Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 11

Energy Economics 69 (2018) 185–195

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Energy Economics

journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/eneeco

Does the level of energy intensity matter in the effect of energy


consumption on the growth of transition economies? Evidence from
dynamic panel threshold analysis
Celil Aydin a,⁎, Ömer Esen b
a
Department of Economics, Bandırma Onyedi Eylül University, 10200, Balıkesir, Turkey
b
Department of Economics, Muş Alparslan University, Muş 49250, Turkey

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: This study investigates whether the effect of energy consumption on economic growth differs by the level of en-
Received 12 August 2016 ergy intensity. We employ an advanced dynamic panel threshold regression model to test for the “threshold”
Received in revised form 10 November 2017 level of energy intensity that has an asymmetrical energy consumption effect on economic growth; we consider
Accepted 17 November 2017
12 Commonwealth of Independent States countries over the period 1991–2013. The estimated panel threshold
Available online 26 November 2017
regression model suggests 0.44% as the threshold level of energy intensity. Energy consumption above this
JEL classification:
level significantly retards economic growth, whereas energy consumption below the level is found to have a sta-
C24 tistically significant positive effect on economic growth. Thus, when the threshold level of energy intensity (one
Q43 of the important indicators of energy efficiency) is exceeded, energy consumption significantly hinders growth. If
O11 policy makers pay more attention to energy intensity while formulating new energy policies, substantial gains
can be achieved in low energy intensity environments.
Keywords: © 2017 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
Dynamic panel threshold analysis
Energy consumption
Economic growth
Energy intensity

1. Introduction over the USSR's economic structure. These countries constituted just
one part of the interactive economy in terms of technology and produc-
The transition of a centrally planned economy into a market economy tion management principles. The multidimensional economic relations
requires a long and socially costly process involving comprehensive and of previous periods were eliminated after the dissolution of the Soviet
continuous development and change for the whole economic system. system, with the result of economic regression for the transitioning
The main component of a successful transformation is a set of corporate states. For several reasons such as obsolete technology and lack of cap-
and structural regulations. Because these corporate and structural regula- ital, the transition economies that took up this production structure did
tions would include sustainable economic and behavioral principles, the not have the production capacity to meet their internal demand during
transition process must be gradual. For a real-world example, the reason the transition process. In addition, political failures and widespread
why the Soviet system lost its power was the loss of its economic influ- poverty increased the social and political tension in the post-Soviet
ence (Havrylyshyn, 2001). Thus, a resource allocation mechanism based countries. Thus, the transition countries that had sufficient energy and
on centralist planning is inadequate for the efficient and effective use of other natural resources used them, at least to some extent, to alleviate
economic resources. Studies on the determinants of economic growth the problems that arose during the transition process. The energy sector
during a transition process have emphasized that increasing the efficiency acted as growth engine in this process. In addition, the energy sector has
of production factors can be more determining than pumping additional an important place in public and export income. The countries' exports
investments into the economy (Havrylyshyn and Wolf, 1999). consisted of mostly energy products, and as a result, there was large in-
When the Union of Soviet Socialist Republics (USSR) dissolved in the stability in their currency income and energy prices. Furthermore, the
early 1990s, the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS) countries fluctuations observed in their energy prices adversely affected their eco-
transitioning from centralist planning into free market economies took nomic development. However, for sustainable growth, the production
structure of the transition countries must depend less on the export of
⁎ Corresponding author.
labor-intensive goods and unprocessed raw material (especially oil
E-mail addresses: celil.aydin@atauni.edu.tr (C. Aydin), o.esen@alparslan.edu.tr and gas) to the developed countries and focus more on industries re-
(Ö. Esen). quiring intensive capital and advanced technology. This emphasizes

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2017.11.010
0140-9883/© 2017 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
186 C. Aydin, Ö. Esen / Energy Economics 69 (2018) 185–195

the importance of energy consumption depending on the increased pro- following the collapse of the socialist regime at the end of the 1980s. In
duction and efficient use of energy. line with this purpose, we believe that this study contributes significantly
As the efficient use of energy implies the finding of new energy re- to the literature on the foundations of the transition economies' economic
sources, the effective and efficient use of energy resources is no less im- growth by examining the issue in terms of where the states take active
portant than the energy consumption for economic development. As roles. This study contributes to the literature in four different aspects:
the literature review shows, energy intensity is an indicator of energy (i) First, our sample consists of 12 economies transitioning from the social-
efficiency. The energy intensity ratios of a country depend on certain ist economic system to the market economic system. While these coun-
factors (e.g., the production structure of the economy, scale of indus- tries experience different market economies, they face identical
tries, capacity utilization levels, consumption habits of societies, popula- problems such as poverty, less developed infrastructure, strong and strict
tion, climatic conditions, technological developments, energy policies, command installation, and a public sector that is continuously becoming
and amount of energy resources). Energy intensity refers to the amount bigger and clumsier. Apart from the extremely centralized, interventionist,
of energy an economy uses per unit value added in a specific production and clumsy structure of the socialist system, several reasons such as lack of
process, or the intensity of energy usage in the production process good infrastructure, obsolescence of technology, and lack of capital directly
(Gomulka, 1990; Fisher-Vanden et al., 2004; Liao et al., 2007). Hence, affect their efficiency and economic growth. Therefore, our study of coun-
energy intensity is the measure of energy use efficiency of an economy tries carrying out corporate and structural regulations to overcome poverty
in the production process. Low energy intensity means that the econo- is a good contribution to the literature. (ii) Second, while earlier studies ex-
my is using its energy resources more efficiently and effectively in pro- amine the energy consumption–economic growth nexus, we analyze the
duction; that is, it indicates that the amount of energy consumed to effect of energy consumption on growth by taking into account how ener-
generate one unit of income is low (Kavak, 2005: 12). In this sense, gy resources are used in terms of efficiency. Energy intensity level is one of
the use of less energy to satisfy the energy needed for growth contrib- the most important factors determining the relationship between energy
utes to an economy in several ways (e.g., less dependence on external consumption and growth. (iii) Third, in contrast to previous studies, we
energy sources and increased resistance to external shocks). Under analyze the long-term relationship between variables by taking national
such circumstances, the resources should be channeled to investments and international tendencies into consideration. (iv) Fourth, previous stud-
generating high added value so as to create an environment allowing ies focus on the effects of energy consumption on economic growth as-
for energy to be used as efficiently as possible. Productivity can be in- suming that the relationship is linear, meaning that the effect of energy
creased through the consumption of less energy through improved en- consumption on growth is the same (symmetrical) for both intense and
ergy efficiency. Besides promoting economic growth, this can help even periods. On the other hand, we assume that the relationship between
reduce greenhouse gas emissions, which is supposed to be the main energy consumption and economic growth need not necessarily be linear.
cause of climate change. Thus, we can conclude that the transition Thus, the effects of energy consumption on growth are asymmetrical. In
from energy resources providing lower efficiency and high pollution other words, the effects depend on the energy intensity. This study offers
to energy options offering more efficiency could boost the economy an alternative to the extant literature by employing an innovative non-
rather than hinder economic growth (Belke et al., 2011). Otherwise, linear dynamic panel threshold regression analysis.
the low contribution of each factor to production—and, thus to The purpose of this paper is to investigate whether level of energy
growth—would mean low income levels, restricted new investment op- intensity plays an important role in the effect of energy consumption
portunities, and impeded long-term and steady economic growth. on the growth of twelve CIS countries in the transition process. In the
From the literature review, most studies examining the relationship study, the threshold regression model was used to find the threshold
between energy consumption and economic growth focus on models level above which energy consumption adversely affects economic
and analysis techniques that use a linear hypothesis based on causal re- growth. Moreover, the study aims to put the energy consumption-
lationship. Analyses and interpretations based on the assumption of lin- growth debates, which are built most often on an incorrect theoretical
ear relationship between energy consumption and economic growth and empirical basis, on a solid ground. This paper is organized as fol-
point to the symmetrical relationship between increases and decreases lows. Section 1 discusses the effect of energy consumption on economic
in energy consumption and economic growth. These studies view the en- growth within the framework of the efficient use of energy. Section 2
ergy consumption level as indicator of development, assuming that a briefly reviews the theoretical and empirical literature focusing on the
country's production and welfare level are based on the amount of energy relationship between energy consumption and economic growth.
it consumes. However, the development of a country should be measured Section 3 describes the model and econometric methodology used in
by its ability to create more economic value using less energy (i.e., deliver the study. Section 4 examines both the linear and non-linear effect of
the same production output with a lower amount of energy), rather than energy consumption on economic growth in two steps. In the first
energy consumption rates. Energy consumption is indeed important for step, whether energy consumption has an effect on economic growth
economic growth, but it must be balanced. The energy saved through ef- is examined through an analysis of co-integration and causality under
ficient usage is more valuable than the energy produced. Increasing the structural breaks based on linear assumptions. In the second step, con-
efficiency of energy is more economical than investments to obtain addi- sidering that a long-term and linear relationship exists between the var-
tional energy resources. Also, it could be more costly and time consuming iables, it is questioned whether the effect of energy consumption on
to produce the same amount of energy that can be obtained through sav- economic growth changes according to energy intensity through the
ings. Moreover, saving energy is relatively quicker and cheaper; that is, it use of non-linear threshold regression techniques. Section 5 provides
is more efficient. Therefore, how energy is consumed is more important policy implications and conclusions.
than the amount of energy consumed. This asymmetry points to a non-
linear relationship. Empirical studies in the literature provide very little 2. Literature review
information on whether this relationship is linear (i.e., whether energy
consumption has a threshold level) or not. The importance of energy as an input for economic growth had been
The relationship between energy consumption and economic growth ignored until the 1973–1974 and 1978–1979 oil crises. With these oil
has been one of the most frequently discussed issues in the economics lit- shocks, the entire world realized that energy and energy-based inputs
erature, especially after the oil crises in the 1970s. However, the issue has play an important role in the production process. As a result, the num-
not been addressed in terms of the economies transitioning from centrally ber of studies examining the relationship between energy and econom-
planned to free market economies. This study aims to empirically reveal ic growth gradually increased. Although many studies examine the
the effect of energy consumption on the economic growth of 12 CIS coun- effect of energy consumption on economic growth, the debates are
tries transitioning from centrally planned to free market economies still ongoing about whether energy consumption is the locomotive of
C. Aydin, Ö. Esen / Energy Economics 69 (2018) 185–195 187

economic growth or has little adverse or no effect on economic growth. supporting these results. Aydin and Esen (2016) examined whether the
In the literature, many studies investigating the effect of energy con- level of energy intensity plays an important role in the relationship be-
sumption on economic growth have arrived at different results. For ex- tween energy consumption and economic growth in the case of Turkey.
ample, Yu and Choi (1985) for Philippines, Masih and Masih (1996) for They observed that energy consumption significantly promotes economic
India and Pakistan, Soytas and Sari (2003) for Turkey, France, Germany, growth when energy intensity is below 0.191, the threshold level, where-
and Japan, Shiu and Lam (2004) for China, Sari and Soytas (2007) for as it has a negative effect on economic growth when energy intensity is
Indonesia, Iran, Malaysia, Pakistan, Singapore, and Tunisia, Narayan above this threshold. A similar study conducted by Aydin and Esen
and Smyth (2008) for G7 countries, Lee and Chang (2008) for 16 (2017) emphasizes that the level of energy intensity has a particular
Asian countries, Apergis and Payne (2009a) for six Central American threshold value, that energy consumption is an important hurdle to eco-
countries, Apergis and Payne (2009b) for 11 CIS countries, Menyah nomic growth when such threshold is exceeded, and that the level of in-
and Wolde-Rufael (2010) for South Africa, Tsani (2010) for Greece, Al- tensity has to be considered for sustainable growth performance.
Mulali and Sab (2012) for 30 Sub-Saharan African countries, Iyke
(2015) for Nigeria, and Esen and Bayrak (2017) for 75 net energy- 3. Model, data set, and econometric method
importing countries have found that energy consumption promotes
economic growth, while other studies, such as Yu and Hwang (1984) This study investigates whether the effect of energy consumption on
for the US, Yu and Choi (1985) for the US, the UK, and Poland, Masih economic growth is dependent upon energy intensity level based on a
and Masih (1996) for Malaysia, Singapore, and the Philippines, Cheng sample of 12 CIS countries (Azerbaijan, Armenia, Belarus, Georgia,
(1999) for India, Oh and Lee (2004) for Korea, Al-Iriani (2006) for 6 Kazakhstan, Kyrgyzstan, Moldova, Russia, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan,
Gulf Cooperation Council countries, Mehrara (2007) for 11 oil exporting Uzbekistan, and Ukraine) in the transition process covering the period
countries, Menegaki (2011) for 27 European countries, and Hamit- from 1991 to 2013. This relationship was examined based on the neoclas-
Haggar (2012) for Canada, support the view that energy consumption sical production function used by Ghali and El-Sakka (2004), Lee and
has little or no effect on economic growth. Chang (2007), and Huang et al. (2008). Eq. (1) shows the production
Most studies dealing with the relationship between energy consump- function, which includes energy consumption as a factor of production
tion and economic growth depend on the assumption that a linear and like capital stock and labor:
causal relationship exists between the two variables. Following the selec-
tion of econometric models, analyses are conducted in accordance with _ it þ βxit þ ε it
Y_ it ¼ α 0 initiali þ α 1 EC ð1Þ
this assumption. If models are selected and analyses are carried out by as-
suming that there is a linear relationship between the two variables, it is where Y_ indicates the real GDP growth at time t in country i; initial indi-
directly accepted as a presupposition that the variables display similar be- _ is the energy consumption rate; x rep-
cates the initial level of income; EC
haviours regardless of the production structure of the country. On the resents other macroeconomic variables that might have an impact on
other hand, energy consumption can have a non-linear effect on economic economic growth; and ε denotes the white noise error term.
growth depending on the way the energy is used. Although energy con- The literature review shows that the real GDP is taken as a basis in the
sumption is regarded as a development indicator in the growth and devel- international comparisons as it gives important information about the
opment literature, the focus of recent debates has mostly been on the growth performances of economies; however, in comparing the living
need to consider the ability to create more economic value by using less standards of different countries or examining the changes in the welfare
energy as an indicator of development, instead of the energy consumption level of a country over time, the real GDP per capita is preferred as it
levels. In line with such debates there has been an increase in the number takes into account the number of people living in a country. In this sense,
of studies focusing on the possibility that a non-linear relationship exists we used the annual growth rate of real GDP per capita (dgdp) as an indica-
between economic growth and energy consumption and on the potential tor of living standards. We also used the growth rate of energy consump-
asymmetric effect energy consumption has on economic growth. tion per capita (dec) as the independent variable of the model. The energy
The empirical research in the literature dealing with energy and consumption growth rate was calculated based on the logarithmic differ-
growth offers very little information about the existence or non- ence of energy consumption per capita (tons of oil equivalent). To control
existence of a non-linear relationship between energy consumption and the effects of other macroeconomic variables related to economic growth,
economic growth (i.e., about the existence or non-existence of a threshold we used the following control variables based on the studies of Khan and
level for energy consumption). Lee and Chang's (2007) research is among Senhadji (2001), Drukker et al. (2005), Huang et al. (2008), and Kremer
the most important studies conducted based on the assumption that a et al. (2013): percentage of GDP dedicated to investment (igdp), growth
non-linear relationship exists. Using one-sector and two-sector growth of labor force participation rate (dlab), inflation (π),1 initial income level
models, they investigated the linear and non-linear effects of energy con- (dgdpit-1), openness (open), terms of trade (dtot), standard deviation of
sumption on economic growth in Taiwan for the period from 1955 to openness (sdopen), and standard deviation of terms of trade (sdtot). We
2003. Their findings indicate that a non-linear relationship exists and is also used energy intensity (tpes/Y) as the threshold variable. In addition,
characterized by a “U-shape” pattern between the two variables for considering that the fluctuations in energy prices could affect economic
Taiwan. According to this pattern, first a decrease and then an increase growth over energy demand/consumption, the uncertainty variable of en-
occur. In this pattern, although the energy consumption under the esti- ergy prices (uncertainty) was added to the model (Bernanke, 1983;
mated optimal values positively affects economic growth at a significant Papapetrou, 2001; Belke and Goecke (2005).2 We obtained the data
level, the relationship is insignificant over the threshold (or even a nega-
tive relationship exists). Conducting a similar study, Huang et al. (2008) 1
Annual change in Consumer Price Index representing all prices and that which is con-
separated the data covering the 1971–2002 period into two periods for sidered to affect energy consumption (energy price, peripheral taxes, exchange rate, the
82 countries and investigated the relationship between energy consump- price of consumption goods, etc.) was added to the model (Belke and Dreger, 2015).
2
To calculate the uncertainty variable, we first apply a stationarity test on the annual
tion and economic growth in these periods. Their analysis results indicate
change observed in the monthly raw oil prices, and find stationarity at I(0). Then, in order
a non-linear relationship between the two variables. to select the optimal average equations, we form various ARMA (p,q) models. ARMA
The literature on the role of energy intensity in this relationship pro- (1,12) was determined to be the most optimal average equation in view of the AIC values
vides little evidence. Hu and Wang (2006) examined the energy efficiency and cost of the Box-Jenkins methodology. In order to test for an ARCH effect in the average
of 29 regions of China and determined, by finding a U-shaped relationship equation, we used the ARCH-LM test, and found that the ARCH effect did exist. Then, on
testing the ARCH–GARCH models, the GARCH (1,1) model was selected as the most opti-
between energy efficiency and per capita income, that energy efficiency mal model. When the ARCH-LM was applied again, we found that the ARCH effect did not
would rise along with economic growth. Honma and Hu (2008), who exist. Finally, we calculated the annual average of the monthly variance values, including
conducted a similar study for the regions of Japan, obtained findings those for the period 1991–2013.
188 C. Aydin, Ö. Esen / Energy Economics 69 (2018) 185–195

about real GDP per capita and percentage of GDP dedicated to investment the threshold value with the smallest sum of squared residuals (S(γ)) as
from the Penn World Table version 9.0. The data about the inflation rates the most appropriate threshold value (γ ^ ). Eq. (4) shows this procedure
and population were obtained from the United Nations Statistics (UN (Hansen, 2000: 578):
Data), the data about crude oil price were obtained from U.S. Energy Infor-
mation Administration (EIA), and the data about the other variables were ^ ¼ argmin Sn ðγÞ
γ ð4Þ
acquired from the database of the World Development Indicators (WDI).3
We included the lagged value of the growth rate of GDP per capita in Following the earlier studies by Hansen (1999), Caner and Hansen
the model as the explanatory variable based on the assumption that pro- (2004), and Kremer et al. (2013), we estimate the critical values and de-
duction level and structure of an economy are not entirely independent termine the 95% confidence interval of the energy intensity threshold
of the previous periods; thus, production levels in the previous period value. We use Eq. (5) to estimate these critical values:
are also reflected in the subsequent periods (Ramirez-Rondán, 2013).
Г ¼ fγ : LRðγÞ ≤ C ðα Þg ð5Þ
The fixed effects and random effects models used for dynamic panel
data analysis considered the lagged effects of the dependent variable as
In Eq. (5), C(α) is the 95% percentile of the asymptotic distribution of
the explanatory variable. Thus, a relationship emerged between the
the likelihood ratio statistic LR(γ). The underlying likelihood ratio is ad-
lagged values of the dependent variable and the error terms, and this re-
justed to account for the number of time periods used for each cross sec-
lationship led to inconsistencies between the estimations made by fixed
tion. In the dynamic panel model, once the appropriate threshold value
and random effects models and the estimators (Greene, 2000). In such
(γ^ ) is determined, the slope coefficients are estimated by the general-
cases, the dynamic panel data method can eliminate the relationship
between the lagged values of the dependent variable and the error ized method of moments (GMM) for the previously determined instru-
terms and thus increase the reliability of the estimations and consisten- ments and the previously estimated threshold. Eq. (6) gives the
cy of the estimators. dynamic panel threshold model formed with GMM to examine the ef-
In this study, we applied the dynamic panel threshold model devel- fect of the energy intensity threshold value on the relationship between
oped by Kremer et al. (2013) that extends Hansen's (1999) static model energy consumption and economic growth.
for endogenous regressors. We chose the initial level of income as the    
dgdpit ¼ ui þ β1 decit I ðtpes=Y Þit ≤ γ þ δ1 I ðtpes=Y Þit ≤ γ
endogenous regressor (dgdpit-1). Our panel threshold model was built þ β2 decit I ðtpes=Y Þit Nγ þ ∅zit þ εit ; ð6Þ
on Caner and Hansen's (2004) cross-sectional threshold model, where
Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) type estimators are used in where decit represents the growth rate of energy consumption per
order to allow for endogeneity. Eq. (2) shows the model. capita for both regime types, zit represents the vector of control vari-
ables, tpes/Y denotes the threshold variable, β1 and β2 indicate the
yit ¼ ui þ β01 zit Iðqit ≤ γ Þ þ β02 zit Iðqit NγÞ þ εit ; ð2Þ regime-dependent slope coefficients, and δ1 indicates the fixed regime
coefficient. Following Bick (2010) and Kremer et al. (2013), we use
where i represents the units within the scope of the cross section (i = 1, the initial income level dgdpit − 1(z2it) as the endogenous variable.
…,n), t indicates the time series dimension for each unit (t = 1, …, T), yit The number of instrumental variables in the estimations using the dy-
is the dependent variable, μi is the country-specific fixed effect, εit ≈ namic panel analysis method is important because it affects the results
(0,σ2) is the independently and identically distributed error term, I(.) (Roodman, 2009). However, the number of instrumental variables in a fi-
is the indicator function specifying the regime, qit is the threshold vari- nite sampling model displays the interchangeable relationship between
able, and ϒ is the threshold value. In addition, zit indicates an m- the efficiency of the estimators and the deviation. While the use of all
dimensional vector of explanatory regressors that may include the the possible lagged dependent variables as instrumental variables in-
lagged values of the dependent variable and other endogenous vari- creases the efficiency of the estimators, using just one lagged dependent
ables. The vector of explanatory variables is partitioned into a subset variable as instrumental variable makes the estimated coefficients neu-
z1it of exogenous variables uncorrelated with εit and a subset of endog- tral. (Kremer et al., 2013). Taking the efficiency into account and based
enous variables z2it correlated with εit (Kremer et al., 2013). on Arellano and Bover's (1995) study, all the lagged values of the depen-
In the first step of the model estimation in Eq. (2), the individual ef- dent variable in the model are used as instrumental variables.4
fects (μi) have to be eliminated via a fixed-effects transformation. There-
fore, we apply the forward orthogonal deviation method suggested by 4. Findings
Arellano and Bover (1995). Eq. (3) gives the method:
rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi  This study examines the role of energy intensity in the relationship be-
T−t 1   tween the economic growth and energy consumption of 12 CIS countries
εit ¼ εit − εiðtþ1Þ þ ⋯ þ εiT ð3Þ
T−t þ 1 T−t in two steps. In the first step, we examine whether energy consumption
affected economic growth using analyses based on linear assumptions.
The most distinguishing feature of this method is that it can avoid In the second step, we consider the long-term relationship between the
the serial correlation of the transformed error terms. This feature allows variables and examine whether the effect of energy consumption on eco-
for applying the estimation procedure derived for a cross-sectional nomic growth changes according to the energy intensity.
model to dynamic panel data models. While analyzing the long-term relationship between economic
The next step of the estimation procedure involves the use of two- growth and energy consumption, we need to distinguish between na-
stage least squares (2SLS) to estimate the energy intensity threshold tional and international tendencies. Therefore, the variables should be
level. To this end, we first estimate a reduced-form regression for the categorized as the countries' common or idiosyncratic variables.
endogenous variables (z2it) as a function of the instruments (Xit). The While national developments have a role in the development of idio-
endogenous variables (z2it) in the structural equation are then replaced syncratic variables, the international trends effective in the development
by the predicted values (^z2it). Finally, we estimate the model in Eq. (2) of variables also drive the common variables. Moreover, the idiosyncratic
via least squares for a fixed threshold (ϒ). This step is repeated for the variables may differ from country to country. Most of the co-integration
subsets of the threshold variable q. From the threshold values, we select tests examining the long-term relationship between variables consider

3 4
For the basic information and descriptive statistics of the variables, see Tables A.1 and In addition, we use only one lagged value of the dependent variable as instrumental
A.2, respectively, in Appendix A. In addition, the graphics of the variables are given in variable in the study. The number of selected instrumental variables has no significant ef-
Fig. B.1, Appendix B. fect on the results.
C. Aydin, Ö. Esen / Energy Economics 69 (2018) 185–195 189

only the common variables and disregard the country's idiosyncratic fea- Once the GDP per capita and energy consumption per capita series
tures. Because the results of such tests may change when the idiosyncratic are found to be stationary at their first difference level, it is important
features are taken into account, this study prefers the tests that consid- to test for the long-term relationship between the two variables. For
ered the countries' common variables as well as idiosyncratic features this purpose, we use the LM-based test developed by Westerlund and
(Dobnik, 2011; Belke et al., 2014a; Belke et al., 2014b). Edgerton (2008). This test checks for the co-integration relationship be-
First, we examine the dependency between cross sections (coun- tween non-stationary series in cases of cross-sectional dependency and
tries) and whether the dependency between the panel cross sections af- for more than one structural break in the co-integration relationship.
fects the estimation results to a great extent (Breusch and Pagan, 1980; The Zφ(N) and Zτ(N) test statistics in the panel co-integration test
Pesaran, 2004). Thus, the cross-sectional dependency in the series and results show a co-integration relationship between GDP per capita
co-integration equation needs to be tested. In addition, this factor and energy consumption per capita in cases of cross-sectional depen-
should be kept in mind when selecting the unit root and co- dency and structural breaks.7 Therefore, we conclude that the series
integration tests. Otherwise, the analysis would be incorrect. Therefore, move together in the long run. The structural break dates found in the
we first analyze the existence of cross-sectional dependency using the co-integration equations of the panel countries are given in Table A.7,
Adjusted Lagrange Multiplier (LMadj) test developed by Breusch and Appendix A. By applying the approach of Westerlund and Edgerton
Pagan (1980) and corrected by Pesaran et al. (2008). (2008), we found one structural break in both specifications for each
From the cross-sectional dependency test results, the null hypothe- country with mean and regime shifts,8 which can be associated with
sis of “no cross-sectional dependency” formulated with regard to the huge global shocks.
GDP per capita and energy consumption per capita series is strongly As a next step, the long-term relationship between GDP per capita
rejected. Thus, we conclude that the series and the model involved and energy consumption per capita was estimated by means of the
cross-sectional dependency.5 From this result, a shock affecting one Fully Modified Ordinary Least Squares (FMOLS) and Dynamic Ordinary
country does affect other countries too. It is also important to choose Least Squares (DOLS) methods, taking each country's break dates ob-
the methods used to test for cross-sectional dependency. Therefore, in tained as a result of the co-integration tests. The findings are shown in
the following parts of the study, we use the panel unit root tests as Table A.8 in the Appendix A. The first and second columns in Table A.8
well as panel co-integration analysis methods, both of which take show the estimation results of FMOLS and DOLS, respectively, under
cross-sectional dependency into consideration. conditions where country-specific structural breaks are disregarded.
The second part of the analysis examines whether the panel data The last two columns, on the other hand, show the estimation results
remained stationary over time. The first problem with panel unit root under conditions where country-specific structural breaks are taken
analysis related to whether the panel cross sections are independent into consideration.
from each other. We divide the panel unit root tests into two categories, As the long-run estimation results show, when country-specific
the first-generation and second-generation tests. The first-generation structural breaks are not taken into account, the energy consumption
tests are further divided into two categories depending on whether per capita effect on GDP is statistically significant and negative under
the panel cross sections are homogenous or heterogeneous. While both methods. In contrast, when the country-specific structural breaks
Levin et al. (2002), Breitung (2000), and Hadri (2000) depended on are taken into account, the effect decreases, but the direction does not
the homogeneity hypothesis, Im et al. (2003), Maddala and Wu change. The possible long-run negative effect of energy consumption
(1999), and Choi (2001) depended on the heterogeneity hypothesis. on economic growth can be attributed to the excessive energy con-
The second-generation unit root tests are based on the assumption sumption of inefficient sectors or inefficient energy supply in the
that the panel cross sections are not independent, and that a shock af- economies.
fecting one cross-sectional units also affects the other units in various In the next stage, we analyze the causality between the GDP per
ways. Among the main second-generation unit root tests were Multi- capita and energy consumption per capita. In this context, we estimated
variate Augmented Dickey Fuller (MADF) developed by Taylor and the dynamic panel error-correction model by using the pooled mean
Sarno (1998), Seemingly Unrelated Regression Augmented Dickey Full- group (PMG) method proposed by Pesaran et al. (1999). The Granger
er (SURADF) developed by Breuer et al. (2002), and Cross-sectional causality between the GDP per capita and energy consumption per
Augmented Dickey Fuller (CADF) developed by Pesaran (2006). capita was controlled for with the Wald chi-squared test.9
However, as these tests may give deviant, incorrect results, there is a As the dynamic panel causality test results show,10 as a whole, a bi-
unit root in the panel when structural breaks occur in the series (Lee directional causal relationship exists between ΔGdp per capita and ΔEC
and Strazicich, 2004; Carrion-i-Silvestre et al. 2005). In order to elimi- per capita in the long-term, short-term, and strong causality conditions.
nate the shortcomings of these tests, Bai and Carrion-i-Silvestre Thus, ΔGdp per capita is a Granger causality for ΔEC per capita, and ΔEC
(2009) developed a method to test the stationarity of the series in per capita is a Granger causality for ΔGdp per capita. Furthermore, the
cases of cross-section dependency and multi structural breaks. This error correction terms (ECT) of the bidirectional causal relationship
test can evaluate the stationarity of the series of the panel in cases of are predicted to be significant at the 1% level with negative coefficients,
structural breaks in the averages and trends of the series. Thus, the sta- indicating that the relationship will move to equilibrium in the long run
tionarity of the series was tested using Bai and Carrion-i-Silvestre's after an external shock.
(2009) second-generation unit root test that regards both the cross- Thus far, we analyzed the effect of energy consumption on economic
section dependency and the structural breaks. growth. The analyses based on the linearity hypothesis show that the
Bai and Carrion-i-Silvestre (2009) claimed that Z* and P* statistics absolute effect of energy consumption on growth is the same (symmet-
can be used when the sample number is small, and that a simplified rical) in both the intense and even periods. However, we need to note
cluster is appropriate for level and trend break models (Liddle and that when the effect of energy consumption on growth is asymmetrical,
Messinis, 2015). Hence, we focus on these two (simplified) statistics meaning that the energy intensity is high, the effect of energy
in the test results. The results showed that the “series includes unit
root” null hypothesis cannot be rejected in terms of GDP per capita 7
The panel co-integration test results with structural breaks and cross-sectional depen-
and energy consumption per capita levels, but can be rejected in its dence are shown in Table A.6, Appendix A.
first difference at the 1% significance level.6 8
The countries' structural break dates are added to the dynamic panel threshold model
as (dummyit).
9
This study uses the Stata routine “xtpmg” proposed by Blackburne and Frank (2007)
5
The cross-sectional dependency test results are shown in Table A.3, Appendix A. to estimate the dynamic panel error-correction model using the PMG method.
6 10
Bai and Carrion-i-Silvestre (2009). The panel unit root test results with structural The dynamic panel causality test results for the CIS countries are given in Table A.9,
breaks and cross-sectional dependence are given in Tables A.4 and A.5, Appendix A. Appendix A.
190 C. Aydin, Ö. Esen / Energy Economics 69 (2018) 185–195

consumption on growth will not be the same during the intense and
even periods. Therefore, we analyze the role of energy intensity in the
relationship between energy consumption and economic growth
using a dynamic panel threshold model that is not based on the linearity
hypothesis.
The role of energy intensity on the non-linear relationship between
economic growth and energy consumption was examined for the peri-
od 1991–2013 for 12 CIS countries. The obtained findings are shown in
Table 1. The upper part of Table 1 shows the estimated energy intensity
threshold level and the corresponding 95% confidence interval. The
middle part of the table shows the effect of energy consumption per
capita on economic growth for both regime types. β ^ denotes the mar-
1
ginal effect of energy consumption per capita on economic growth in
^ indicates the marginal effect
the low energy intensity regime, while β 2
of energy consumption per capita on economic growth in the high ener-
gy intensity regime. In a low energy intensity regime, the energy inten-
sity level is below the estimated threshold value, while in a high energy
intensity regime, the energy intensity level is above the estimated
threshold value.
As shown in Table 1, the estimated threshold value for energy inten-
sity is 0.44 (via two-stage least squares). Fig. 1 shows the sum of the Fig. 1. The sum of the squared errors of the threshold values.
threshold value squared errors for the model. In the model, the lower
limit of the threshold value at the 95% confidence level is 0.31, while industrialization, if the economic structure turns to more low energy in-
the upper limit is 1.58. These findings show that, in general, energy in- tensity industries and to technological developments that favor the effi-
tensity increases in the initial stages of economic development, but cient use of energy, it may decrease the energy intensity (Leach et al.,
shows a declining trend in the developed economies from the increas- 1986).
ing share of the services (tertiary) sector in economic growth during The results show that the regime-dependent coefficients are statisti-
the development process. In the underdeveloped or developing econo- ^ = 0.553 and β ^ = −0.331), meaning that energy
cally significant (β 1 2
mies, an increase in energy intensity is an expected consequence of in-
consumption per capita has a positive marginal effect on economic
dustrialization. In countries that have achieved a certain level of
growth in the regime with low energy intensity, but a negative marginal
effect in the regime with high energy intensity. In other words, the rate
Table 1 of energy consumption per capita below the threshold level has a posi-
Economic growth and energy consumption. tive effect on economic growth. If the rate is above the threshold value,
Estimated threshold value (tpes/Y) it would affect economic growth negatively. If we examine the regime-
^
γ 0.44*** dependent coefficients, we would find the effect of energy consumption
95% confidence interval [0.31–1.58] per capita on economic growth higher in the regime with low energy
Effect of energy consumption per capita (dec)
^
intensity.
β 0.553***
1
(0.191) Table 1 shows the GDP per capita first-degree lagged value coeffi-
^
β 2
−0.331*** cient in the model statistically significant. On the other hand, the control
(0.100) variable coefficients generally comply with the a priori expectations.
Effect of control variables First, the GDP percentage dedicated to investment and growth of labor
initialit −16.634*** force participation rate has a positive effect on GDP per capita. A quick
(3.732) increase in investment and growth of labor force participation can
igdpit 0.125**
lead to an increase in GDP. Second, inflation and the terms of trade
(0.053)
dlabit 0.389**
have a negative effect on GDP per capita. A decrease in inflation and for-
(0.171) eign trade rates can increase the GDP per capita. In addition, a significant
totit −0.101** relationship clearly exists between the dummy variable and GDP per
(0.051) capita. Because fluctuations in energy prices affect the economic growth
sdtotit −27.425***
over energy demand/consumption, we again estimate the non-linear
(9.078)
openit 1.345 relationship between economic growth and energy consumption
(3.016) under uncertain conditions using the dynamic panel threshold model.
sdopenit −9.701* The results are given in Table 2.
(5.497) As Table 2 shows, the estimated threshold value for energy intensity
πit −0.003***
(0.0007)
is 0.44 under uncertain conditions. The model's lower limit for the
dummyit 8.404*** threshold value at the 95% confidence level is 0.31, while the upper
(2.059) limit is 1.55. Thus, taking or not taking uncertainty into consideration
^
δ1 5.688* does not affect the threshold value for energy intensity. In other
(3.221)
words, the fluctuations observed in energy prices do not affect the ener-
Number of observations gy intensity threshold level.
^
tpes=Y ≤ γ 53 From the results, the regime-dependent coefficients are statistically
tpes=YNγ^ 223
significant (β^ = 0.494 and β ^ = −0.336) under uncertain conditions.
Number of countries 12 1 2
Thus, when uncertainty is not taken into consideration, the marginal ef-
Notes: The table shows the results for the dynamic panel threshold model. All available
fect of energy consumption per capita on economic growth is positive in
lags of the dependent variable are used as instruments in the analysis. Standard errors
are given in parentheses. *, **, *** indicate significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels, a regime with low energy intensity, whereas it is negative in a regime
respectively. with high energy intensity. When the regime coefficients are analyzed
C. Aydin, Ö. Esen / Energy Economics 69 (2018) 185–195 191

Table 2 consideration. For the estimation of long-term coefficients, we used the


Economic growth and energy consumption including energy prices among the explanato- DOLS and FMOLS estimators. From the findings, energy consumption
ry variables.
has a long-term, negative, and statistically significant effect on economic
Estimated threshold value (tpes/Y) growth. Studies have observed that when structural breaks are consid-
^
γ 0.44*** ered, the effects decreased for both methods, but the direction did not
95% confidence interval [0.31–1.55]
change. These findings support the hypothesis that the consumption of
Effect of energy consumption per capita (dec)
^ 0.491** more energy increases economic growth. Thus, it is more important to
β1
(0.202) focus on increasing the efficiency of energy rather than the consumption
^
β −0.336*** of energy. Using the model used to find the validity of a long-term rela-
2
(0.101) tionship, we carried out the Granger causality test of the causal relation-
The results pertaining to the used control variables and uncertainty variables are not ship between the variables, to find mutual causal relationships between
shown in the table for the sake of completeness. the variables in three cases (i.e., short-run, long-run, and strong causality).
In the second step, we found a long-term relationship between the
in terms of growth, energy consumption above the threshold has a variables. In addition, we examined whether the effect of energy con-
stronger effect on economic growth in the model that takes uncertainty sumption on growth changes according to the level of energy intensity.
into consideration, whereas below the threshold, it has a stronger effect This study employed an advanced dynamic panel threshold regression
in the model that does not take uncertainty into consideration. model to investigate whether there existed a “threshold” energy intensity
level in the asymmetrical effect of energy consumption on economic
5. Conclusion and discussion growth.
This study offers a better empirical model than the standard linear re-
Following the independence of the Soviet bloc member states, a new gression analysis models. The findings strongly suggest that the intensity
process began. As regards their economic organization, the states turned level of energy is an important factor in explaining the effect of energy
from a completely statist and centralist structure to the market economy. consumption on economic growth. This outcome implies that energy con-
The process of states in the region moving into the market economy has sumption has a non-linear effect on economic growth. The estimated
been closely followed and discussed continuously throughout the threshold regression model suggests 0.44% as the threshold energy inten-
world. Economies that extend over a vast geography with their economic sity value, below which energy consumption significantly promotes the
underground and aboveground resources, labor potential, large produc- growth of transition economies. However, energy consumption is detri-
tion, and market potential and raise issues about their future are of con- mental to economic growth when it is above the threshold level
cern to all countries and international economic/political organizations. (i.e., 0.44%). Because fluctuations in energy prices will affect economic
In order to maintain this process without any loss or delay, these coun- growth with energy demand/consumption, we once again estimated
tries must use their resources effectively and efficiently. the non-linear relationship between economic growth and energy con-
Even though the energy usage of developed economies falls behind sumption under uncertain conditions using the dynamic panel threshold
international standards to a great extent, it moves ahead along with in- model. The findings showed that the threshold value of energy intensity
dustrialization efforts, and the economies' income levels increase. does not change if uncertainty is taken into consideration or not. An anal-
Therefore, it is important to meet the energy required for economic ysis of the regime coefficients in terms of growth showed that energy con-
growth with less consumption of energy not only to comply with the sumption above the threshold level has a stronger effect on economic
global climate change policies but also to gain other benefits, such as de- growth in the model that took uncertainty into consideration. On the
crease in the country's external payment deficit and air pollution-based other hand, below the threshold, energy consumption has a stronger ef-
diseases, increase in employment, and reduction in household expendi- fect in the other model. In other words, fluctuations in energy prices
tures. Energy efficiency means turning every unit of used energy into have a weak effect on the energy intensity threshold level.
more services and products. In such an environment, it is important to In conclusion, the policy implication of this study is that it is desir-
direct the resources toward high value-added investments and create able to keep energy intensity below the threshold level in transition
appropriate conditions for the use of resources as efficiently as possible. economies because it may help maintain sustainable growth. Using
Otherwise, the low contribution of each resource relative to production the dynamic panel threshold technique, we show that the effect of ener-
(growth) will result in income level stagnation (at low levels) and sub- gy consumption on economic growth is negative when the energy in-
sequently lead to a fall in new investment opportunities, continuously tensity level is high, but can be positive when the intensity level is
hindering economic growth in the long run. low. Thus, a substantial increase in growth can be achieved by focusing
Previous studies analyzing the relationship between energy con- on energy efficiency. The optimal level of energy intensity provides pol-
sumption and economic growth mainly use linear models and achieve icy makers with much flexibility when they seek to implement a cost-
inconsistent results. However, this study examined the role of energy effective strategy for economies without increasing their energy con-
intensity in the relationship between energy consumption and the eco- sumption or worrying too much about energy security.
nomic growth of transition economies by using a recently developed Whether the country is a net energy exporter with rich resources or
panel threshold regression model. We examined 12 CIS countries that a net energy importer with poor resources, it must use energy in an ef-
transitioned from a centrally planned economy to a free market econo- fective and efficient manner both in terms of production and consump-
my following the collapse of the Soviet Union. tion, and take necessary steps to have a competitive sustainable
This study examined the relationship between energy consumption economic structure. By decreasing their energy intensity in production
and economic growth in two steps. The first step used a linearity hypoth- and daily life, increasing the efficiency in all energy chains, decreasing
esis and analyzed whether energy consumption affected economic losses and fugitives, applying productive technologies in production, re-
growth. As regards panel data analysis, the study examined the existence habilitating buildings, and educating all relevant parties, countries can
of dependency among panel cross sections. Observing cross-sectional de- ensure their economic growth and make significant contributions to
pendency, we researched the stability of serials with the help of a second- the global climate problems. Therefore, although most of the CIS coun-
generation unit root test from Bai and Carrion-i-Silvestre (2009) that tries in transition do not have problems in terms of reserves, they
takes cross-sectional dependency and structural breaks into consider- must be cautious when applying strategies and policies to increase the
ation. In order to examine the co-integration relationship between efficient use of their energy resources and energy efficiency in order to
the variables, we used Westerlund and Edgerton's (2008) LM-based quicken their economic development, attain their growth aims, and im-
test, which takes more than one cross-sectional dependency into prove their living standards.
192 C. Aydin, Ö. Esen / Energy Economics 69 (2018) 185–195

Appendix A

Table A.1
Basic information about the variables.

Abbreviation Explanation

dgdp Annual growth rate of real GDP per capita ($)


dec Logarithmic difference of energy consumption per capita (kg of oil equivalent)
tpes/Y Total primary energy consumption as a percentage of GDP measured at purchasing power parity (tons of oil equivalent/$1000)
π Annual percent changes in the Consumer Price Index (CPI)
igdp Percentage of GDP dedicated to investment ($)
dlab Employment/population growth rate
dgdpit-1 GDP per capita of the previous term
open Logarithm of export and import as percentage of GDP
sdopen Standard deviation of openness
dtot Import/export growth rate
sdtot Standard deviation of terms of trade
uncertainty Oil price uncertainty

Table A.2
Descriptive statistics.

tpes/Y dgdp dec π igdp dlab open dtot

Mean 1.481 0.565 −3.665 268.087 47.770 −0.155 4.518 1.304


Std. dev. 1.183 14.542 10.391 1100.743 24.459 2.750 0.373 16.899
Min 0.187 −77.653 −54.125 −18.930 10.102 −23.804 3.329 −43.016
Max 5.962 37.151 44.665 1544.380 117.701 14.736 5.666 108.906

Table A.3
Cross section dependence.

Test Gdp per capita EC per capita

Statistics Statistics

CDBP 100.199*** 108.006***


CDLM 2.977*** 3.656***
CD −2.050** −2.847***
LMadj 9.242*** 9.580***

*, **, *** indicate significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively.

Table A.4
Bai and Carrion-i-Silvestre (2009) Panel unit root test statistics with structural breaks (in level and trend) and cross-section dependence.

Test Level Difference

GDP per capita


Z −0.677 −2.526
P 45.606 54.655
Pm 3.119 −2.526
Z⁎ −0.737 −2.526***
P⁎ 32.674 54.655***
P∗m 1.252 −2.526***

EC per capita
Z −1.038 −2.105
P 37.573 65.275
Pm 1.959 5.957
Z⁎ −1.355 −2.105**
P⁎ 34.456 65.275***
P∗m 2.953 5.957***

**, and *** indicate significance at the 5% and 1% levels, respectively. P ∗ and Pm⁎ denote the corresponding P and Pm statistics that are computed by means of the p-values of the
simplified MSB statistics, respectively. The 1%, and 5% critical values for the standard normal distributed Z and Pm statistics are 2.326 and 1.645, while the critical values for
the chi-squared distributed P statistic are 42.980 and 36.415, respectively. The number of common factors is estimated using the panel Bayesian information criterion proposed
by Bai and Ng (2002).
C. Aydin, Ö. Esen / Energy Economics 69 (2018) 185–195 193

Table A.5
Bai and Carrion-i-Silvestre (2009) Panel unit root test statistics (in level and trend).

Variables* Z⁎ P⁎ P∗m

dlab −2.139** 47.025*** 3.323***


dtot −2.629*** 64.773*** 5.885***
open −0.964 25.147 0.165
igdp −1.575 53.704*** 4.287***
inflation −2.987*** 83.438*** 8.579***

* indicates in differences. **, and *** indicate significance at the 5% and 1% levels, respectively. The 1%, and 5% critical values for the standard normal distributed Z and Pm statistics are 2.326
and 1.645, while the critical values for the chi-squared distributed P statistic are 42.980 and 36.415, respectively.

Table A.6
Panel cointegration test results with structural breaks and cross-section dependence.

Model Zφ(N) Zτ(N)

No break −5.130*** −2.666***


Mean shift −2.734*** −2.466***
Regime shift −2.558*** −1.552*

Notes: The LM-based test statistics Zφ(N) and Zτ(N) are normal distributed. The number of common factors is determined by means of the information criterion proposed by Bai and Ng
(2004) and the maximum number is set to 5. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Table A.7
Estimates of breaks.

Country Mean shift Regime shift

Armenia 2006 2006


Azerbaijan 2006 2006
Belarus 2006 2006
Georgia 2006 2006
Kazakhstan 2000 2000
Kyrgyz Republic 2000 2000
Moldova 2000 2000
Russian Federation 1996 1996
Tajikistan 2005 1996
Turkmenistan 2005 2005
Ukraine 2005 2005
Uzbekistan 2005 2005

Notes: The break dates are selected by means of the test approach suggested in Westerlund and Edgerton (2008) which follows the strategy of Bai and Perron (1998) to determine the
location of structural breaks.

Table A.8
Results of long-run estimations.

Dependant variables (Gdp per capita) Without structural break With structural break

FMOLS DOLS FMOLS DOLS

β β β β

EC per capita −0.732*** −0.920*** −0.559*** −0.660***


(0.078) (0.074) (0.112) (0.121)
Dummy 0.237*** 0.239***
(0.085) (0.086)

Notes: Numbers in parentheses are standard errors. *, **, *** indicate significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels, respectively. In estimations made with the FMOLS and DOLS methods, lag lengths
were selected in accordance with the Hannah-Quin criteria.

Table A.9
Results of dynamic panel causality tests in CIS countries.

Dependent variable Sources of causation (independent variable)

Short-run Long-run Strong causality

Δ Gdp per capita Δ EC per capita ECT Δ Gdp per capita, ECT ΔEC per capita, ECT

Δ Gdp per capita – 43.27*** −0.06*** – 82.16***


Δ EC per capita 45.94*** – −0.46*** 231.53*** –

Notes: The table displays the Wald chi-squared test statistics' empirical realizations for short-run and strong causality. In parentheses, the sum of the lagged coefficients for each short-run
change is shown. As shown, the lag length is two. ECT refers to the coefficient of the error-correction terms as εy and εe, respectively. ∗∗∗, ∗∗, and ∗ show that the null hypothesis of no
causation is rejected at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively.
194 C. Aydin, Ö. Esen / Energy Economics 69 (2018) 185–195

Appendix B

Fig. B.1. Variables graphics.

Appendix C. Supplementary data Belke, A., Goecke, M., 2005. Real options effects on employment: does exchange rate un-
certainty matter for aggregation? Ger. Econ. Rev. 6/2, 185–203.
Belke, A., Dobnik, F., Dreger, C., 2011. Energy consumption and economic growth: new in-
Supplementary data to this article can be found online at https://doi. sights into the cointegration relationship. Energy Econ. 33 (5):782–789. https://
org/10.1016/j.eneco.2017.11.010. doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2011.02.005.
Belke, A., Beckmann, J., Czudaj, R., 2014a. The regime-dependent adjustment in energy
spot and futures markets - a smooth transition approach. Econ. Model. 40/1,
400–409.
References Belke, A., Beckmann, J., Czudaj, R., 2014b. Does global liquidity drive commodity prices?
J. Bank. Financ. 48, 224–234.
Al-Iriani, M.A., 2006. Energy–GDP relationship revisited: an example from GCC countries Bernanke, B.S., 1983. Non-monetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of
using panel causality. Energ Policy 34 (17):3342–3350. https://doi.org/10.1016/ the Great Depression.
j.enpol.2005.07.005. Bick, A., 2010. Threshold effects of inflation on economic growth in developing countries.
Al-Mulali, U., Sab, C.N.B.C., 2012. The impact of energy consumption and CO 2 emission Econ. Lett. 108 (2), 126–129.
on the economic growth and financial development in the Sub Saharan African Blackburne, E.F., Frank, M.W., 2007. Estimation of nonstationary heterogeneous panels.
countries. Energy 39 (1):180–186. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2012.01.032. Stata J. 7 (2), 197–208.
Apergis, N., Payne, J.E., 2009a. Energy consumption and economic growth in Central Breitung, J., 2000. The local power of some unit root tests for panel data. In: Baltagi, B.
America: evidence from a panel cointegration and error correction model. Energy (Ed.), Nonstationary Panels, Panel Cointegration, and Dynamic Panels. Advances in
Econ. 31 (2):211–216. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2008.09.002. Econometrics vol. 15. JAI Press, Amsterdam, pp. 161–178.
Apergis, N., Payne, J.E., 2009b. Energy consumption and economic growth: evidence from Breuer, J.B., McNown, R., Wallace, M., 2002. Series-specific unit root tests with panel data.
the Commonwealth of Independent States. Energy Econ. 31 (5):641–647. https:// Oxf. Bull. Econ. Stat. 64 (5), 527–546.
doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2009.01.011. Breusch, T.S., Pagan, A.R., 1980. The Lagrange multiplier test and its applications to model
Arellano, M., Bover, O., 1995. Another look at the instrumental variables estimation of specification in econometrics. Rev. Econ. Stud. 47 (1), 239–253.
error-components models. J. Econ. 68, 29–51. Caner, M., Hansen, B.E., 2004. Instrumental variable estimation of a threshold model. Eco-
Aydin, C., Esen, Ö., 2017. Does too much energy consumption harm economic growth for nomic Theory 20, 813–843.
Turkish republics in the transition process? New evidence on threshold effects. Int. Carrion-i-Silvestre, J.L., Barrio-Castro, T.D., Lopez-Bazo, E., 2005. Breaking the panels: an
J. Energy Econ. Policy 7 (2), 34–43. application to the GDP per capita. Econ. J. 8 (2), 159–175.
Aydin, C., Esen, Ö., 2016. Threshold effects of energy consumption on economic growth in Cheng, B.S., 1999. Causality between energy consumption and economic growth in India:
Turkey. J. Environ. Manag. Tourism 7 (3):370–382. https://doi.org/10.14505/ an application of cointegration and error-correction modeling. Indian Econ. Rev. 34
jemt.v7.3(15).02. (1), 39–49.
Bai, J., Perron, P., 1998. Estimating and testing linear models with multiple structural Choi, I., 2001. Unit root tests for panel data. J. Int. Money Financ. 20 (2), 249–272.
changes. Econometrica 66 (1), 47–78. Dobnik, F., 2011. Energy consumption and economic growth revisited: structural breaks
Bai, J., Carrion-i-Silvestre, J.L., 2009. Structural changes, common stochastic trends, and and cross-section dependence. Ruhr Economic Papers, No: 303 https://doi.org/
unit roots in panel data. Rev. Econ. Stud. 76 (2), 471–501. 10.2139/ssrn.1981869.
Bai, J., Ng, S., 2002. Determining the number of factors in approximate factor models. Drukker, D., Gomis-Porqueras, P., Hernandez-Verme, P., 2005. Threshold Effects in the Re-
Econometrica 70 (1), 191–221. lationship Between Inflation and Growth: A New Panel-Data Approach (Working
Bai, J., Ng, S., 2004. A PANIC attack on unit roots and cointegration. Econometrica 72, Paper).
1127–1177. Esen, Ö., Bayrak, M., 2017. Does more energy consumption support economic growth in
Belke, A., Dreger, C., 2015. The transmission of oil and food prices to consumer prices. IEEP net energy-importing countries? J. Econ. Financ. Admin. Sci. 22 (42):75–98. https://
12 (1):143–161. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10368-014-0283-x. doi.org/10.1108/JEFAS-01-2017-0015.
C. Aydin, Ö. Esen / Energy Economics 69 (2018) 185–195 195

Fisher-Vanden, K., Jefferson, G.H., Liu, H., Tao, Q., 2004. What is driving China's decline in Maddala, G.S., Wu, S., 1999. A comparative study of unit root tests with panel data and a
energy intensity? Resour. Energy Econ. 26 (1):77–97. https://doi.org/10.1016/ new simple test. Oxf. Bull. Econ. Stat. 61, 631–652.
j.reseneeco.2003.07.002. Masih, A.M.M., Masih, R., 1996. Energy consumption, real income and temporal causality:
Ghali, K.H., El-Sakka, M.I.T., 2004. Energy use and output growth in Canada: a multivariate results from a multi-country study based on Cointegration and error-correction
cointegration analysis. Energy Econ. 24, 355–365. Modelling techniques. Energy Econ. 18 (3):165–183. https://doi.org/10.1016/0140–
Gomulka, S., 1990. The Theory of Technological Change and Economic Growth. Routledge, 9883(96)00009-6.
London. Mehrara, M., 2007. Energy consumption and economic growth: the case of oil exporting
Greene, W.H., 2000. Econometric Analysis. Fifth edition. Prentice Hall, USA. countries. Energ Policy 35 (5):2939–2945. https://doi.org/10.1016/
Hadri, K., 2000. Testing for stationarity in heterogeneous panel data. Econ. J. 3 (2), j.enpol.2006.10.018.
148–161. Menegaki, A.N., 2011. Growth and renewable energy in Europe: a random effect model
Hamit-Haggar, M., 2012. Greenhouse gas emissions, energy consumption and with evidence for neutrality hypothesis. Energy Econ. 33 (2):257–263. https://
economic growth: a panel cointegration analysis from Canadian industrial doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2010.10.004.
sector perspective. Energy Econ. 34 (1):358–364. https://doi.org/10.1016/ Menyah, K., Wolde-Rufael, Y., 2010. Energy consumption, pollutant emissions and eco-
j.eneco.2011.06.005. nomic growth in South Africa. Energy Econ. 32 (6):1374–1382. https://doi.org/
Hansen, B.E., 1999. Threshold effects in non-dynamic panels: estimation, testing, and in- 10.1016/j.eneco.2010.08.002.
ference. J. Econ. 93, 345–368. Narayan, P.K., Smyth, R., 2008. Energy consumption and real GDP in G7 countries: new
Hansen, B.E., 2000. Sample splitting and threshold estimation. Econometrica 68 (3), evidence from panel cointegration with structural breaks. Energy Econ. 30 (5):
575–603. 2331–2341. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2007.10.006.
Havrylyshyn, O., 2001. Recovery and growth in transition: a decade of evidence. IMF Econ. Oh, W., Lee, K., 2004. Energy consumption and economic growth in Korea: testing the
Rev. 48 (1):53–87. https://doi.org/10.2307/4621690. causality relation. J. Policy Model 26 (8):973–981. https://doi.org/10.1016/
Havrylyshyn, O., Wolf, T., 1999. Determinants of growth in transition countries. Financ. j.jpolmod.2004.06.003.
Dev. 36 (2), 12–15. Papapetrou, E., 2001. Oil price shocks, stock market, economic activity and employment
Honma, S., Hu, J.L., 2008. Total-factor energy efficiency of regions in Japan. Energy Policy in Greece. Energy Econ. 23 (5), 511–532.
36 (2):821–833. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2007.10.026. Pesaran, M.H., 2004. General Diagnostic Tests for Cross Section Dependence in Panels
Hu, J.L., Wang, S.C., 2006. Total-factor energy efficiency of regions in China. Energ Policy (CESifo Working No. 1229).
34 (17):3206–3217. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2005.06.015. Pesaran, M.H., 2006. Estimation and inference in large heterogeneous panels with a mul-
Huang, Bwo-Nung, Hwang, M.J., Yang, C.W., 2008. Does more energy consumption bolster tifactor error structure. Econometrica 74 (4), 967–1012.
economic growth? An application of the nonlinear threshold regression model. Energ Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y., Smith, R.P., 1999. Pooled mean group estimation of dynamic het-
Policy:755–767 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2007.10.023. erogeneous panels. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 94 (446), 621–634.
Im, K.S., Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y., 2003. Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. Pesaran, M.H., Ullah, A., Yamagata, T., 2008. A bias-adjusted LM test of error cross-section
J. Econ. 115 (1), 53–74. independence. Econ. J. 11 (1), 105–127.
Iyke, B.N., 2015. Electricity consumption and economic growth in Nigeria: a revisit of the Ramirez-Rondán, N.R., 2013. Essays on Dynamic Panel Threshold Models. Doctoral disser-
energy-growth debate. Energy Econ. 51:166–176. https://doi.org/10.1016/ tation. University of Wisconsin–Madison.
j.eneco.2015.05.024. Roodman, D., 2009. A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxf. Bull. Econ. Stat. 71
Kavak, K., 2005. Energy Efficiency in the World and Turkey and Investigation of Energy Ef- (1), 135–158.
ficiency in Turkish Industry. State Planning Organization (Turkey), Ankara (DPT- Sari, R., Soytas, U., 2007. The growth of income and energy consumption in six devel-
2689. (10/10/2012), www.dpt.gov.tr/DocObjects/Download/3226/enerji.pdf). oping countries. Energ Policy 35 (2):889–898. https://doi.org/10.1016/
Khan, M.S., Senhadji, A.S., 2001. Threshold Effects in the Relationship Between Inflation j.enpol.2006.01.021.
and Growth. Technical Report, IMF Staff Papers. p. 48. Shiu, A., Lam, Pun-Lee, 2004. Electricity consumption and economic growth in China.
Kremer, S., Bick, A., Nautz, D., 2013. Inflation and growth: new evidence from a dynamic Energ Policy 32 (1):47–54. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0301-4215(02)00250-1.
panel threshold analysis. Empir. Econ. 44 (2), 861–878. Soytas, U., Sari, R., 2003. Energy consumption and GDP: causality relationship in G-7
Leach, G., Obermair, J.L., Hoffmann, G.M.L., 1986. Energy and Growth. Butterworth Pub- countries and emerging markets. Energy Econ. 25 (1):33–37. https://doi.org/
lishers, England. 10.1016/S0140-9883(02)00009-9.
Lee, Chien-Chiang, Chang, Chun-Ping, 2007. The impact of energy consumption on eco- Taylor, M.P., Sarno, L., 1998. The behavior of real exchange rates during the post-Bretton
nomic growth: evidence from linear and nonlinear models in Taiwan. Energy 32 woods period. J. Int. Econ. 46 (2), 281–312.
(12):2282–2294. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.energy.2006.01.017. Tsani, S.Z., 2010. Energy consumption and economic growth: a causality analysis for
Lee, C.C., Chang, C.P., 2008. Energy consumption and economic growth in Asian econo- Greece. Energy Econ. 32 (3):582–590. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.eneco.2009.09.007.
mies: a more comprehensive analysis using panel data. Resour. Energy Econ. 30 Westerlund, J., Edgerton, D.L., 2008. A simple test for cointegration in dependent panels
(1):50–65. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2007.03.003. with structural breaks. Oxf. Bull. Econ. Stat. 70 (5), 665–704.
Lee, J., Strazicich, M.C., 2004. Minimum LM Unit Root Test with one Structural Break. Man- Yu, E.S., Choi, J.Y., 1985. Causal relationship between energy and GNP: an international
uscript. Department of Economics, Appalachian State University, pp. 1–16. comparison. J. Energy Dev. 10 (2).
Levin, A., Lin, C., Chu, C.J., 2002. Unit root tests in panel data: asymptotic and finite-sample Yu, E.S., Hwang, B., 1984. The relationship between energy and GNP: further results. En-
properties. J. Econ. 108 (1), 1–24. ergy Econ. 6 (3):186–190. https://doi.org/10.1016/0140-9883(84)90015-X.
Liao, H., Fan, Y., Wei, Yi-Ming, 2007. What induced China's energy intensity to fluctuate:
1997–2006? Energ Policy 35 (9), 4640–4649.
Liddle, B., Messinis, G., 2015. Revisiting sulfur Kuznets curves with endogenous breaks
modeling: substantial evidence of inverted-Us/Vs for individual OECD countries.
Econ. Model. 49, 278–285.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi