Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 12

Policy and Society

ISSN: 1449-4035 (Print) 1839-3373 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rpas20

The role of agencies in policy-making

Tobias Bach, Birgitta Niklasson & Martin Painter

To cite this article: Tobias Bach, Birgitta Niklasson & Martin Painter (2012) The role of agencies in
policy-making, Policy and Society, 31:3, 183-193, DOI: 10.1016/j.polsoc.2012.07.001

To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1016/j.polsoc.2012.07.001

© 2012 Policy and Society Associates (APSS)

Published online: 03 Mar 2017.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 8665

Citing articles: 2 View citing articles

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at


http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=rpas20
Available online at www.sciencedirect.com

Policy and Society 31 (2012) 183–193


www.elsevier.com/locate/polsoc

The role of agencies in policy-making


Tobias Bach a,*, Birgitta Niklasson b, Martin Painter c
a
University of Hannover, Hannover, Germany
b
University of Gothenburg, Gothenburg, Sweden
c
City University of Hong Kong, People’s Republic of China

Abstract
There is an extensive literature on the proliferation of agencies and the delegation of authority to such bodies across different
countries. Much of this research asks whether New Public Management (NPM)-style agencification reforms have been
implemented according to the original objectives, and what consequences – intended or unintended – the reforms have produced.
Yet much of this research lacks an explicit link to the literature on the policymaking functions of public bureaucracies and their
interactions with elected politicians. What are the consequences of agencification for the policy process at large? What policy
relevant tasks do agencies perform, to what extent are they involved in policy-making, and what factors influence the quality and
quantity of their participation? This introductory article gives an overview of key concepts such as ‘‘public agencies’’ and ‘‘policy
autonomy’’ and the research literature. Moreover, it critically discusses relevant theoretical perspectives, outlines the articles
included in this themed issue and argues for a more systematic and theoretically guided analysis of agencies’ role in policy-making.
# 2012 Policy and Society Associates (APSS). Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Public agencies; Policy-making; Policy cycle; Delegation; Autonomy; Principal–agent analysis

1. Introduction: why should we study the role of agencies in policy-making?

This themed issue brings together several articles on the role that government agencies play in policy-making
processes. The policy activities of government agencies (a more precise definition follows below) constitute an
important aspect of their autonomy vis-à-vis their political principals and we claim that there is a need for a more
systematic, theoretically guided analysis on the role of agencies in policy-making. The articles in this collection take a
step in this direction.
There is an extensive literature on the proliferation of agencies (or ‘‘agencification’’ as it is often somewhat
clumsily labeled) and the delegation of authority to such bodies across different countries (Christensen & Lægreid,
2006; Lægreid & Verhoest, 2010; Pollitt & Talbot, 2004; Verhoest, Van Thiel, Bouckaert, & Lægreid, 2012). This
literature has expanded in recent years in response to the spread of agencification within the context of New Public
Management (NPM) reforms. A lot of this research addresses whether these administrative reforms have been
implemented according to the original objectives, and what consequences – intended or unintended – the reforms have
produced. The main focus of this literature is on different aspects of the managerial autonomy of public agencies, for
example agencies’ accountability toward politicians and stakeholders; the use and effects of performance management

* Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: bach@ipw.uni-hannover.de (T. Bach), Birgitta.Niklasson@pol.gu.se (B. Niklasson), samartin@cityu.edu.hk (M. Painter).

1449-4035/$ – see front matter # 2012 Policy and Society Associates (APSS). Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.polsoc.2012.07.001
184 T. Bach et al. / Policy and Society 31 (2012) 183–193

techniques; and problems of coordination across organizational borders. Yet much of this research lacks an explicit
link to the literature on the policy-making functions of public bureaucracies and their interactions with elected
politicians.
There is an implicit assumption in the NPM agencification model that, in return for enhanced managerial autonomy,
agencies will refrain from becoming involved in policy-making. If this proposition has been fulfilled, agency policy
autonomy should be more restricted after NPM reforms. But has this indeed been so? What are the consequences of
agencification for the policy process at large? What policy-relevant tasks do agencies perform? To what extent are they
involved in policy-making? What factors influence the quality and quantity of their participation? These are the
general questions addressed by the introductory article and the individual articles in this themed issue.
All these questions touch upon the perennial question of democratic control of the bureaucracy (Aberbach &
Rockman, 2006; Painter & Yee, 2011; Svara, 2006). This question is concerned with what the division of labor
between democratically supported political leaders and the civil service looks like and whether it conforms to some
kind of ideal-type. Researchers on these fields are far from reaching an agreement on what the ideal should be,
whether different ideals can in fact be reached (and in that case how), and how close to the ideals we are today. Our
hope is primarily that this issue will shed some more light on the last of these questions. However, before taking a
closer look at the ideals that have been suggested, we clarify what we mean by ‘‘public agencies’’ and by ‘‘policy
autonomy’’.

2. What do we mean by ‘‘public agencies’’?

In many countries ‘‘agency’’ is used as a generic term for all kinds of public organizations and will include ‘‘central
agencies’’ headed by ministers as well as ‘‘executive agencies’’ headed by public officials. The articles in this issue
explicitly focus on the latter group. The organizations studied in this themed issue are public sector organizations
structurally separated from the government offices but ‘‘close enough to permit ministers/secretaries of state to alter
the budgets and main operational goals of the organization’’ (Pollitt, Talbot, Caulfield, & Smullen, 2004, p. 10). Thus,
they belong to the wide range of semi-autonomous bodies that Chester (1953) places in his third category of public
sector organizations (the first being departments; the second, local authorities; and the third, ‘‘the rest’’). According to
Thynne (2004) agencies are ‘‘executive bodies, as well as those statutory bodies which are not incorporated and do not
have responsibilities that rightly distance them from ministerial oversight and direction (. . .). They are all public law,
non-ministerial organisations which relate to ministers or the government as agents to a principal.’’ (p. 96). This
category also covers organizations sometimes discussed in terms of quasi-non-governmental organizations (quangos),
fringe bodies, and non-departmental public bodies (Wettenhall, 2003). We will refer to these organizations as
government agencies, or just agencies. Whereas some countries have a long tradition of delegation to public agencies
(such as Sweden, Germany, or the US) others (such as the UK, the Netherlands, or Belgium) have only more recently,
as participants in the agencification trend, witnessed an increase in the number of such bodies.
Formally, the main task of these agencies is usually some form of policy implementation, such as service delivery,
regulation or exercising different kinds of public authority (Pollitt et al., 2004; Van Thiel, 2012; Thynne, 2004).
Normally policy formulation is formally the task of the ministerial departments (which we will also refer to as the
parent ministries) and possibly the ministerial cabinets. The chief executives of agencies are usually civil servants,
who are appointed by the government or the minister in charge. In most countries, the political responsibility for the
activities of the agencies also remains with the ministers or – like in Sweden – with the cabinet.
These agencies are thus not strictly comparable to many US agencies, which are ‘‘caught in the middle’’ (Weingast,
2005) between Presidential and Congressional influence. In parliamentary contexts, the control of agencies by the
legislature, by and large, takes place via the parent ministry and the politically responsible minister. All empirical
articles in this collection focus on agencies in parliamentary systems of government, with the partial exception of the
contribution on Hong Kong agencies. However, Hong Kong has a machinery of government inherited from British rule
that strongly resembles the ‘‘ministerial’’ governments typically found in parliamentary systems.
To sum up, the agencies covered in this themed issue operate at arm’s length from their political principals and
enjoy some degree of autonomy. However, it is generally assumed that they possess little, if any, policy autonomy. In
the following section we clarify what we mean by ‘‘policy autonomy’’ and outline the empirical literature on public
agencies’ policy autonomy.
T. Bach et al. / Policy and Society 31 (2012) 183–193 185

3. Policy autonomy

The concept of autonomy refers to a capacity to act independently from the control of other actors. In our context, it
relates in the first instance to a dependency relationship between two or more actors, one or more of whom are formally
configured as superior or supervising actors (the ‘‘principals’’). In parliamentary systems of government, in addition to
the competencies delegated to agencies by statute, agency autonomy is a function of the delegation of roles and
competencies from the parent ministry. We focus on one particular aspect of agency autonomy, namely policy
autonomy, which can then be understood as the degree of policy-making competency enjoyed by an agency in relation
to its parent ministry (Verhoest, Peters, Bouckaert, & Verschuere, 2004). However, policy-making competencies come
in many forms because policy-making is a complex process in which there are multiple roles. Thus, the degree of
policy autonomy can vary across different roles in the policy process.
A fruitful distinction to make at the outset is that between formal and de facto autonomy. The actual (de facto)
policy autonomy that agencies enjoy may diverge from their formal policy autonomy (what the agency’s statute and
other legal documents specify as the appropriate agency role in policy-making) (Yesilkagit, 2004). All the papers in
this issue aim at describing and explaining the de facto political autonomy of public agencies.
The concept of policy autonomy is closely linked to Carpenter’s notion of ‘‘bureaucratic autonomy’’ which he
defines as a situation in which ‘‘politically differentiated agencies take sustained patterns of action consistent with
their own wishes, patterns that will be not checked or reversed by elected authorities, organized interests, or courts.’’
(Carpenter, 2001, p. 14). In other words, bureaucratically autonomous agencies are able to sustain preferred policies
through their administrative actions (perhaps against demands for change); they are capable of designing new policies
according to their own preferences; they may fight for those policies in the public realm; and their actions may change
the policy preferences of their ‘‘principals’’, potentially with the result of new authoritative policy enactments. The
bureaucratic autonomy perspective is useful because of its explicit focus on power and influence over policy outcomes
through multiple agency interventions in different stages of the policy process. In addition it highlights the possible
importance of a wider stage of action and of actors than simply the dyadic relationship of minister and agency.
Agencies’ relations of dependency with these actors (organized interests, clients and ‘stakeholders’ more generally)
may also significantly affect their policy autonomy vis-à-vis ministers and parent ministries.
A bureaucratic autonomy perspective in one sense turns the policy-operations split on its head and argues that
granting autonomy (of any kind) may result in an enhanced policy role for an agency. The empirical task becomes one
of observing the impacts of an agency on policy-making and policy outcomes across all phases of the policy cycle. We
argue that a distinction should be made between (1) agency involvement in and influence over authoritative policy
decisions and (2) agency involvement in and influence over a wider range of decisions and actions that significantly
affect policy outcomes, which we propose as a measure of policy autonomy more generally. These dimensions
essentially reflect different stages of the policy process, which will be elaborated in more detail below.
Scattered findings on agencies’ policy autonomy can be gleaned from a diverse existing literature. First, it is a
common finding that agencies do have policy roles and functions. A quantitative, comparative study analyzing the
perceived policy autonomy of agencies in Flanders, Ireland, and Norway (Verhoest, Roness, Verschuere, Rubecksen,
& MacCarthaigh, 2010) found that perceived policy autonomy is fairly high in all three countries, particularly among
older agencies. In an in-depth case study, Egeberg (1995) compares the role of two central agencies in transportation
policy in Norway. He finds that a lot of policy formulation takes place at the agency level and attributes variation across
agencies to organizational factors at the ministry and agency level. In a cross-national design based on survey data,
Maggetti (2009) analyzes the ‘‘centrality’’ of regulatory agencies in specific policy processes and finds that regulatory
agencies generally had central positions in those processes. Substantial policy-making activities among agencies are
also detected in the Netherlands (Yesilkagit & Van Thiel, 2008) and Germany (Bach, 2010).
Policy involvement has been found to vary according to formal roles and functions. Agencies do not all conform to
a single blueprint. In the UK, different mixtures of formal roles can be found, with some agencies having only
executive tasks, others having both policy and executive tasks, and a third type sharing both functions with the parent
department (Talbot, 2004). This variety is reflected both in formal mandates such as executive agencies’ framework
documents and also theses agencies’ de facto involvement in policy formulation (Gains, 2003). Yesilkagit and Van
Thiel (2008) found significant differences between legal types, suggesting that politicians may be more willing to
delegate policy roles where they can exercise close oversight. An in-depth case study of the participation of a large
service delivery agency in Flanders in two policy processes explains variation in the agency’s influence by the agency’s
186 T. Bach et al. / Policy and Society 31 (2012) 183–193

capacity for policy development, the agency’s policy preferences, and the political principal’s willingness to include
the agency in the policy process (Verschuere, 2009; Verschuere & Bach, 2012).
Cross-national differences have also been observed, pointing to the importance of national traditions and contexts.
Elder and Page (1998) compare the policy roles of agencies in Sweden and Germany. A key finding is that Swedish
agencies seem to have more extensive policy-making roles compared to their German counterparts. This difference is
attributed to the consensus-orientation of the Swedish politico-administrative system (i.e. many issues which in other
contexts would be considered ‘‘policy’’ are understood as ‘‘operational’’) and the consultation procedure during which
‘‘draft reports of commissions of inquiry intended to lead to legislation are circulated to interested administrative
agencies inter alia for their comments’’ (Elder & Page, 1998, p. 37). They report several episodes of policies that
originated in public agencies, which does not seem to represent a consistent pattern, though. According to Pierre
(2004) several Swedish agencies have become ‘‘sources of policy’’ in the 1990s and have ‘‘either put forward
extensive policy proposals or – by virtue of their institutional autonomy – formulated programs to guide their actions’’
(pp. 210–212).
In sum, the involvement of agencies in policy formulation is quite common, even in contexts where norms of
separating policy and operations prevail. This is the case both for NPM-type agencies and for other types. Moreover,
agency involvement in policy formulation comes in many guises, such as developing policy proposals, drafting laws
and regulations, commenting on draft laws in order to assess the practicability of policy proposals, evaluating existing
policies, or formulating programs or rules as part of the agency’s formal sphere of authority. Several studies suggest
that agencies’ contributions to policy formulation by and large are based on their experiential knowledge from policy
implementation. Also, parent ministries seem to have a gatekeeping function with regard to agencies’ policy
participation. Finally, the literature review underlines the relevance of politico-administrative contexts, something that
is also followed up by some of the studies in this issue (Niklasson & Pierre, 2012; Painter & Yee, 2012; Verschuere &
Vancoppenolle, 2012). In the next section we link the literature on agencies’ policy autonomy to a ‘‘stages’’ or ‘‘policy
cycle’’ understanding of the policy process.

4. Ideal roles in the policy cycle

Mintrom (2012) defines public policies as ‘‘the choices that governments make on behalf of citizens living in their
jurisdictions. These choices are codified in the rules, plans, principles, and strategies that guide government action’’
(pp. 1–2). This definition presents a somewhat static picture of public policy, but it is important from our perspective to
recognize that it also a dynamic process. Policies are complex series of decisions that stretch over long periods of time.
‘‘Policy in action’’ involves a series of stages and events, sometimes depicted in simplified form as a policy cycle.
Standard models describe a series of stages such as problem-definition, agenda-setting and advocacy, setting of goals
and targets, formulation and analysis of options, selection of the preferred option, policy implementation, evaluation,
and feedback (for critical reviews of these models see Colebatch, 2006; Jann & Wegrich, 2007).
One common way of defining the ideal roles of politicians and civil servants in the policy process is to tie these
actors to a specific part of the policy cycle. An ideal that was advocated many years ago by prominent scholars such as
Weber (1978) and Wilson (1887) is that policies should be formulated by politicians and implemented by civil
servants. Thus, all stages except for the implementation, evaluation, and feedback stages should be the domain of the
politicians and the later stages should be that of the civil servants (Hill, 2009). The ideas of NPM, which started to
spread in the 1980s, pushed for administrative reforms that were in line with this ideal (Hood, 1995). The principle of a
policy-administration dichotomy was given fresh impetus in NPM by drawing on principal–agent theories of
delegation, in which a dichotomous division of roles and responsibilities was a central feature (Verschuere, 2009). This
resulted in the agencification trend; in many countries, agencies were created or reformed in ways inspired by NPM-
thinking (Van Thiel, 2012). New public agencies, operating ‘‘at arm’s length’’ from their political principals, were
founded in order to secure the managerial autonomy of the civil service in the implementation process. One idea
behind these reforms was that agencies should become more like private companies, supposedly leading to efficiency
gains. Overarching policies, on the other hand, were to be created by politicians with the support of ministerial
departments and policy staffs.
There are both normative and also empirical objections to the ideal division of labor within the policy cycle as
presented above, however. From a democratic point of view, one could claim that it is legitimate for politicians to
exercise control over the outputs of the civil service, including the implementation process. Reserving the latter for the
T. Bach et al. / Policy and Society 31 (2012) 183–193 187

experts suggests technocracy, not democracy. Politicians, not civil servants, will be held accountable for government
output, including the acts of the administrators. Leaving the normative arguments aside, from an empirical viewpoint it
is hard to keep the policy stages apart in practice, since different parts of the policy cycle may be occurring
simultaneously. For example, elaboration and measurement of the pros and cons of different options (which is mostly a
technical process often done by professional civil servants) can help to re-formulate the problem or to envisage
different goals and targets (which is what political leaders should be doing). The stages may even occur in a different
order; the analysis of options may be retrospective, so as to demonstrate that the preferred option is the right one.
Similarly, there is no sharp distinction between when a policy is created and when it is implemented. Policy decisions
can just as well be made during the implementation stages of the policy process as during the earlier stages. As part of
their implementation role, agencies are often delegated the power to make decisions on what tools and methods should
be used in order to achieve a goal that has been set up by the politicians. These kinds of decisions contribute to the
shaping of the policy in significant ways and they certainly affect the outcome and the future development of the
policy. Decisions made by agencies during the implementation stages can therefore be viewed as policy-making
decisions (Howlett, Ramesh, & Perl, 2009; Jann & Wegrich, 2007; Verschuere, 2009). Hence, several researchers refer
to agencies’ authority to make these kinds of operational decisions as policy autonomy (Yesilkagit & Van Thiel, 2008)
or implementation autonomy (Bach, 2010).
Policies are in fact going through constant change and re-formulation throughout the whole policy cycle.
Consequently, there is also not a simple or neat fit of roles for different actors in the policy cycle that can be captured in
formal statements. In reality, the policy roles occupied by political and administrative leaders are diverse and multiple.
Moreover, roles and contributions are not static. Societal pressures and events continually place agency chiefs and
politicians in new situations to which they must respond (indeed, politicians often respond by diving headlong into the
details of agency administration) (Pollitt et al., 2004). In the process, agency chiefs are called upon both to use their
administrative discretion and also to perform roles in on-going deliberative (or policy) processes. While they may
recognize limits and constraints on their roles due to the nature of the formal delegations that constitute their office,
their de facto discretion (the space they enjoy to define their own roles) may be extensive. For example, policy-making
includes giving and receiving advice based on various forms of knowledge, which comes from many quarters
including administrators. In a technical sphere (so long as it remains defined as such), agency chiefs may well be
trusted for their policy knowledge and advice, primarily because they are considered better at understanding a
particular field and it has become the norm that they take the lead (Gains, 2003).
There are clearly conflicting considerations and criteria on how to divide roles and functions in the policy process
between political and administrative actors, or ‘principal and agent’. But in spite of the problems related to attempts to
distinguish neatly between policy-making activities and roles in different stages of the policy cycle, this framework
allows us to analyze and compare the involvement of agencies in the policy process systematically through observing
their different contributions. Several papers in this issue mainly look at the earlier stages of the policy cycle, that is,
those before the actual implementation (Bach, 2012; Handke, 2012; Niklasson & Pierre, 2012), but some articles cover
the whole policy cycle (Painter & Yee, 2012; Verschuere & Vancoppenolle, 2012).

5. Theoretical perspectives in the study of government agencies

This section highlights how the approach to the study of policy autonomy in this themed issue relates to some of the
main theoretical perspectives in contemporary research on government agencies. Much of the discussion of agency
roles in the traditional public administration literature is embedded in theories of ‘formal institutionalism’. That is, the
starting proposition is that the legal-formal definitions of institutional rules and structures primarily determine
behaviour and outcomes (Moe, 1997). However, as our conceptual discussion has already argued, formal and
structural explanations must be supplemented by theoretical understandings of the informal dimensions of agency
roles and contributions within a wider social and political context. But staying with institutional approaches for the
moment, a powerful strand of theory in the literature is drawn from rational choice institutionalism. The delegation
perspective on agencies assumes that political decision-makers delegate authority to (executive) agencies which may
behave as rational agents pursuing their own preferences, which differ from those of their political principals. There is
now a vast literature on how politicians supposedly engage in deliberately designing administrative structures and
procedures in order to curb agency discretion and to prevent bureaucratic drift (Braun & Gilardi, 2006; Huber &
Shipan, 2002; Pollack, 2002).
188 T. Bach et al. / Policy and Society 31 (2012) 183–193

Our conceptual analysis has already covered ground that suggests this approach is of limited application for
understanding the policy roles of agencies. The dichotomous division of labor between politicians and civil servants
implicit in delegation theories and principal–agent accounts of politico-administrative relations is notoriously slippery
in principle and it is even more difficult to sustain in practice. The assumption that policy is equated with goals or
strategy is not always helpful in analyzing how policy and administrative decisions are actually made. One meaning of
policy to a politician is whatever, for the moment, is politically controversial (Pollitt et al., 2004). This does not always
include policy in the sense conveyed in principal–agent theory but it often includes operations, particularly when they
go wrong. Most scandals are generally revealed in the detail, not the big picture, at which point politicians cannot but
escape being directly engaged. This confusion of roles may work the other way round as well. Sometimes, policy may
be delegated where governments are facing a hot potato and see no way out, other than to shift the blame or put it off by
‘passing the parcel’. Other times, they are pressured to intervene reluctantly by public demand and media criticism.
What politicians accept responsibility for is always politically contingent and does not conform to neat, logical
prescriptions. More generally, the strong focus of the delegation literature on formal structures as means of preventing
‘‘bureaucratic drift’’ of agencies tends to underestimate the dynamics of politico-administrative relations in the post-
delegation stage.
A further confounding factor for an unambiguous principal–agent view of the policy process is that there are layers
of principals and agents, not just one relationship. In the case of Hong Kong, for example, the principal official (a
position similar to a minister) is clearly the principal in relations with the permanent head of the policy bureau
(equivalent to a ministry). For most purposes, however, the head of the bureau is viewed as the principal by the
department or agency head, although the latter is supposedly conveying the principal officials’ preferences. Exactly
who might be pulling the wool over whose eyes is not always clear. In this sense, studying the policy autonomy of
agencies in many instances will necessarily have to focus on ministry–agency relations, rather than minister–agency
relations, or perhaps triadic constellations involving all three parties (Gains, 2003).
Most theories of agency delegation do not in fact discuss policy autonomy (Bendor, Glazer, & Hammond, 2001;
Moe, 1997; Pollack, 2002). They talk about agency autonomy in a broader sense. They do not even always focus on
delegation between ministries or departments and agencies; they talk more generally about delegation between voters
and elected representatives, legislators to the executive branch, the government to different ministries, and ministries
to agencies. They have used game theory and rational choice models in order to decide when a principal is likely to
delegate power to an agent. Pollack (2002) concludes that it is (1) when there is only imperfect information available
and there is a demand for policy-relevant expertise, (2) when the politicians need to be tied down to making credible
commitments and there is a demand for independent, credible agents, and (3) when there are conflicting preferences
among principals and between principals and agents. However, this body of literature tends to be almost exclusively
focused on the US context and more particularly on the legislative policy-making. Moreover, these studies generally
pay little attention to the mechanisms underlying how organizational structure and agency tasks shape the de facto
autonomy of public agencies (Painter & Yee, 2011).
The shortcomings of principal–agent analysis for our purposes suggest also that a starting point in NPM views of
the world will not be particularly fruitful. Many researchers take their starting point in NPM, at least for formulating
working hypotheses (Gains, 2003; Verhoest et al., 2010; Verschuere, 2009; Yesilkagit, 2004). However, because
NPM does not represent a coherent theory, analyses that explicitly tests propositions concerning the implementation
of NPM on the organizational level, or the fit between empirical findings and NPM models and prescriptions often
leads to suggestions for other analytical perspectives. For example, a fundamental problem of rationalistic
approaches is highlighted by Yesilkagit (2004), who aptly summarizes the implications of agencification for the
policy process:
What does happen when the agency is formally established and left alone to perform its tasks? How does the
political world become a different place? What is the nature of the interactions between the agency and the
political and administrative actors in this new environment? (Yesilkagit, 2004, p. 534).
He proceeds by arguing that rational choice accounts of delegation assume that principals and agents instantly adapt
their behavior to the new circumstances, which seems to be an all too optimistic assumption. He claims that ‘‘game
theories of delegation neglect the time period newly established political actors need to understand and interpret the
rules that are in play after the delegation decision’’ (Yesilkagit, 2004, p. 535). Drawing on Berger and Luckmann’s
(1966) ideas of the social construction of reality, Yesilkagit addresses these weaknesses by using the concept of
T. Bach et al. / Policy and Society 31 (2012) 183–193 189

habituation, which describes the process of institutionalization: ‘‘It refers to the initial steps human actors take when
they encounter a world of a social state of affairs that was unknown to them before.’’ (Yesilkagit, 2004, p. 536).
Variables such as time and the degree of ‘habituation’ by actors to new roles and relationships bring into play
historical, social and political dimensions that economistic theories of delegation and principal–agent interaction
exclude. For example, Gains (2003) takes her starting point in policy network and power dependency theory. She
claims that this kind of approach is fruitful when analyzing the impact of agencification on policy outcomes:
The differential financial, legal, managerial and structural autonomies granted to agencies clearly led to differing
relationships between agencies and the parent department and its minister. Agencification in each case led to the
necessity for agency and department to exchange resources to achieve their goals. This process created power
dependent networks operating under formal and informal rules of the game (Gains, 2003, p. 75).
This research shows that even though ‘‘[a]gencies were deliberately set up to implement and not make policy (. . .)
these ‘bureaucratic’ networks did impact on policy outcomes’’ in various ways (Gains, 2003, p. 74). For instance, the
author demonstrates that agencies may have a strong influence on the definition of operational goals and may even
determine the general policy agenda, depending on the type of resource exchange involved.
In this collection, the authors do not adopt a single theoretical approach or test a common set of propositions drawn
from a single perspective. Historical institutionalism is perhaps the most common, but not the only, starting point for
the separate authors. That aside, they have in common the view that policy autonomy is a feature of social and political
relationships within a complex, on-going set of processes that constitute policy-making. Just as they adopt varying
theoretical perspectives they also adopt different methodologies, in common with the approaches already adopted in
the literature: single country or cross-country comparative analysis using survey data, in which many variables are
controlled for one another (Verhoest et al., 2010); qualitative comparative approaches (Maggetti, 2009; Pollitt et al.,
2004); and single-country case study analysis based on rigorous data collection (Carpenter, 2001; Egeberg, 1995;
Verschuere, 2009).

6. The articles in this issue

The article by Birgitta Niklasson and Jon Pierre takes a historical-institutionalist perspective on agencies’ policy
autonomy in Sweden. The main theoretical claim is that the norms and values regarding agencies’ role in policy-
making which dominated at the time of agency creation have a long-lasting effect on those agencies. Such norms and
values can grow to permeate the entire organizational structure and it may take a substantial policy shift or radical
administrative reform – often connected to a crisis situation or severe performance failure – to change them. The
introduction of Program Budgeting in 1963 is depicted as such a paradigm shift, whereas administrative reforms
following NPM ideas starting from 1990 are something like ‘‘variations on a theme’’ which have not altered the
administrative system in a similar way as the earlier reforms. The authors test their hypothesis based on a
comprehensive survey of Swedish agencies, complemented with other sources. Moreover, they control for variables
related to the agencies’ external relationships, their tasks and their organizational structure. The empirical analysis
confirms that indeed agencies founded before 1963 even today report higher levels of policy autonomy than agencies
founded after 1963, whereas agencies created after the NPM reforms do not report higher levels of policy autonomy.
Also, the analysis reveals that in addition to the variable measuring the period of creation, the level of public attention
has the strongest effect on agencies’ policy autonomy. This corresponds to the survey findings of Bach (2012), but
contradicts the case study findings of Handke (2012) who finds that high salience reduces policy autonomy because the
ministry takes over activities previously performed by the agency.
The contribution of Tobias Bach covers the involvement of agencies in policy formulation in Germany, analyzing a
comprehensive survey among federal agencies. The politico-administrative context is characterized by strong norms
of separating policy and operations among ministries and agencies. Against the background of – mostly anecdotal –
evidence of agency involvement in policy formulation and a supposed decline in the importance of ministerial
bureaucracies in policy formulation, the article aims at explaining variation in policy autonomy by referring to agency
features related to task, structure and culture. The empirical findings confirm a high degree of variation in policy
autonomy among federal agencies. Moreover, it shows that task characteristics seem to be most relevant for explaining
variation in policy autonomy, although the research also finds significant effects of structural and cultural
characteristics. Among other things, the political salience of an agency is identified as an important task characteristic
190 T. Bach et al. / Policy and Society 31 (2012) 183–193

for explaining policy autonomy, a finding which is also made by Niklasson and Pierre (2012). Also, contrary to many
recent writings about the supposedly increasing power of regulatory agencies over policy decisions, the analysis does
not support those claims.
The article by Martin Painter and Wai-Hang Yee addresses the empirical puzzle raised by an earlier survey that
senior executives of Hong Kong agencies report high levels of policy autonomy, regardless of organizational form. To
this end, the authors conducted case studies of several Hong Kong agencies and their relationships with their political
principals. The case studies exemplify different types of agencies’ policy roles and rationales of politicians to delegate
policy autonomy. The first type refers to a segmentation of policy fields, which may either take place through
deliberate delegation of policy autonomy for specific parts of a policy field (while still keeping an eye on the agency’s
activities) or through permanent delegation on part of the government in less salient policy fields. The second type of
dividing policy roles among political executives and agency executives consists of a segmentation of the policy
process, which may for instance take place through agencies having a strong role in agenda-setting or high levels of
discretion in policy implementation. In theoretical terms, the case studies illustrate the poor performance of well-
known accounts of separating policy and operations and conflicting interests among political principals and
administrative agents in explaining the policy roles of agency executives in a system of government characterized by a
tightly integrated political and administrative elite. In such a context, decision-making may better be explained from a
cultural perspective which explains decision-making as matching of behaviour with role expectations (a ‘‘logic of
appropriateness’’). The segmentation of policy fields and processes can be understood as a mechanism to avoid
competition over control of policy, which would inevitably create conflict within a political and administrative elite
that highly values consensus and cooperation.
In his article Stefan Handke studies the roles and inter-organizational relations of the German Ministry of Finance
and the Financial Supervisory Authority in financial market policy. Similar to the contributions of Verschuere/
Vancoppenolle and Painter/Yee this is a qualitative study mainly based on expert interviews with senior officials and
politicians. Handke argues that the relationship between the ministry and the agency is characterized by a substantial
imbalance in terms of expertise and manpower to the detriment of the ministry’s capacity in policy formulation and
control of the agencies’ operational activities. This imbalance became obvious during the financial crisis in 2008. A
key finding is that the ministry heavily depends on the regulatory agency in daily business (including the development
of regulatory standards and the like) and lacks qualified personnel to effectively control the agency. The control
problems are particularly obvious in the context of EU or transnational agency networks in which the agency is heavily
involved. Also, the article shows that the agency is better characterized as a ‘‘trustee’’ acting on behalf of consumers
and market participants rather than an ‘‘agent’’ acting on behalf of the ministry. Although the agency has been formally
delegated wide-ranging operational as well as standard-setting tasks by law, yet the ministry may hierarchically
instruct the agency on any matter. Thus in formal terms the agency is not legally independent, yet in practice it has a lot
of autonomy both in terms of implementation as well as policy formulation. Also, the article addresses the agency’s
preferences, i.e. what do agencies actually want? Three orientations are described, namely organizational survival and
growth (‘‘budget maximization’’), bureaucratic discretion, efficient policies and organizational reputation (‘‘policy
seeking’’), and a convenient job (‘‘bureau shaping’’). Handke shows that the policy autonomy of the agency may also
be explained by deliberate delegation of policy functions to the agency by the ministry, which was not considered
problematic under conditions of low political salience (see also the article by Painter and Yee on how political
bureaucracies deliberately vacate policy space which is filled by agencies).
The article by Bram Verschuere and Diederik Vancoppenolle investigates the roles of ministers and their political
advisors, ministerial departments and semi-autonomous agencies in two policy processes in Flanders (Belgium). The
case of Flanders allows for a straightforward empirical test of how the separation of policy and operations works in
practice, which was at the core of a comprehensive administrative reform heavily inspired by NPM thinking. The
authors study policy decisions in the fields of social policy (care for disabled people) and transport policy (public
transport), in which the agencies responsible for operations were involved in various stages. Several key findings
emerge from their study: First, they show that a dyadic model of department–agency relations fails to account for the
high influence of ministers and their ‘‘cabinets’’ of political advisers. In the policy processes they study, policy related
interactions take place between the cabinets and senior agency officials, literally by-passing the ministerial
departments which according to the reform objectives should be the primary policy advisers of the ministers. This
suggests that management reforms might be ‘‘blind’’ to the reality of political decision making, which in the case of
Flanders (and presumably other countries with cabinets of political appointees) relies heavily on ministerial cabinets.
T. Bach et al. / Policy and Society 31 (2012) 183–193 191

Second, their work indicates a rather clear division of tasks between the political leadership (ministers and cabinets)
and agencies: whereas ministers and cabinets decide on strategic lines and supervise the further steps in the decision-
making process, the influence of the agencies is higher in the stages where strategic decisions need to be made
operational. Thus, there seems to be some division of labor along the policy-operations dimensions, yet agencies are
granted substantial autonomy in putting general policy lines into practice. Finally, they emphasize that executive
agencies are not homogeneous actors when it comes to policy formulation, as representatives of stakeholder groups in
the agency’s governing board may be involved at various stages of the decision process.
To summarize, besides variation in terms of context and methodology, the articles in this collection also vary in
terms of their empirical and theoretical approaches. Several studies are rich in quite detailed description, looking into
what role specific government agencies play in the policy-making process (Handke, 2012; Painter & Yee, 2012;
Verschuere & Vancoppenolle, 2012). These studies use different theoretically-grounded scenarios of role divisions
among oversight authorities and agencies (Verschuere & Vancoppenolle, 2012); political explanations for ‘voluntary
vacancy’ by political leaders and segmentation of the policy process between different actors (Painter & Yee, 2012);
and formal delegation approaches such as principal–agent and trustee theory (Handke, 2012), to structure the case
analysis. Other studies in this collection aim at explaining the level of policy autonomy of government agencies by
drawing on comprehensive survey material which allows for multivariate testing of hypotheses (Bach, 2012;
Niklasson & Pierre, 2012). Yet another group of studies improves our understanding of the effect of specific
explanatory variables by analyzing causal mechanisms over time. This particularly applies to the study by Niklasson
and Pierre, who provide an in-depth account of how ‘‘critical junctures’’ in history affect policy autonomy.

7. Conclusion

This introductory article had several objectives: first, we reviewed the empirical literature on the role of agencies in
policy-making and set out the research agenda of the themed issue. Then we proceeded with some conceptual
clarifications of ‘‘public agencies’’ and ‘‘policy autonomy’’, using the policy cycle framework for studying agencies’
policy-making roles in the different stages of the policy process. Such an approach allows for a systematic empirical
scrutiny and comparison of agencies’ bureaucratic autonomy while acknowledging the complexity and contingency of
the policy process.
There are many different ways through which public agencies potentially contribute to ‘‘who gets what, when, and
how’’. This variety is reflected in the contributions included in this themed issue, which address agency contributions
to policy in different stages of the policy process. In terms of theoretical approaches, we argue that rational choice
institutionalism and principal–agent accounts of delegation offer only limited insights into de facto bureaucratic
autonomy. Partly, this can be related to a bias in this literature toward legislative control over bureaucracy, which tends
to reduce the bureaucracy to an instrument in achieving political ends (Moe, 1997). For instance, as indicated by the
Hong Kong paper, agencies’ policy autonomy is not necessarily the result of a power struggle between politicians and
the agencies. Instead, the level of policy autonomy appears to be a consequence of political unwillingness (disinterest).
We briefly outlined more promising theoretical angles which are also used in the contributions in this themed issue.
These include approaches rooted in historical institutionalism, resource dependency theory, and contingency theory of
organizational structure. In the remainder of the conclusion, we highlight some ‘‘loose ends’’ which will require
further attention in the future.
The contributions in this themed issue cover the role of agencies in policy-making in different parts of the world.
However, none of the contributions is explicitly comparative in character. Nevertheless, the articles contain (mostly
implicit) assumptions about how politico-administrative contexts affect the phenomenon under scrutiny, which may
guide future research. For instance, the article on Hong Kong (Painter & Yee, 2012) suggests that similar role
perceptions and career patterns of politicians and senior bureaucrats open up for potentially high degrees of agency
policy autonomy. The other articles pay less attention to the question whether politicians and agency officials share
similar values and career patterns, though. More generally, studies on politico–administrative relations focus on senior
ministry bureaucrats, rather than agency executives (Aberbach & Rockman, 2006). Taking into consideration the
growth in the number of public agencies, we believe that senior agency bureaucrats deserve more attention in this kind
of research.
Another dimension of comparison is more explicitly related to the formal institutional context and the effect of
administrative reforms. As the Swedish article (Niklasson & Pierre, 2012) shows, administrative reforms may
192 T. Bach et al. / Policy and Society 31 (2012) 183–193

have a profound effect on the role of agencies in policy-making. The contribution on agencies in Flanders
(Verschuere & Vancoppenolle, 2012) illustrates very well how structural changes create confusion about
appropriate roles in policy-making. The articles show that creating or reforming of agencies is not a mere
technical or managerial issue, even though it may sometimes be labeled as such by decision-makers. A more
general point is that reform history needs to be taken into account when studying and comparing agency roles in
policy-making. For instance, the creation of agencies will almost inevitably lead to more complex relationships
which more often than not will involve multiple principals and stakeholders (Verschuere & Vancoppenolle,
2012). Thus, in order to understand the policy role of agencies, we possibly need to look at their interactions with
other actors than just the parent ministry, e.g. NGOs, other agencies, and private businesses.
A relevant topic which has been raised in comparative research on ministry–agency relations (although explicitly
excluding the issue of policy autonomy) has to do with the relative explanatory power of context versus task
characteristics. There is reason to believe that agencies providing similar services (e.g. labor market policies) share
many similarities, irrespective of their politico-administrative context. Such a perspective suggests that a structured,
comparative analysis along the lines of Pollitt et al. (2004) could be a way forward to draw more robust inferences on
the relative importance of context for agency policy autonomy. Such an approach could possibly also shed more light
on the question whether regulating agencies play a more pivotal (or perhaps different) part in policy-making than other
kinds of agencies.

Acknowledgements

Most contributors to this themed issue are part of the COBRA and COST-CRIPO networks (see http://
soc.kuleuven.be/io/cost/ for more information). The articles included have been presented on various workshops
organized by these networks, and we thank our colleagues for their helpful comments and support.

References

Aberbach, J., & Rockman, B. (2006). The past and future of political–administrative relations: Research from ‘‘bureaucrats and politicians’’ to ‘‘in
the web of politics’’ and beyond. International Journal of Public Administration, 29(12), 977–995.
Bach, T. (2010). Policy and management autonomy of federal agencies in Germany. In P. Lægreid & K. Verhoest (Eds.), Governance of public sector
organizations – proliferation, autonomy and performance (pp. 89–110). Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Bach, T. (2012). The involvement of agencies in policy formulation: explaining variation in policy autonomy of federal agencies in Germany. Policy
and Society, 31(3), 211–222.
Bendor, J., Glazer, A., & Hammond, T. (2001). Theories of delegation. Annual Review of Political Science, 4, 235–269.
Berger, P. L., & Luckmann, T. (1966). The social construction of reality: A treatise in the sociology of knowledge. Middlesex, UK: Penguin Books.
Braun, D., & Gilardi, F. (Eds.). (2006). Delegation in contemporary democracies. London: Routledge.
Carpenter, D. P. (2001). The forging of bureaucratic autonomy: reputations, networks, and policy innovation in executive agencies, 1862–1928.
Princeton, N.J. Princeton University Press.
Chester, D. N. (1953). Public corporations and the classification of administrative bodies. Political Studies, 1(1), 34–52.
Christensen, T., & Lægreid, P. (Eds.). (2006). Autonomy and regulation: Coping with agencies in the modern state. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Colebatch, H. K. (2006). Beyond the policy cycle: The policy process in Australia. Sydney: Allen and Unwin.
Egeberg, M. (1995). The policy administration dichotomy revisited: The case of transport infrastructure planning in Norway. International Review of
Administrative Sciences, 61(4), 565–576.
Elder, N. C. M., & Page, E. C. (1998). Culture and agency: Fragmentation and agency structures in Germany and Sweden. Public Policy and
Administration, 13(4), 28–45.
Gains, F. (2003). Executive agencies in government: The impact of bureaucratic networks on policy outcomes. Journal of Public Policy, 23(1),
55–79.
Handke, S. (2012). A problem of Chief and Indian - The role of the supervisory authority BaFin and the ministry of finance in German financial
market policy. Policy and Society, 31(3), 237–247.
Hill, M. (2009). The public policy process. London: Pearson/Longman.
Hood, C. (1995). Contemporary public management: A new global paradigm? Public Policy and Administration, 10(2), 104–117.
Howlett, M., Ramesh, M., & Perl, A. (2009). Studying public policy: Policy cycles & policy subsystems (3rd ed.). Ontario: Oxford University Press.
Huber, J. D., & Shipan, C. R. (2002). Deliberate discretion? The institutional foundations of bureaucratic autonomy Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Jann, W., & Wegrich, K. (2007). Theories of the policy cycle. In F. Fischer, G. J. Miller, & M. S. Sidney (Eds.), Handbook of public policy analysis:
Theory, politics, and methods (pp. 43–62). Boca Raton (FL): Taylor & Francis.
Lægreid, P., & Verhoest, K. (Eds.). (2010). Governance of public sector organizations – proliferation, autonomy and performance. Hampshire:
Palgrave Macmillan.
T. Bach et al. / Policy and Society 31 (2012) 183–193 193

Maggetti, M. (2009). The role of independent regulatory agencies in policy-making: A comparative analysis. Journal of European Public Policy,
16(3), 450–470.
Mintrom, M. (2012). Contemporary policy analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.
Moe, T. (1997). The positive theory of public bureaucracy. In D. C. Mueller (Ed.), Perspectives on public choice (pp. 455–480). Cambridge, MA:
Cambridge University Press.
Niklasson, B., & Pierre, J. (2012). Does Agency Age Matter in Administrative Reform?: Policy Autonomy and Public Management in Swedish
Agencies. Policy and Society, 31(3), 195–210.
Painter, M., & Yee, W.-H. (2011). Task matters: A structural–instrumental analysis of the autonomy of Hong Kong government bodies. The
American Review of Public Administration, 41(4), 395–410.
Painter, M., & Yee, W.-H. (2012). Agencies and Policy in an Administrative State: the Case of Hong Kong. Policy and Society, 31(3), 223–235.
Pierre, J. (2004). Sweden: Central agencies – a report from Utopia. In C. Pollitt & C. Talbot (Eds.), Unbundled government. A critical analysis of the
global trend to agencies, quangos and contractualisation (pp. 203–214). London, New York: Routledge.
Pollack, M. A. (2002). Learning from the Americanists (again): Theory and method in the study of delegation. West European Politics, 25(1),
200–219.
Pollitt, C., & Talbot, C. (2004). Unbundled government. A critical analysis of the global trend to agencies, quangos and contractualisation.
Routledge: London, New York.
Pollitt, C., Talbot, C., Caulfield, J., & Smullen, A. (2004). Agencies: How governments do things through semi-autonomous organizations.
Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Svara, J. (2006). Introduction: Politicians and administrators in the political process: A review of themes and issues in the literature. International
Journal of Public Administration, 29(12), 953–976.
Talbot, C. (2004). Executive agencies: Have they improved management in government? Public Money & Management, 24(2), 104–112.
Van Thiel, S. (2012). Comparing agencies across countries. In K. Verhoest, S. Van Thiel, G. Bouckaert, & P. Lægreid (Eds.), Government agencies:
Practices and lessons from 30 countries (pp. 18–26). Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Thynne, I. (2004). State organisations as agencies: An identifiable and meaningful focus of research? Public Administration and Development, 24(2),
91–99.
Verhoest, K., Peters, B. G., Bouckaert, G., & Verschuere, B. (2004). The study of organisational autonomy: A conceptual review. Public
Administration and Development, 24(2), 101–118.
Verhoest, K., Roness, P. G., Verschuere, B., Rubecksen, K., & MacCarthaig, M. (2010). Autonomy and control of state agencies: Comparing states
and agencies. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Verhoest, K., Van Thiel, S., Bouckaert, G., & Lægreid, P. (Eds.). (2012). Government agencies: Practices and lessons from 30 countries.
Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Verschuere, B. (2009). The role of public agencies in the policy making process: Rhetoric versus reality. Public Policy and Administration, 24(1),
23–46.
Verschuere, B., & Bach, T. (2012). Executive agencies, ministers, and departments: Can policy and management ever be separated? Administration
& Society, 44(2), 183–206.
Verschuere, B., & Vancoppenolle, D. (2012). Policy-making in an era of agencification: An exploration of task divisions between politicians, core
departments and public agencies. Policy and Society, 31(3), 249–258.
Weber, M. (1978). Economy and society. Berkeley, Los Angeles: University of California Press.
Weingast, B. R. (2005). Caught in the middle: The President, Congress, and the political–bureaucratic system. In J. D. Aberbach & M. A. Peterson
(Eds.), The executive branch (pp. 312–343). Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press.
Wettenhall, R. (2003). Exploring types of public sector organizations: Past exercises and current issues. Public Organization Review, 3(3), 219–245.
Wilson, W. (1887). The study of administration. Political Science Quarterly, 2(2), 197–222.
Yesilkagit, K. (2004). Bureaucratic autonomy organizational culture, and habituation: Politicians and independent administrative bodies in the
Netherlands. Administration & Society, 36(5), 528–552.
Yesilkagit, K., & Van Thiel, S. (2008). Political influence and bureaucratic autonomy. Public Organization Review, 8(2), 137–153.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi