Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 21

J. Serv. Sci.

& Management, 2008,1: 172-192


Published Online August 2008 in SciRes (www.SRPublishing.org/journal/jssm)

The Theory of the Revenue Maximizing Firm


Beniamino Moro

Department of Economics, University of Cagliari, Viale Sant’Ignazio 17 - 09123 Cagliari (Italy)


Email: moro@unica.it

ABSTRACT
An endogenous growth model of the revenue maximizing firm is here presented. It is demonstrated that, in a static
analysis, a revenue maximizing firm in equilibrium equates the average product of labor to the wage rate. In a dynamic
analysis, the maximization rule becomes the balance between the rate of marginal substitution - between labor and
capital - and the ratio of the wage rate over the discount rate. When the firm satisfies this rule, it grows endogenously
at the rate of return on capital. The firm may also have multiple stationary equilibria, which are very similar to the
static equilibrium.
JEL classification: D21, O41.
Keywords: firm, theory of the firm, revenue maximization, endogenous growth
1. Revenue Maximization Versus Profit
Maximization and the Theory of the Firm
The original idea of a firm that maximizes revenue in- More recently, the revenue-maximization dominance
stead of profit was put forward by Baumol [2, 3], and hypothesis has been re-proposed by Uekusa-Caves [34],
further investigated during the sixties by Cyert-March Komiya [25, 26], Blinder [4, 5] and Tabeta-Wang [32,
[12], Galbraith [19], Winter [39] and Williamson [36]. 33]. In all these papers it is argued that the separation of
Autonomously, a similar idea was also investigated by ownership and control in public companies causes a de-
Rothbard [31], a precursor of the Austrian theory of the viation of management from the pure profit maximization
firm.1 Nonetheless, the main stream economic thought, as principle and provides a considerable degree of decision-
Cyert-Hedrick [11] pointed out in their review article, making autonomy for managers. In fact, in an oligopolis-
remains characterized by an ideal market with firms for tic market, each firm may set up its own goal, and the
which profit maximization is the single determinant of choice to maximize revenue or profit depends on the real
behavior. 2 Indeed, the relevance of pure profit- interests of the managers, and is also influenced by the
maximization is not so obvious for modern corporations corporate culture and institutional arrangements of the
when ownership and control of the firm are separated and country where the firm operates. According to Kagono et
there are no dominant owners that merely maximize their al. [23], the principal objectives of Japanese firms are
profits [27]. growth and market-share gaining, which imply that they
are revenue maximizers, while US corporations empha-
1 size more on short run investment returns and capital
See Anderson [1], and for the Austrian school see Foss [15, 18], and
Witt [41].
gains, which means that they are profit maximizers.3 In
2
In fact, during the ‘30s and ‘40s, a great dispute was due to the “Old
Marginalist Debate” which questioned the relevance of the profit-
3
maximization assumption in neoclassical theory of the firm. In the ‘70s, Blinder [5] builds up a model to demonstrate that revenue-maximizers
the marginalist debate changed tone with the emergence of the theories like Japanese firms have an advantage when competing with profit-
of agency costs, property rights, and transactions costs theories of the maximizers. Particularly, he points out that the revenue-maximizer is
firm. These gave rise to the “New Institutionalist” field of research, likely to drive its profit-maximizers rivals out of business if either aver-
where the object of study changed from how to reconcile firm behavior age costs are declining or learning is a positive function of cumulative
with marginalist principles to how to reconcile firm structure with mar- output. Tabeta-Wang [33] find the following four reasons to explain
ginalist principles. Following the seminal work by Coase [8], papers why Japanese firms are in general able to act like revenue-maximizers.
belonging to the Institutionalist debate can be divided in the transactions First of all, in Japan, expansion in firm-size is a necessary condition to
costs economics [24, 37, 38], and the contractual field of research [6, 13, maintain the life-time employment system and internal promotion. Sec-
21, 22]. The old marginalist debate re-emerged in the ‘80s with the ondly, a faster growth of the firm helps hiring new young employees,
evolutionary theory of the firm by Nelson-Winter [30], Winter [40], and and keeping low the average age of the work force helps to maintain low
Foss [14]. Finally and more recently, we also have a “Knowledge- labor costs. Thirdly, Japanese firms pursue the growth-oriented strategy
based” theory of the firm [16, 17, 20], and a “Resource-based” theory [9, also because there is little external pressure for short-term earnings, and
10]. tax rates on reinvested earnings are lower than tax rates on dividends.

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


The Theory of the Revenue Maximizing Firm 173

fact, as Anderson [1] points out, the profit maximizing where the rate of growth is obtained from the solution of
versus the revenue maximizing strategy of the firm still a system of differential equations which fully describes
stays as an open question, the answer to which only time the dynamics of the model. Also in this section, the prob-
will tell. lem is first analyzed without taking into account any
minimum acceptable return on capital constraint (sections
A parallel problem to this dispute is how to formalize
3.1-3.4) and then with such a constraint (section 3.5). Our
the firm behavior in the two cases. At this regard, the
main conclusion is that, in a dynamic context, the equilib-
mainstream microeconomic analysis has been mainly
rium of a revenue maximizing firm requires not only that
oriented to the profit maximization strategy, while very
the marginal rate of substitution between labor and capital
little attention has been devoted to the revenue maximiz-
to be equal to the shadow value of the capital-labor ratio,
ing case. Apart from the static analysis during the sixties,
but that this value also balances the ratio of the wage rate
the latter field of research is very poor. After the seminal
over the discount rate.
work by Leland [28], Van Hilton-Kort-Van Loon [35]
and Chiang [7] put the problem in the contest of the op- Further, if we introduce a minimum acceptable return
timal control theory and demonstrated that a revenue on capital constraint, this must be added to the discount
maximizing firm subject to a minimum profitability con- rate when determining the equilibrium equality with the
straint is in equilibrium at a smaller capital-labor ratio rate of marginal substitution between labor and capital.
than a profit maximizing one. This result is also obtained As a consequence, a change of the minimum acceptable
here. Anyway, Leland’s model suffers of some limitations return on capital rate has the same effect as a variation of
- e.g. he considers constant the share of profits used to the discount rate. Finally, section 4 is devoted to the con-
self-financing the accumulation of capital - which pre- cluding remarks.
clude him to develop a complete dynamic model which
fully describes the dynamics of a revenue maximizing 2. The Static Analysis of the Firm Behavior
firm. The aim of this paper is to fill the gap in this field of 2.1. The Equilibrium Conditions Without a
research, presenting a complete endogenous growth
Minimum Acceptable Return on Capital Con-
model of a revenue maximizing firm.
straint
The paper is organized as follows. In section 2, the
problem of a revenue maximizing firm versus the classi- We make the following neoclassical assumptions on the
cal problem of profit maximization is analyzed from a firm production function Q=Q(K, L), where K is capital
static point of view. First of all, the analysis is made and L is labor:
without taking into account a minimum acceptable return a) Q is linear homogenous and strictly quasi-concave,
on capital constraint (section 2.1) and then with such a which implies that Q=Q(K, L)=Lf(k), where f(k)=Q(K/L,
constraint (section 2.2). In section 2.3, the analysis is 1) and k=K/L; f(0)=0 and lim f ( k ) = ∞ ;
k →∞
generalized into a rate of profit maximization problem
b) the marginal productivity of capital QK = f '(k ) has
and into a revenue per unit of capital maximization prob-
lem, respectively. We obtain the fundamental rule fol- lim f ' (k ) = ∞ and lim f ' (k ) = 0 ;
k →0 k →∞
lowed by a static revenue maximizing firm, according to
which the firm equates the average product of labor to the c) the marginal productivity of labor QL = f (k ) − kf ' (k )
wage rate. The same rule also applies in a dynamic con- has lim = 0 and lim = ∞.
k →0 k →∞
text.
In section 3, we use the optimal control theory to de- We also assume that the price of the firm’s output is
scribe the dynamics of a revenue maximizing firm. With normalized to one, so that both the nominal and the real
respect to Leland’s model, this paper differs on the fol- wage rate can be indicated by w. First of all, we demon-
lowing two assumptions: a) we suppose that the firm’s strate that if the firm program is:
accumulation of capital is limited to the non distributed Maximize [Q( K , L) − wL ] (1)
profits and b) we also suppose that the share of the rein-
vested profits is endogenously determined by the firm, subject to Q(K, L) ≥ 0
while in Leland’s model this is a constant. We also dem- then there are no limits to the expansion of capital, which
onstrate that only some of the possible dynamic equilibria means that no finite capital-labor ratio exists in equilib-
(stationary equilibria) correspond to those discussed in rium. To see this, let us form the Lagrangian function:
the static analysis. Anyway, it is also demonstrated that
an endogenous growth equilibrium of the firm does exist, ℑ = Q ( K , L) − wL + λQ (2)

Lastly, there is some possibility that administrative guidance and con-


where λ is a Lagrangian multiplier. The Kuhn-Tucker
trols lead Japanese firms to act like revenue-maximizers. At this regard, conditions state that in equilibrium we have:
Nakamura [29] clamed that administrative guidance and controls play a ∂ℑ
role as a “shelter from the storm” once the firm grows beyond the limits = QK + λQK = 0 → (1 + λ )QK = 0 (3)
∂K
of a market accepted profitability.

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


174 Beniamino Moro

∂ℑ market price exists for capital, the firm takes advantage of


= QL − w + λQL = 0 → (1 + λ )QL = w (4)
∂L accumulating capital without limits. So, the only way to
avoid that is to fix the level of capital K 0 . If we do that,
∂ℑ
= Q ≥ 0, λ ≥ 0, λQ = 0 (5) the problem becomes definite, both for the profit maxi-
∂λ mizing firm and for the revenue maximizing one.
Clearly we see that if Q>0, which means that the firm
For the profit maximizing firm, the Lagrangian func-
produces something, from (5) we have λ=0, so as equa-
tion is maximized only with respect to the labor factor,
tion (3) reduces to QK = 0 and equation (4) to QL = w .
while capital stays constant. In this case, from equation
Thus, while equation (4) states a limit to the decreasing of (4), when Q>0 and λ =0, we have:
the marginal productivity of labor, which cannot fall un-
der the level of the real wage rate, from equation (3) it QL = f (k ) − kf ' (k ) = w (11)
follows that no limits to capital accumulation exist in this
problem. Given that QK = f ' (k ) → 0 for k → ∞ and which is the well known rule of the profit maximizing
firm that equates the marginal productivity of labor to the
QL = f ( k ) − kf ' ( k ) → ∞ for k → ∞ , it follows that no fi- real wage rate. In the same way, for the revenue maximiz-
nite k exists which maximizes the profit of the firm. ing firm, if f(k)>w, so as from (10) we have λ =0, then
from (9) we obtain QL = 0 , which implies, according to
Under the same conditions, no equilibrium exists for
the revenue maximizing firm too. To see this, let the firm assumption c), that k = 0. In this case, the firm does not
maximization program be: produce anything. On the contrary, if the firm does pro-
duce something, it must be:
Maximize Q (K, L) (6)
Q
subject to Q( K , L) − wL ≥ 0 = f (k ) = w (12)
L
where Q − wL ≥ 0 can be interpreted as the non bank- Therefore, we can conclude that the rule for a profit
ruptcy constraint. The Lagrangian of this problem takes maximizing firm is given by equation (11), and the capi-
the form: ∧
tal-labor ratio that satisfies it can be indicated with k , so
ℑ = Q ( K , L) + λ [Q ( K , L) − wL ] (7) that we can write:
from which we derive the following Kuhn-Tucker condi- ∧ ∧ ∧
tions: f ( k ) − k f '( k ) = w (13)

∂ℑ whereas the rule for a revenue maximizing firm is given


= QK + λQK = 0 → (1 + λ )QK = 0 (8)
∂K by equation (12) and the capital-labor ratio that satisfies
∂ℑ
= QL + λQL − λw = 0 → QL + λ (QL − w) = 0 (9) Q
= f (k )
∂L f(k) L
∂ℑ
= Q − wL ≥ 0, λ ≥ 0, λ (Q − wL ) = 0

(10) C
∂λ f( k )
QL = f (k ) − kf ' (k )
If the non bankruptcy constraint is not binding, that is A
if Q − wL >0, which implies f(k)>w, then from (10) we f(kw)=w
B
deduce that λ =0. In this case, from equation (8) we have
QK = 0 and from equation (9) we have QL = 0 . These
conditions are not consistent, because the former is satis-
fied for k→ ∞ , while the latter for k→0. On the contrary,
if the non bankruptcy constraint is binding, that is if
Q=wL, which implies f(k)=w, then from (10) we deduce
that λ >0. In this case, from equation (8) we again have
QK = 0, while from equation (9) we obtain
λ = QL / (w − QL ) . But, once again, the capital-labor ratio
k = k w for which the condition f (k w ) = w is satisfied is ∧
0 k
not an equilibrium ratio, because we have QK = f (k w ) >0,
kw k

while equation (8) requires that QK → 0 . Figure 1. The average productivity of labor function f(k)
and the marginal productivity of labor function f(k)-
This inconsistency depends on the fact that, if no rental kf’(k) with respect to the capital-labor ratio k

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


The Theory of the Revenue Maximizing Firm 175

it can be indicated with kw, so that we have: maximization program:


f (k w ) = w (14) Maximize Q(K0, L) (20)
Both these conditions are shown in figure 1, where the subject to Q(K0,L) − wL ≥ r0 K 0 .
functions f(k) and QL = f (k ) − kf ' (k ) are depicted. Since
The Lagrangian of this problem is:
f’(k)>0, we deduce that QL always stays below f(k). Once
the real wage rate w and the level of capital K 0 are given, ℑ = Q ( K 0 , L) + λ [Q ( K 0 , L) − wL − r0 K 0 ] (21)
the profit maximizing firm is in equilibrium at the point B, from which we derive the following Kuhn-Tucker condi-
∧ ∧ ∧
'
where f (k ) − k f (k ) = w . In this point, the output per tions:
∧ ∂ℑ
worker is f ( k ) , so the profit per worker is given by the = QL + λ (QL − w) = 0 (22)
∂L
difference:
∂ℑ
∧ ∧ ∧ = (Q − wL − r0 K 0 ) ≥ 0, λ ≥ 0, λ (Q − wL − r0 K 0 ) = 0 (23)
f (k ) − w = k f (k ) '
(15) ∂λ

If we indicate with r the rate of profit or the rate of net If the constraint is not binding, that is if
return on capital, so that: Q − wL − r0 K 0 >0, from (23) we have λ = 0 and from
equation (22) we deduce that QL = 0, hence the firm does
Q − wL f (k ) − w
r= = (16) not produce anything. If on the contrary the firm does
K k
produce something, the constraint is binding, so that
then, from equation (15) we deduce that the maximum Q − wL − r0 K 0 = 0 and λ >0. In this case, from equation

rate of profit r is given by: (22) we have:

∧ f (k ) − w ∧ QL
r= = f ' (k ) (17) λ= (24)
∧ w − QL
k
∧ while, from the condition Q − wL − r0 K 0 = 0 , we have:
which says that r is equal to the marginal productivity of
∧ Q − wL
capital corresponding to the optimal capital-labor ratio k . = r0 (25)
K0
A revenue maximizing firm is in equilibrium at point A,
where the average productivity of labor equals the real which says that the rate of return on capital must be equal
wage rate, that is f ( k w ) = w . At this point the profit rate to the minimum acceptable rate. This condition can be put
is zero, as we have: in the form:
f (kw ) − w f ( k ) − kr0 = w (26)
rw = =0 (18)
kw
If we consider that the range of r0 is:
Each level of w corresponds to a minimum capital-
labor ratio k w for which we have a null rate of profit. 0 ≤ r0 ≤ f ' ( k ) (27)
Given the amount of capital, the firm employs more labor
it follows that the curve f (k ) − kr0 has an intermediate
if it maximizes revenue than if it maximizes profits; and
this explains why the equilibrium ratio k w is smaller than mapping between f(k) and f (k ) − kf '(k ) , as it is depicted
∧ in figure 2(a). Given the level of capital K 0 , the real
the profit maximizing one k . If w increases, both ratios

wage rate w and the minimum acceptable return on capi-
k w and k increase, and their difference increases too. tal r0 , the equilibrium point of a revenue maximizing
firm is no more A, but A’, where equation (26) is satisfied.
2.2. The Equilibrium Conditions with a Mini- Let k0 = K 0 /L0 be the capital-labor ratio which satisfies
mum Acceptable Return on Capital Constraint equation (26), in point A’ the output per worker of the
If we introduce a minimum acceptable return on capital firm is f (k0 ) . Clearly, at this point the rate of return on
constraint of the form: capital is:
f ( k0 ) − w
Q − wL f (k ) − w r0 = (28)
= ≥ r0 (19) k0
K0 k

then a revenue maximizing firm solves the following where k w ≤ k0 ≤ k . When r0 varies between zero and

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


176 Beniamino Moro

f ' (k ) , the equilibrium point A’ ranges between A and B, f (k ) − w


r (k ) = (29)
while the equilibrium capital-labor ratio ranges between k
∧ For each level of w and K 0 , the rate of profit varies as
k w and k . In figure 2(b), both the revenue-capital ratio
follows. In the interval 0≤ k< k w , it is negative and in-
Q / K 0 (which is equal to the output-capital ratio, because
creases with respect to k, ranging from −∞ to zero. In the
P=1) and the rate of profit r are depicted. The rate of ∧
profit varies with respect to k according to the rule: interval k w ≤ k ≤ k , it is positive and increasing, and

f (k )

C f (k )

f (k )

f ( k0 ) C'
f ( k ) − kr0
A A' f ( k ) − kf '(k )
f (k w ) = w
B

(a)

0
k

Q (b)
, r
K0

f (k w ) / k w

f (k0 ) / k0

∧ Q / K 0 = f (k ) / k
r
r0
r (k )

0 ∧
kw k0 k k

Figure 2. The mapping of the revenue-capital ratio (output-capital ratio) Q/K0 and the rate of profit r(k) with respect
to k

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


The Theory of the Revenue Maximizing Firm 177

∧ mum acceptable return on capital constraint of the form r


varies between zero and its maximum value r given by:

≥ r0, then the equilibrium point is A’ in figure 2(a), where
∧ f (k ) − w f (k ) − kr0 = w. Given the level of capital K 0 , the employ-
r= ∧
(30)

k ment in point A’ is equal to L0 for which L ≤ L0≤ Lw and
∧ k0= K0/L0. Therefore, in this point equation (28) is veri-
Finally, in the interval k < k< ∞ , it is positive and de-
fied.
creasing, and tends asymptotically to zero for k→ ∞ .

From figure 2(b), we see that for k= k w the rate of pro- Thus, if r0 increases from zero to r , the equilibrium
∧ ∧ point A’ moves along the segment AB, going away from
fit r is zero, for k= k it takes the maximum value r , while
point A to point B. Point A’ is as far from point A as
for k= k0 it equals r0 . In figure 2(b), the revenue-capital higher the minimum acceptable return on capital r0 is.
ratio or output-capital ratio Q K 0 = f (k ) / k is also depicted. An optimal level of the capital-labor ratio k0 for which
Given the level of capital K 0 , this increases with respect ∧
k w ≤ k0 ≤ k corresponds to each predetermined level of
to L, so it decreases with respect to the capital-labor ratio
r0 . Given the level of capital K0, this also corresponds to
k. Using de L’Hôpital’s rule we have:

d an employment level L0 for which L ≤ L0≤ Lw, where Lw
f (k ) is the maximum level of employment compatible with the
f (k )
lim = lim dk = lim f ' (k ) = ∞ (31) ∧
k →0 k k →0 d k →0
k respect to the non bankruptcy constraint and L is the
dk
level of employment that maximizes the rate of profit.
f (k ) Introducing a minimum acceptable rate of return on capi-
lim = lim f ' (k ) = 0 (32) tal amounts to introduce a limit to the expansion of the
k →∞ k k →∞
production and the employment of the firm.
so the ratio f(k)/k ranges between infinity and zero for 0<
k< ∞ . Furthermore, we can check if the sign of its deriva- 2.3. A Generalization of the Static Theory of a
tive is negative: Revenue Maximizing Firm
d f (k ) Once we have proven that, given the absolute value of
= − [ f (k ) − kf '(k )] k 2 < 0 (33) capital K 0 , the profit maximization of a firm amounts to
dk k
the maximization of the rate of profit (or the rate of return
But for k< k w the ratio Q K 0 = f (k ) / k does not make on capital), while the maximization of the revenue
sense, because it does not respect the non bankruptcy amounts to the maximization of the revenue (or output)
constraint. On the contrary, for k≥ k w , this ratio is eco- per unit of capital, these results can be generalized for
nomically meaningful and decreases with k, tending as- each given level of capital K 0 . So, the equilibrium condi-
ymptotically to zero as k → ∞ . Hence, its maximal eco- tions, both for a profit or for a revenue maximizing firm,
nomically meaningful value Qw / K 0 = f (k w ) / kw corre- become independent from the absolute value of capital
sponds to a capital-labor ratio equal to k w . and labor employed in the production process. They only
depend on the capital-labor ratio. Therefore, if we define:
Therefore, once the level of capital K0 is given, if the
Q − wL f (k ) − w
objective function of the firm is to maximize profits, this r= = (34)
K k
corresponds to maximize the rate of profit. In this case,

the optimal quantity of labor to be employed is L for as the rate of profit (or the rate of net return on capital),
∧ ∧ then the program of a profit maximizing firm becomes:
which k = K 0 / L and the equilibrium point is B in figure
Q − wL
2(a). On the contrary, if the objective function of the firm Maximize (35)
K
is to maximize revenue, this corresponds to maximize the
revenue or output per unit of capital. In this case, the op- Q

subject to ≥0
K
timal quantity of labor to be employed is Lw > L for which
∧ The Lagrangian of this problem takes the form:
k w = K 0 /Lw and k w < k . Then, the equilibrium point is A
Q − wL Q
in figure 2(a), which corresponds to the maximum level ℑ= +λ (36)
K K
of employment compatible with the respect of the non
bankruptcy constraint. from which the following Khun-Tucker conditions can be
derived:
If the revenue maximizing firm must respect a mini-

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


178 Beniamino Moro

∂ ℑ KQK − (Q − wL) λKQK − λQ


= + =0 (37) ing, that is if Q−wL>0, then from (48) we deduce λ =0. In
∂K K2 K2 this case, from equation (50) we have QL =0, which im-
∂ ℑ QL − w λQL plies:
= + =0 (38)
∂L K K QL = f ( k ) − kf '(k ) =0 (51)
∂ℑ Q Q or:
= ≥ 0, λ ≥ 0, λ = 0 (39)
∂λ K K
f(k)= kf ' (k ) (52)
Equations (37) and (38) can also be stated in the form:
This last equation is satisfied only for k=0, that is,
(1+ λ ) [Q − KQK ] = wL (40)
when the firm does not produce anything. Analogously,
for λ =0, also equation (49) leads to the same conclusion.
(1+ λ ) QL =w (41) In fact, if λ =0, then Q=K QK , and dividing by L we ob-
If the firm produces, then Q/K>0 and from equation tain (52). It follows that, if the firm produces, the non
(39) we deduce that λ=0, thus equations (40) and (41) bankruptcy constraint must be binding, which implies:
take the form: Q−wL=0 → f(k)=w (53)
Q−K QK = wL → f (k ) − kf ' (k ) = w (42) In this case, from (48) we deduce that λ >0 and the
value of λ can be determined either from (49) or (50).
QL = f ( k ) − kf ' (k ) = w (43) Using the latter, we have:

These two equations state the same maximization rule, (1+ λ )[ f (k ) − kf ' (k ) ]= λ f(k) (54)
corresponding to the equality of the marginal productivity
The same result is obtained from (49) dividing by L.
of labor to the real wage rate. This again re-asserts that
From (54) we have:
the equilibrium capital-labor ratio for a profit maximizing

firm is k . f ( k ) − kf ' ( k ) QL
λ= '
= (55)
kf (k ) kQK
Likewise, the program of a revenue maximizing firm
becomes: which defines the equilibrium value of λ . Equation (55)
can also be put in the form:
Q
Maximize (44)
K QL
MRS L / K = = λk (56)
QK
Q − wL
subject to ≥0
K where MRS L / K stays for the marginal rate of substitution
where the firm respects a non bankruptcy constraint. To between labor and capital. If we interpret λ as the shadow
solve this problem, let us form the Lagrangian function: price of capital, then (56) means that in equilibrium the
Q λ (Q − wL ) marginal rate of substitution must equal the shadow value
ℑ= + (45)
K K of per capita capital. As we shall see later, this rule also
applies in a dynamic analysis. Because equations (53) and
from which the following Kuhn-Tucker conditions can be (56) are satisfied for k= k w , it is confirmed that the equi-
derived:
librium capital-labor ratio for a revenue maximizing firm
∂ ℑ KQK − Q λ [KQK − (Q − wL)] is k w , that is the value of k which guaranties the equality
= + =0 (46)
∂K K2 K2 between the average productivity of labor and the real
wage rate.
∂ ℑ QL λ (QL − w)
= + =0 (47)
∂L K K Finally, if the firm must satisfy a minimum return on
capital constraint, the maximization program is as follows:
∂ ℑ Q − wL λ (Q − wL)
= ≥ 0, λ ≥ 0, =0 (48) Maximize
Q
(57)
∂λ K K K
Equations (46) and (47) can be put in the form: Q − wL
subject to ≥ r0
K
(1+ λ ) (Q−K QK )= λwL (49)
where r0 is the minimum acceptable rate of return on
(1+ λ ) QL = λ w (50) capital. The Lagrangian of this problem is:

respectively. If the non bankruptcy constraint is not bind- Q ⎡ Q − wL ⎤


ℑ= + λ⎢ − r0 ⎥ (58)
K ⎣ K ⎦

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


The Theory of the Revenue Maximizing Firm 179

from which we derive the following Kuhn-Tucker condi- capital-labor ratio for a revenue maximizing firm, when a
tions: minimum rate of return on capital constraint must be sat-
isfied, is k= k0 . To this value of k we have the balance
∂ ℑ KQK − Q ⎡ KQK − (Q − wL) ⎤
= + λ⎢ ⎥=0 (59) between the average productivity of labor, net of the
∂K K2 ⎣ K2 ⎦
minimum acceptable rate of return on capital, and the real
∂ ℑ QL λ (QL − w) wage rate. This condition is also obtained in the follow-
= + =0 (60) ing dynamic analysis.
∂L K K

∂ ℑ Q − wL ⎡ Q − wL ⎤
3. The Dynamic Analysis of the Revenue
= − r0 ≥ 0, λ ≥ 0, λ ⎢ − r0 ⎥ = 0 (61) Maximizing Firm
∂λ K ⎣ K ⎦

Given that equations (59) and (60) are similar, respec- 3.1. The Equilibrium Conditions without a
tively, to equations (46) and (47), they can again be put in Minimum Acceptable Return on Capital Con-
the form of equations (49) and (50). From (61) we can straint
conclude that, if the minimum rate of return on capital In the dynamic analysis, K, L and Q are all functions of
constraint is not binding, then λ =0. In this case, equa- time t. Therefore, the instant dynamic production function
tions (51) and (52) follow, and k=0. On the contrary, if is
the firm does produce, the minimum rate of return on
capital constraint must be binding. Therefore, it must be: ⎡ ⎤
Q = Q ⎢ K (t ), L(t )⎥ (67)
⎣ ⎦
Q − wL f ( k ) − w
r0 = = (62) where Q has the same properties as in a)-c) of section 2.1.
K k
Let P be the price of the output, so the instant revenue is
or PQ. The objective function of a revenue maximizing firm
then is the present value (PV) of all future revenues, that
f (k ) − kr0 = w (63) is
and λ is positive. In this case, either from (49) or (50), ∞ ⎡ ⎤
we conclude that
PV =

0
PQ ⎢ K (t ), L(t )⎥ e −ρt dt
⎣ ⎦
(68)

(1+ λ )[ f (k ) − kf ' (k ) ]= λ [ f (k)−kr0] (64) where ρ is the instantaneous discount rate.


and The dynamics of capital accumulation can be defined
' as follows:
f (k ) − kf (k ) QL
λ= = (65)
k (QK − r0 ) K& = α {PQ[K (t ), L(t )] − WL}
'
k[ f (k ) − r0 ] (69)

which is positive for k < k , as the difference where K& = dK/dt is the net instantaneous investment
(there is no depreciation of capital), while W is the nomi-
f '(k ) − r0 = QK − r0 is also positive.
nal wage rate. Finally, 0≤ α ≤1 is the share of instantane-
Equation (65) can be put in the form: ous profits the firm decides to accumulate.
QL Normalizing P=1 so as w=W/P=W indicates both the
NMRS L / K (r0 ) = = λk (66) real and the nominal wage rate, equation (69) must satisfy
QK − r0
the condition:
which states the equilibrium condition for a revenue
maximizing firm in the case that a minimum rate of return K& = α (Q−wL) ≥0 (70)
on capital constraint must be satisfied. In this case, the which is both the law of motion of capital and the instan-
equilibrium rule becomes the equality of the net marginal taneous non bankruptcy constraint.
rate of substitution between labor and capital ( NMRS L / K ),
which is a function of r0 , to the shadow value of per cap- Starting from an initial level of capital K 0 , the pro-
ita capital λ k. Now, the NMRS L / K is defined as the ratio gram of the revenue maximizing firm is
of the marginal productivity of labor over the marginal ∞

productivity of capital net of the minimum acceptable rate


Maximize
∫ 0
Q ( K ,L)e − ρt dt (71)
of return r0 .
subject to K& = α (Q-wL) ≥0, 0≤ α ≤1, and K(0)= K 0 ,
Since equations (63) and (66), as is shown in figure 2,
are satisfied for k= k0 , it is confirmed that the equilibrium K ∞ free, K 0 , w given.

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


180 Beniamino Moro

In this problem, K is the state variable while L is a con- in the employment of the labor factor, which corresponds
trol variable. What about α , which is the share of instan- to condition (9) and conditions (22) or (24) from a static
taneous profits the firm decides to accumulate?4 In fact, point of view. This rule requires that the firm must bal-
we can suppose that the firm can decide in each instant of ance the ratio of the marginal productivity of labor over
time to accelerate the speed of capital accumulation by the wage rate, net of the same marginal productivity of
increasing the value of α . We have the maximum speed labor, to the shadow price of capital along the entire time
if α =1, while there is no capital accumulation if α =0. In path of the costate variable λ .
the latter case, all profits are distributed to the stockhold- Condition (74) again represents the dynamics of capital,
ers. Hence, it is obvious to consider α as a second con- while condition (75) is the equation of motion of the co-
trol variable of the problem. state variable λ . Equations (74) and (75) together form
To solve the program (71), let us indicate with H C the the Hamiltonian or canonical system.
current value Hamiltonian: Finally, equations (76) are the transversality conditions.
The first one requires the limit of the present-value Ham-
H C = Q ( K , L) + λα (Q − wL) (72) iltonian vanishes as t→ ∞ . The second one requires the
shadow price of capital in discounted value vanishes as
where λ is a dynamic Lagrangian multiplier. Further-
more, as the costate variable is strictly adherent to the t→ ∞ . Since the term e − ρt →0 as t→ ∞ , both these trans-
state variable K, λ can also be interpreted as the shadow versality conditions are satisfied for finite values of HC ≠0,
price of capital. and λ ≠0. This will be demonstrated in section 3.4.

Because the Hamiltonian is linear with respect to α , the Condition (74), dividing by L and remembering that
maximization rule ∂ H C / ∂ α = 0 does not apply in this α =1, can be put in the form:
case. Instead, we have a maximum in one of the extreme K&
values of the α interval [0, 1]. Moreover, since λ is = f (k ) − w (78)
L
positive, as we will see later, H C is maximized for α =1
Since from the definition of k=K/L we have K=kL, and
if Q−wL>0, while, for Q−wL=0, α is indeterminate.
K& = k& L+k L& , dividing by L and substituting we obtain:
Furthermore, since Q is a strictly quasi-concave function,
the Hamiltonian H C is a concave function of K and L. So, K& & L&
the following conditions of the maximum principle are = k + k = f (k ) − w (79)
L L
necessary and sufficient for the solution of the program
(71): and finally:

∂ HC L&
= QL + λα (QL − w) = 0 (73) k& = f (k ) − w − k (80)
∂L L
Given the real wage rate w, equation (80) describes the
∂ HC
K& = = α (Q − wL ) (74) dynamics of the capital-labor ratio as a function of the
∂λ
rate of growth of employment L/ & L . Analogously, from

∂ HC condition (75), setting α =1, we obtain:


λ& = − + ρλ = −QK − λαQK + ρλ (75)
∂K λ& = λ [ ρ − f '(k )] − f '(k ) (81)

lim H C e − ρt = 0, lim λe − ρt = 0 (76) which describes the dynamics of λ , given ρ , as a func-


t →∞ t →∞
tion of the capital-labor ratio.
Condition (73) guarantees the employment of the labor Conditions (77), (80) and (81), taken together, form a
factor is optimized along the time path L(t). If the firm system of three equations, two of which are differential
does make profits, Q−wL>0 and α =1, and from condi-
tion (73) we obtain: equations, in three unknowns, given by k, λ and L&/ L .
These equations fully describe the dynamics of a revenue
QL f (k ) − kf ' (k ) maximizing firm. Given the real wage rate w and the dis-
λ= = (77)
w − Q L w − [ f (k ) − kf ' (k )] count rate ρ , we can find a steady state equilibrium for
k& = λ& = 0 . This equilibrium is characterized by a time
This is the dynamic optimization rule the firm follows
constant value of the triple (k, λ , L&/ L ). Furthermore, our
system can be decomposed into two sub-systems: the first
4
In Leland’s model [28], α is an exogenous parameter on which the one made up by equations (77) and (81), where the vari-
firm exerts no influence. This assumption is not realistic and, at the same & L does not appear, and the second one corre-
able L/
time, it contributes to limit Leland’s analysis.

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


The Theory of the Revenue Maximizing Firm 181

sponding to equation (80) alone, which is the only equa- However, equation (77) is not economically meaning-
tion where the employment rate of growth L&/ L is pre- ful for 0≤ k< k w , because in this range the non bankruptcy
sent. So, the first subsystem made up by equations (77) constraint is not satisfied. Anyway, for k = k w , the firm
and (81) can be solved autonomously, and its solution
does not make profits, so we have Q−wL=0 and α is
gives, for λ& = 0, the steady state values of k and λ . Sub- indeterminate in the open range α ∈[0, 1) . In this case,
stituting the equilibrium value of k in equation (80) and from (73) we obtain:
setting k& = 0, the second subsystem yields the equilib-
& L. QL f (k w ) − k w f ' (k w )
rium growth rate of employment L/ λ= = (84)
α [ w − Q L ] α [ w − f (k w ) + k w f ' (k w )]
Now, let us concentrate, first of all, on the subsystem
made up by equations (77) and (81), which can be de- where λ is defined with respect to α for k = k w . The
picted in a phase diagram on the plane k, λ . To construct
mapping of the function Gw(k, λ) = 0 is depicted in figure 3.
this, we must pay attention to equation (77). Like in the
∧ The part of this function that has an economic meaning
static analysis, let us indicate with k the capital-labor ∧
ratio which satisfies the equality between the marginal belongs to the range [ k w , k ); for k = k w , the function
productivity of labor and the real wage rate, that is Gw (k , λ ) = 0 becomes a truncated vertical line, where the
∧ ∧ ∧
QL = f ( k ) − k f ' ( k ) =w; and let us indicate with k w the
truncation point A is given by:
capital-labor ratio which satisfies the equality between the f (k ) − kf '(k )
λ A = lim (85)
average productivity of labor and the real wage rate, that k →k w w − [ f (k ) − kf ' ( k )]
is f ( k w ) = w . From equation (77), since QL →0 as k→0,
whereas the ratio QL /(w− QL) → ∞ as (w− QL) →0 and where the limit is calculated as k→ k w from the right. For
∧ ∧
k→ k , we deduce that λ is an increasing function of k, k w <k< k , instead, the curve Gw (k , λ ) = 0 is defined by
∧ the expression (77).
which goes from zero to infinity as k goes from zero to k .
Furthermore, we can find that the sign of the derivative of Since the equilibrium condition the firm must respect
λ with respect to k is positive. To find this, let us write in employing labor is satisfied only along the curve
equation (77) in the implicit form: Gw (k ,λ ) = 0 , it follows that the dynamics of the firm can
be fully described only by a point of this curve belonging
Gw (k , λ ) = f (k ) − kf '( k ) + λ [ f (k ) − kf ' (k ) − w] = 0 (82) ∧
to the range [ k w , k ). To find this point, we need to take
where Gw is the implicit function existing between k and
into account condition (81), which describes the dynam-
λ . The sub-index w in G means that this function is de- ics of the shadow price of capital λ .
fined for any given w. Differentiating (82), we have:
The static analysis has suggested that a profit maximiz-
dλ ∂ Gw / ∂ k (1 + λ )kf " (k ) ∧
=− = >0 (83) ing firm is in equilibrium in k , while a revenue maximiz-
dk ∂ Gw / ∂ λ f (k ) − kf ' (k ) − w
ing firm is in equilibrium in k w . Furthermore, if a reve-

which is positive because for k < k we have w nue maximizing firm must also respect a minimum ac
> f ( k ) − kf ' (k ) and f " (k ) < 0.
λ
λ
Gw (k ,λ ) = 0 λMax B'

λB B
A
λA λ& = 0

0 kw ∧
k k 0 k+ kw k
Figure 3. The mapping of the function Gw(k, λ) Figure 4. The mapping of the λ& = 0 curve

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


182 Beniamino Moro

ceptable return on capital constraint, its equilibrium point λ → ∞ . Since f (k ) decreases with k, for k > k+ we have

is intermediate between k w and k . We are led to an ρ − f ' (k ) > 0, and λ >0, so we have positive values of the
analogous conclusion in a dynamic context too, but with a shadow price of capital. Furthermore, always for values
fundamental specification. As long as the firm grows, the of k> k+, differentiating equation (86), we have:
dynamic equilibrium point is intermediate between k w
dλ ∂ λ& /∂ k (1 + λ ) f " (k )
∧ =− = <0 (89)
and k . Once the firm stops growing, the stationary equi- dk ∂ λ& /∂ λ ρ − f ' (k )
librium of a revenue maximizing firm is the same as the
The sign of this expression is negative because the de-
static one and corresponds to a capital-labor ratio equal
to k w . nominator is positive, while f " (k ) < 0. As k→ k+ from
the right, [ ρ − f ' (k )] →0, so dλ / d k → − ∞ . This means that
When a revenue maximizing firm must also respect a
minimum acceptable return on capital constraint in a dy- the curve λ& =0 is asymptotic as k→ k+ from the right,
namic context, we have two cases. If the constraint is not decreases as k increases and becomes zero as k→ ∞ , be-
binding, in the equilibrium point the firm grows at a rate ing lim f ' (k ) = 0.
which is smaller than the rate of profit. Otherwise, if the k→∞

constraint is binding, the firm does not grow any more. In By definition, the value of k+ depends on the discount
the latter case, all profits that the firm realizes are distrib- rate ρ . For sufficiently high values of ρ , we find that k+
uted to the stockholders to satisfy the minimum accept-
has an intermediate value between zero and k w . In this
able return on capital constraint, and nothing remains to
the firm for self-financing and capital accumulation. The case, the curve λ& = 0 is economically meaningful only for
∧ k ≥ k w , that is to say only for those values of k for which
equilibrium point k0, being k w ≤ k0 ≤ k , is the capital-
the non bankruptcy constraint is satisfied. For k > k w , the
labor ratio to which it corresponds a rate of profit exactly
equal to the minimum return on capital rate r0 . Obviously, curve λ& = 0 is defined by equation (88), while for k = k w
also in this case the firm rate of growth is zero. We dem- the curve is defined by equation (87) with a value of α
onstrate all this in the following sections. which varies in the open interval 0≤ α <1. In the latter
case, the stationary values of λ are given by:
3.2. The Equilibrium Capital-labor Ratio
As previously seen, the dynamics of the costate variable f ' (k w )
λ is given by equation (81). First we need to map in a λ (λ& = 0) = (90)
ρ − αf ' ( k w )
phase diagram the stationary points of λ , given by:
As α varies, equation (90) describes the segment BB’,
λ& = λ [ ρ − αf ' (k )] − f ' (k ) = 0 (86) whose extreme value at B’ (obtained for α = 0) is
from which we obtain:
f ' (k w )
λ Max = (91)
f ' (k ) ρ
λ (λ& = 0) = (87)
ρ − αf ' ( k ) while in point B the stationary value of λ is given by:
If the firm makes profits, Q−wL>0 and α =1. In this f '(k ) f '( k w )
case, equation (87) reduces to: λB = lim '
= (92)
k →kw ρ − f (k ) ρ − f ' (k w )
f '( k )
λ (λ& = 0) = (88) where the limit is calculated as k→ k w from the right.
ρ − f ' (k )
Overlapping the two curves Gw (k ,λ ) = 0 and λ& = 0 on the
which describes the stationary points of the shadow price same graph, we can depict the phase diagram of our
of capital λ with respect to the capital-labor ratio k. The model. We can have many cases, depending on the rela-
map of this curve, from now on defined as the λ& = 0 tive location of the points A, B e B’. For λB > λ A , where
curve, which is depicted in figure 4, depends on the value λ A is defined by equation (85), we have the situation
of ρ . For ρ < f ' (k ) , the curve λ& = 0 gives negative val- depicted in figure 5. In this case, the dynamic equilibrium
ues of λ , which are not economically meaningful. There- of a revenue maximizing firm may occur at two points of
fore it must be ρ ≥ f ' (k ) in order to have significant eco- the capital-labor ratio, corresponding respectively to k
nomic values of λ . and k w . However, the only dynamic equilibrium is point
Let k+ be the level of k which satisfies the equation E, to which an endogenous growth of the firm corre-
− −
ρ − f ' (k + ) = 0, so if k→ k+ from the right, then we have sponds, which is defined by the pair of values (k , λ ) .

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


The Theory of the Revenue Maximizing Firm 183

λ
k& = 0
− +
λMax B' Gw = 0 MRS L / K

MRS L / K

λB B

w E
E
ρ

λ
A + λ& = 0
λA


0 k+ kw
k
∧ k
0

k k k
Figure 6. The mapping of the dynamic equilibrium con-
Figure 5. The phase diagram for 0 < k+< kw dition MRSL/K = w/ρ
At this point, the dynamic equilibrium of a revenue tion of k. Furthermore, because as k→0 we have QL →0
maximizing firm is characterized by the stationarity of
and QK → ∞ , whereas as k→ ∞ we have QL → ∞ and
both the capital-labor ratio at the level k and the shadow
− QK →0, it follows that MRS L / K →0 as k→0 and
price of capital at the level λ . The equilibrium value of
MRS L / K → ∞ as k→ ∞ . This is shown in figure 6. It is
the capital-labor ratio k can be found taking the equa-
clear from this figure that an increase of the real wage
tions (77) and (88) as a system of simultaneous equations,
rate w or a decrease of the discount rate ρ imply an in-
whose solution gives:
crease of the equilibrium capital-labor ratio k .
f (k ) − kf ' ( k ) f ' (k )
'
= (93) In a neighborhood of point E in figure 5, the value of
w − f (k ) + kf (k ) ρ − f ' (k )
λ tends to depart from its equilibrium value λ . This can
while the equilibrium value of the capital shadow price be demonstrated by differentiating (81) with respect to k:
λ is given by: ∂ λ&
= −λ f " ( k ) − f "
( k ) >0 (97)
' '
∂k
f (k ) f (k ) − k f (k )
λ= = (94) which is positive, since f " (k ) < 0. According to (97), as
ρ − f '(k ) w − [ f (k ) − k f ' (k )]
k increases (going rightwards), λ& should follow the (−, 0,
From equation (93), rearranging we obtain: +) sign sequence. So, the λ -arrowheads must point down-
f (k ) − kf '(k ) w ward to the left of λ& = 0 curve, and upward to the right of
= (95)
f ' (k ) ρ it. This means that λ& < 0, implying λ decreases with re-
spect to time, on the left of the λ& = 0 curve, while λ& >0,
which can be expressed in the form: implying λ increases with respect to time, on the right of
QL w the λ& = 0 curve.
MRS L / K = = (96)
QK ρ Since the value of the capital-labor ratio at the point E
where, like in the static analysis, MRS L / K is the rate of is constant at the level k , from (80), which is the second
marginal substitution between labor and capital. Equation subsystem that describes the dynamics of the revenue
(96) represents the optimizing rule which must be fol- maximizing firm, we have:
lowed by a revenue maximizing firm in a dynamic con- L&
k& = f ( k ) − w − k = 0 (98)
text. This rule requires that the rate of marginal substitu- L
tion between labor and capital be equal to the ratio be-
from which we deduce:
tween the real wage rate and the discount rate. Since the
marginal productivity of labor increases with respect to L& f (k ) − w
= (99)
the capital-labor ratio, whereas the marginal productivity L k
of capital decreases, the MRS L / K is an increasing func-
Therefore, in the dynamic equilibrium of point E, the

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


184 Beniamino Moro

growth rate of employment is given by the return on capi- ∧


which assumes a positive value because for k < k the real
tal rate corresponding to the equilibrium capital-labor
wage rate is greater than the marginal productivity of
ratio k . As k is stationary, this implies that K grows at
labor. This suggests that k& should follow the (−, 0, +)
the same rate as L. Furthermore, the linear homogeneity
of the production function implies that Q increases at the sign sequence as k increases. Hence the k-arrowheads
same rate, too. Thus, we have: should point leftwards to the left of the k& =0 curve, and
rightwards to the right of it. This means that, for k< k , we
L& K& Q& f (k ) − w
= = = =r (100) have k& < 0, so k decreases with respect to time, while for
L K Q k
k> k we have k& >0, so that k increases with respect to
where r is the common growth rate of labor, capital and
time.
output.
Therefore, along the Gw (k ,λ ) = 0 curve, the arrowheads
Therefore, in point E we have a balanced growth of the
firm, where the rate of growth r is endogenously deter- point rightwards and upward to the right of the point E
mined. Therefore, this is a neoclassical endogenous and they point leftwards and downward to the left of that
model of the revenue maximizing firm, which goes fur- point. So, both the capital-labor ratio k and the shadow
ther beyond Leland’s analysis. price of capital λ , when moving along the Gw (k ,λ ) = 0
curve to optimize the use of labor, tend to increase to the
There is no transitional dynamics in this model. In fact,
right of point E and to decrease to the left. It follows that
if the firm begins its activity with the capital K(0)=K0, it
point E is dynamically unstable, and the firm can remain
must choose from the beginning the level L0 of the labor
in equilibrium at that point only if it has chosen to stay
factor for which we have K0/L0= k and it must keep per- there from the beginning.
manently fixed this capital-labor ratio. So, the equilibrium
time path of k is constant. If, on the contrary, the firm begins its activity with a
capital-labor ratio greater than k , the dynamics of the
Analogously, the equilibrium time path of the shadow
model suggests that the firm must choose a point on the
price of capital is also constant at the level indicated by
right of point E along the Gw (k ,λ ) = 0 curve; so, it is in-
(94), whereas the equilibrium time paths of labor, capital
and output depend on the rate of endogenous growth r as duced to over-accumulate capital, approaching asymp-

defined by (100). They are defined respectively by the totically the capital-labor ratio k which maximizes the
following exponential functions: rate of profit. But, in this case, a dynamically efficient
L = L0 e r t (101) equilibrium point for a revenue maximizing firm does not

K = K 0 er t (102) exist, because when k tends to k the shadow price of
capital tends to infinity, so it has not a stationary value.
Q = Q0 e r t (103)
On the contrary, if the firm begins its activity with a
where, given K 0 , the value of L0 is defined by capital-labor ratio smaller than k , the dynamics of the
L0 = K 0 / k , whereas that of Q0 is given by Q0 = model suggests that the firm must choose a point on the
left of the point E along the Gw (k ,λ ) = 0 curve. So, it is
Q( K 0 , L0 ).
induced, following the arrowheads, to under-accumulate
The k& = 0 curve given by (98) must plot as a vertical capital moving along this curve towards the point A. In
straight line in figure 5, with horizontal intercept k . In a the point A, the value of α becomes indeterminate in the
neighborhood of point E along the Gw (k ,λ ) = 0 curve, the open interval 0≤ α <1. For λB ≤ λ ≤ λMax , both equations
value of k, and not only that of λ , tends to depart from its Gw (k ,λ ) = 0 and λ& = 0 are satisfied, so the equilibrium
equilibrium value. This can be demonstrated differentiat- capital-labor ratio becomes k w . In this case, we have
ing (80) with respect to k: multiple equilibria along the segment BB’, all character-
.
∂ k& L ized by the stationarity of the capital-labor ratio at the
= f ' (k ) − (104) level k w and by zero profits, so the endogenous growth
∂k L
rate of the firm is null.
Substituting to L& /L its value given by (99), in a
neighborhood of the point E we have: 3.3. Market Conditions and the Role of the Dis-
count Rate
∂ k& w − [ f (k ) − k f ' (k )] The firm can also be pushed to a stationary point by the
= >0 (105)
∂k k market conditions given by the ratio w/ρ. Given the real
wage rate w, the ratio k+ depends, as seen, on the value of
the discount rate ρ . If ρ increases, the ratio k+ in figure

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


The Theory of the Revenue Maximizing Firm 185

5 decreases, so the λ& = 0 curve shifts down and left. This w f ' (k w )
λ A = λMax = = (111)
implies the point E also shifts down and left, along the k w ρ Max ρ Max
Gw (k ,λ ) = 0 curve, as shown by the arrowheads, until it
overlaps to point A. At the same time, the movement to For ρ > ρ Max , point B’ is under point A, which implies
the left of the λ& = 0 curve makes the point B also to coin- that λMax < λ A , so no equilibrium exists for a revenue
cide with the point A. maximizing firm.
When these three points coincide, a revenue maximiz- On the contrary, when ρ decreases, always keeping a
ing firm does not have an endogenous growth equilibrium fixed real wage rate, the ratio k+ increases. When k+
any more; it only has multiple stationary equilibria along equals kw, the dynamic equilibrium of the firm becomes a
the segment BB’, all characterized by the stationarity of unique equilibrium of endogenous growth, corresponding
the capital-labor ratio at the level k w . On the contrary,
to point E in figure 5. Let us indicate with ρ + < ρ w the
the equilibrium values of the shadow price of capital
level of the discount rate for which we have k+= k w . Then,
range from λ A , which now coincides with λB , and λMax .

If we indicate with ρ w the discount rate to which it cor- for r < ρ ≤ ρ + , the revenue maximizing firm has a unique
responds a λ& = 0 curve whose point B coincides with dynamic equilibrium of endogenous growth in point E.
point A, so as λB = λ A , the common value of the shadow This equilibrium stays unique until the discount rate takes

price of capital is then given by: another critique value given by r , which corresponds to

f (k w ) − k w f ' (k w ) f ' (k w ) the equality k+= k . In fact, remembering that, according
λA = = = λB (106) ∧ ∧
w − f (k w ) + k w f '(k w ) ρ w − f ' (k w ) to the (17), we have r = f '(k ) , from the definition of k+
∧ ∧
while the value of λMax , remembering equation (91), is
we deduce that, when ρ = r , the equality k+= k is satis-
given by: fied.
∧ ∧
f '( k w ) For ρ ≤ r , we have k+≥ k , so again no equilibrium of a
λMax = (107)
ρw
revenue maximizing firm exists. In this case, as we shall
Because in this case w = f(kw), and taking account of see later, the objective integral is no longer convergent.
(95), from equation (106) we get: As ρ →0, also f ' (k + ) → 0 , so k+→ ∞ . This is why, to
make the objective integral converging, the condition
f (k w ) − k w f ' (k w ) w
λ A = λB = = (108) ∧ ∧
k w f '( k w ) kwρw ρ > r must be satisfied, which implies that r < r . This

which can also be put in the form: also implies that the case k = k , when the equilibrium
points of a revenue maximizing firm and of a profit
QL w
MRS L / K = = λA kw = (109) maximizing firm should coincide, does not exist. In fact,
QK ρw ∧
we always have k < k .
If we exclude the last equality, this condition corre-
sponds to condition (56) of the static theory. It says that Referring once again to figure 5, we can summarize the
in a stationary equilibrium the marginal rate of substitu- following cases:

tion between labor and capital must equal the shadow - for ρ ≤ r , no equilibrium of the revenue maximizing
value of the capital per worker. Furthermore, in a dy-
firm exists;
namic analysis, it also must equal the ratio between the ∧
real wage rate and the discount rate. So, in this case, the - for r < ρ ≤ ρ + , we have a unique equilibrium of en-
stationary values of λ belong to the range: dogenous growth corresponding to the stationary point E
w − f ' (k w ) = (k , λ ) in figure 5;
λ A = λB = ≤λ ≤ = λMax (110)
kwρw ρw - for ρ + < ρ < ρ w , we have an endogenous growth equi-
librium in point E of figure 5 and multiple stationary
If ρ increases beyond ρ w , the λ& = 0 curve again shifts equilibria without growth corresponding to the interval
down and left, so point B shifts under point A, while point BB’ in the same figure;
B’ approaches point A. When point B’ coincides with - for ρw≤ ρ < ρ Max , we only have multiple stationary equi-
point A, this remains the only stationary equilibrium point. libria without growth in the interval AB’, being A, in this
If we indicate with ρ Max the corresponding discount rate, case, over B;
in this case we have: - for ρ = ρ Max , we have a unique stationary equilibrium
without growth corresponding to point A=B’;

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


186 Beniamino Moro

- for ρ > ρ Max , again no equilibrium of the revenue maxi- infinity, while the instantaneous rate of profit varies with
mizing firm exists. respect to k from − ∞ to zero in the interval 0< k ≤ k w , it

3.4. The Present Value, the Net Present Value per becomes positive and increasing in the range k w < k < k ,
Unit of Capital and the Transversality Conditions ∧ ⎡ ∧ ⎤ ∧
further it assumes its maximum value r = ⎢ f (k ) − w⎥ k
∧ ⎣ ⎦
In general, for P=1 and r < ρ ≤ ρ Max , the present value ∧
(PV) of future revenues of the firm is: for k= k , and then it decreases towards zero as k→ ∞ . As
∞ a consequence, the ratio NPV/K0 also varies from − ∞ to
PV =
∫ 0
Lf ( k )e − ρt dt (112) zero in the interval 0< k ≤ k w , it becomes positive and

where L=L0ert and L0=K0/k, while r is any endogenous increasing in the range k w < k< k , further it assumes its
∧ ∧
growth rate which must be smaller than r . Substituting maximum value for k = k , and then it decreases towards
we have: zero as k→ ∞ . The mapping of r with respect to k is also
∞ depicted in figure 7(c). This corresponds to the mapping
PV =
∫ 0
L0 f (k )e − ( ρ − r )t dt (113) of the rate of profit in the static analysis.

∧ The condition ρ > r , which is necessary for the con-
It is clear that PV converges only if ρ >r. As ρ > r >r,
vergence of the objective integral, is also necessary and
this condition is satisfied. Dividing (113) by K0, we ob- sufficient to satisfy the transversality conditions of our
tain the present value of future revenues per unit of initial optimal control problem. These conditions are:
capital:

lim H c e − ρ t = 0 (118)
f ( k ) − ( ρ − r )t

PV t →∞
= e dt (114)
K0 0 k
lim λe − ρ t = 0 (119)
t →∞
Given K 0 , when L0 varies between infinity and zero,
the capital-labor ratio k varies between zero and infinity, which must be satisfied along the optimal paths of the
while the instantaneous output per unit of capital f(k)/k, involved variables.
remembering (33), varies between infinity and zero, de- It is immediate to verify the (119), as in equilibrium we
creasing with respect to k. But, for k< k w , the ratio f(k)/k have λ = λ , where λ is constant if the firm has an en-
is not economically meaningful, because it does not re- dogenous growth equilibrium in point E of figure 5,
spect the non bankruptcy constraint. Whereas for k≥ k w , whereas it takes a value which ranges between λ B and
as in the static analysis, the ratio f(k)/k is economically λ Max if the firm is in a stationary equilibrium correspond-
meaningful. It decreases with k and tends asymptotically ing to the capital-labor ratio k w . In both cases, as the
to zero as k→ ∞ . So, its maximum value is given for term e− ρ t → 0 for t → ∞ , condition (119) is satisfied.
k= k w , as we can see in figure 7(c).
To verify condition (118), we need to write it in the ex-
In the same way, we can define the net present value
tended form:
NPV as follows:

lim [ Q + λ α ( Q − wL )] e − ρ t = 0 (120)
NPV =
∫ [Lf (k ) − wL] e − ρt
dt (115)
t→∞
0
If we have a stationary equilibrium, Q and L are con-
where L=L0e and L0= K 0 /k. This equation can be put in
rt stant, so equation (120) is satisfied. If, otherwise, we have
rt
the form: an endogenous growth equilibrium, then Q = Q0 e and
∞ L = L0 e rt , where r = [ f (k ) − w] / k is the endogenous growth
NPV =
∫ 0
L0 [ f (k ) − w] e − ( ρ − r )t dt (116)
rate. Substituting these values, the condition (120) be-
∧ comes:
which is convergent as ρ > r >r. Dividing (116) by K 0 ,
we obtain the net present value per unit of capital:
[ ]
lim Q0 + λα (Q0 − wL0 ) e − ( ρ − r ) t = 0
t →∞
(121)

∞ ∞ ∧
f ( k ) − w − ( ρ − r )t which is satisfied because ρ > r > r .
∫ ∫
NPV
= e dt = re − ( ρ − r )t dt (117)
K0 0 k 0
3.5. The Equilibrium Conditions with a Mini-
As said, given K 0 , when L0 varies between infinity mum Acceptable Return on Capital Constraint
and zero, the capital-labor ratio k varies between zero and

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


The Theory of the Revenue Maximizing Firm 187

f(k)
f(k)

f (k ) − k r
A E
w f (k ) − kf ' (k )
B

(a)

0
k
λ
Gw = 0
λMax B'
k& = 0

λB B
(b)

E

λ
λ& = 0
A

0
k+ k

f (k ) / k , r

f (k w ) / k w
(c)
− −
f (k ) / k


f (k ) / k
r

r r (k )

0 − ∧ k
kw k k

Figure 7. The endogenous growth dynamics of the revenue maximizing firm

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


188 Beniamino Moro

If the firm must respect a minimum acceptable return on If the minimum acceptable return on capital constraint
capital constraint of the form: is not binding, from (131) we have γ =0. Furthermore,
π since ℑc is linear with respect to α , its value is maxi-
≥ r0 , for all t ∈ [0,∞ ] (122)
K mized for α =1. In this case, the equations (130), (132)
where π = Q − wL is the instantaneous profit of the firm, and (133) respectively reduce to:
then we must modify the optimal control problem to take
account of this. As the constraint can also be expressed in [ ]
Gw (k ,λ ) = f (k ) − kf ' (k ) + λ f (k ) − kf '(k ) − w = 0 (134)
the form:
L&
k& + k = f (k ) − w − r0 k >0 (135)
Q − wL − r0 K ≥ 0 (123) L

the program of the revenue maximizing firm becomes: [ ]


λ& = − f '( k ) − λ f ' (k ) − r0 + ρλ (136)

Maximize
∫ 0
Q ( K , L)e − ρt dt From (134) we obtain:

subject to f (k ) − kf ' (k )
λ= (137)
K& = α [Q − wL − r0 K ] (124) w − [ f ( k ) − kf ' (k )]

0≤ α ≤1 which is the same as (77). So, all observations just re-


ferred to the Gw ( k , λ ) = 0 curve also apply to (134).
Q − wL − r0 K ≥ 0
As to λ& = 0 curve, it now depends not only on the dis-
and K(0)=K0, K ∞ free, K0, w, r0 given. count rate ρ , but also on the minimum return on capital
The current value Hamiltonian must, in this case, be constraint rate r0 . In order to stress this dependence, from
extended to form a Lagrangian function in current value, now on this curve will be indicated by the symbol λ&r = 0 .
which takes account of the new constraint (123). This From (136), setting the stationarity condition, we obtain:
Lagrangian is:
[ ]
.
λ&r = − f ' (k ) + λ ( ρ + r0 ) − f ' (k ) = 0 (138)
ℑc = Q + λα (Q − wL − r0 K ) + γ (Q − wL − r0 K ) (125)
from which we derive:
where λ and γ are two dynamic Lagrangian multipliers
expressed in current values. As ℑc is concave in K and L, f '( k )
λ ( λ&r =0) = (139)
and it is linear with respect to α , the following conditions ( ρ + r0 ) − f '(k )
of the maximum principle are necessary and sufficient for
the solution of the program (124): The only difference between this expression and (88) is
that here we have ρ + r0 in the denominator instead of
∂ ℑc
= QL + λα (QL − w) + γ (QL − w) = 0 (126) only ρ . Hence, introducing a minimum acceptable return
∂L
on capital rate r0 is analogous to increasing the discount
∂ ℑc rate for the same amount.
= Q − wL − r0 K ≥ 0, γ ≥ 0, γ (Q − wL − r0 K ) = 0 (127)
∂γ
Therefore, let k++ be the level of k which satisfies the
K& =
∂ ℑc
= α (Q − wL − r0 K ) (128) equation ( ρ + r0 ) − f ' (k ) = 0 , so that as k→k++ from the
∂λ
right we have λ → ∞ . Since f '(k ) decreases with k, for
∂ ℑc
λ& = − + ρλ = −QK − λα (QK − r0 ) − γ (QK − r0 ) + ρλ (129)
∂K k>k++ we have ( ρ + r0 ) − f ' (k ) >0, which implies λ >0.
Furthermore, if we differentiate equation (138), we obtain:
and in addition we must maximize ℑc with respect to α .
These conditions can be expressed in the following per dλ ∂λ& / ∂ k − f " (k ) − λf " (k ) (1 + λ ) f " (k )
capita form: =− r =− = <0
dk &
∂λr / ∂λ '
( ρ + r0 ) − f (k ) ( ρ + r0 ) − f ' (k )
Gw (k ,λ ) = f ( k ) − kf ' ( k ) + (λα + γ ) [ f (k ) − kf ' (k ) − w] = 0 (130) (140)

f ( k ) − w − r0 K ≥ 0, γ ≥ 0, γ [ f (k ) − w − r0 k ] = 0 (131) For k++< k, this derivative takes a negative value be-


L& cause the denominator is positive, whereas f " (k ) < 0. As
k& + k = α [ f (k ) − w − r0 k ] (132)
L k→k++ from the right, ρ + r0 − f ' (k ) → 0 , so dλ / dk → −∞ .
[ ]
λ& = − f ' (k ) − (λα + γ ) f ' (k ) − r0 + ρλ (133) Therefore, the λ&r =0 curve is asymptotic for k→ k++ from
the right, it decreases when k increases and it takes a null

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


The Theory of the Revenue Maximizing Firm 189

λ λ

λMax B'

Gw = 0
λMax B'

λ& = 0
λB
B λB B E
≈ E'
λ&r = 0 λ
λA λ& = 0
A
λ&r = 0
0 k ++ kw k0 k

Figure 8: The mappings of λ&r = 0 and λ& =0 curves ≈ − ∧


0 k + + k + k w k0 k k k k

value as k→ ∞ , because lim f ' (k ) = 0 . Furthermore, as Figure 9. The dynamic equilibrium of a revenue maxi-
k →∞
mizing firm (for 0 < k++< k0) with a minimum acceptable
we know from its definition, the value of k++ depends on return on capital constraint
the discount rate ρ and on the minimum return on capital
rate r0 . Given r0 , for sufficiently high values of ρ , the
ratio k++ is intermediate between zero and k0, being k0 that MRS L / K MRS L / K
value of k which satisfies the minimum acceptable return
on capital constraint with the equality sign, that is:
f ( k0 ) − w
r0 = (141) E
k0
w /ρ
As it is shown in figure 8, the λ&r = 0 curve is economi-
cally meaningful only for k ≥ k0, that is only for those w E'
capital-labor ratios which satisfy the minimum acceptable ρ + r0
return on capital constraint. For k > k0, the λ&r = 0 curve is
defined by (139), while for k = k0 equation (133) stays
true, from which we obtain: 0 ≈ −
k
k k
' '
f ( k 0 ) + γ [ f (k 0 ) − r0 ]
λ= (142)
ρ − α [ f ' (k 0 ) − r0 ] Figure 10. The endogenous growth equilibria of the reve-
nue maximizing firm with and without a minimum ac-
In this case, γ > 0 because of equation (131), whereas ceptable return on capital constraint
0≤ α < 1, so the maximum value of λ is given by:
capital constraint. We must point out now that the en-
f ' (k0 ) + γ [ f '(k0 ) − r0 ] f ' (k0 ) + γ [ f ' (k0 ) − r0 ] dogenous growth equilibrium is no more at point E, but at
λMax = lim = point E’, where there is the stationarity of the capital-
α →0 ρ − α[ f '(k0 ) − r0 ] ρ
≈ −
(143) labor ratio at the level k < k .
The value of λB can be defined as the limit of equation Taking the equations (137) and (139) together, we
(139) for k→k0 from the right, that is: form a system whose solution gives the stationary value

k , which is the equilibrium capital-labor ratio. Corre-
f ' (k )
λB = lim (144) sponding to this ratio, we have:
k →k0 (ρ + r0 ) − f ' (k )
QL w
MRS L/ K = = (145)
Overlapping the Gw (k ,λ ) = 0 curve to the λ&r = 0 curve, QK ρ + r0
we obtain figure 9, which is similar to figure 5, but with
which is the counterpart of equation (96) in the case the
the difference due to the minimum acceptable return on
firm must respect a minimum acceptable return on capital

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


190 Beniamino Moro

constraint. From (145), it is clear that r0 exerts the same r0 , that is:
effect as ρ on the equilibrium marginal rate of substitu- ≈ f ( k0 ) − w
tion. In figure 10, both equilibrium conditions, given re- r= = r0 (150)
k0
spectively by (96) and (145), are depicted.
≈ ≈
From (135), being k a stationary level of k, at point E’ In this case, we have r * = r - r0 = 0, and the firm is in a
stationary equilibrium where all profits are given out to
we have k& = 0 . This means that, remembering α =1,
the stockholders to satisfy the minimum acceptable return
from (132) we have:
on capital constraint. As a consequence, nothing remains
≈ ≈ L≈
. to the firm to finance the accumulation of capital and its
k& = f (k ) − w − r0 k − k = 0 (146) growth process.
L
Finally, according to the respective positions of points
and the employment growth rate in E’ is given by: A, B and B’, we can do the same reasoning as in figure 5.
So, let ρ 0 be the value of ρ for which the λ& = 0 curve

L& f (k ) − w ≈ passes over point A in figure 9; in order that points A and
= − r0 = r − r0 (147)
L ≈ B coincide, and from equation (149) we have:
k
≈ ⎡ ≈ ⎤ ≈ f ( k 0 ) − k 0 f ' (k 0 ) f ' (k 0 )
where r = ⎢ f (k ) − w⎥ k measures the actual return on λ A = λB = = (151)
⎣ ⎦ w − [ f (k 0 ) − k 0 f ' (k 0 )] ( ρ 0 + r0 ) − f ' (k 0 )
capital rate corresponding to the equilibrium point E’, that
≈ Substituting the value of w − f (k0 ) calculated from
is to the capital-labor ratio k . Equation (147) says that in
equation (150), we obtain:
a dynamic equilibrium the employment of the firm grows
at a rate equal to the difference between the real return on f (k 0 ) − k 0 f ' (k 0 ) QL
capital rate and the minimum acceptable return on capital λ A = λB = = (152)
k 0 [ f '(k 0 ) − r0 ] k 0 (QK − r0 )
rate. If we indicate with r * this difference, taking account
of the linear homogeneity assumption on the production where QL and QK are the marginal productivities, respec-
function, we have: tively, of labor and capital measured for k=k0. The equa-
tion (152) can be put in the form:
L& K& Q& ≈
r* = = = = r − r0 (148) QL
L K Q MRS L / K (r0 ) = = k 0 λ A = k 0 λB (153)
QK − r0
For r0 = 0, the dynamic equilibrium of the firm is at
≈ which corresponds to condition (66) just found in the
point E of figure 9. In this case, r * = r = r . For r0 >0, the static analysis. As we know, this condition says that in
dynamic equilibrium of the firm is at point E’, corre- equilibrium the shadow value of per worker capital must
≈ − equal the net marginal rate of substitution between labor
sponding to a stationary capital-labor ratio equal to k < k . and capital, where the latter, which is indicated by
When r0 increases, the point E’ moves along the MRSL/K(r0), is given by the ratio of marginal productivity
≈ of labor over the marginal productivity of capital, net of
Gw (k ,λ ) = 0 curve from E to A. For r0 = r , when the firm the minimum rate of return on capital r0.
gives out all profits to the stockholders, its dynamic equi-
librium is at point A, where the capital accumulation rate 4. Concluding Remarks
and the growth rate are both zero. In conclusion, we have shown that there exist three values
We are led to the same conclusion if the minimum re- of the equilibrium capital-labor ratio that can be found
turn on capital constraint is binding. In this case, the rela- both in a static and in a dynamic analysis of the theory of

tions (142), (143) and (144) hold, whereas the value of the firm. They are the ratio k where the firm maximizes
λ A in figure 9 is given by:
profits, the ratio kw where the firm maximizes revenue,
and the ratio k0 where the firm maximizes revenue subject
f (k ) − kf '( k ) to a minimum acceptable return on capital constraint, if
λ A = lim (149)
k →k0 w − [ f (k ) − kf ' (k )] the latter is binding.
Furthermore, we have found two values of the equilib-
where the limit is calculated from equation (137) for k→
rium capital-labor ratio that exist only in the dynamic
k0 from the right. Therefore, we have multiple stationary
analysis of a revenue maximizing firm. They are the ratio
equilibria, all corresponding to the capital-labor ratio k0,
which determines an actual return on capital rate equal to k where the firm is in an endogenous growth equilibrium,

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


The Theory of the Revenue Maximizing Firm 191

≈ [18] Foss N. J., “Austrian Insights and the Theory of the Firm”,
and the ratio k where the firm, not only is in an endoge- Advances in Austrian Economics, 4, 1997, pp.175-98.
nous growth equilibrium, but it also satisfies a minimum [19] Galbraith J.K., The New Industrial State, Boston, Hough-
acceptable return on capital constraint. Obviously, when ton-Mifflin, 1967.

the firm is in equilibrium in k , it grows at a smaller rate [20] Grant R. M., “Toward a Knowledge-based Theory of the
than that guaranteed in k , as the difference is exactly the Firm”, Strategic Management Journal, 17, 1996, pp.109-
22.
minimum return on capital rate given out to stockholders
to satisfy the constraint. [21] Jensen M. C., A Theory of the Firm: Governance, Resid-
ual Claims, and Organizational Forms, Boston, Harvard
University Press, 2003.
[22] Jensen M. C.-Meckling W. H., “Theory of the Firm:
REFERENCES Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Struc-
[1] Anderson W. L., Profit Maximizing versus Revenue ture”, Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 1976, pp.305-60.
Maximizing Firms? Only time Will Tell, mimeo [23] Kagono T.-Nonaka I.-Sakakibara K.-Okumura A., Strate-
(http://www.mises.org/asc/2003/asc9anderson.pdf), 2003. gic vs. Evolutionary Management: A US-Japan Compari-
[2] Baumol W., Business Behavior, Value, and Growth, New son of Strategy and Organization, Amsterdam, Elsevier,
York, Macmillan, 1959. 1985.
[3] Baumol W., “On the Theory of the Expansion of the [24] Klein B.-Crawford R. G.-Alchian A. A., “Vertical Integra-
Firm”, American Economic Review, 52, 1962, pp.1078-87. tion, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting
Process”, Journal of Law and Economics, 21, 1978,
[4] Blinder A. S. , “International Perspective: Trading with
pp.297-326.
Japan: Why the US Loses even on a Level Playing Field”,
Business Economics, 27, 1992, pp.25-29. [25] Komiya R., “Japanese Firms, Chinese Firms: Problems for
Economic Reform in China”, Journal of the Japanese and
[5] Blinder A. S., “A Simple Note on the Japanese Firm”,
International Economies, 1, 1987, pp.31-61.
Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 7,
1993, pp.238-55. [26] Komiya R., Business Enterprise in Japan, Boston, The
MIT Press, 1992.
[6] Cheung S. N. S., “The Contractual Nature of the Firm”,
Journal of Law and Economics, 26, 1983, pp.1-21. [27] Larner R. J., “Ownership and Control in the 200 Largest
Non-financial Corporations, 1929 and 1963”, American
[7] Chiang A. C., Elements of Dynamic Optimization, New
Economic Review, 56, 1966, pp.777-87.
York, McGraw-Hill, 1992.
[28] Leland H. E., “The Dynamics of a Revenue Maximizing
[8] Coase R. H., “The Nature of the Firm”, Economica, 4,
Firm”, International Economic Review, 13, 1972, pp.376-
1937, pp.386-485.
85.
[9] Conner K. R., “A Historical Comparison of Resource-
[29] Nakamura T., The Postwar Japanese Economy, its Devel-
based Theory of five Schools of Thought within Industrial
opment and Structure, Tokyo, University of Tokyo Press,
Organization Economics: Do We Have a New Theory of
1981.
the Firm?”, Journal of Management, 17, 1991, pp.121-154.
[30] Nelson R. R.-Winter S., An Evolutionary Theory of Eco-
[10] Conner K. R.-Prahalad C. K., “A Resource-based Theory
nomic Change, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press,
of the Firm: Knowledge versus Opportunism”, Organiza-
1982.
tion Science, 7, 1996, pp.477-501.
[31] Rothbard M. N., Man, Economy, and State, Auburn (Ala-
[11] Cyert R. M.-Hedrick C. L., “Theory of the Firm: Past,
bama), L. von Mises Institute, 1993 ed, 1962.
Present, and Future; An Interpretation”, Journal of Eco-
nomic Literature, 10, 1972, pp.398-412. [32] Tabeta N.-Wang R., “Relative Revenue-maximizing Strat-
egy Under Cournot Duopolistic Competition: the Case of
[12] Cyert R. M.-March J. G., A Behavioral Theory of the Firm,
US-Japan Bilateral auto trade”, SABRE Working Papers
New Jersey, Prentice Hall, 1963.
Series, n. 1996a, pp.8-96.
[13] Fama E., “Agency Problems and the Theory of the Firm”,
[33] Tabeta N.-Wang R., Who Will Be the Winner when a
Journal of Political Economy, 88, 1980, pp.288-307.
Profit-Maximizer Meets a Revenue-Maximizer?-The case
[14] Foss N. J., “Theories of the Firm: Contractual and Compe- of US-Japan Auto Trade, mimeo
tence Perspectives”, Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 3, (http://www.ntu.edu.sg/nbs/sabre/ working_papers/19-
1993, pp.127-44. 96.pdf), 1996b.
[15] Foss N. J., “The Theory of the Firm: The Austrians as [34] Uekusa M.-Caves R. E., Industrial Organization in Japan,
Precursors and Critics of Contemporary Theory”, Review Wasinghton DC, the Brooking Institution, 1976.
of Austrian Economics, 7, 1994, pp.31-65.
[35] Van Hilton O.-Kort P.-van Loon P.J.J.M., Dynamic Poli-
[16] Foss N. J., “Firms, Incomplete Contracts, and Organiza- cies of the Firm. An Optimal Control Approach, Berlin,
tional Learning”, Human Systems Management, 15, 1996a, Springer-Verlag, 1993.
pp.17-26.
[36] Williamson J., “Profit, Growth, and Sales Maximization”,
[17] Foss N. J., “Knowledge-based Approaches to the Theory Economica, 33, 1966, pp.1-16.
of the Firm: Some Critical Comments”, Organization Sci-
[37] Williamson O. E., “Transaction-cost Economics: The
ence, 7, 1996b, pp. 470-6.

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM


192 Beniamino Moro

Governance of Contractual Relations”, Journal of Law 72.


and Economics, 22, 1979, pp.233-61. [40] Winter S. G., “On Coase, Competence, and Corporation”,
[38] Williamson O. E., “The Logic of Economic Organization”, in O. E. Williamson- S. G. Winter (Eds.), The Nature of
in O. E. Williamson- S. G. Winter (Eds.), The Nature of the Firm – Origins, Evolution, and Development, Oxford,
the Firm – Origins, Evolution, and Development, Oxford, University Press, 1991.
University Press, 1991. [41] Witt U., “Do Entrepreneurs Need Firms? A Contribution
[39] Winter S. G., “Economic Natural Selection and the The- to a Missing Chapter in Austrian Economics”, Review of
ory of the Firm”, Yale Economic Essays, 4, 1964, pp.225- Austrian Economics, 11, 1999, pp.99-109.

Copyright © 2008 SciRes JSSM

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi