Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 6

Egalitarianism among Hunters and Gatherers

Author(s): Elizabeth A. Cashdan


Source: American Anthropologist, New Series, Vol. 82, No. 1 (Mar., 1980), pp. 116-120
Published by: Wiley on behalf of the American Anthropological Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/676134 .
Accessed: 17/05/2014 18:00

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Wiley and American Anthropological Association are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and
extend access to American Anthropologist.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Sat, 17 May 2014 18:00:20 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
REPORTS AND COMMENTS

Egalitarianism Among Hunters from the conditions of hunting and gathering,


and Gatherers and no social sanctions to reinforce sharing and
egalitarianism would be needed. Bushman
ELIZABETH A. CASHDAN groups, however, are in fact typified by strong
and continual socialization against hoarding
Population Studies Center
(i.e., toward economic equality) and against
University of Michigan
displays of arrogance and authority (i.e., to-
ward social and political equality). This has
The literature of anthropology is rich in
been discussed most fully for the !Kung; Lee
theories and discussions on the causes of stratifi-
(1969) has eloquently described how his at-
cation, while egalitarianism has largely been
considered to be simply the baseline upon which tempts to provide a large ox for a Christmas
feast were met with scorn by the !Kung recip-
stratification develops. Material from !Kung
ients, the scorn succeeding as a mechanism that
ethnographers, however, indicates that the
prevents any tendency on the part of a good
egalitarianism found among most Bushman
hunter or provider to become arrogant and
groups is a phenomenon resulting from strin-
think of himself as a "big man." The proper
gent constraints, not simply a natural condition
behavior of a !Kung hunter who has made a big
that represents the absence of stratification.
kill is to speak of it in passing and in a
These constraints arise from high spatial and
deprecating manner (Lee 1969; Draper 1978); if
temporal variability in food supply, together
an individual does not minimize or speak lightly
with a paucity of means to buffer this variabili-
of his own accomplishments, his friends and
ty. The //Gana Bushmen of the northeastern relatives will not hesitate to do it for him. The
Kalahari, on the other hand, have ways of buf-
social pressure toward economic equality and
fering environmental variability that are not
available to most other Bushman groups, and it sharing is equally strong. Both food and ma-
terial goods are continually shared and circu-
appears that these buffers allow a relaxing of
lated (Marshall 1961; Draper 1978; Wiessner
the constraints that make strict egalitarianism a
1977), and if a person is not generous, the
necessity. Among the //Gana one sees a greater
norms of sharing are "reinforced" by continual
tolerance for individual accumulation, and
badgering and dunning for gifts (Draper 1978).
greater (although uninstitutionalized) economic
and political inequality. The following discus- Draper (1978) and Wiessner (1977) argue that
sion considers the implications of those environ- the emphasis on sharing and recirculation is a
mental buffers on the question of egalitarian- kind of "insurance" against local scarcity and en-
ism, using data collected by the author in 1976 vironmental variability among a people who have
and 1977. no other means of buffering the variability.
Speaking of the !Kung, Draper says that because
Bushman Egalitarianism their "mobility renders food storage virtually im-
possible, the !Kung have no insurance against
One obvious reason for the economic egalitar- hard times . . . For the !Kung . . the stored
ianism prevalent among hunter-gatherers in surplus is the group and the more distant groups
general and Bushman groups in particular is scattered in the bush, with the social and eco-
that the mobility associated with hunting and nomic insurance which they provide" (1978:40).
gathering hinders the accumulation of proper- She argues that "under these circumstances, one
ty; material goods cannot readily be carried would expect to find cultural values . . . in favor
from camp to camp, and without a home base, of regular sharing of temporary windfalls"
any substantial accumulation of property is pre- (1978:40). Wiessner (1977) argues similarly that
vented. If that were the sole cause of Bushman the !Kung have no means of coping with envi-
egalitarianism, however, an "equality" based on ronmental variability other than a strategy of
lack of material goods would arise automatically "pooling risk." In Wiessner's discussion this
116

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Sat, 17 May 2014 18:00:20 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
REPORTS AND COMMENTS 117

takes the form of a "storage of social obliga- the rainy season. If the crop has been a good
tions" through the delayed reciprocity of hxaro one, the marotsi provides additional moisture
exchange, but it applies also to all the mecha- for a few months into the dry season as well.
nisms for economic leveling among the !Kung. The resulting sedentism is particularly impor-
Because an individual shares what he has when tant in that it makes it feasible for the //Gana
someone is in need, without regard to the direct to have a permanent home-base settlement at
equality of balanced reciprocity, such a strategy the field location. The //Gana spend about half
protects the !Kung from an uncertain but devas- the year at wild-melon locations, where they
tating loss by substituting a certain but small subsist chiefly on game and bush foods, but they
loss (Wiessner 1977). Mechanisms for leveling use their home base as a storage site throughout
wealth (which include the pervasive socializa- the year for both bush foods (in particular dry
tion against the individual accumulation of game meat and dry berries) and cultivated
property) are therefore a kind of social insur- crops (beans, marotsi, and maize). The practice
ance that protects the !Kung from the extreme of storing meat is particularly striking in view of
variability of their Kalahari environment. its absence in other Bushman groups, where the
rules of meat distribution ensure that all meat
/,'/Gana Subsistence and Economic Buffers gets distributed widely and the hunter himself
keeps only a small portion of his own kill. Al-
The relationship between egalitarianism and though considerable informal sharing of food
lack of economic buffers among the !Kung ap- occurs among the //Gana, even with agricul-
tural food, there appears to be considerably
pears to be typical of most Bushman groups,
but the //Gana are an interesting exception- greater tolerance for accumulation than among
an exception that in fact "proves the rule." The other Bushman groups.
//Gana are a population of about 800 in- The home base also enables the //Gana to
dividuals who live in the northern and eastern store items of wealth and the means to obtain
parts of Botswana's Central Kalahari Game Re- wealth, particularly skins and furs, which are
serve. Their territory overlaps with that of the collected in quantity and traded outside the
G/wi, to the southwest, but the //Gana de- Central Reserve. Some of the items purchased
scribed here comprise 209 individuals who live in exchange for the skins (drums and other
in the northeastern parts of the region. The water containers) are further protection against
//Gana, like the G/wi, must cope with an en- the uncertainties of local rainfall. The wealth
vironment characterized by low and extremely that the //Gana have derived from the sale of
variable rainfall, and by an absence of perma- furs and skin mats has even enabled a few
nent standing water (see Silberbauer 1965, //Gana entrepreneurs to purchase in the last
1972; Tanaka 1969, 1976). Unlike the G/wi, few years a small number of cattle. These ani-
however, the //Gana supplement their basic mals are kept with relatives outside the Central
hunting-and-gathering subsistence strategy with Reserve because there is insufficient water for
a small amount of food production as a measure cattle within the reserve. Because they are kept
of protection against environmental variability outside the region, they have no direct effect on
that is unavailable to other Bushman groups. //Gana subsistence, but they have a potential
Together with beans and some maize, the indirect effect since, like the hard cash that pur-
//Gana cultivate a type of domesticated tsama chased them, they can be converted into food by
melon called marotsi, which is valued for its trading them to Bantu farmers outside the re-
water storage capacity. Because water does not serve.
last in the pans of this region for longer than one Food production among the //Gana also
or two weeks after a heavy rain, cultivation of a takes the form of goat husbandry. Goats, unlike
naturally storable form of moisture (the marotsi cattle, are able to obtain sufficient moisture
melons) is a buffer against local variability in from wild plants (chiefly moisture-bearing
water and is important also in that it permits the melons and roots), and therefore remain with
//Gana a degree of sedentism unavailable to the the //Gana in the Central Reserve throughout
G/wi. Unlike the G/wi, who must move from the year. The potential significance of goat
pan to pan in search of water even during the meat as a buffer in a hunter-gatherer diet is ob-
rainy season, the cultivated marotsi melons pro- vious although the actual impact of goat meat
vide the //Gana with moisture between showers on the //Gana diet is difficult to assess. In "nor-
when the nearby pans become dry and help mal" years of abundant game the number of
them to remain virtually sedentary throughout goats killed solely for food is extremely small,

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Sat, 17 May 2014 18:00:20 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
118 AMERICAN ANTHROPOLOGIST [82, 1980]

even in bands with a large number of goats, but both individuals and bands could also be ex-
goats are also eaten on certain ritual occasions pected.
and are eaten when they die of natural causes. Comparison of animal ownership is par-
During my stay with the //Gana, there was ticularly revealing as a measure of equality, be-
abundant game meat, and goats appeared to be cause, together with the possession of cash, it is
a very minor part of the diet, but it would be probably the best way of storing wealth. The
reasonable to expect that goats, as a "stored" //Gana invest in few possessions other than
form of meat on the hoof, would be an impor- some basic household effects such as blankets,
tant source of meat during years of little game. cups, and pots. The inequality of ownership is
illustrated in Figure 1, which shows ownership
Lack of Egalitarianism Among the //Gana of the most expensive items--donkeys, horses,
drums, and cattle. Since the people who own a
Although this summary of //Gana subsis- large number of any one of these items are also
tence is brief (further discussion is in Cashdan likely to own a large number of the other items,
1977 and in press), it can be seen that agricul- the inequality in total ownership is consider-
ture, storage, and husbandry are important able. Wealth varies not only from individual to
buffers that protect the //Gana to some extent individual but from band to band, as Table I il-
from temporal variability in the supply of water, lustrates. The variance in ownership between
bush foods, and game. It can therefore be ex- bands is particularly obvious with respect to
pected that the //Gana are somewhat less de- goat ownership, with a wealthy band owning
pendent on the insurance provided by the eco- about 150 goats (including kids) and a poor
nomic leveling mechanisms typical of other band owning only about 20. These figures are
Bushman groups, and therefore a greater toler- based on observations of goats kept in kraals
ance of the accumulation of possessions by indi- and camps, and the actual range of ownership is
viduals and a greater disparity in wealth among probably even greater than these figures sug-

10
-J

-70

a 7
6 6-
z-" -,
5 -,
u_
0 4
w3 3-

Z 1-

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11

NUMBER OF WEALTH ITEMS OWNED


Figure 1. Distribution of ownership, by individual. This graph summarizes the number of adults
owning any combination of wealth items (donkeys, horses, cattle, and drums). For example, ten in-
dividuals own only one of these four wealth items; five individuals own some combination totaling
two items, etc.

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Sat, 17 May 2014 18:00:20 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
REPORTS AND COMMENTS 119
TABLE I. DISTRIBUTION OF OWNERSHIP, BY BAND.

Band number: 1 2 3 4 5
# adults in band: 26 23 11 32 13

# donkeys owned 7 8 5 21 5
# donkeys per adult 0.27 0.35 0.45 0.66 0.38

# horses owned 4 2 2 5 0
# horses per adult 0.15 0.09 0.18 0.16 0

# cattle owned 5 0 0 17 0
# cattle per adult 0.19 0 0 0.53 0

# drums owned 9 2 5 8 2
# drums per adult 0.35 0.09 0.45 0.25 0.15

total owned 25 12 12 51 7
total per adult 0.96 0.52 1.09 1.59 0.54

gest, because people with few or no goats care parent, however, that there is a fairly general
for the goats of wealthier individuals. agreement about which individuals have the
Evidence for economic inequality among the prestige and authority to speak for the group.
//Gana can be found also in their compara- Not surprisingly, these prestigious individuals
tively high rate of polygyny. Polygyny is per- were chiefly middle-aged or older men with
mitted in other Bushman groups but is rare. three wives and were among the wealthiest of
Among the IKung, fewer than 5% of married the //Gana. They owned most of the animals
men have more than one wife, although within and drums, and were the sole owners of certain
this population the more sedentary !Kung tend other scarce and valuable items (e.g., the
to be the most polygynous (H. C. Harpending: firearm and the two large steel traps known to be
personal communication). Among the //Gana, in the region). The exceptions to this association
on the other hand, approximately 25% of mar- of wealth with political prestige are younger men
ried men have more than one wife; almost 10% who have recently begun leaving the Central
of married men had 3 wives (4/41), while 15% Reserve for several months at a time in order to
(6/41) had two wives. Marriage among the do wage work in the Johannesburg mines.
//Gana typically involves a bride-price of goats Among the //Gana, then, wealth and prestige
(in 9 marriages, the mode was 10 goats paid as are associated, and a wealthy person is re-
bride-price), so only a wealthy man can afford spected. This contrasts strikingly with other
to have many wives. Bushman groups, where there are constraints
Unfortunately, I have no data on political in- against the accumulation of property by indi-
equality to compare with the data on economic viduals, and a "wealthy" person who does not
inequality, but, impressionistically, the differ- recirculate his possessions is subject to disap-
ence betweeen the //Gana and other Bushman proval and criticism rather than respect.
groups is striking. Before my first meeting with
the //Gana, I had visited the Dobe area and Conclusion
had seen for myself the self-deprecating manner
of the !Kung. The inequality that exists among the //Gana
I was thus totally unprepared for my first en- has an entrepreneurial, "big man" flavor; there
counter with the //Gana, in which several indi- are no formal positions of leadership, and the
viduals each claimed to be the "headman" of "headmen" have no economic redistributive
Molapo (a major //Gana home-base location) role, nor any formal political power. Inequality
and attempted to speak for others, including among the //Gana can therefore be explained
those in other Molapo bands. As such behavior best not as the development of any formal
would indicate, there are no clear-cut positions organization of "ranking" or "stratification,"
of authority among the //Gana; it became ap- but, rather, as the inevitable result of the lifting

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Sat, 17 May 2014 18:00:20 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
120 AMERICAN ANTHROPOLOGIST [82, 1980]

of the constraints that produce strict Central Kalahari Bushmen; a Preliminary


egalitarianism among other Kalahari hunter- Report. In African Studies III. T. Umesao,
gatherers. These constraints arise from a lack of ed. pp. 1-20. Kyoto: Kyoto University
means to buffer environmental variability, and Press.
are a form of social insurance for hunter- 1976 Subsistence Ecology of Central Kala-
gatherers living in unpredictable environments. hari San. In Kalahari Hunter-Gatherers:
This view, then, holds that there is nothing Studies of the !Kung San and their
"natural" (statistically or socially) about the ex- Neighbours. Richard B. Lee and Irven
treme leveling typical of most Bushman groups DeVore, eds. pp. 98-119. Cambridge,
and suggests that the type of inequality found Mass.: Harvard University Press.
among the //Gana can be seen as the inevitable Wiessner, Pauline W.
result of economic buffers that make such level- 1977 Hxaro: A Regional System of Reciproc-
ing mechanisms unnecessary. ity for Reducing Risk among the IKung
San. Ph.D. dissertation, University of
Acknowledgment. This work was supported Michigan.
by NSF Grant SOC 75-02253 to Patricia Draper
and Henry Harpending. Submitted 9 November 1978
Accepted 21 March 1979
References Cited Final revisions received 28 October 1979

Cashdan, Elizabeth A.
1977 Subsistence, Mobility, and Territorial
Organization among the / /Ganakwe of the
Northeastern Central Kalahari Game Re- More on Misconceptions
serve. Report to the Government of about Workload and Birthrates:
Botswana. Gaborone: Ministry of Local Reply to Spenser and Hum
Government and Lands, Botswana.
In press The Effects of Food Production on RICHARD W. THOMPSON
Mobility in the Central Kalahari. In Causes University of Illinois, Urbana
and Consequences of Food Production in
MICHAEL C. ROBBINS
Africa. J. Desmond Clark and Stephen A.
Brandt, eds. Berkeley: University of Cali- University of Missouri, Columbia
fornia Press.
Draper, Patricia Spenser and Hum (AA 79:911-912, 1977) re-
1978 The Learning Environment for Ag- cently challenged a number of our conclusions
gression and Anti-Social Behavior among concerning relations between workload and sea-
the !Kung. In Learning Non-Aggression. sonal variation in birthrates and conceptions in
Ashley Montagu, ed. pp. 31-53. New Mexico and Uganda (Thompson and Robbins
York: Oxford University Press. 1973). Basing their challenge on a reanalysis of
Lee, Richard B. our published data, they suggest that we
1969 Eating Christmas in the Kalahari. overlooked the importance of workload as a de-
Natural History 78 (December): 14-22, terminant of conception rates and imply that
60-63. our claim for a relation between seasonality of
Marshall, Lorna conceptions and climatic variables is unsubstan-
1961 Sharing, Talking and Giving: The Re- tiated. They contend that ". .. workload and
lief of Social Tensions among the IKung migration seem to be the factors requiring most
Bushmen. Africa 31:231-249. emphasis in determining seasonal variation in
Silberbauer, George B. birthrates" (p. 912).
1965 Report to the Government of Bechu- While we welcome this reanalysis of our data
analand on the Bushman Survey. Gabo- in the interest of resolving the issue of seasonali-
rone: Botswana Government Printer. ty in birth and conception, we are somewhat
1972 The G/wi Bushmen. In Hunters and puzzled as to why Spencer and Hum seem to
Gatherers Today. M. G. Bicchieri, ed. pp. think their results contradict our basic conclu-
271-325. New York: Holt, Rinehart and sions. In fact, their reanalysis reinforces our po-
Winston. sition. They seem most disturbed by our state-
Tanaka, Jiro ment that "These findings do not support and
1969 The Ecology and Social Structure of in fact appear to contradict the hypothesis pro-

This content downloaded from 129.219.247.33 on Sat, 17 May 2014 18:00:20 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi