Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 22

Urban Studies, Vol. 41, No.

10, 1909–1929, September 2004

‘Best Places’: Interurban Competition, Quality of


Life and Popular Media Discourse

Eugene J. McCann
[Paper first received, February 2003; in final form, November 2003]

Summary. This paper explores relationships between the politics of urban competitiveness and
popular media discourse about the ‘good life’ and ‘good places’. Specifically, it focuses on the
influence of popular ‘best places to live’ rankings on urban policy in three US cities. It addresses
two issues: how and why similar policies are transferred from place to place; and, how
‘extra-economic’ factors are mobilised in formulating local economic development policy. It
argues that the media’s role in these processes is understudied and that its normative discourse
is powerful and political. This argument is influenced by and illustrative of a recent attempt to
locate the study of discursive power much more centrally in political economy approaches to
urban studies.

Introduction
The politics of urban development and in- for various perspectives on the future of a
terurban competition have been the focus of place (for example, K. G. Ward, 2000a). It
a great deal of scholarship in urban studies in has also been argued that local media have a
recent decades (Cochrane, 1999; Cochrane et stake in advocating for urban growth given
al., 1996; Cox, 1999; Cox and Mair, 1988; their own ‘local dependence’ (Cox and Mair,
Hall and Hubbard, 1998; Jonas and Wilson, 1988). Nevertheless, the national popular
1999a; Lauria, 1997; Logan and Molotch, media’s role in promoting, legitimating and
1987; Peck, 1995; Peck and Tickell, 1995). diffusing hegemonic ideas about the good
Over time, there has been an increasing at- life, good places and good local economic
tention to the role discourse and representa- development policy has been relatively un-
tion play in framing and facilitating the derstudied.
activities of urban growth coalitions (Boyle, This paper will investigate the relationship
1999; Jessop, 1997; Jonas and Wilson, between urban policy-making and media dis-
1999b). Examples of competing discourses course through a study of the ‘best places’
and of the discursive construction of place in rankings produced annually by numerous
the politics of local economic development popular magazines in the US. This study will
have frequently been drawn from the popular allow me to address two key concerns at the
media since local newspapers, magazines heart of the contemporary literatures on the
and television are regularly used as outlets politics of local economic development and

Eugene J. McCann is in the Department of Geography, Simon Fraser University, 8888 University Drive, Burnaby, British
Columbia, Canada V5A 1S6. Fax: 604 291 5841. E-mail: emccann@sfu.ca. The research upon which this paper is based was
funded by a grant from the Ohio State University Research Foundation. The author would also like to acknowledge the hospitality
of the Department of Geography at the University of Texas, Austin. Thanks to Rini Sumartojo for her research assistance and to
Kevin Ward, Michael Timberlake and two anonymous reviewers for very helpful comments. The author is also grateful to the
geographers at the University of Illinois, Wittenberg University and Ohio University to whom earlier versions of the paper had
been presented. All arguments and conclusions are entirely the responsibility of the author.
0042-0980 Print/1360-063X On-line/04/101909–21  2004 The Editors of Urban Studies
DOI: 10.1080/0042098042000256314
Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
1910 EUGENE J. MCCANN

urban entrepreneurialism. The first concern is ing and specifying the extra-economic as-
with the ways in which successful economic pects of local economic development that are
development policies formulated in one loca- currently valorised in localities across the
tion are promoted to and adopted by other country. The current impulse towards cre-
cities. This “serial reproduction” of policies, ating livable and attractive environments for
as Harvey (1989, p.10) referred to it in the certain class fractions as a central part of a
original statement of the entrepreneurial city wider economic development strategy pro-
thesis, tends to foster ‘weak competition’ vides a particularly clear insight into the
(Cox, 1995) and a ‘crowding’ in the market- politics of developing innovative ‘new com-
place (Jessop, 1998) that works to the detri- binations’.
ment of most cities by fostering a ‘treadmill’ Therefore, this paper will focus primarily
effect in which every city feels an external on the influential lists of ‘best places to live’
pressure to upgrade continually its policies, produced by the personal finance publication,
facilities, amenities and so on to stave off Money magazine since they are explicit in
competition and maintain its position in the their combination of ‘economic’ and ‘extra-
competitive urban hierarchy.1 Its continued economic’ criteria. The paper will begin with
prevalence, however, makes it an important more detailed discussions of contemporary
topic of on-going investigation that also res- scholarship on interurban competition and
onates with the wider literature on ‘policy issues of livability and quality of life in the
transfer’ that has emerged in recent years US. It will then draw on examples from three
(Dolowitz and Marsh, 2000; Peck and US cities: Lexington, Kentucky, Austin,
Theodore, 2001; Radaelli, 2000; Stone, Texas, and Columbus, Ohio. These cities are
2000). The second concern in the contempor- discussed because of certain important simi-
ary literature is with the use of ‘extra-econ- larities, differences and connections. All are
omic’ factors—i.e. the social, cultural and small or mid-sized cities that have little his-
political elements of urban life—in the tory of heavy industry and have grown rap-
construction and legitimation of interurban idly since the 1970s. They contain the
economic competition (Jessop, 1997, 1998; primary research universities of their respect-
Jessop and Sum, 2000). In his recent engage- ive states, are either the seat of state govern-
ment with the entrepreneurial city thesis, ment or are located close to it and all locate
Jessop (1997, p. 31) places “the entrepreneu- issues of livability at the heart of their econ-
rial concern to create ‘new combinations’ omic development strategies. They differ in
of economic and/or extra-economic factors terms of their popular reputation for livabil-
which will further urban and regional ity and economic development, however.
competitiveness” at the heart of his dis- Austin has consistently ranked highly as a
cussion. This attention to the porous good place to live in the past decade, while
boundaries of ‘the economic’ in local econ- Lexington and Columbus are generally not
omic development is often less explicitly examples used in the national conversation
stated in other discussions of urban compe- on successful examples of innovative econ-
tition and politics, but it is a significant as- omic development policy. Both have created
pect of a great deal of contemporary writing new economic development strategies ex-
on this topic (Jonas and Wilson, 1999b; Mc- plicitly aimed at emulating Austin’s success
Cann, 2002). in creating an image as a good place to live,
A study of the relationships between the however. The paper concludes by arguing
popular media’s ‘best places’ rankings and that the study of the relationships between
the politics and policy of local economic media discourse and urban politics resonates
development informs both of these concerns with a more widespread attempt in urban
by outlining how media discourse anoints studies to understand the power of discourse
certain cities as successful and worth emulat- in the construction of urban economies.

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
‘BEST PLACES’ 1911

Economy and Livability in the City: rates, racial harmony, and good health and
Changing Definitions and Conceptual shopping facilities. These, the authors argue,
Connections are all factors that can be changed for the
better, given the correct urban policies. The
Developing social indicators intended to
relationship between livability, consumption
measure urban livability or quality is not the
and urban policy is maintained in the most
sole preserve of popular publications. It has
recent US academic research on urban qual-
been the focus of numerous social science ity of life. Florida’s work (Florida, 2000,
research exercises since the 1960s (see Pa- 2002; Florida and Gates, 2001) focuses on
cione, 1982 and 1990 for reviews). The pur- the aspects of cities—amenities, environmen-
pose of much of this work has been to tal quality and social tolerance (acceptance
identify the salient aspects of city life that of gay and lesbian communities, for in-
influence social well-being. On this basis, it stance)—that make them attractive to young
is hoped to “advance the goal of a humane or ‘knowledge workers’. By extension, Florida
livable city” (Pacione, 1990, p. 2). The argues that policy-makers must understand
vagueness of this goal and of the term ‘qual- how
ity of life’ itself means that disparate re-
search foci have been grouped under the The new economy dramatically transforms
rubric of ‘urban livability’ at different times. the role of the environment and natural
Geographers and others working with a amenities from a source of raw material
range of theoretical and methodological and a sink for waste disposal to a key
frameworks have researched a variety of as- component of the total package required to
pects of urban life and their effects on indi- attract talent and in doing so generate
viduals and groups’ quality of life: economic growth (Florida, 2000, p. 5).
overcrowding, natural hazards and ambient Cities that rank highly as places with virtu-
environmental conditions, stressful events in ous combinations of high technology, high
everyday life, urban form in relation to ease amenity, and social tolerance in Florida’s
of access and orientation, security and pri- analyses include Seattle, Washington, the
vacy, residential satisfaction and community San Francisco Bay area, greater Boston, and
ties, among others (Cutter, 1985; Pacione, Austin, Texas—cities that also frequently
1990). A connecting theme among most of rank highly on the popular media’s rankings
this work is its applied aspect; a concern with of the best places in which to live and invest.
informing policy to promote better condi-
tions of urban life for entire populations or
particular social groups. Policy Innovation, the Media and Urban
Since the 1980s, however, a related strand Quality of Life
of academic work on urban livability has The changing definitions of quality of life
emerged that is more interested in urban and the changing purposes to which livability
quality of life as an object of consumption research has been put over the years empha-
for mobile residents and, relatedly, as a sell- sise the power-laden, political nature of this
ing point for cities. For example, Findlay et concept. As Ley has noted
al.’s study of livability in British cities seeks
to provide urban managers with a map of One important form of power is the ability
to define the terms of public discourse, and
“where the best quality of life can be found”
an eloquent example of this form of power
and a set of comparable indicators to mea-
is the career of the term ‘urban livability’.
sure the performance of their city in attract-
Over its twenty years of widespread usage,
ing “a person or family on the move”
the term has served a range of masters
(Findlay et al., 1998, p. 271). In this study,
(Ley, 1990, p. 34).
the main characteristics of high quality of life
were low crime, pollution and cost of living The contemporary master of a great deal of

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
1912 EUGENE J. MCCANN

popular and academic livability research is Entrepreneurship … involves the devising


the influential and highly political neo-liberal and realisation of new ways of doing
vision of the city as a commodity that should things to generate above-average
be branded and marketed as part of a wider profits … in the course of capitalist com-
process of interurban competition (Brenner petition (Jessop, 1998, p. 83).
and Theodore, 2002).
The marketing of cities with the intention Nonetheless, the marketing of cities as nice
of attracting the most desirable labour force places in which to live and attempts to rise to
or industry is not new, of course (Greenberg, the top of popular best places rankings do not
2000; Rutheiser, 1996, ch.1; S. Ward, 1998a, necessarily entail true innovation. Rather,
1998b; Kearns and Philo, 1993). The impetus many have noted that the ideologies, strate-
behind the scholarly interest in contemporary gies and geography of urban entrepreneurial-
interurban competition can largely be at- ism—from the dominant definition of cities
tributed to Harvey’s (1989) influential paper as primarily competitive entities to the serial
on the shift from managerialism to en- reproduction of festival markets, waterfront
trepreneurialism in late capitalism. Harvey’s developments, etc.—are very similar from
entrepreneurial city thesis hangs on three place to place. Indeed, Harvey’s original
related arguments (Harvey, 1989, pp. 6–8). statement of the entrepreneurial thesis
First, the on-going restructuring of economic identifies this issue as one of the central
and political relations at higher scales, in- problematics in the study of contemporary
cluding the national and the global, has en- urbanisation
tailed a fundamental change in the There seems to be a general consensus
organisation of public policy in the US, emerging throughout the advanced capital-
Britain and other parts of the industrialised ist world that positive benefits are to be
world. Secondly, with the rise of en- had by cities taking an entrepreneurial
trepreneurialism there has been a related shift stance to economic development. What is
in which power over policy at the local level remarkable, is that this consensus seems to
is increasingly located in private institutions hold across national boundaries and even
that control governing coalitions where state across political parties and ideologies
agencies play a facilitative role. The risks (Harvey, 1989, p. 4).
associated with development are borne
largely by the public sector at the local level, The hegemonic, normative discourse of in-
however. This location of risk distinguishes terurban competition that sustains and en-
the entrepreneurial city from previous rounds courages relative ideological conformity over
of civic boosterism. Thirdly, there is a refo- large parts of the developed world is, as I
cusing away from policies primarily aimed at will illustrate, tied up with the popular me-
the provision and maintenance of public dia’s representation of cities and the urban
goods in a clearly demarcated territory. In- system, including the publication of best
stead, the initiatory or speculative impulse at places rankings. But what exactly are the
the heart of urban entrepreneurialism is ori- linkages between media representations and
ented towards the construction of spectacular what cities do to enhance their competitive-
sites or places that are hoped will stimulate ness? I suggest that there is a mutually rein-
further investment. forcing relationship between the formulation
Recently, Jessop (1997, 1998; Jessop and of contemporary local economic develop-
Sum, 2000) has partially reformulated the ment policy and the media’s production of
entrepreneurial city thesis by replacing Har- these rankings.
vey’s emphasis on what institutions bear the On the one side of this relationship, the
risks associated with speculation, with a rankings gain a remarkably high level of
definition of entrepreneurialism in terms of importance and legitimacy by being seen to
innovation (Jessop, 1998, footnote 9). be taken seriously by politicians, public pol-

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
‘BEST PLACES’ 1913

icy professionals, consultants, business lead- constant circulation and repetition of their
ers and private consultants, and local media measurement criteria and results by national
(as I will illustrate in the following section). and local media outlets and, crucially, by the
Therefore, they are represented by their pub- private consultants frequently hired by cities
lishers as being more than mere entertain- to envision strategies for their future (Jessop
ment or simply of interest to a few mobile and Sum, 2000; Olds, 1997), provide cities
individuals, families or investors. They are, with clear choices regarding policies they
instead, presented as relatively weighty state- might enact, the goals they set themselves,
ments on the condition of US cities. The the cities they choose to emulate and com-
other side of this relationship involves the pete with, and so on. In the more extreme
rankings’ role as a discursive frame that both cases, the rankings come to be regarded as
enables and legitimates entrepreneurial pol- ‘off the shelf’ solutions to complex economic
icy initiatives. development problems. Secondly, the rank-
A discursive frame, in this sense, is a ings and the policy solutions they suggest are
persuasive, widely accepted and powerful constructed by national media with no easily
simplification of the world. It selectively perceptible links to the individual cities they
identifies and connects certain elements of feature. This lends them an aura of objec-
everyday life and place in a way that mo- tivity (which is reinforced by their constant
bilises and legitimates a particular set of repetition by a wide array of actors in the
actions or policies while setting other under- policy process) that can be used to legitimate
standings and agendas outside the bounds of the policy choices made by policy profes-
consideration (Barnes and Duncan, 1992; sionals in individual cities. A city’s ranking
Nash, 2000; Snow and Benford, 1992; Tar- at the top of a ‘best places’ list can, then, be
row, 1992). ‘Best places’ rankings frame the discussed by local politicians as an objective
complex US urban world through two related affirmation of the city’s high quality of life,
simplifications: first, they define the urban as a mark of approval for its economic devel-
system as a primarily competitive complex opment policies and a marker of its import-
and individual cities as fundamentally and ance within the US urban system.
naturally competitive entities, driven to vie Interurban competition is not only charac-
with each other for first place; secondly, the terised by the repetition of a few dominant
rankings focus the terms of policy debate by ideas about what makes a ‘best place’, how-
defining cities’ success relative to high levels ever. Entrepreneurship defined as innovation
of attention to middle-class livability con- entails, according to Jessop, new combina-
cerns (for example, the apparently contradic- tions of factors that will enhance urban com-
tory desires for high levels of amenities and petitiveness. He argues that these innovative
low taxation) or to providing the proverbial combinations now involve an intermixing of
‘good business environment’ of low operat- economic and ‘extra-economic’ factors
ing costs and highly skilled workers. (Of where the former are defined as “com-
course, as Florida (2002) and Nevarez (2003) modities and fictitious commodities” and the
have shown, these two aspects are intercon- latter are political and social factors that are
nected.) “economically relevant” but are “not mone-
These discursive simplifications resonate tised and/or do not enter directly into ex-
deeply with US urban politicians and policy change relations” (Jessop and Sum, 2000,
professionals and, as a result, the rankings p. 2290). With the greater centrality of the
play an active role in enabling the implemen- ‘extra-economic’ come stronger links be-
tation of entrepreneurial policy strategies. tween innovation and marketing (Jessop,
The link between the rankings and what 1998, p. 84) and a related rise in the import-
these actors do to increase their city’s com- ance of image, representation and narrative
petitiveness has at least two concrete ele- in urban policy formulation which is re-
ments. First, their unequivocal nature and the flected in a significant literature on the topic

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
1914 EUGENE J. MCCANN

(Kearns and Philo, 1993; Paddison, 1993; publication of Money magazine’s “Best
Sadler, 1993; Short and Kim, 1998; Short et Places to Live” ranking. Since 1987, the
al., 1993; Waitt, 1999; K. G. Ward, 2000a, popular consumer affairs and investment
2000b). These stronger links between mar- periodical has been compiling annual rank-
keting and innovation involve “opening new ings of approximately 300 cities. The lists
markets—whether by place marketing are based on an annual survey of approxi-
specific cities in new areas and/or modifying mately 500 of its subscribers. The survey
the spatial division of consumption through asks the subscribers to think about what cri-
enhancing the quality of life for residents, teria they would use if they were choosing a
commuters, and visitors” and are comple- new city in which to live. In this regard, they
mented by policies targeted towards are asked to rank approximately 40 regional
“refiguring or redefining the urban hierarchy characteristics on a scale of 1 to 10. The
and/or altering the place of a given city magazine takes the results of this survey and
within it” (Jessop, 1998, pp. 84–85). compares them with census data for US
In many contemporary cities, these sorts of metropolitan areas. From this, it produces a
attempts at enhancing competitiveness are, ranked list of the cities weighted in terms of
with greater or lesser success, wrapped up in the preferences of its subscribers. Over the
attempts to improve amenities and culture, as years, this process has produced an interest-
Florida’s (2000, 2002; Florida and Gates, ing geography in which a small number of
2001) work has suggested. This includes, cities appear quite consistently in the maga-
among other things, zine’s top 10 (Figure 1). This spatial distri-
the modernization of the infrastructures bution is the product of the class and
and assets of urban regions (communica- demographic characteristics of the maga-
tions, cultural institutions, higher educa- zine’s readership. In the mid 1990s, the last
tional strengths and capacities) to attract years in which the magazine published de-
investment and visitors and support exist- tails of those surveyed, the median age of the
ing economic activities; and [the formu- sample was around 48 and the median house-
lation of policies addressing] the need to hold income was approximately $78 000.
limit further suburbanisation, retain popu- These characteristics are reflected, for in-
lation (particularly middle-to-upper in- stance, in the strong presence of the small
come families) and workplaces and create city of Rochester, Minnesota, in the rankings
compact livable cities (Harding, 1995, each year. This is largely due to the location
p. 27, quoted in Jessop, 1998, p. 80). in the city of the Mayo Clinic, a renowned
The elements of a city’s infrastructure, gov- medical facility, and to the heavy weighting
ernance structure and culture that are necess- Money’s subscribers give to available, high-
ary for its rise in the urban hierarchy are, I quality health care in their definition of a
will suggest, worked out through policy- good place to live.
making processes that combine economic In 1987, subscribers seemed to desire a
and extra-economic factors. These combina- city with little property crime, high personal
tions are frequently articulated in reference safety and an appreciating housing market,
to the normative narrative of the ‘good city’ among other factors (Money Magazine, 1987,
presented by the national media’s best places p. 34). Accordingly, Nashua, New Hamp-
rankings. In this paper, I will discuss in detail shire, Norwalk, Connecticut, and Wheeling,
how this process works, using three interre- West Virginia, were the top-rated places. The
lated case studies. first two were experiencing the effects of
economic expansion in certain sectors while
Wheeling ranked surprisingly high in the
Popular Urban Livability Rankings: The
listing due to its low house prices and crime
Case of Money Magazine
rates. Since then, similar criteria have shaped
An annual media event in the US is the the ranking (Table 1).

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
‘BEST PLACES’ 1915

Table 1. Top criteria for choosing a city according to Money’s recent surveys of its subscribers

1994 1995 1996 1997

1 Low crime rate Clean water Low crime rate Low crime rate
2 Clean water Clean air Clean water Clean water
3 Clean air Low crime rate Clean air Plentiful doctors
4 Plentiful doctors Plentiful doctors Plentiful doctors Clean air
5 Many hospitals Many hospitals Many hospitals Many hospitals
6 Strong state Strong state Housing appreciation Good schools
government government
7 Low income taxes Low income taxes Good schools Housing appreciation
8 Low property taxes Low property taxes Low property taxes Low property taxes
9 Housing appreciation Housing appreciation Low income taxes Strong state
government
10 Affordable medical Good schools Strong state Low income taxes
care government

Note: 1997 is the last year in which Money published a full list of the criteria. In 1998, it published
the top five: clean water, low crime rate, clean air, good schools and low property taxes.

Despite the rather specific nature of Portland has finally gotten this ‘official
Money’s ranking criteria (and those of most seal of recognition’ from one of the na-
other similar publications), the cities they tion’s leading financial magazines (Katz,
identify as the ‘best places’ are represented 2000).
as universally desirable. This process of gen-
This reaction is replicated by leaders in high-
eralisation takes place through other popular
ranking cities across the country. A page on
media at the national scale and, to a much
the Durham, North Carolina, website entitled
greater extent, at the local level as well as
“Why do business in Durham?” answers the
through the work of translocal policy consul-
question entirely through references to its
tants and place marketers. Each year, local
high rankings on Money’s list and on similar
newspapers and television stations whose
rankings produced by a number of other
city ranks on any list, but especially the
popular and trade publications (City of
major ones like Money’s and Fortune’s, por-
Durham, 2001). The city’s visitor centre, for
tray the ranking as an important achievement
its part, has covered two walls with framed
representing an objective affirmation of the
copies of issues of Money and other
city’s high quality of life, its leaders’ sound
magazines in which Durham has ranked
economic development strategy and its
highly. On the other hand, a low ranking,
significance within the hierarchy of US cities
while often studiously ignored by local me-
(Table 2).
dia and élites, can occasionally prompt pub-
Money’s ranking is also noted by local
lic consternation and indignation. For
state agencies and private economic develop-
example, Flint, Michigan—the city whose
ment organisations. These agencies often
economic decline after the closure of a Gen-
mention their position on the national rank-
eral Motors plant in the 1980s was docu-
ing when they promote their city to potential
mented in Michael Moore’s film Roger and
investors, residents and visitors. For exam-
Me—ranked last out of the 300 cities in
ple, when Money (2000, p. 150), conferred
Money’s first list (Money, 1987). Local busi-
‘best city’ status on Portland, Oregon, the
ness leaders quickly organised a protest rally
city’s mayor said in a press release
at which copies of the magazine were burned
We’re #1 [sic], but of course those of us by people holding signs proclaiming that
who live here have always known “Money is the root of all evil” (Moore,
that. … I am extremely proud … [that] 1996). Clearly, those involved in local econ-

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
1916 EUGENE J. MCCANN

Table 2. Money’s best places to live, 1994–97

Rank 1994 1995 1996 1997

1 Raleigh, Durham Gainesville, FL Madison, WI Nashua, NH


and Chapel Hill, NC
2 Rochester, MN Rochester, MN Punta Gorda, FL Rochester, MN
3 Provo and Orem, UT Jacksonville, FL Rochester, MN Monmouth and Ocean
Counties, NJ
4 Salt Lake City and Seattle, WA Fort Lauderdale, FL Punta Gorda, FL
Ogden, UT
5 San Jose, CA Ocala, FL Ann Arbor, MI Portsmouth, NH
6 Stamford and Fort Lauderdale, FL Fort Myers, FL Manchester, NH
Norwalk, CT
7 Gainesville, FL Salem, NH Gainesville, FL Madison, WI
8 Seattle, WA Raleigh, Durham and Austin, TX San Jose, CA
Chapel Hill, NC
9 Sioux Falls, SD Las Vegas, NV Seattle, WA Jacksonville, FL
10 Albuquerque, NM Naples, FL Lakeland, FL Fort Walton Beach, FL

Note: 1997 is the last year in which Money published straightforward top 10 rankings. Since then, it
has identified best places by region and by city size (1998–2000) and by quality of neighbourhoods
(2002). In 2001, it devoted its best places feature to a profile of New York.

omic development have come to take the best organisations frequently gain certain powers
places rankings produced by the popular me- to create and implement policy. Lexington,
dia seriously (Pacione, 2001, p. 381). For Kentucky, underwent significant changes in
some, they simply provide another weapon in governance in the 1990s, particularly with
a larger place marketing strategy while for regard to how and by whom decisions about
others, as I will discuss in the following the future social and economic development
sections, their criteria and the places they of the city should be made.
anoint as exemplary provide a framework for In 1994, for instance, Lexington’s Cham-
the development of new policy. ber of Commerce in collaboration with a
private consultant and the financial and pol-
itical support of the city government initiated
The Media’s Best Places Criteria Framing a planning process, called New Century Lex-
Urban Policy ington (McCann, 2001; New Century Lex-
Central to the entrepreneurial city thesis is ington, 1995a, 1995b). Central to the New
the argument that urban entrepreneurialism is Century process was the use of collaborative
accompanied and facilitated by a shift to- ‘visioning’, a decision-making technique
wards governance in which, among other characterised by a rhetoric of openness,
things, the array of policy alternatives for which is welcoming to direct input of ideas
local economic development has grown to of all interested parties and by a focus on
include both more direct forms of private- evoking inspirational visions of the future
sector involvement and the opportunity for a rather than on outlining the concrete policies
wider variety of decision-making processes needed to foster change (McCann, 2001).
(see K. G. Ward, 2000c; Hubbard et al., 2002 The aim of the new planning process was to
for reviews). Through this shift, certain insti- develop a set of goals for how the city should
tutions of the state gain power and legiti- develop, economically, socially and environ-
macy, others lose out, while groups such as mentally, in the subsequent decades. This
business coalitions and community activist was to act as a framework for the creation of

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
‘BEST PLACES’ 1917

Figure 1. Cities regularly appearing in Money’s top 10, 1987–2002. Note: Since 1987, Money’s
rankings have featured Rochester, Minnesota, eight times—more than any other city. Austin, Texas,
San Francisco, California, and Seattle, Washington, have appeared seven times; Madison, Wisconsin,
six times; Minneapolis–St Paul, Minnesota, five times; and Boston, Massachusetts, Gainesville, Florida,
Nashau, New Hampshire, and Raleigh–Durham–Chapel Hill, North Carolina, have each appeared four
times. The 2001 edition is not included in these figures since the magazine decided to forego its normal
survey in favour of a feature on New York in the wake of the 11 September attack. It is worth noting
that Money did briefly laud six other cities in 2001. As the authors put it, “inspired by New York, we
went looking for other cities that feature a strong sense of community—as well as low crime, nice
weather, low property taxes and excellent education”. These cities were Ann Arbor, Michigan, Austin,
Texas, Missoula, Montana, Portland, Oregon, Providence, Rhode Island, and Sarasota, Florida.

future policies in areas as diverse as land use other places in which standard economic in-
planning, economic development and public centives were coupled with the perceived
education. Elected officials’ willingness to need to offer potential investors ‘extra-econ-
accept this privately led process and to omic’ incentives, particularly high levels of
pledge to put its recommendations at the amenity and quality of life; the structure of
centre of future policy processes illustrates the decision-making process circumscribed
the taken-for-granted nature of direct private- the range of visions of the city’s potential
sector input into policy in the contemporary future that could be discussed by focusing on
US. In the context of the present argument, certain predetermined criteria and goals.
two aspects of the New Century process are Money magazine’s rankings figured promi-
particularly relevant: the question of how to nently in both these aspects of the process.
create the best future for the city was under- The consultant began the first planning
stood to revolve around competition with meeting—attended by business and political

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
1918 EUGENE J. MCCANN

leaders, local activists and other residents— by also deploying Lexington’s picturesque
by providing a focus for discussion. He ar- surrounding landscape and Southern ‘small
gued that, in order to be successful in the town ambience’ as another marketing tool.
future, Lexington needed to identify its com- Furthermore, the wide scope of the process
petitors, which he defined as a group of 50 entailed the capacities of various agencies
similar small and mid-sized Southern and and institutions dealing with economic and
Midwestern cities, and be aware of its rela- ‘extra-economic’ factors to be combined in a
tive standing among this group. He empha- novel and productive way.
sised his point by distributing a number of These new combinations necessitated a
photocopied business reports, crime reports, new form of decision-making in which a
magazine articles and spreadsheets to the disparate group of ‘stakeholders’ were asked
participants, all of which ranked cities in to be involved in planning the vision from its
terms of particular attributes or made argu- initial stages. As the first visioning meeting
ments about why a specific aspect of a place went on, participants were asked to identify
was crucial to its general prosperity. In the which criteria they, as a group, considered
rankings, the consultant highlighted Lexing- most important for the city’s future. The
ton’s position in various categories (30th in high-ranking criteria were discussed in more
manufacturing, 21st in services, 5th in edu- detail with the intention of gaining consensus
cation level, 40th in murders and so on). He on relevant policy goals. For instance,
used these to identify the categories in which “Become one of the top five places of similar
the city could do better and the cities listed population size in the US in terms of earn-
on the rankings that could be viewed as ings per job by 2015” was adopted as a goal
targets and as examples of how to develop (author’s field notes, 26 April, 1995). In turn,
effective policy (author’s field notes, 26 these goals became the topics of discussion
April, 1995). of the subsequent visioning meetings held
While framing discussion in terms of com- under the auspices of New Century Lexing-
petition, the New Century consultant also ton and were central to the final ‘vision’
distributed a list of the top criteria Money statement produced by the group (McCann,
magazine used in compiling its 1992, 1993 2001). This vision was to be turned over to a
and 1994 best places rankings. These, he small group of ‘strategic planners’ in the
argued, were key elements that made a city Chamber of Commerce who were charged
attractive to potential investors and that made with making specific policy recommenda-
it a good place to live for the existing popu- tions to the city government and local plan-
lation and for newcomers. The choice of ners.
Money’s criteria is particularly interesting The vision was touted as the outcome of
since this publication explicitly defines its an inclusive process in which all views of the
‘best places’ in terms of their quality of life, city’s potential future were considered
including not only their potential for new equally and where consensus-based decision-
investors but also their ‘extra-economic’, so- making created unity of purpose upon which
cial and cultural, characteristics. In this new policies could be built. On the other
sense, the Chamber of Commerce’s project hand, the vision can be read as a direct
to revision Lexington was, from the outset, reflection of the terms of the debate set at the
intent on developing new combinations of first planning meeting. The consultant’s in-
economic and ‘extra-economic’ factors to in- troductory presentation constituted a discur-
crease the city’s competitiveness (Jessop, sive framing of Lexington’s current
1997, 1998). It was a self-conscious attempt economic and social character, its potential
to improve on the city’s traditional methods future and its position in the US urban hier-
of attracting industry—which, since the archy. This framing defined a playing-field in
1950s, had primarily involved assembling which the interurban politics of place compe-
land packages and offering tax incentives— tition was represented as an indisputable fact.

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
‘BEST PLACES’ 1919

Money’s criteria, along with the other data, Given this context, the rankings not only
set the conditions of possibility for the devel- provide a league table in which cities can see
opment of a vision of the future of the city. their position relative to their competitors
and as a result of which they can set new
goals to do better. The rankings also act as a
Local Economic Development Strategy road map for urban political and business
and the Ambivalence of Being a ‘Best leaders intent on gathering information on
Place’ best practices of economic development. For
The case of Lexington is one example of instance, each year a group of Lexington’s
how the best places rankings and criteria city officials and representatives of the
have an affect on how urban policy is formu- Chamber of Commerce hit the road on a
lated. It is a particularly clear case due to the fact-finding trip to a different city. Given the
explicit reference to Money’s criteria and the discussion in the previous section, it is no
use of those criteria in setting the limits for surprise that Austin, Texas, and Madison,
discussion. The role of the popular media in Wisconsin, another perennial favourite of
the serial reproduction of entrepreneurial Money, were both destinations for this group
policies and landscapes can be traced further, in the 1990s (Bean, 1992; Baniak, 1997).
however. The tendency of popular ranking Indeed, Austin hosts numerous similar dele-
exercises continually to identify the same gations each year, all intent on learning the
limited number of cities as best places—to formula for the city’s success and transfer-
live, to invest, to start a new business, etc.— ring it back to their own city. In this section,
means that certain places become widely I will discuss Austin’s economic develop-
known as exemplars or ‘success stories’. In ment model in more detail before turning to
turn, the majority of cities who regularly its relationship to other cities, using Colum-
appear in the mediocre middle of the various bus, Ohio, as an example of a place with an
rankings identify the anointed few as places explicit strategy aimed at rising higher in the
to be competed with through imitation. This, various best place rankings by emulating
in turn, creates a treadmill in which pressure Austin.
is put back on innovative cities to upgrade
continually their quality of life in order to
Narrating Austin’s Economic Development:
maintain their competitive advantage and to
National Media and Local Professionals’ Ac-
avoid the downward trajectory upon which
counts
‘losing’ cities can find themselves moving.
As Harvey puts it, interurban competition Money has placed Austin on its top 10 list 8
operates as an “ ‘external coercive power’ times since 1991. Recently, the city has also
over individual cities to bring them closer featured highly on a range of other rankings.
into line with the discipline and logic of Fortune magazine ranked Austin among its
capitalist development” (Harvey, 1989, top 10 cities for business 6 times in the
p. 10). Thus, cities 1990s, for instance. The consensus view
among these publications is that Austin has
have no option, given the coercive laws of achieved both high levels of livability and
competition, except to keep ahead of the economic growth, making it a model combi-
game, thus engendering leap-frogging in- nation of an ideal hometown and an econ-
novations in life-styles, cultural forms, omic boomtown. As Money put it in 1999
products, and service mixes, even institu-
tional and political forms, if they are to Austin has always been graced by its loca-
survive. The result is a stimulating if often tion—nestled in the Texas Hill Country, it
destructive maelstrom of urban-based cul- has too much rolling terrain, too much in
tural, political, production and consump- the way of grass and wildflowers, to be
tion innovations (Harvey, 1989, p. 12). mistaken for the flat and dusty Texas of

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
1920 EUGENE J. MCCANN

the imagination. Built around government omic development, especially in the national
(the state capitol dome looms over down- media and among those working in the city’s
town) and education (the state university is technology sector, those in the city’s busi-
the city’s largest employer and cultural ness community who were engaged in econ-
force), it’s both artsy and smart. … omic development planning prior to the mid
1980s present a different narrative of the
[In the late 1980s, the] city succeeded in city’s success. They are particularly con-
wooing start-up shops and creating a re- cerned with the way the popular understand-
markably hospitable business climate. A ing of Austin’s economic development fails
young UT [University of Texas] student to acknowledge the decades of strategic plan-
named Michael Dell built a computer ning and entrepreneurship that set the stage
company in town that now employs for the 1990s technology boom. This strategy
19,800 and has seen its stock price some is based on what was, at the time, a relatively
52,000 per cent since its 1988 IPO [initial new and innovative combination of what
public offering of stock] … Jessop would refer to as economic and ‘ex-
But Austin wouldn’t make MONEY’s tra-economic’ factors. Specifically, it en-
Best Places list if it were just a tech boom- tailed the development of strong linkages
town. … [It also] boasts symphonies, art between key actors and institutions in key
museums, film festivals, good restaurants economic, political and social sectors while
and good football as well as some of the also constructing a vision in which culture
best live music in the country. For those and a clean environment would be used as
looking for safe, clean water, it has that resources to attract clean industry.
too. So in one sense you could say that The first action, according to this narra-
they’re lucky in Austin (Money, 1999, tive, occurred in 1957 with a University of
p. 134). Texas report recommending that the city at-
tempt to recruit ‘light’ or ‘clean’ industry
This account can be, and frequently is, chal- that would complement research and technol-
lenged on at least two counts. First, as I have ogy initiatives at the university without pol-
already suggested, Money’s rankings and luting the city’s environment. This formed
those of the other major publications, such as the basis for strategic efforts over the next 25
Fortune, reflect the upper-middle-class char- years to develop light manufacturing and
acteristics of their subscribers and a gener- technology as the third element of the city’s
ally pro-business and development stance. economy, along with higher education and
Their narratives tend, as a result, to paint a government (Engelking, 1996; Gosdin, 2000;
rosy view of the ‘best places’ while generally interviews with economic development lead-
ignoring the potential negative consequences ers, October and November 2000). This strat-
of economic development on cities and the egy proved successful in creating a branch
continued poverty and inequality that exist plant manufacturing economy in the city,
behind a successful place marketing image. anchored by corporations like IBM and Mo-
While these concerns are very important, the torola. The process of attracting these com-
second challenge to the standard media nar- panies also solidified a partnership between
rative of Austin’s success comes from the state government, local business interests and
local business community and is more di- the university which, in 1983, competed suc-
rectly relevant to my purpose at this point in cessfully with 57 other US cities to attract
the paper. Money’s description of Austin’s the city’s first major research and develop-
economic success marks the late 1980s as a ment corporation (Engelking, 1996; Gibson
turning-point after which the pleasant and Rogers, 1994).
government and college town blossomed into This success strengthened the tripartite
a high-technology centre. While this is a partnership driving the city’s economic de-
widely held understanding of the city’s econ- velopment. It also indicated that, as the city

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
‘BEST PLACES’ 1921

became more than a branch plant economy, of life to natural endowments rather than
new strategies needed to be formulated in purposeful strategy seems, however, to have
order to shape future development. A new created a certain degree of ambivalence
strategic economic plan was commissioned among business leaders towards the best
in the mid 1980s. The plan’s title, Creating places rankings. For one senior member of
an opportunity economy: enhancing quality the Chamber of Commerce
of life in a changing economy (SRI Inter-
Our economic prosperity is very closely
national Policy Center, 1985), indicated a
linked with quality of life, so as one does
continuation of an economic development
well, so does the other. So, I think being
strategy that linked development and livabil-
recognised as one of the best places to
ity. This linkage is underscored in the plan’s
invest and live is reinforcing. It is encour-
introduction
aging, and we all take, you know, pride
If … Austin is to link economic develop- and are glad that we’re recognised (inter-
ment with high quality of life, steps need view with senior economic development
to be taken now to maintain a diverse but leader, 2000).
balanced economy, to improve education
In this regard, the Chamber maintains a web-
and training for all Austinites, to upgrade
page dedicated to tracking the city’s position
the community’s physical and environ-
on various best places rankings (Greater
mental infrastructure, and to preserve and
Austin Chamber of Commerce, 1999) while
add to Austin’s social, cultural, and rec-
city government agencies maintain two oth-
reational amenities (SRI International Pub-
ers (e-Austin, 2001; City of Austin, 2001).
lic Policy Center, 1985, p. v).
Another member of the Chamber’s senior
The ‘opportunity economy’ model continues staff was at pains to point out that the city
to frame economic development policy in the does not court such attention, however.
city. It entails a continued attention to main-
In fact, we’ve never ever been focused on
taining existing socially embedded, or ‘extra-
how do we make ourselves number one in
economic’, factors that shape the city’s
Fortune magazine or Forbes or Money
economic development while also encourag-
magazine. … But what’s happened is the
ing on-going efforts to further innovate in
media has come to Austin and is asking,
this context. It also involves a continuing
“What’s Austin’s secret recipe for suc-
attention to the issues of urban amenity,
cess?”. And so we’re having a chance to
quality of life and culture as resources in and
share it with the media and, of course, the
for economic development. This means that,
media writes more about it. That creates
“in local public policy deliberations, quality
more buzz about Austin, which in turn
of life is a constant consideration, and what
sends more companies … (interview with
constitutes quality of life is a constant subject
senior economic development leader,
of debate” (Engelking, 1996, p. 39; ICF
2000).
Kaiser, 1998).
Austin’s ambivalence stems from the view
that its economic development priorities—
Austin’s Ambivalent Relationship to Best
ones that emphasised clean air and water as
Places Rankings
early as the 1950s and that have continued to
Despite the differences in emphasis, Money’s stress the interconnections between the econ-
description of Austin as a good place to live omic and the ‘extra-economic’—pre-dated
might be read as an affirmation of longstand- and influenced the contemporary consensus
ing economic development policy. The me- on local economic development that is
dia’s tendency to attribute the city’s reflected in the pages of Money and other
economic success largely to the arrival of a publications. This is not to suggest that the
few entrepreneurs in the 1990s and its quality attention Austin has received from the na-

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
1922 EUGENE J. MCCANN

tional media in recent years has had no affect policies pursued by a small number of cities.
on economic development strategy. Rather, Furthermore, it “consolidate[s] a limited but
business leaders have become increasingly widely accepted set of diagnoses and pre-
discerning when deciding which types of scriptions for the economic and political
investment to attract difficulties [cities face]” (Jessop, 1997, p. 30)
by encouraging the majority of cities to learn
For companies that just contact us—the
from and reproduce the policy formulae of
6–800 inquires [annually]—we have a
the annointed few.
screening criteria and we don’t just want
This process of imitation is often seen on
anybody now because it’s putting more
the urban landscape. Harvey, for instance,
pressure on the infrastructure, so we’ll
notes that contemporary cities’ competitive
look at their median wage rate—we don’t
stance
need to attract companies that are going to
pay minimum wage. We want to see how may even force repetitive and serial repro-
socially responsible they are. Will they duction of ‘world trade centers’ or of new
contribute to solving problems with air cultural and entertainment centers, of wa-
quality and water and transport, things of terfront development, of postmodern shop-
that nature? And then we figure out which ping malls, and the like (Harvey, 1989,
ones we really want to help and we en- p. 10).
courage those (interview with senior econ-
There is also a tendency for cities to transfer
omic development leader, 2000).
and reproduce policies from places known
Of course, this is a problem most urban for good practices in governance and econ-
growth coalitions would be glad to have. omic development. A desirable outcome of
While Austin discourages the advances of this transfer would be a careful modification
interested companies that it finds inappropri- of policy to match the place-specific charac-
ate, the cities ranked in the middle and bot- teristics of the new location and, as a result,
tom of the popular rankings look to Austin as the creation of ‘strong’ or sustainable com-
a model of how to attract investment and petitive advantage (Cox, 1995; Jessop,
residents. The city has become a favourite 1998). It is likely, however, that the ‘weak’
case study in policy circles (for example, and unsustainable serial reproduction of cer-
Miller, 1999) and has become a prime desti- tain landscape elements from city to city
nation for fact-finding trips organised by under urban entrepreneurialism will be paral-
growth coalitions from around the US and lelled by the emergence of decontextualised
beyond, such as the one taken by the group ‘copy-cat’ policies that fail to achieve their
from Lexington (Bean, 1992). long-term economic development goals. In
this context, contemporary urban growth
coalitions find themselves challenged with
Idea(l) Transfer: Learning from the Suc-
balancing their need to learn from best prac-
cessful, Chasing the Media Spotlight and
tices while avoiding uncritically copying
the Problems of Implementation
other cities’ policies.
The ways in which individual cities become Columbus, Ohio, is a city currently grap-
widely known as success stories in economic pling with this dilemma as it attempts to plan
development are numerous. As I have al- its future economic development and, relat-
ready argued, the role of the popular media edly, to enhance its image at the national
in this process should not be underestimated. level in order to compete for corporate in-
The rankings produced by mainstream publi- vestment. For years, there has been an on-go-
cations like Money and Fortune construct a ing discussion in the city over how best to
hegemonic narrative of what criteria are distinguish Columbus from the state’s other
necessary to rise up the urban hierarchy. This major cities, Cleveland and Cincinnati. This
narrative both draws upon and affirms the is despite the fact that the local economy has

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
‘BEST PLACES’ 1923

grown in recent decades whereas the rest of Austin’s tripartite leadership coalition—
Ohio has suffered the sorts of economic de- government at the city and state levels, the
cline commonly associated with the US business community and the university.
‘Rustbelt’. In a recent article on how to These were intended to provide the visitors
improve the city, Columbus Monthly maga- with an understanding of the roles played by
zine argued that Columbus needed to “get a each in the city’s economic development and
better attitude” and “market a national im- of the interactions between the partnership
age” (Paprocki, 2001, pp. 36–37). In support members. Other meetings focused on key
of this argument, a local advertising execu- aspects of the city’s economy, such as the
tive argued, “We’re endlessly apologizing high technology sector, and the policies in
for not being a place with a pedigree. Let’s place to sustain its development, such as
be confident in who we are—a city on the workforce development and venture capital
rise”. A city council member struck a similar programmes (Greater Columbus Chamber of
note saying Commerce, 2000a). While the lessons
learned from such a trip will vary somewhat
How do we escape from being branded as
from one participant to another, a senior
a frumpy, vanilla, no-town town? …
executive in one of Columbus’ private econ-
We’re America’s best kept secret. Let’s
omic development institutions identified two
get a core group of high-profile, forward-
areas in which the city could learn from
thinking Columbus people to lobby for us
Austin: coalition building for economic de-
to the rest of the world (Paprocki, 2001,
velopment and the creation of a consistent
p. 37).
and attractive image.
A concern with Columbus’ image and its Reflecting on the visit, this executive ar-
ability to be economically competitive per- gued that “a community needs to have a
meates local business and political institu- consensus-driven strategy for the fu-
tions. A year before the Columbus Monthly ture … [involving] the critical mass of key
article was published, for instance, the leadership … Austin did that. Austin created
Mayor’s office and the Chamber of Com- within the community a very defined objec-
merce organised the city’s first ‘leadership tive [to attract clean, high technology and
trip’, a fact-finding visit to Austin. Despite light manufacturing industry]”. On the other
the similarities between Austin and Colum- hand, he argued, Columbus, “continues to
bus in terms of economic history and rela- make a mistake [since all of its] plans are
tionship to education and state government, either owned by an individual or an organis-
Columbus has not experienced the same part- ation. And because they are owned, there
nership model of urban governance that de- was never any broad-based ownership built
veloped in Austin from the 1950s onwards for these ideas”. For him, the visit to Austin
nor has it experienced the recent economic not only highlighted the lack of a consensus
boom that has fundamentally reshaped among Columbus’ business and political
Austin. Furthermore, Columbus does not find élites on economic development but also
itself in the upper echelon of many best pointed out a parallel and problematic lack of
places rankings and, whereas Austin limits clarity in the city’s branding activities
the number of companies seeking to locate
there, many in Columbus’ business com- You have a community here of 1.6 million
munity worry that the relative invisibility of people without the foggiest notion of
the city means that it is losing out on corpo- where they’re going. Literally. … There is
rate investment. Austin was chosen as a des- no image development. There is no mar-
tination for the leadership trip because of keting mentality in this community at
these similarities and crucial differences. all. … You have to be creating brand dis-
The agenda for the three-day trip included tinction based on what you are building
a number of meetings with representatives of to. … It’s got to be consistent, consistent

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
1924 EUGENE J. MCCANN

and differentiating enough to … start to some are more scientifically determined


become the brand of the community (inter- than others. But you have to be out there.
view with senior economic development You have to have a presence. You have to
leader, 2001). have a willingness to work at it and under-
stand that you are competing. That’s why
The outcome of the Columbus delegation’s
image starts to take on a very important
visit to Austin is a new regional economic
role. … And if you want to be moving up
development strategy for greater Columbus
on the ladder on these lists, you better be
that is explicitly “modelled after the strategy
out there talking about yourself, you better
that drove much of Austin’s success” and to
be out there with a message about who
overcome the lack of vision and consensus
you are and what you stand for and how
that senior economic development leaders
that is a sustainable, competitive advan-
have recently identified as a major stumbling
tage over other cities who are doing the
block for the city (Greater Columbus Cham-
same. … [I]f you don’t have that … you
ber of Commerce, 2000, 2001). The new
get left behind (interview with senior
strategy focuses on strengthening the
economic development leader, 2001).
“socially constructed, socially regularised
and socially embedded [i.e. ‘extra-econ- Clearly, the trip to Austin had an invigorat-
omic’] factors” that Jessop and Sum (2000, ing effect on many of those who participated.
p. 2311) argue are crucial to many contem- The delegation was presented with a well-re-
porary economic development strategies. The hearsed narrative of Austin’s economic de-
first step in this new process is the creation of velopment that crystallised existing
three ‘strike forces’ intended to take immedi- discomfort with the fragmented nature of
ate action on key issues of concern: venture governance in the Columbus while present-
capital, place marketing and outreach to cor- ing the alternative of a coherent partnership
porations. The “Marketing Columbus” strike between government, the private sector and
force was specifically charged with the university. The presentations in Austin
“develop[ing] a strategy to ensure that also challenged Columbus to create a
Columbus is at the top” of Money’s and other stronger and more coherent brand for itself in
similar lists. Participants in a follow-up order to attract investment. Austin’s success
meeting after their return from Austin were in this regard and its prominence on national
informed that the best places rankings has encouraged Colum-
bus to see these rankings as a critical focus of
Chamber has already completed an initial
future marketing efforts and to make raising
analysis of “Best City” Rankings that can
the city’s standing on the lists a key compo-
be used to jump start this effort. This
nent of its new regional strategy.
analysis can be used to drive our strate-
This renewed vigour notwithstanding, in-
gies—whether they are visits to the edi-
terviews with Austin’s economic develop-
torial boards or their consultants, hosting
ment leaders around the time of the
those groups in Columbus and other mar-
Columbus delegation’s visit suggested that
keting activities (Greater Columbus
for them, the recipe for competitiveness was
Chamber of Commerce, 2000b, p. 2).
not easily transferred. As one long-time
Asked how important it was for the city to member of the coalition that shaped the de-
raise its standing in popular best places rank- velopment of Austin’s technology sector put
ings, a senior economic development pro- it,
fessional argued strongly that it was
Once a month we’ll get a big contingent
important for a competitive city.
from different states and communities.
If you are very competitively oriented, And … the ones that I think can succeed
then those kind of things become incredi- are the ones that are close to really suc-
bly important. And I will tell you that cessful universities. So I think Columbus

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
‘BEST PLACES’ 1925

has a good shot at it because Ohio State is and transferred from place to place and the
a very good school. But there seems to be best places rankings produced by the popular
need to have a combination of a good media since the 1980s. The paper speaks to
university and a nice place to live. And in two continuing concerns in the literature on
the last 30 years or so, a nice place to live interurban competition and urban en-
has included a lot of sunshine. … So, I trepreneurialism: the question of how and
think it’s difficult for the great universities why similar policies are reproduced or trans-
in the Midwest, but it’s not imposs- ferred from place to place even as cities
ible. … You can’t do anything about the attempt to distinguish themselves from each
climate, so they need to … plan on recruit- other; and, the issue of how ‘extra-economic’
ing a lot of people who grew up in the factors are mobilised in the discursive con-
Midwest, who think this is a wonderful struction, legitimation and dissemination of
place to live, and not expect a lot of ideas about good local economic develop-
Californians. … Every economic develop- ment policy. The paper argues that the role of
ment issue cannot mimic Austin (interview the national popular media in these processes
with senior economic development leader, has been understudied. I suggest that the
2000). media’s normative discourse on what makes
a place good for life and investment is
For their part, local economic development powerful and political in the way that it aids
professionals in Columbus are aware of the in the production of contemporary local
potential pitfalls of relying too closely on a economic development policy. This argu-
policy model imported from elsewhere. They ment, then, is influenced by and illustrative
also express awareness of the downsides of of a larger and relatively recent attempt to
Austin’s economic expansion—not least the locate the study of discursive power much
congestion and environmental stress—that more centrally in political economy ap-
have accompanied the city’s rapid growth. proaches to urban studies (Jonas and Wilson,
Nonetheless, those involved in the trip to 1999b; McCann, 2002; Urban Studies,
Texas continue to pursue the goal of creating 1999).
a more coherent combination of economic This perspective has been clearly argued
and extra-economic factors in a policy model by Jonas and Wilson (1999b) in their dis-
that melds a diverse array of powerful inter- cussion of the politics of urban growth. For
ests, similar to that developed in Austin. At them, urban growth coalitions are equally
the same time, these groups continue to take engaged in creating the material conditions
the criteria of the media’s best places rank- for growth and in legitimating their practices
ings seriously and they remain attuned on through carefully constructed discursive
these rankings as an important focus of mar- strategies intended to convince people “of
keting exercises in order to make Columbus the importance of growth to their well-being”
a permanent fixture on the top of Money’s (Jonas and Wilson, 1999b, p. 8). These pol-
and other lists. The success of this effort is itical interventions are largely directed at a
yet to be determined but, from Austin’s per- popular audience in order to have most effect
spective at least, it is far from certain. and to generate maximum support for urban
entrepreneurial policies and growth-oriented
agendas. This discursive strategy is high-
Conclusion: The Popular Media and the
lighted by Jessop (1997) whose work on the
Discursive Construction/Limitation of
entrepreneurial city thesis has taken seriously
Possible Urban Futures
the role of narrative and discourse in the
The purpose of this paper has been to explore production of the economy and economic
the linkages among local economic develop- space. For him, a key characteristic of the
ment strategies in US cities, the processes urban entrepreneurialism is the “discursive
through which these strategies are valorised construction [of the economy] as a distinc-

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
1926 EUGENE J. MCCANN

tive object (of analysis, regulation, gover- in the past 15 years, it has had an increasing
nance, conquest, and/or other practices)” ability to frame policy-making discussions in
(Jessop, 1997, p. 29). Once this economic many US cities. In some cases, local élites
space has been discursively defined in this first refer directly to common ‘best places’
way, it can become a key element in the criteria—such as low tax rates and the im-
development of what Cox and Mair (1988) portance of sports facilities—and subse-
referred to as a ‘localist ideology’ which quently prioritise these elements in their
undergirds feelings of commonality and posi- visions of the future of the place. Therefore,
tivity towards growth coalition agendas both the contemporary local economic goal in the
within the locality itself and also among US is to manufacture a city that is simul-
friendly agents and institutions working at taneously an ideal hometown and an econ-
other scales (Jessop and Sum, 2000). omic boomtown as imagined in the glossy
It is in this context that popular best places pages of popular magazines like Money. This
rankings become salient to the activities of goal entails the restrictive framing of which
local business and political élites. This media visions of the future are acceptable in policy-
discourse clearly demarcates one city from making discussions.
another in its ranking process, defines each For example, in the case of Lexington, the
place as essentially and naturally competitive development of a vision of the future along
by placing them on a ‘league table’ and the lines of Money’s criteria and in accord-
simultaneously draws upon and reinforces a ance with standard discourses of urban com-
highly problematic view of cities as socially petitiveness almost predetermined a final
and economically homogeneous by making plan that was in line with growth coalition
statements like “you could say that they’re aspirations. The terms of the discussion set
lucky in Austin” (Money, 1999, p. 134). The by the rankings and statistics produced by the
rankings also draw upon and reinforce what consultant made it very difficult to propose
might be understood as ‘mainstream’ ideas alternative futures. Coupled with this was an
of what constitutes the good life or well-be- unproblematised acceptance of the criteria
ing and therefore provide a firm foundation developed by Money. This meant that there
for growth discourse. As Jonas and Wilson was no room to question the definition of,
put it, growth coalitions’ political actions means to achieve or consequences of ‘low
taxes’, for instance. After all, the types of
seek to strike a responsive chord in main-
criteria used by Money and other publica-
stream thought. … Thus, power becomes
tions in ranking cities as good places to live
wielded not through contextless articula-
tend to be hard to argue with, at least when
tions that foist power and a new way of
taken at face value. ‘Safe streets’, ‘vibrant
seeing on an unsuspecting mainstream but
economy’ and ‘high quality of education for
through cultivating prevailing beliefs and
our children’ might, in the US context, be
values (Jonas and Wilson, 1999b, p. 9;
termed ‘motherhood and apple pie’ issues. It
emphasis added).
is hard to suggest that they are not good
Media narratives of the good life and good things, but the very fact that that they seem
places resonate with, concretise and validate self-evidently desirable for any policy pro-
prevailing beliefs about how economic de- cess often makes it very difficult to question
velopment policy should be conducted in the means by which these ends will be
many cities. Therefore, they can, in certain achieved.
cases, have significant impacts on the politics The danger for urban growth coalitions in
of interurban competition. believing the hype of the rankings and tailor-
The national media’s discursive framing of ing policy towards their criteria is that no
interurban politics is related to its influence room will be left in the policy discussion for
on the character of intraurban politics. As alternative visions or for stories that do not
best places rankings have grown in influence fit the narrative of prosperity. Cities en-

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
‘BEST PLACES’ 1927

sconced at the top of the rankings may be Durham? (http://www.ci.durham.nc.us/busi-


more aware of this danger than those pre- nesses/; accessed December 2002).
COCHRANE, A. (1999) Redefining urban politics
occupied with the chase to raise their pos- for the twenty-first century, in: A. E. G. JONAS
ition in Money’s next list. For these reasons, and D. WILSON (Eds) The Urban Growth Ma-
the relationships between the popular me- chine: Critical Perspectives Two Decades
dia’s narrative representations of place and Later, pp. 109–124. Albany, NY: State Univer-
the practices of urban governance, policy- sity of New York Press.
COCHRANE, A., PECK, J. and TICKELL, A. (1996)
making and politics are worthy of continued Manchester plays games: exploring the local
study. These rankings and the reaction to politics of globalisation, Urban Studies, 33,
their publication should be seen as more than pp. 1391–1336.
entertainment. Their development and use in COX, K. R. (1995) Globalisation, competition and
the policy process can be analysed in the the politics of local economic development,
Urban Studies, 32, pp. 213–225.
context of the neo-liberal shift towards a COX, K. R. (1999) Ideology and the growth co-
view of cities as fundamentally competitive alition, in: A. E. G. JONAS and D. WILSON (Eds)
entities and consumption spaces. The crucial The Urban Growth Machine: Critical Perspec-
question, then, for any policy-making pro- tives Two Decades Later, pp. 21–36. Albany,
cess intent on developing a good place to live NY: State University of New York Press.
COX, K. R. and MAIR, A. (1988) Locality and
in reference to these rankings is, “a good community in the politics of local economic
place for whom?”. development, Annals of the Association of
American Geographers, 78, pp. 307–325.
CUTTER, S. (1985) Rating places: a geographer’s
Note view of quality of life. Washington, DC: As-
sociation of American Geographers.
1. I am indebted to an anonymous reviewer for DOLOWITZ, D. P. and MARSH, D. (2000) Learning
emphasising this aspect of interurban compe- from abroad: the role of policy transfer in
tition. contemporary policy-making, Governance: An
International Journal of Policy and Adminis-
tration, 13, pp. 5–24.
E-AUSTIN (2001) Take the ‘A’ list (http://www.e-
References
austin.org/alists.htm; accessed December
BANIAK, P. (1997) Leaders will seek ideas in 2002).
Wisconsin: officials to get tips on better UK- ENGELKING, S. E. (1996) Austin’s opportunity
city ties, Lexington Herald–Leader, 14 May. economy: a model for collaborative technology
BARNES, T. J. and DUNCAN, J. S. (1992) Introduc- development, Annals of the New York Academy
tion: writing worlds, in: T. J. BARNES and J. S. of Sciences, April, pp. 29–47.
DUNCAN (Eds) Writing Worlds: Discourse, Text FINDLAY, A., MORRIS, A. and ROGERSON, R.
and Metaphor in the Representation of Land- (1988) Where to live in Britain, 1988, Cities,
scape, pp. 1–17. New York: Routledge. August, pp. 268–276.
BEAN, D. (1992) Austin’s success model for Lex- FLORIDA, R. (2000) Competing in the age of tal-
ington. Lexington Herald–Leader, 29 April, ent: environment, amenities, and the new econ-
p. B2. omy. Pittsburgh, PA: R. K. Mellon Foundation.
BOYLE, M. (1999) Growth machines and propa- FLORIDA, R. (2002) The Rise of the Creative
ganda projects: a review of readings of the role Class: And How It’s Transforming Work,
of civic boosterism in the politics of local Leisure, Community and Everyday Life. New
economic development, in: A. E. G. JONAS and York: Basic Books.
D. WILSON (Eds) The Urban Growth Machine: FLORIDA, R. and GATES, G. (2001) Technology
Critical Perspectives Two Decades Later, and tolerance: the importance of diversity to
pp. 55–70. Albany, NY: State University of high-technology growth. Center on Urban and
New York Press. Metropolitan Policy, Brookings Institution,
BRENNER, N. and THEODORE, N. (2002) Cities and Washington, DC.
the geographies of ‘actually existing neoliberal- GIBSON, D. V. and ROGERS, E. M. (1994) R and D
ism’, Antipode, 34, pp. 349–379. Collaboration On Trial: The Microelectronics
CITY OF AUSTIN (2001) Austin rates national atten- and Computer Technology Corporation.
tion (http://www.ci.austin.tx.us/news/01/rank- Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.
ings; accessed April 2001). GOSDIN, M. (2000) Austin’s power, Texas Tech-
CITY OF DURHAM (2001) Why do business in nology, July.

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
1928 EUGENE J. MCCANN

GREATER AUSTIN CHAMBER OF COMMERCE (1999) strategies in and for (inter)urban competition,
News bulletin (http://www.austinchamber.org/ Urban Studies, 31(12), pp. 2287–2313.
The Chamber/About The Chamber/ JONAS, A. E. G. and WILSON, D. (Eds) (1999a) The
News and Events/News Bulletin/Past Issues/ Urban Growth Machine: Critical Perspectives
Oct11/). Two Decades Later. Albany, NY: State Univer-
GREATER AUSTIN CHAMBER OF COMMERCE (2000a) sity of New York Press.
The state of the regional economy. Austin, TX: JONAS, A. E. G. and WILSON, D. (1999b) The city
Greater Austin Chamber of Commerce. as a growth machine: critical reflections two
GREATER COLUMBUS CHAMBER OF COMMERCE decades later, in: A. E. G. JONAS and D. WILSON
(2000a) Greater Columbus Leadership Trip, (Eds) The Urban Growth Machine: Critical
Austin 2000 Handbook. Columbus, OH: Perspectives Two Decades Later, pp. 3–18. Al-
Greater Columbus Chamber of Commerce. bany, NY: State University of New York Press.
GREATER COLUMBUS CHAMBER OF COMMERCE KATZ, V. (2000) Press release: PORTLAND IS
(2000b) Notes on Austin benchmarking trip #1. Mayor Vera Katz applauds Money maga-
follow-up meeting. Columbus, OH: Greater zine’s first time recognition of the Rose City as
Columbus Chamber of Commerce. the best in the US. City of Portland, Oregon, 14
GREATER COLUMBUS CHAMBER OF COMMERCE November.
(2001) News Release. Greater Columbus KEARNS, G. and PHILO, C. (Eds) (1993) Selling
Chamber, City of Columbus, the Ohio State Places: The City as Cultural Capital. Oxford:
University commit to regional economic devel- Pergamon Press.
opment strategy for 21st century (http:// LAURIA, M. (Ed.) (1997) Reconstructing Urban
www.columbus-chamber.org/pritem/pr010221a. Regime Theory: Regulating Urban Politics in a
html). Global Economy. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
GREENBERG, M. (2000) Branding cities: a social LEY, D. (1990) Urban livability in context, Urban
history of the urban lifestyle magazine, Urban Geography, 11, pp. 31–35.
Affairs Review, 36, pp. 228–263. LOGAN, J. R. and MOLOTCH, H. (1987) Urban
HALL, T. and HUBBARD, P. (Eds) (1998) The En- Fortunes: The Political Economy of Place.
trepreneurial City: Geographies of Politics, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Regime, and Representation. New York: Wi- MCCANN, E. J. (1999) Race, protest, and public
ley. space: contextualizing Lefebvre in the US city,
HARDING, A. (1995) European city regimes? In- Antipode, 31(2), pp. 163–184.
ter-urban competition in the new Europe. Paper MCCANN, E. J. (2001) Collaborative visioning or
presented at the ESRC Local Governance Con- urban planning as therapy? The politics of pub-
ference, Exeter, September. lic-private policy-making, The Professional
HARVEY, D. (1989) From managerialism to en- Geographer, 53(2), pp. 207–218.
trepreneurialism: the transformation of urban MCCANN, E. J. (2002) The cultural politics of
governance in late capitalism, Geografiska An- local economic development: meaning-making,
naler, 71 B, pp. 3–17. place-making, and the urban policy process.
HUBBARD, P., KITCHIN, R., BARTLEY, B. and Geoforum, 33, pp. 385–398.
FULLER, D. (2002) Thinking Geographically: MCCANN, E. J. (2003) Framing space and time in
Space, Theory and Contemporary Human Ge- the city: urban policy and the politics of spatial
ography. London: Continuum. and temporal scale, Journal of Urban Affairs,
ICF KAISER CONSULTING GROUP (1998) Long 25(2), pp. 159–178.
range strategic economic development plan for MILLER, J. (1999) Regional case study: Austin
the Austin region. Austin, TX: Greater Austin Texas. Or, “How to create a knowledge econ-
Chamber of Commerce. omy”. European Commission Delegation,
JESSOP, B. (1997) The entrepreneurial city: Re- Washington, DC (http://www.eurunion.org/
imaging localities, redesigning economic gov- partner/austin.htm).
ernance, or restructuring capital?, in: N. JEWSON Money Magazine (1987) The best places to live,
and S. MACGREGOR (Eds) Transforming Cities: 16(8), pp. 34–44.
Contested Governance and New Spatial Divi- Money (1999) The best places to live, 28(11),
sions, pp. 28–41. New York: Routledge. pp. 130–136.
JESSOP, B. (1998) The narrative of enterprise and Money (2000) The best places to live, 29(13),
the enterprise of narrative: place marketing and pp. 148–159.
the entrepreneurial city, in: T. HALL and P. MOORE, M. (1996) Flint and me: Michael Moore
HUBBARD (Eds) The Entrepreneurial City: Ge- returns to our first last-place city, Money, July,
ographies of Politics, Regime, and Representa- pp. 88–89.
tion, pp. 77–99. New York: Wiley. NASH, K. (2000) Contemporary Political Soci-
JESSOP, B. and SUM, N.-L. (2000) An entrepreneu- ology: Globalization, Politics, and Power.
rial city in action: Hong Kong’s emerging Cambridge, MA: Blackwell.

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
‘BEST PLACES’ 1929

NEVAREZ, L. (2003) New Money, Nice Town: How urban representations: selling the city in
Capital Works in the New Economy. New difficult times, in: T. HALL and P. HUBBARD
York: Routledge. (Eds) The Entrepreneurial City: Geographies
NEW CENTURY LEXINGTON (1995a) New Century of Politics, Regime, and Representation,
Lexington: A Partnership for Developing a pp. 55–76. New York: Wiley.
Shared Vision of the Lexington Community in SHORT, J. R., BENTON, L. M., LUCE, W. B. and
the 21st Century and a Strategic Plan for WALTON, J. (1993) Reconstructing the image of
Achieving the Vision. Lexington, KY: New an industrial city, Annals of the Association Of
Century Lexington/Lexington Herald-Leader. American Geographers, 83, pp. 207–224.
NEW CENTURY LEXINGTON (1995b) New Century SNOW, D. and BENFORD, R. (1992) Master frames
Lexington Partnership Vision. Lexington, KY: and cycles of protest, in: A. MORRIS and C.
New Century Lexington, Inc. MUELLER (Eds) Frontiers in Social Movement
OLDS, K. (1997) Globalizing Shanghai: the ‘glo- Theory, pp. 133–155. New Haven, CT: Yale
bal intelligence corps’ and the building of University Press.
Pudong, Cities, 4(2), pp. 109–123. SRI International Public Policy Center (1985)
PACIONE, M. (1982) The use of objective and Creating an opportunity economy: enhancing
subjective measures of life quality in human quality of life in a changing economy. Austin,
geography, Progress in Human Geography, 6, TX: Austin Chamber of Commerce.
pp. 495–514. STONE, D. (2000) Non-governmental policy trans-
PACIONE, M. (1990) Urban livability: a review, fer: the strategies of independent policy insti-
Urban Geography, 11, pp. 1–30. tutes, Governance: An International Journal of
PACIONE, M. (2001) Urban Geography: A Global Policy and Administration, 13, pp. 45–70.
Perspective. New York: Routledge. TARROW, S. (1992) Mentalities, political cultures,
PADDISON, R. (1993) City marketing, image re- and collective action frames: constructing
construction and urban regeneration, Urban meanings through action, in: A. MORRIS and C.
Studies, 30, pp. 339–350. MUELLER (Eds) Frontiers in Social Movement
PAPROCKI, R. (2001) What Columbus needs: ten Theory, pp. 174–202. New Haven, CT: Yale
ways to make us a better city, Columbus University Press.
Monthly, October, pp. 32–40. Urban Studies (1999) Special Issue: Discourse
PECK, J. A. (1995) Moving and shaking: business and Urban Change, 36(1).
elites, state localism, and urban privatism, WAITT, G. (1999) Playing games with Sydney:
Progress in Human Geography, 19, pp. 16–46. marketing Sydney for the 2000 Olympics, Ur-
PECK, J. and THEODORE, N. (2001) Exporting ban Studies, 36, pp. 1055–1077.
workfare/importing welfare-to-work: exploring WARD, K. G. (2000a) From rentiers to rantiers:
the politics of Third Way policy transfer, Pol- ‘active entrepreneurs’, structural speculators’,
itical Geography, 20, pp. 427–460. and the politics of marketing the city, Urban
PECK, J. A. and TICKELL, A. (1995) Business goes Studies, 37, pp. 1093–1107.
local: dissecting the “business agenda” in WARD, K. G. (2000b) State licence, local settle-
Manchester, International Journal of Urban ments, and the politics of ‘branding’ the city,
and Regional Research, 19, pp. 79–95. Environment and Planning C, 18, pp. 285–300.
RADAELLI, C. M. (2000) Policy transfer in the WARD, K. G. (2000c) A critique in search of a
European Union: institutional isomorphism as a corpus: re-visiting governance and re-interpret-
source of legitimacy, Governance: An Inter- ing urban politics, Transactions of the Institute
national Journal of Policy and Administration, of British Geographers, NS, 25, pp. 169–185.
13, pp. 25–43. WARD, S. (1998a) Selling Places: The Marketing
RUTHEISER, C. (1996) Imagineering Atlanta: The and Promotion of Towns and Cities, 1850–
Politics of Place in the City of Dreams. New 2000. London: E & FN Spon.
York: Verso. WARD, S. (1998b) Place marketing: a historical
SADLER, D. (1993) Place-marketing, competitive comparison of Britain and North America, in:
places, and the construction of hegemony in T. HALL and P. HUBBARD (Eds) The En-
Britain of the 1980s, in: G. KEARNS and C. trepreneurial City: Geographies of Politics,
PHILO (Eds) Selling Places, pp. 175–192. Ox- Regime, and Representation, pp. 31–54. New
ford: Pergamon Press. York: Wiley.
SHORT, J. R. and KIM, Y. H. (1998) Urban crises/

Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015
Downloaded from usj.sagepub.com at NORTH DAKOTA STATE UNIV LIB on May 23, 2015

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi