Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 38

Inclusive Wealth

Report 2014
Measuring progress toward sustainability
CONTRIBUTORS
Science Advisory Group Report Director
Partha Dasgupta, Chair – University of Cambridge, Anantha Duraiappah – United Nations Educational,
United Kingdom Scientific and Cultural
Mame Baba Cisse – Ambassador of Senegal in Malaysia, Organization – Mahatma Gandhi Institute of Education
Malaysia for Peace and
Ligia Costa – Fundação Getulio Vargas, Brazil/Institut Sustainable Development, India
d’études politiques de Paris
(Sciences Po), France Science Director
Justin Lin – Peking University, China Pablo Muñoz – United Nations University – International
Jane Lubchenco – Oregon State University, United Human Dimensions Programme on Global
States Environmental Change, Germany
Harold Mooney – Stanford University, United States
Hamid Zakri – Science Advisor to the Prime Minister of Review Board
Malaysia, Malaysia Katharine Abraham – University of Maryland, United
States
Authors Francisco Alpízar – University of Gothenburg, Sweden/
Adnan Alsaati – Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Environment and Development initiative, Costa Rica
United States Paul Chinowsky – University of Colorado, United States
Kenneth Arrow – Stanford University, United States Kanchan Chopra – Institute of Economic Growth, India
Giles Atkinson – London School of Economics and Amrita Ghatak – Gujarat Institute of Development
Political Science, United Kingdom Research, India
Edward Barbier – University of Wyoming, United States Dolf de Groot – Wageningen University, Netherlands
Ross Collins – Massachusetts Institute of Technology, George Halkos – University of Thessaly, Greece
United States Nick Hanley – University of St. Andrews, United Kingdom
Elorm Darkey – University of Milan, Italy/Université Dale Jorgenson – Harvard University, United States
catholique de Louvain, Belgium Gopal Kadekodi – Center for Multidisciplinary
Partha Dasgupta – University of Cambridge, United Development Research, India
Kingdom Chris Kennedy – George Mason University, United States
Anantha Duraiappah – United Nations Educational, Jeremy Lauer – World Health Organization, Switzerland
Scientific and Cultural Organization - Mahatma Gandhi Ramanan Laxminarayan – Environmental Institute
Institute of Education for Peace and Sustainable Center for Disease Dynamics, United States/Princeton
Development, India University, United States
Cecília Fernandes – United Nations University – Andreas Löschel – University of Münster, Germany
International Human Dimensions Programme on Linwood Pendleton – Duke University, United States
Global Environmental Change, Germany Bob Scholes – Council for Scientific and Industrial
Barbara Fraumeni – Central University for Finance and Research, South Africa
Economics, China Mesfin Tilahun – Mekelle University, Ethiopia
Haripriya Gundimeda – Indian Institute of Technology Hui Wei – Australian Bureau of Statistics, Australia
Bombay, India
Nabila Jamshed – United Nations Educational, Scientific
and Cultural Organization - Mahatma Gandhi Institute
of Education for Peace and Sustainable Development,
India
Pushpam Kumar – United Nations Environment
Programme, Kenya
Gang Liu – Statistics Norway, Norway
Shunsuke Managi – Tohoku University, Japan
Kevin Mumford – Purdue University, United States
Pablo Muñoz – United Nations University – International
Human Dimensions Programme on Global
Environmental Change, Germany
Kira Petters – University of Bonn, Germany
Vivek Sakhrani – Massachusetts Institute of Technology,
United States
Noelle Selin – Massachusetts Institute of Technology,
United States
Rodney Smith – University of Minnesota, United States
Kenneth Strzepek – United Nations University, Finland/
University of Colorado, United States/Massachusetts
Institute of Technology, United States
v
vi
Inclusive Wealth
Report 2014

Measuring progress toward sustainability

SUMMARY FOR DECISION-MAKERS


Copyright
United Nations University – International Human Dimensions
Programme on Global Environmental Change 2014

United Nations Campus


Platz der Vereinten Nationen 1
53113 Bonn, Germany
Tel: +49 228 815 0600
Email: secretariat@ihdp.unu.edu
URL: www.ihdp.unu.edu

Editors:
John Tkacik
Carmen Scherkenbach

Cover Illustration:
Katja Cloud - INKeye, Bonn

The Inclusive Wealth Report 2014 is a joint initiative of the UN University – International
Human Dimensions Programme on Global Environmental Change (UNU-IHDP) and the
UN Environment Programme (UNEP), in collaboration with the UNESCO Mahatma Gandhi
Institute of Education for Peace and Sustainable Development (UNESCO-MGIEP), ASCENT
Africa Sustainability Centre, the Malaysian Industry-Government Group for High Technology
(MIGHT), Science to Action (S2A), the Ministry of Environment – Government of Japan, the
UN University – Institute for the Advanced Study of Sustainability (UNU-IAS), and endorsed by
the Science and Technology Alliance for Global Sustainability.

Project assistants:

Elorm Darkey
Cecília Fernandes
Kira Petters

The views expressed in this publication are those of the authors and do not necessarily
represent or reflect those of the institutions they belong to.

Suggested Citation:

UNU-IHDP and UNEP. (2014). Inclusive Wealth Report 2014. Measuring progress toward
sustainability. Summary for Decision-Makers. Delhi: UNU-IHDP.

2
CONTENTS

4 Foreword by Partha Dasgupta


6 Preface by Anantha Duraiappah
8 Inclusive Wealth Report: an introduction
The IWR 2012
8
The IWR 2014
9
Audience and structure of the report
9
11 What the data says
Accounting for the inclusive wealth of nations:
11
key findings of the IWR 2014
The contribution of human, produced, and natural capital
11
to the Inclusive Wealth Index ( )
Wealth compositions
16
Adjusted Inclusive Wealth Index (
19 adj)
Measuring economic performance: a comparison of
22
inclusive wealth, GDP, and HDI
24 The IWR 2014 and policy: a preliminary exploration
Revising the present System of National Accounts
24
Investment in education
24
Investment in agriculture
25
Investment in energy
27
28 Key messages of the IWR 2014
31 Conclusion
32 References
32 Abbreviations

3
only able to crudely approximate this ideal,
FOREWORD the outcome of which was also included
in the IWR 2012. Data on many items that
should eventually be included in the IWR
will by necessity appear only in physical
terms for some time to come, while many
other items of significance (ecosystems other
than forests, for example) will continue to
National accounts are descriptors. They be absent even in physical terms. Economic
describe the state of an economy and form evaluation inevitably involves cutting cor-
the raw material for both assessing per- ners. But it is essential for good practice to
formance and prescribing policy. National understand where those cut corners happen
accounts are meant to contain the kinds of to be. For this reason, the authors of the IWR
information that are essential for economic 2012 extensively addressed the conceptual
evaluation. The system of national accounts foundations of economic evaluation.
currently in use throughout the world, how-
ever, suffers from extreme narrowness. Vast The IWR 2012 offered a set of capital accounts
quantities of information relevant for eco- for each of the 20 countries on its list, akin
nomic evaluation do not appear in them. to balance sheets of private firms. Inclusive
Some don’t because the appropriate data are wealth is the social value of an economy’s cap-
difficult, even impossible, to collect; but oth- ital assets. The assets comprise (i) manufac-
ers don’t because until recently the theory tured capital (roads, buildings, machines, and
and practice of economic evaluation didn’t equipment), (ii) human capital (skills, educa-
ask for them. In recent years, a demand for tion, health), and (iii) natural capital (sub-soil
“green national accounts” has arisen due to resources, ecosystems, the atmosphere). Such
a growing recognition that contemporary other durable assets as knowledge, institu-
national accounts are an unsatisfactory tions, culture, religion – more broadly, social
basis for economic evaluation. The qualifier capital – were taken to be enabling assets;
“green” signals that we should be especially that is, assets that enable the production and
concerned about the absence of informa- allocation of assets in categories (i)-(iii). The
tion on our societies’ use of the natural effectiveness of enabling assets in a country
environment. gets reflected in the shadow prices of assets
in categories (i)-(iii). For example, the shadow
price of a price of farming equipment would
be low in a country racked by civil conflict,
The IWR 2012 whereas it would be high elsewhere, other
things being equal.
The inaugural publication on inclusive
wealth (the IWR 2012), issued jointly by The System of National Accounts (SNA)
UNU-IHDP and UNEP, provided an account that are still being developed by the United
of what is needed for a comprehensive set of Nations and their affiliated international
national accounts. The procedures recom- agencies do not yet contain several of the
mended there were put to work in estimating additions and reclassifications that were
changes in inclusive wealth per capita from made in the IWR 2012. That is why the
the period 1990-2008 in 20 countries repre- empirical estimates reported in the IWR
senting various stages of economic develop- 2012 were of significance. Being a first
ment. The IWR 2012 suggested that national attempt, the estimates were conducted
governments and international agencies mainly with natural capital in mind. Even
should go beyond even green national within that category, particular attention
accounts, reclassifying certain classes of was paid to forests, land, sub-soil resources,
goods and services and adding others that and the atmosphere as a sink for carbon.
are currently missing. At the moment, we are Estimates of human capital were restricted

4
to education, the measurement of which has preference”), while others estimate the value
a long history in economics. of the benefits to people by observing their
behavior (“revealed preference”). One way to
The IWR 2014 extends the IWR 2012 in estimate the combined benefit of improved
three ways: (a) the coverage is expanded to health is by recording people’s willingness
140 countries; (b) the basis for the estimates to pay for better health (e.g., observing how
of education as a capital asset is a more much people spend on health). Some studies
sophisticated approach, developed by Dale estimate the benefits enjoyed from item (2)
Jorgenson and collaborators; and (c) health by the output lost when workers are absent
as a form of capital asset receives attention owing to illness (the costs of air pollution are
in the main body of work. Health poses spe- often estimated on the basis of lost days of
cial problems of estimation, so it is worth work owing to bronchial congestion).
explaining why.
Unfortunately, there are no systematic stud-
ies of items (1) and (2) that could be used
Health capital to cover the 140 countries in question. The
present study confines itself to item (3), by
Health is a capital asset and should be seen using tables that have been prepared by
as a component of a person’s human capital. economists reporting the value of a statisti-
In order to compare the relative significance cal life in various countries. The approach is
of an economy’s various capital assets with not without weaknesses, but represents an
one another, they must be expressed in a important first step, and the authors of the
common currency. That common currency IWR 2014 are to be applauded for inaugurat-
is typically monetary, say, dollars. But the ing in an official publication what is likely to
currency could be any chosen commodity, be a long process of evaluation of health as a
or a basket of commodities; for example, a form of capital asset.
basket of consumption goods. Health capital
is health status expressed in that common That said, I do not believe that a central find-
currency. ing of the publication will be overturned, no
matter how refined the valuation exercise
Good health brings three benefits to a becomes in future. Namely, that health is the
person: most significant component of the wealth of
1. It adds directly to the person’s well-being nations. The authors show that it swamps
(she feels good); the value of all other forms of capital assets
2. It enables the person to be productive by an order of magnitude and more. This
(a healthy person works better and can will come as a surprise to all of us who have
work for longer hours than an unhealthy thought that in a reasonably well-ordered
person); society the various forms of capital assets
3. It contributes to her longevity (a healthy are on a par with one another; after all that
person can be expected to live longer is what the theory of economic development
than an unhealthy person). tells us to expect. The estimates in the IWR
Items (1) and (3) are direct benefits (they 2014 tell us otherwise.
constitute aspects of a good life), while item
(2) is an indirect benefit (a means to a bet-
ter life). It is humanity’s good fortune that
good health offers the three benefits jointly
(they are not in competition!). Economists
Partha Dasgupta
have developed elaborate methods for esti-
Chair of the IWR science advisory group and
mating the value of each type of benefit.
Frank Ramsey Professor Emeritus of Economics
Some involve asking people to report their
at the University of Cambridge, United Kingdom
willingness to pay for the benefits (“reported

5
that the successors to the Millennium
PREFACE Development Goals will be known as the
Sustainable Development Goals.

But how will we know when we are devel-


oping sustainably? GDP growth still domi-
nates policy planning, implementation,
and evaluation for countries of all levels of
There can be no doubt that, over the past development. We have no way of know-
two decades, many countries have done ing whether that growth is sustainable and
much to improve their citizens’ well-being. inclusive – whether the activities that gener-
Of course, some have a better record than ate that growth will be possible in five years
others, but overall the trend has been or fifty; whether they enrich the few at the
positive. Gross domestic product (GDP), expense of the many. Countries have spent
although stagnant in some highly advanced decades chasing production, consumption,
economies, has risen steadily across most and employment at all costs as the ticket to
of the world. Human Development Index well-being. But there is more to well-being
(HDI) scores have also improved for a sub- than GDP, and it is time countries have
stantial number of countries over the same approached policy planning strategically,
time period. A cursory glance at these two and over the long term.
trends might suggest that we are on the
We have seen, since the seminal Brundtland
right track; that we should continue with
Report in 1987, successive efforts call for
business as usual.
audacity and ambition in tackling sustain-
That first glance would be misleading. Over ability, but with only limited success. We
the past twenty years we have seen, it is will continue to see only limited success so
true, enormous gains in economic activity long as our definitions of economic success
and output, and indeed as well in many of and socioeconomic well-being continue to
the quality of life indicators comprising the be based on GDP.
HDI.
The case against GDP as a metric for eco-
On the other hand, serious questions have nomic success and socioeconomic well-
arisen as to the equitability and – more being can be distilled into three main points:
importantly – the sustainability of those The first relates to the extent to which
gains. As Thomas Piketty demonstrated in income alone is conflated with well-being.
his groundbreaking Capital in the Twenty- Although it is undoubtedly a necessary con-
First Century, inequality is steadily growing, dition for well-being, it is not a sufficient
and will continue to as long as returns on one. As the World Bank’s Voices of the Poor
capital exceed the rate of overall growth. study found, poor people themselves define
In the era of globalization and instant well-being not only in terms of income, but
communication, such levels of inequal- as “peace of mind, … belonging to a commu-
ity, both within and across nations, are nity, … safety, … [and] good health”, among
unsustainable. others.

Meanwhile, these gains have come at a mas- Second, GDP measures the market value of
sive cost to ecosystem health, biodiversity, all final goods and services produced in a
air quality, and climate resiliency. One of specific time period, but ignores the envi-
the welcome key outcomes of the Rio+20 ronmental externalities produced through
Conference on Sustainable Development the production process. Nor does GDP
was the agreement by countries to focus reflect scarcity arising from dwindling natu-
explicitly on sustainability in crafting the ral resources, which are often public goods
post-2015 development agenda. It is thus with no market prices.

6
Third, GDP represents flows only for a speci- monitor and assess it. The report, however,
fied, generally short, time period. It does not should not only be useful for policy-makers
provide information on the state of those but also our education systems, educators,
capital stocks necessary to generate the and students – providing an understanding
income measured. Equally important, it pro- of the productive base available to societ-
vides no insight into whether those capital ies and how it has to be managed to ensure
stocks – what we call inclusive wealth – are sustainability of human well-being. We
sufficient to generate consumption flows for hope countries find the IWR 2014 useful as
future generations. they gather in 2015 to finalize the post-2015
development agenda and the Sustainable
The Sustainable Development Goals are Development Goals. It is time to plan – and
thus destined for only limited success as measure – the future we want holistically,
long as we are missing an adequate frame- and inclusively.
work to measure progress, and do so in an
integrated and holistic manner.

The Inclusive Wealth Report (IWR) aims to


provide a comprehensive overview of the
status of capital stocks of three key assets for
Anantha Duraiappah
nations. These assets are tracked over the
past 21 years, and the sustainability implica- Report Director to the Inclusive Wealth Report

tions of trends and changes in these assets Project, and Director of United Nations
are appraised. The report does not attempt Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization
to provide a comprehensive overview of – Mahatma Gandhi Institute of Education for
human well-being. Instead, it provides guid- Peace and Sustainable Development, India
ance and insight for policy-makers on how
their economies are generating income, how
depreciation and reinvestment are affecting
capital stocks, and whether system trajecto-
ries are sustainable.

The IWR 2014, while still suffering from


incomplete data in some areas, is a sig-
nificant improvement over the IWR 2012
in both breadth and depth, particularly in
the areas of education and health capital
stocks. We hope that policy-makers at the
international, national, and state level will
see the IWR 2014 as a useful tool, and as
encouragement to take the steps necessary
to close gaps in data and to utilize the inclu-
sive wealth accounts presented in the report
as guidance.

We acknowledge that it may be early to


use the report for practical policy-making;
however, this was also the case 60 years ago,
when nations began designing economic
policies based on an incomplete set of GDP
accounts. We are confident that countries
will recognize the need for a comprehensive
and integrated picture of the three pillars
of sustainability, and the benefit of a tool to

7
Inclusive Wealth
Report:
An Introduction demonstrated that the principal pillars of
the wealth of nations, human capital and
natural capital, have remained largely hid-
den to policy-makers due to the limita-
tions of traditional economic indices. It was
discovered that the biggest returns were
coming from factors not accounted by the
Systems of National Accounts.

The IWR does not reject GDP. It acknowl-


The Inclusive Wealth Report (IWR) is a edges GDP’s practicality for tracking effi-
biennial effort to evaluate the capacities of ciency of resource use for production, and
nations around the world to improve their for providing an overview of interdependen-
citizens’ well-being, and do so sustainably cies among economic sectors held within
for the benefit of present and future genera- the System of National Accounts. Neither
tions. The report provides a comprehensive does the IWR aim to modify GDP to accom-
measure of development and progress. The modate missing elements, as Green GDP
results of the IWR indicate that GDP is an initiatives attempt. The IWR starts from the
inadequate measure for assessing long-term premise that all development is conditional
prosperity, and reveal education, health, on the existence of several key assets, and
and the environment as investments that that the total value of these assets should
will truly unleash the potential of young not be allowed to decline if human well-
and interconnected populations around being is to be furthered sustainably.
the world for development. The Inclusive
Wealth Index ( ) will be crucial to mea-
suring progress toward the Sustainable
Development Goals, and in the planning The IWR 2012
and evaluation of sustainable development
The Inclusive Wealth Index was launched
as a policy paradigm.
with the first IWR at Rio+20 in 2012, and
Inclusive wealth is a tool, rather than a represented the first attempt by the inter-
prescription. In the first IWR in 2012, we national scientific and policy communities
to develop a framework for quantifying and
tracking sustainable development, inclusive
of produced, human, and natural capital. It
“…a better way to size up wealth”
drew upon two decades of data for 20 coun-
– The Economist
tries covering three types of capital to quan-
“...if governments could agree to use the IWI as part of their tify and demonstrate the impact and returns
overall economic accounting, it would be a substantial step
of investing in them. The report, subtitled
towards true sustainable development.”
Measuring progress toward sustainability,
– The Huffington Post
focused on natural wealth, and offered valu-
“...this impressive research project… is the first serious attempt able insights for development policy. The
to measure the total wealth of the planet’s richest countries.” report was experimental in nature but, as
– TIME
Time Magazine noted, was the first serious

8
effort to measure the true total wealth of
nations. Audience and structure of the
report
The primary audience of the Inclusive
The IWR 2014 Wealth
Report 2014 will be researchers and
policy-makers. The inclusion of environ-
The IWR 2014 has been expanded from 20 mental damage in the accounts – such as
to 140 countries, and the time horizon has damages caused by global environmental
been updated to include data from 2009 change and climate change – can be useful
and 2010 in addition to the original 1990 to in determining transnational compensa-
2008 periods. While the IWR 2012 included tions, and as a guide for international nego-
a special focus on natural capital, the IWR tiations on trans-boundary assets.
2014 does the same for human capital. The
two main components of human capital The report will also be useful for national
are education and health. However, while economic planning agencies when con-
health is a key component of human capital, sidering macroeconomic fiscal policies.
we have left it out of the main human capital Changes in the various capital assets and
wealth accounts as we did for the IWR 2012. their contributions toward inclusive wealth
Education accounts have been expanded for can provide key information as to where
the full set of 140 countries in 2014. future investments should be targeted to
generate optimal returns for increasing the
The natural capital wealth accounts have overall productive base of a country.
been revised with new estimates for forest
accounts, which included improved estimates The IWR is also targeted toward the
for forest physical accounts and updated research community. The 2014 edition
values for non-timber forest product goods identifies and elaborates on a large num-
and services taken from The Economics ber of areas within the framework still in
of Ecosystems and Biodiversity (TEEB) need of theoretical refinement and empiri-
and Ecosystem Service Valuation Database cal data. For instance, the IWR 2014 does
(ESVD, Van der Ploeg and de Groot 2010). not address the issue of inequality within
and among nations; yet the significance
Total factor productivity (TFP) was treated of wealth as a common denominator
as a residual in the IWR 2012. The esti- for measuring inequalities is becoming
mates were taken from the Total Economy more evident, as recently demonstrated
Database (Conference Board 2012). In the by Thomas Piketty in Capital in the 21st
IWR 2014, TFP is still treated as a residual, Century (Piketty 2014). Using inclusive
but is now generated by including natural wealth rather than income alone can pro-
capital as an explicit factor input to the pro- vide a more complete picture of inequality
duction process. This approach allows us to in contemporary societies across the world.
extract directly the contribution of natural
capital toward production, and not have it Finally, the report offers a valuable tool for
be reflected implicitly in the TFP, as was the the educational establishment. It gives stu-
case in 2012. dents a unique framework with which to
analyze the sustainability of countries and
The report also takes a first stab at using observe trade-offs being made across the
scenario analysis for specific areas, applying asset stocks a country holds. It also offers
inclusive wealth methodology and results to insights into the value of human and natu-
guide policy-making at the project level. The ral capital, which have been ignored to a
inclusive wealth framework allows using a large extent in mainstream economic syl-
social cost-benefit approach to project design labi, and in particular within the education
and implementation (Dasgupta et al. 1972). for sustainable development discourse.

9
The IWR 2014 is presented in three parts. presented highlighting theoretical and
Part I comprises two chapters. Chapter 1 empirical challenges and opportunities.
presents the empirical computations of Part III contains three chapters with two
inclusive wealth for 140 countries over presenting new estimates and challenges
the period of 1990 to 2010. Chapter 2 for natural capital accounting, and a third
provides basic policy guidance on invest- focusing on using the inclusive wealth
ment strategies to improve the inclusive framework for social cost-benefit analysis
wealth of a country. In Part II of this report, at the project level. The complete theoreti-
three chapters providing detailed analysis cal model, methodologies, and data set are
of the human capital wealth accounts are presented in the annexes of the report.

10
What the
Our estimates show that 128 of the 140
countries assessed (91 percent) experienced
a positive annual average growth rate in

data says the Inclusive Wealth Index ( ), while the


remaining 12 countries exhibited negative
growth (see Figure 2-a). On a per capita
basis, the number of countries showing
positive growth rates in wealth fell from 128
to 85 (61 percent). Per capita, 55 countries
experienced negative growth rates in (39
percent) (see Figure 2-b). Figure 1 also shows
changes in per capita wealth after adjusting
( ) by TFP, damages from climate change,
and oil capital gains (see Figure 2-c). Only 58
of the 140 counties experienced an increase
in Adjusted Inclusive Wealth.

Accounting for the inclusive


wealth of nations: key findings of The contribution of human, pro-
the IWR 2014 duced, and natural capital to
In this section we explore one of the funda- Inclusive Wealth
mental questions of the report: have nations In Figure 3 we break down the contributions
been expanding or depleting their inclusive of each capital asset group to the total inclu-
wealth over the past decades? The direction sive wealth average growth rates. In particu-
of such changes in wealth correlates posi- lar we look at trajectories of the individual
tively with the movements of inter-temporal capital asset groups, which do not always
welfare, and therefore its relevance. reflect the trajectories of total inclusive
In the following analysis, we show changes wealth.
in wealth for the 140 nations under exami- In 137 nations, human capital experienced
nation over the time period between 1990 positive growth during the period of 1990
and 2010. to 2010. In the case of produced capital, 132
of 140 experienced positive growth. Natural
capital accounts experienced positive
Box 1: Assets in the Inclusive Wealth Index growth in only 24 countries (see Figure 3).

The Inclusive Wealth Report project tracks changes in three Patterns on the capital type contribution
categories of capital assets: human capital, produced capital, to inclusive wealth at an individual country
and natural capital. These three capital asset groups can all level show that human capital is the major
be broken down into various subcomponents (see Figure 1).
contributor to the growth rates in wealth
For the IWR 2014, as in 2012, we have excluded health capital
from the human capital asset group as this asset, according for 101 out of 140 countries. In 27 of 140
to existing methodologies, so dominates wealth capital that countries produced capital is the greatest
any changes, even modest, would disproportionately influence contributor to inclusive wealth. In only 12
overall trends in capital asset stocks. Combining the former of 140 countries did natural capital make up
three capital types with other factors affecting nations’ wealth,
namely oil capital gains, carbon damage, and TFP, leads us to
the largest contributor affecting the changes
our second measure of wealth: the Adjusted Inclusive Wealth in wealth (negatively).
Index ( adj). Figure 1 illustrates the full array of capital assets
accounted for within the Inclusive Wealth Index, as well as
the three items integrated into the Adjusted Inclusive Wealth
Index.

11
Figure 1
Schematic representation of the Inclusive Wealth Index ( ) and the Adjusted
Inclusive Wealth Index ( adj).

Natural capital + Human capital + Produced capital

Fossil Fuels Education Equipments


Oil Health* Machineries
+ Natural gas Roads
Coal others

Minerals
Bauxite, Nickel,
Copper, Phosphate,
+ Gold, Silver, Iron, Tin,
Lead & Zinc
Adjusted

+ Forest resources
Timber
Non-timber forest resources

Agricultural land
+ Cropland
Pastureland
Factors
affecting

(1) Carbon damages


(2) Oil capital gains
(3) Total factor productivity

*Not included in the Inclusive Wealth Index calculations


Note: assets are added by evaluating their changes at their social (shadow) price.

Regarding the magnitude of the average wealth. There are several possible explana-
country1 contribution of each capital cate- tions for this: some of these countries had
gory to the growth rates in inclusive wealth, already achieved high levels of education
the general trend shows that human capital across their populations, thus leaving them
has been the major contributor (55 percent), with less room to improve from already
followed by produced capital (32 percent), high levels of human capital. In some areas,
and natural capital (13 percent). This pattern high rates of migration likely resulted in low
can also be seen at regional and sub-regional growth in human capital. In other areas,
levels, with Europe being the only excep- natural capital makes up a relatively small
tion. In particular in Eastern and Northern part of growth in total wealth. See Table 1
Europe, produced capital has been the major for further information.
contributor to overall growth in inclusive
Per capita, 138 of the 140 countries assessed
1 This is an average across countries, where
experienced positive contribution in human
every nation is equally weighted. capital to inclusive wealth; 117 of 140 exhibit

12
Figure 2
Annual average growth rates in , per capita and adj for the 140 countries assessed in the IWR 2014
during the time period between 1990 and 2010.

Figure 2 a: Growth in Inclusive Wealth Index

Figure 2 b: Growth in Inclusive Wealth Index per capita

Figure 2 c: Growth in Adjusted Inclusive Wealth Index

Key
>1 < -1
0 to 1 no data
-1 to 0

13
Percentage

14
-2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6
Bahrain
Figure 3

Maldives
Singapore
United Arab Emirates
Jordan
Afghanistan
Israel
Viet Nam
Bangladesh
Yemen
Mauritania
Gambia
Kenya
Luxembourg
Republic of Korea
Costa Rica
Uganda
Qatar
Pakistan
Cyprus
Rwanda
Spain
China
Ireland
Guatemala
Malaysia
Haiti
Dominican Republic
Philippines
Panama
India
Egypt
Chile
Niger
Mexico
Turkey
Morocco
Tunisia
El Salvador
Lesotho
Mauritius
Malta
Syrian Arab Republic
Thailand
Sri Lanka
Swaziland
Burundi
Togo
Benin
Ghana
Côte d'Ivoire
New Zealand
Senegal
Botswana
Germany
Australia
South Africa
Namibia
United States of America
Slovenia
France
Honduras
Austria
Colombia
Greece
Fiji
Netherlands
Brazil
growth rates before per capita adjustment disaggregated by capital form, annual average for 1990-2010.

Jamaica
Belgium
Argentina
Portugal
Czech Republic
Saudi Arabia
Canada
Indonesia
Slovakia
Mali
United Kingdom
Iceland
Poland
Uruguay
Australia
South Africa
Namibia
United States of America
Slovenia
France
Honduras
Austria
Colombia
Greece
Fiji
Netherlands
Brazil
Jamaica
Belgium
Argentina
Portugal
Czech Republic
Saudi Arabia
Canada
Indonesia
Slovakia
Mali
United Kingdom
Iceland
Poland
Uruguay
Switzerland
Kyrgyzstan
Italy
Belize
Hungary
Sweden
Nicaragua
Sierra Leone
Japan
Finland
Malawi
Norway
Paraguay
Key

Algeria
Estonia
Sudan (former)
Peru
Serbia
Barbados
Latvia
contribution
contribution
contribution

Denmark
Venezuela
Iran
Ecuador
Croatia
Lithuania
Human Capital average

Natural Capital average

Gabon
Produced Capital average

Nepal
Romania
Cambodia
Albania
Cameroon
Nigeria
United Republic of Tanzania
Lao People's Democratic Republic
Cuba
Armenia
Mozambique
Trinidad and Tobago
Democratic Republic of the Congo
Zambia
Tajikistan
Kazakhstan
Bulgaria
Guyana
Iraq
Kuwait
Congo
Central African Republic
Mongolia
Russian Federation
Bolivia
Liberia
Zimbabwe
Papua New Guinea
Ukraine
Myanmar
Republic of Moldova

15
-2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6
Percentage
Table 1 and global level. Country-level results are
Relative contribution (in percentage) of human, produced, and shown in Figure 4, which depicts the rela-
natural capital to growth by sub-regions, regions, and total tive importance of each capital type in total
world average wealth.

In addition to the overview of the countries’


Human Produced Natural capital portfolios presented in Figure 4, we
capital capital capital
further explore how the capital portfolio is
Africa 62 20 19 composed for an average nation on a global
Eastern Africa 56 24 20 level. When analyzing the mean composition
Middle Africa 47 13 40 across the country sample for each capital
Northern Africa 57 29 14 type, the shares of the average country over
Southern Africa 66 27 7 the period of study clearly demonstrate the
Western Africa 72 12 15 importance of human capital wealth, with a
Asia 54 32 14 representation of 54 percent. Developments
Eastern Asia 29 56 15
over time show that while for the average
South-Central Asia 60 27 12
country the contribution of human capital
South-Eastern Asia 46 37 17
Western Asia 61 26 13
and produced capital to the total wealth
increased, the share of natural capital has
Europe 44 50 6
declined.
Eastern Europe 36 51 14
Northern Europe 38 55 7 The dominance of human capital over the
Southern Europe 50 48 2 other two capital types tends to be a fair rep-
Western Europe 55 45 1
resentation of the sample, holding true for
Latin America and the Caribbean 61 26 13
101 out of the 140 countries evaluated. What
Caribbean 67 23 10
Central America 64 26 10
is more, in 89 of these 101 countries the per-
South America 56 28 16 centage of human capital in total wealth is
Northern America 54 41 5 50 percent or higher. For those countries in
Northern America 54 41 5 which human capital is not the most impor-
Oceania 49 31 21 tant relative source of wealth (39 of 140),
Australia/New Zealand 48 43 8 natural capital is the most important asset
Melanesia 49 18 33 category in all but one.
Total World Average 55 32 13
A more specific analysis is presented in
Note: The figures represent the average relative contribution by asset cat-
Table 2, which includes a disaggregation of
egory of those countries comprising the (sub-)region to growth in .
average capital type at the regional and sub-
Contributions with negative sign as in the case of natural capital are taken in
regional level. These breakdowns show that
absolute numbers.
European countries in general, and Western
European countries in particular, have a
a positive contribution in produced capital; very low share of natural capital in relation
whilst the contribution of natural capital is to that of human capital, which tends to be
positive for only 13 nations. high. In fact, the only regions in which natu-
ral capital is the most important source of
wealth are: Middle Africa, South America,
and Melanesia. The wealth portfolios of
Wealth compositions the sub-regions of Latin America and the
Caribbean are also interesting since each
In this section we explore the sources of
of them reveals a different trend, contrary
nations’ wealth by looking at the composi-
to common understanding of regional eco-
tion of individual countries’ productive bases
nomic similarities (see Table 2).
valued at their shadow price. Composition
is shown for our three capital asset stock An interesting observation can be seen in
groups at a country, sub-regional, regional, the correlations between the composition

16
Figure 4
Percentage of human, produced, and natural capital in total wealth, annual average for 1990-2010.

Figure 4 a: Percentage of natural capital in total wealth

Figure 4 b: Percentage of produced capital in total wealth

Figure 4 c: Percentage of human capital in total wealth

Key
> 80 20 to 40
60 to 80 < 20 Note: It is worth remarking that the maps do not aim at describing where natural capital is in the world, but

40 to 60 no data rather to measure the relative importance of each capital asset in the total wealth for every country.

17
Table 2
Regional and subregional composition (in percentage) of wealth by capital form,
average 1990-2010.
Human capital Produced capital Natural capital
Africa 47 13 40
Eastern Africa 47 12 41
Middle Africa 16 7 77
Northern Africa 56 18 26
Southern Africa 59 18 23
Western Africa 52 12 37
Asia 51 18 31
Eastern Asia 47 22 31
South-Central Asia 54 19 26
South-Eastern Asia 46 16 39
Western Asia 53 16 31
Europe 66 26 8
Eastern Europe 57 28 15
Northern Europe 67 24 9
Southern Europe 70 24 6
Western Europe 70 28 2
Latin America and the Caribbean 52 17 31
Caribbean 68 22 10
Central America 58 18 25
South America 39 13 48
Northern America 62 19 19
Northern America 62 19 19
Oceania 45 17 38
Australia/New Zealand 53 24 23
Melanesia 37 9 53
Total World Average 54 18 28

Figure 5
Percentage shares of human capital and natural capital in total wealth, average
1990-2010
100%
Key
Low Income
Lower Middle Income
75% Upper Middle Income
High Income
Human Capital

50%

25%

0%

0% 25% 50% 75% 100%

Natural Capital
18
of human and natural capital (see Figure Remarkably, of the 85 countries that had
5): countries with a high share of human shown positive per capita, 33 moved
capital are generally likely to have a low into the negative bracket after adjust-
share of natural capital, and vice versa. ments. Considering this, the global outlook
This is particularly true in the case of high- becomes far less optimistic. We have now
income2 countries, which have relatively identified 82 countries – over half our sam-
high wealth held in human capital, and ple – that are facing long-term issues in sus-
relatively low wealth in natural capital. taining current consumption patterns. After
This is partially explained by the relative adjustments, only 58 countries exhibited a
stability of produced capital’s proportion in positive trend.
total wealth. Produced capital’s share tends
toward around 18 percent in most nations; When we drill down into specific adjust-
for 70 percent of the countries measured, ment impacts, TFP shows negative growth
produced capital made up between 12 and in 91 out of the 140 studied countries. The
28 percent of total wealth. average growth rates in TFP range from
± 6 percent, and thus had a considerable
impact on results in several countries, such
as China, which moved in to a negative
Adjusted Inclusive Wealth Index position in adj due to negative changes
in TFP.
This subsection investigates how countries’
performances based on are impacted In the case of climate change, results con-
after taking into account three factors: 1) firm that most of the countries (134 of 140)
climate change, in particular damages that would experience negative economic con-
nations have suffered as a result of increased sequences from this phenomenon. The six
carbon concentration in the atmosphere; 2) remaining countries would exhibit improve-
total factor productivity changes, captur- ments in the productive base. Regarding the
ing exogenous contributions of multiple magnitude of the climate change damages in
missing factors to economic growth; 3) oil relation to the inclusive wealth of the coun-
capital gains, reflecting how changes in oil tries, it is estimated that such effects, at less
prices may increase or decrease the value of than 0.25 percent, are still relatively low.
a country’s productive base. Similarly to the
Trends for oil capital gains illustrate that
IWR 2012, we refer to this adjusted figure as
most of the nations (119 of 140) suffer from
“Adjusted Inclusive Wealth Index” ( adj).
increases in the price of oil. The remaining
An overview of the estimates is illustrated in 21 countries3 show positive changes (essen-
Figure 6, which shows how each of the three tially a positive economic re-evaluation of
adjustments contributes to . In addition, oil reserves). Three countries, for example,
Figure 6 displays the final adjusted measure enjoy high oil capital gains at a rate of at
of wealth, adj. least 3 percent: Kuwait (7.0 percent), Iraq
(5.9 percent), and Saudi Arabia (3.5 percent).
Out of 55 countries for which we had These magnitudes offset unadjusted nega-
reported negative growth in per capita, tive trends shown in for these nations,
only 10 moved to positive growth rate after and in some cases even the negative impacts
wealth adjustments while the other 45 caused by climate change and TFP. We pre-
remained negative. fer to keep oil capital gains separate from

3 This group is comprised by the following oil-


extractive economies: Kuwait, Iraq, Saudi Arabia,
2 In total there are 42 high-income economies, Iran, Kazakhstan, Venezuela, Canada, Norway,
35 upper middle-income economies, 37 lower Nigeria, Russia, Algeria, Ecuador, Trinidad and
middle-income economies, and 26 low-income Tobago, United Arab Emirates, Qatar, Yemen,
economies. Gabon, Cameroon, and Congo.

19
Percentage

20
-8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Figure 6

Kuwait
Maldives
Serbia
Latvia
Haiti
Ukraine
Spain
Republic of Moldova
Saudi Arabia
Estonia
Lithuania
Viet Nam
Malta
Hungary
Germany
Gambia
Average annual growth rates of

Portugal
Croatia
Rwanda
France
Slovenia
Belgium
Kyrgyzstan
Bangladesh
Republic of Korea
Canada
Tajikistan
Jamaica
Mexico
Romania
El Salvador
Mauritius
Armenia
Turkey
Morocco
Venezuela
United States of America
Denmark
Italy
Fiji
Switzerland
Ireland
Afghanistan
Austria
Netherlands
Lesotho
Barbados
Burundi
adj disaggregated by the three adjustments

Japan
Bahrain
United Arab Emirates
Chile
Luxembourg
Poland
Zimbabwe
United Kingdom
Kenya
Sweden
Israel
Iran
Sierra Leone
Greece
Bulgaria
Cyprus
Russian Federation
Finland
Costa Rica
New Zealand
South Africa
Kazakhstan
Australia
Iceland
Egypt
Czech Republic
Sri Lanka
Algeria
Norway
Lao People's Democratic Republic
Democratic Republic of the Congo
Uruguay
Liberia
Zimbabwe
United Kingdom
Kenya
Sweden
Israel
Iran
Sierra Leone
Greece
Bulgaria
Cyprus
Russian Federation
Finland
Costa Rica
New Zealand
South Africa
Kazakhstan
Australia
Iceland
Egypt
Czech Republic
Sri Lanka
Algeria
Norway
Lao People's Democratic Republic
Democratic Republic of the Congo
Uruguay
Liberia
Pakistan
Gabon
Colombia
Tunisia
Guatemala
Philippines
Dominican Republic
Côte d'Ivoire
Malaysia
Brazil
Mauritania
Sudan (former)
India
Key

Guyana
Togo
Honduras
TFP

Mongolia
Swaziland
Indonesia
Ecuador
Panama
Adjusted

Thailand
per capita

Senegal
Slovakia
Carbon Damage

Jordan
Oil Capital Gains

Argentina
Albania
Zambia
Cuba
Singapore
Central African Republic
Yemen
Nicaragua
Paraguay
Myanmar
Namibia
Cameroon
Bolivia
Botswana
Uganda
Syrian Arab Republic
Nigeria
Niger
Congo
Benin
Malawi
Peru
Belize
Qatar
Ghana
Nepal
Trinidad and Tobago
China
Mali
Papua New Guinea
Cambodia
Mozambique
United Republic of Tanzania
-8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12

21
the initial estimates, because the positive countries5 (61 percent); while for HDI 135 out
changes in wealth for the above three coun- of 140 countries (96 percent) show positive
tries were not the result of improved man- progress. In terms of GDP, 124 of 140 coun-
agement of the countries’ asset portfolios, tries6 (89 percent) show an overall positive
but rather by rises in oil prices. trend in GDP growth over the past 21 years.
Most of the countries with negative growth
rates are located in Africa (9 countries) and
Asia (3 countries). When looking at the three
Measuring economic perfor- measures simultaneously for every country,
mance: a comparison of inclu- we see consistent signs of progress in 80 of
sive wealth, GDP, and HDI the 140 countries assessed (57 percent) across
the three indicators. Signs of regress in all
There exist a number of indicators to evalu-
three indices are found only in Tajikistan,
ate nations’ economic performance and
the United Arab Emirates, and Zimbabwe.
progress. Two of the most commonly used
are gross domestic product (GDP) and the The exclusion of environment in GDP and
Human Development Index (HDI). GDP HDI generally results in a more optimistic
measures the market monetary value of all impression of nations’ development, one
final goods and services produced in a given based in short-term performance rather
economy over a period of time (generally than long-term potential. The evidence sup-
one calendar year). HDI measures a nation’s ports the contention that a broader set of
performance as pertains to a selection of indicators is necessary to adequately mea-
outcomes seen as critical to human well- sure the sustainability of nations’ economic
being, such as life expectancy and educa- performance and progress, and improve
tional attainment, in addition to income. comprehensive well-being assessments.
In this section we provide an overview of
country trends as measured by GDP and
HDI, alongside inclusive wealth. In doing
so, we can identify how these measures of
progress converge or diverge in the assessing
of nations’ performance. Figure 7 presents
these measures in terms of the average per-
centage growth rates in per capita, GDP
per capita, and HDI over the period4 of 1990
to 2010.

Figure 7 shows that growth rates are in


general more moderate than those of GDP
and HDI. In most cases this can be explained 5 For the whole period of study from 1990 to
by the additional factor included in the 2010, 85 countries with a positive growth rate
, natural capital. As most countries experi- per capita can be identified, but for this com-
enced declines in natural capital, total parison the period for some countries had to be
changed to the period of 2000 to 2010, thus the
growth is decelerated as compared to GDP
average growth rate for Afghanistan switched from
and HDI.
negative to positive. This result in 86 countries
with positive growth rates in per capita.
From the previous section, we had identi-
fied a positive growth rate for 86 out of 140 6 Negative in HDI: Lesotho, Swaziland, Tajikistan,
United Arab Emirates, Zimbabwe. Negative in GDP:
Burundi, Central Africa, Côte d’Ivoire, Democratic
4 Due to missing data, Afghanistan, Cambodia, Republic of Congo, Gabon, Haiti, Kyrgyzstan,
Czech Republic, and Estonia are compared for Nigeria, Republic of Moldova, Serbia, Sierra Leone,
the period of 2000 to 2010, and Iraq, Nigeria, and Tajikistan, Togo, Ukraine, United Arab Emirates,
United Arab Emirates for 2005 to 2010. Zimbabwe.

22
Figure 7
Average annual growth rates of per capita, GDP per capita, and HDI, period 1990-2010
(in percentage)

Figure 7 a: per capita

Figure 7 b: GDP per capita

Figure 7 c: HDI

Key
>3 0 to 1
2 to 3 <0
1 to 2 no data

23
The IWR 2014
other things, to provide a benchmarked
framework for measuring and summariz-
ing national income data across all activities

and policy: within an economy and to facilitate compar-


ing such data across countries.

In measuring GDP – which is derived from


a preliminary data in the SNA – various contributions of
ecosystem services, such as bioremediation
by wetlands, storm and flood protection by
exploration mangroves, or the prevention of soil ero-
sion by forests, are ignored, either falling
entirely ouside the production boundary
of the SNA or suffering from low perceived
values.

Similarly, investments in education are


absent from the SNA. Education is reflected
85 of 140 countries – 60 percent – were found in accounts as an expenditure flow, while
to be on a sustainable growth trajectory in no references are made to the notion of
terms of inclusive wealth. The remaining 55 human capital in SNA. There has been some
countries are unable to maintain a produc- discussion on developing satellite accounts
tive base to accommodate the present state for monitoring and keeping track of the
of well-being, nor increases of well-being. changes in human capital, but these remain
That is to say, the present consumption pat- at an early stage.
terns of these countries are not sustainable.
Economists are now increasingly in agree-
Countries on unsustainable trajectories ment that instead of measuring growth in
have essentially two options: They can GDP or income – which are flow accounts
either increase investments to post positive – a more meaningful and correct approach
gains in the rate of inclusive wealth growth, would be to comprehensively measure
or reduce consumption to levels which can growth in wealth: specifically, the entire
be maintained by their productive base. stock of wealth including the value of natu-
ral and human capital, in addition to pro-
It was found that of the three capital asset duced capital.
categories, investment in produced capital
provides the lowest rate of return for the The existing core accounts reflect on aver-
majority of countries. age only 18 percent of a country’s inclusive
wealth. Thus, a first policy recommendation
However, most investments were in the pro- is for countries to begin earnestly develop-
duced capital category, consisting of infra- ing inclusive wealth accounts to comple-
structure, roads, buildings, etc. This might ment existing accounts.
be understandable as it is the only category
recorded explicitly in the System of National
Accounts.
Investment in education
The initial results from the IWR 2014 sug-
gest a quick win for most countries in edu-
Revising the present System of
cation investment, the component with the
National Accounts
highest weighting, yet with relatively low
The System of National Accounts (SNA) investment rates among the countries mea-
of the United Nations attempts, among sured (see Figure 8 ).

24
Figure 8
Growth rates of investment in education per capita across countries (in percentage), 2010/2009

Key
>2 -4 to 1
1.5 to 2 < -4
1 to 1.5 no data

Actual investment within the education The initial results from the IWR 2014 reflect
system would depend on a number of fac- a global decline in cropland and pasture-
tors which determine education wealth land. At the same time, the report indicates
such as literacy accomplishment, wages, that natural capital is second only to human
and demographics. Therefore, countries capital in its weighting within the inclusive
with relatively high literacy rates might wealth portfolio. Thus, investment in natu-
want to explore mechanisms for improving ral capital is another area for which many
the productivity of their literate working countries can easily increase their inclusive
population, while countries with low lit- wealth. Investments in natural capital, and
eracy rates (see Figure 9) should invest in in particular in agricultural land and for-
increasing literacy levels and improve basic est, can produce a twofold dividend: First,
education. they can increase directly; second, they
can improve agricultural resiliency and food
security to accommodate anticipated popu-
lation growth.
Investment in agriculture
Recent declines in cropland and pasture-
Food security is a central policy priority for land in many of the world’s food bowls (see
many countries today. While food security Figure 10) suggest an opportunity to benefit
is a complex issue, one critical factor is the from the double dividend. In , as apposed
availability of suitable arable land. It is esti- to GDP, valuations are based on the social
mated that an additional 3 to 5 million hect- prices of these assets – including not only
ares of cropland might be required to feed the price of the crop in question but also
the growing world population over the next land rental rates, as well as the present dis-
30 years (Wirsenius et al. 2010). counted value of the future flows from the
cropland.

25
Figure 9
Average education levels attained across countries (in years)

Key
12 to 14 0 to 6
6 to 12 no data

Figure 10
Change in cropland wealth per capita (in percentage), 2010/1990

Key
>5 -25 to -15
0 to 5 < -25
-15 to 0 no data

26
countries (134 countries out of 140) would
Investment in energy suffer to some degree from climate change.

A sustainable and secure supply of energy In general, the decision to switch from fossil
is essential for any country’s development to alternative fuel sources (such as renewable
aspirations. Energy is not only important for energy) with reduced detrimental impact on
supporting activities that lead to economic natural capital, becomes rational when the
growth, but also for key aspects of human marginal negative change in natural capital
development and social transformation, stock is greater than or equal to the mar-
such as education, health, and infrastructure. ginal positive changes in the produced and
human capital resulting from the energy in
The link between energy and wealth is question (all other things being equal).
straightforward. In the IWR 2014, natural
capital captures changes in fossil fuel stocks, However, because fossil fuels are finite, their
which currently account for approximately extraction results in declines of natural
81 percent of energy supply. Therefore, capital that are difficult to reverse, leading to
energy is empirically related to wealth. overall declines in . In the face of increas-
Increases in energy demand directly trans- ing scarcity (see Figure 11), the natural direc-
late to negative impacts on natural capital tion should thus be toward investments in
through the depletion of finite fossil fuel renewable resources.
deposits, and thus negative impact on the
Investments in renewable energy can
overall inclusive wealth of a country.
produce a triple dividend: First, they can
Energy, while an essential factor for improv- increase directly by adding to natural
ing well-being, imposes a policy trade-off and produced capital stocks; second, they
(in the current energy mix) by generating improve energy security and reduce risk
negative externalities, mainly to the envi- due to price fluctuations for oil-importing
ronment. A major driving force in declining countries; third, they reduce global carbon
wealth per capita (after population growth) emissions and thus carbon-related damages
is depreciation of natural capital. Adjusted on the inclusive wealth of a country.
Inclusive Wealth also shows that most

Figure 11
Reserves-to-production: remaining extract years of fossil fuels

120
*Estimations based on the year of 2013

100
113
Reserves-to-production ratio

80

60

55 53
40

20

0
Coal Natural Gas Crude Oil

(Source: BP Statistical Review of World Energy 2014)

27
Key messages of
• Produced capital, the capital type for
which by far the most exhaustive (and
reliable) data exists, represents only

the IWR 2014 about 18 percent of the total wealth of


nations. The remaining capital types,
which together constitute 82 percent of
wealth (54 percent in human capital and
28 percent in natural capital), are cur-
rently treated as satellite accounts, at
best, in the System of National Accounts.
• After adjusting for carbon damage, oil
capital gains, and total factor productiv-
ity, the number of progressing countries
drops from 85 to 58 of 140 counties (41
percent). Results show that all three fac-
tors negatively affected inclusive wealth
in most of countries; of the three, total
factor productivity adjustments had the
Accounting for the inclusive greatest negative effect.
wealth of nations: key findings of
the IWR 2014
• Empirical evidence shows average posi-
tive growth in per capita inclusive wealth The IWR and policy lessons
– and thus progress toward sustainable • Countries striving to improve their citi-
development – in 85 of the 140 countries zens’ well-being – and do so sustainably
evaluated (approximately 60 percent). – should reorient economic policy plan-
Gains in inclusive wealth were in general ning and evaluation away from targeting
smaller than those in GDP and HDI: 124 GDP growth as a primary objective and
of 140 nations (89 percent) experienced toward incorporating inclusive wealth
gains in GDP, while 135 of 140 (96 per- accounting as part of a sustainable devel-
cent) showed improvement in HDI over opment agenda.
the same period. • Investments in human capital – in par-
• Human capital is the foremost contribu- ticular in education – would generate
tor to growth rates in inclusive wealth higher returns for growth, as com-
in 101 out of 140 countries. In 27 coun- pared to investments in other capital
tries produced capital was the primary asset groups, in countries with high rates
contributor. On average, human capital of population growth.
contributed 55 percent of overall gains in • Investments in natural capital, in par-
inclusive wealth, while produced capital ticular agricultural land and forest, can
contributed 32 percent and natural capi- produce a twofold dividend: First, they
tal 13 percent. can increase directly; second, they can
• Population growth and natural capi- improve agricultural resiliency and food
tal depreciation are the main drivers of security to accommodate anticipated
declining wealth per capita in the major- population growth.
ity of countries. Population increased • Investments in renewable energy can
in 127 of 140 countries, while natural produce a triple dividend: First, they
capital declined in 127 of 140 countries. can increase directly by adding to
Although both factors each negatively natural and produced capital stocks;
affect growth in wealth, changes in second, they improve energy security
population were responsible for greater and reduce risk due to price fluctuations
declines. for oil-importing countries; third, they

28
reduce global carbon emissions and thus potential for improved well-being and
carbon-related damages. economic growth in the future.
• Investments in research and develop- • Human capital measures including
ment to increase total factor produc- information on present and future
tivity, which decreased in 65 percent of demographic trends, education, and
countries, can immediately contribute wage or income components are essen-
to growth in inclusive wealth in nearly tial for appropriate policy formulation
every country. and analysis.
• Countries should expand the asset
boundary of the present System of
National Accounts (SNA), which cur-
rently captures only 18 percent of a coun- Health capital
try’s productive base, to include human • Most health capital services influence
and natural capital. human well-being directly rather than
through the production of goods and
services that are counted in GDP.
• In the absence of better estimates of the
Human capital measurement: a
direct and productivity effects, gains in
bird’s eye view
life expectancy should be used as the pri-
• Measuring human capital can serve mary measure of health capital.
many purposes: it can help one better
understand drivers of economic growth;
assess the long-term sustainability of a
country’s development path; measure Forest wealth of nations
the output and productivity of the edu- • Forest ecosystems provide a huge range
cational sector; and facilitate informed of tangible and intangible benefits for
discussions on social progress and human well-being. These are of immense
well-being. value and represent an important com-
• All existing approaches to measuring ponent of national and global wealth.
human capital have advantages and • From a global perspective, in 2010 for
disadvantages. However, the monetary the selected countries, forest wealth
measures generated from the cost- amounted to more than US$273 tril-
based and the income-based approaches lion. On the face of it this wealth, in
should arguably be given a “core” status. absolute terms, seems concentrated in
One reason for this is to enable direct relatively few countries. However, for
comparison of figures with those for tra- many other countries, forest capital
ditional produced capital covered by the remains an important component of
SNA, the construction of which is a pri- national wealth. Many of these coun-
mary task of national statistical offices. tries (although not all) have experienced
alarming losses in forest capital over the
past 20 years.
Human capital: country esti-
mates using alternative
approaches Challenges to ecosystem service
• The educational attainment of a coun- valuation for wealth accounting
try’s younger cohort is frequently higher • There is often uncertainty associated
than the educational attainment of the with estimated ecosystem service values,
older cohort; high levels of youth edu- and even more so with scaling up of local
cational attainment correlate to high values to regional or national levels or

29
updating these values annually, which
poses problems for their use in wealth Using inclusive wealth for policy
accounts. evaluation: the case of infra-
• In the absence of reliable estimates, structure capital
the temptation is to use “second-best”
estimates, or to transfer values from • In order to use inclusive wealth for policy
other locations; however, such methods evaluation, we must estimate the impacts
should be used with caution and only of a given policy on the trajectories of the
under specific circumstances, at the risk capital stocks that comprise wealth.
of generating unrealistic values. • A systems view of policy evaluation is
• Progress in incorporating ecological necessary in order to map and quantify
capital in wealth accounts requires the impacts and trade-offs; this can be man-
development of more accurate methods aged using conceptual and mathematical
of valuing ecosystem goods and services models that capture integrated physical
and applying them to a wider range of and economic processes.
ecosystems.

30
Conclusion

The key information the IWR offers policy- The IWR by itself provides information only
makers is an overview of changes in the on changes in asset bases. However, its util-
productive base of a country. It provides ity vastly increases when used in conjunc-
insights into trends within the individual tion with other information about an econ-
capital asset groups, particularly human and omy. For instance, we showed that changes
natural capital – central pillars of inclusive in land use gleaned from the IWR, together
wealth that remain under served by current with information on crop yields, can be uti-
statistical col- lection, analysis, and eco- lized to inform investment decisions on how
nomic policy-making. For natural capital in to direct investments to increase productiv-
particular, the IWR gives insight into how ity. This type of composite analysis is pos-
subcomponents have changed, for instance sible for all the forms of capital comprising
changes in land use and cover, or fossil fuel inclusive wealth.
reserves.
Another potential area of use for the IWR
The Inclusive Wealth Index (2 years, still in is in education. The wealth of information
an early – essentially experimental – stage. in the report as well as the potential areas
However, it fills a crucial gap among the for research it identifies makes it a unique
indicators of well-being and sustainability tool within the education spectrum. It offers
available today, giving information on the a broader under- standing of economics
state of the productive base of an economy, and its contribution to human well-being.
as well as insights into relationships and Moreover, the multi- disciplinary nature
trade-offs among the capital components of of the exercise makes it fertile ground for
the productive base. multidisciplinary collaboration bringing
together economists, ecologists, demogra-
phers, health specialists, and educational-
ists, among others.

31
REFERENCES ABBREVIATIONS

Conference Board. (2014). Total Economy ASCENT ��������������������� Africa Sustainability Centre
Database [Online]. Retrieved from https://www.
conference-board.org/data/economydatabase/
ESVD ��������������������������� Ecosystem Service Valuation Database
GDP ����������������������������� gross domestic product
Dasgupta, P., Sen, A. & Marglin, S. (1972).
Guidelines for Project Evaluation. New York: United HDI ������������������������������ Human Development Index
Nations. IWI ������������������������������� Inclusive Wealth Index

Piketty , T. (2014). Capital in the Twenty First IWIADJ ����������������������� Adjusted Inclusive Wealth Index
Century. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
IWR ����������������������������� Inclusive Wealth Report
Van der Ploeg, S. & De Groot, R. (2010). The MIGHT ����������������������� Malaysian Industry-Government Group for
TEEB Valuation Database–a searchable database of High Technology
1310 estimates of monetary values of ecosystem services.
Wageningen, The Netherlands: Foundation for
SNA ����������������������������� System of National Accounts
Sustainable Development. S2A ������������������������������� Science to Action

Wirsenuis, S., Azar, C. & Bernedes, G. (2010). TEEB ��������������������������� The Economics of Ecosystems and
How much land is needed for global food production Biodiversity
under scenarios of dietary changes and livestock
TFP ������������������������������ total factor productivity
productivity increases in 2030? Agricultural Systems.
103:621-638. UN ������������������������������� United Nations
UNESCO-MGIEP ������
UNESCO Mahatma Gandhi
Institute of Education for Peace an
Sustainable Development
UNEP �������������������������� United Nations Environment Programme
UNU-IAS �������������������� United Nations University – Institute for the
Advanced Study of Sustainability
UNU-IHDP ���������������� United Nations University – International
Human Dimensions Programme on Global
Environmental Change

32
“The demand to increase economic production is simply
unsustainable (…) We will need to realign our value systems
to learn to live within the productive base of our societies.
This requires a change in our education systems, our political
systems and our institutions.”
Zakri Abdul Hamid
Science Advisor to the Prime Minister of Malaysia, founding Chair of the Intergovernmental Science-Policy Platform on
Biodiversity and Ecosystem Services (IPBES) and Member of the UN Secretary-General’s Scientific Advisory Board (SAB)

The Inclusive Wealth Report 2014 (IWR 2014) is the second edition
of the biennial IWR series, which presents an indicator for meas-
uring the inclusive wealth of nations. The IWR 2014 provides an
overview of how the capital asset components of inclusive wealth
evolved between 1990 and 2010 for 140 countries, and analyzes the
meaning of these trends for sustainability. While the asset base
studied is largely unchanged from 2012 – covering natural capital,
human capital, and produced capital – the country sample was
expanded from 20 to 140 nations. While the IWR 2012 focused on
natural capital, the IWR 2014 takes a closer look at human capital.
As in 2012, the IWR 2014 includes a comparative analysis of
country performance against two traditional indicators of pro-
gress, gross domestic product (GDP) and the Human Development
Index (HDI). The IWR 2014 also explores how the findings can be
used to inform macroeconomic policy and sectoral investment
decisions. The report outlines an approach for managing national
asset portfolios through the prism of sustainability, and introduces
an inclusive wealth framework for scenario analysis that can help
guide strategic investment at local, regional, and national levels.
The IWR 2014 offers a wealth of information for the research
and policy communities, identifying key gaps in data and knowl-
edge, and suggesting specific needs for future research, including
in the areas of national accounting practices, education and health
economics, ecosystem services valuation, and economic inequality.
Africa Sustainability Centre
ASCENT

Collaborating institutions: Endorsed by:

Africa Sustainability Centre


ASCENT

y yx2 yx2 y y y

Joint initiative of: Logomark Logotype

Africa Sustainability Centre


z
x
x

The Inclusive Wealth Report 2014 is a joint initiative of the UN University – International Human Dimensions
Programme (UNU-IHDP) and the UN Environment Programme (UNEP), in collaboration with the UNESCO-
Mahatma Gandhi Institute of Education for Peace and Sustainable Development (UNESCO-MGIEP), ASCENT
Africa Sustainability Centre, the Malaysian Industry-Government Group for High Technology (MIGHT), Science to
Action (S2A), the Ministry of Environment – Government of Japan, the UN University – Institute for the Advanced
Study of Sustainability (UNU-IAS), and endorsed by the Science and Technology Alliance for Global Sustainability.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi