1903144019.
cabinet-office.gov.uk/innovation/2002/energy/workingpapers.shtml.
Bauen A. Sustainable heat and electricity supply from gasification-based
PUI. The energy review. London: UK Cabinet Office; 2002. Crown copy-
biomass fuel cycles: the case of Sweden and the UK. In: Sayigh AAM,
right.
editor. Proceedings of World Renewable Energy Congress VI (WREC
Rajeskar B, Hulle F, Jansen J. Indian wind energy programme: performance
2000). Elsevier; 2000.
and future direction. Energy Policy 1999;27:669 – 78.
Bauen A. PIU briefing note on biomass energy. Commissioned input to the
Shell. The evolution of the world’s energy systems. Shell Briefing Paper,
PIU energy review. London: UK Cabinet Office; 2001.
1995.
Bauen A, Kaltschmitt M. Current use and potential of solid biomass in
Thorpe T. A brief review of wave energy. AEA technology for the DTI.
developing countries and their implications for CO2 emissions. Pro-
Crown copyright, 1999.
ceedings of 1st World Biomass Conference. London: James & James;
UNDP/WEC. World energy assessment 2000—energy and the challenge of
2001.
sustainability. New York: UNDP, 2000 (ISBN 9211261260).
BTM Consult. World Market Update 2001, cited in Windpower Monthly,
Utterback D. Mastering the dynamics of innovation. Harvard, USA: Har-
April, 2001.
vard Univ Press; 1997.
Cockerill M. Combined technical and economic evaluation of the Northern
Wind Power Monthly. Financing focus. September, 2000.
European offshore wind resource. J Wind Eng Ind Aerodyn 2001;89
Wind Power Monthly. The windicator. Various issues, 2001.
(7 – 8):689 – 711.
Danish Energy Ministry. Wind power in Denmark, technologies, policies
and results; 1999. www.ens.dk/publikationer/wind_99.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi