Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 4

Telecommunications & Electronic Media

A La Carte Regulation of Pay TV: Good Intentions vs. Good Economics


By Jeffrey Eisenach & Adam Thierer*

I
n his insightful works on political economy, Professor the best of intentions. But a closer look suggests that a la carte
Thomas Sowell warns of the dangers of lawmakers allowing regulation would be a classic case of what we refer to as Sowell’s
good intentions to trump good economics when crafting Law of Wishful Thinking. Indeed, it would likely have the exact
public policy. It is a theme which Friedrich Hayek,1 Milton opposite effects of what its proponents intend, leaving consumers
Friedman2 and others articulated before him, of course, but and families worse off than they are today.
Sowell has more fully developed this cautionary principle in I. Today’s Pay TV Marketplace
books like A Conflict of Visions and The Vision of the Anointed.
Sowell teaches us that noble intentions alone do not necessarily On the face of it, the pay TV marketplace appears to be
translate into sound public policy, and cautions against the functioning efficiently. By any conceivable statistical measure,
hubris that leads policymakers to believe that they can easily consumers today have access to more video outlets and options
improve on market outcomes. Even the best-intentioned than at any time in history, and 86% of Americans subscribe to
policies can spawn unintended consequences, giving rise to still cable, satellite or telco-provided television services.
more regulatory interventions as policymakers seek to rectify Certainly there is no shortage of programming. Indeed,
past mistakes. the long-heralded “500-channel” cable universe is now a reality.
The Federal Communications Commission (FCC) would The overall number of video programming channels available
be wise to heed Sowell’s advice in the ongoing debate over “a la in America has skyrocketed, from just seventy channels in 1990
carte” regulation of cable and satellite television networks and to 565 channels in 2006.3 The resulting diversity “on the dial”
programming. The notion—giving consumers the right to pay has been astounding . There is hardly any human interest or
for only the cable TV channels they want, without having to hobby that is not covered by some video network. As the FCC
purchase a full bundle—is highly appealing on the surface, and concluded in its 2003 Media Ownership Proceeding, “We are
well-intended advocates on both sides of the political divide, moving to a system served by literally hundreds of networks
including the Consumer Federation of America’s Mark Cooper serving all conceivable interests.”4 Exhibit 1 below shows the
and FCC Chairman Kevin Martin, are no doubt acting out of sheer diversity of programming on pay TV today.

Cable and Satellite TV Programming Options


News: CNN, Fox News, MSNBC, C-Span, C-Span 2, C-Span 3, BBC America
Sports: ESPN, ESPN News, ESPN Classics, Fox Sports, TNT, NBA TV, NFL Network,
Golf Channel, Tennis Channel, Speed Channel, Outdoor Life Network, Fuel
Weather: The Weather Channel, Weatherscan
Home Renovation: Home & Garden Television, The Learning Channel, DIY
Educational: The History Channel, The Biography Channel (A&E), The Learning Channel,
Discovery Channel, National Geographic Channel, Animal Planet
Travel: The Travel Channel, National Geographic Channel
Financial: CNNfn, CNBC, Bloomberg Television
Shopping: The Shopping Channel, Home Shopping Network, QVC
Female-oriented: WE, Oxygen, Lifetime Television, Lifetime Real Women, Showtime Women
Family / Children-oriented: Animal Planet, Anime Network, ABC Family, Black Family Channel, Boomerang, Cartoon Network, Discovery
Kids, Disney Channel, Familyland Television Network, FUNimation, Hallmark Channel, Hallmark Movie Channel, HBO Family,
KTV – Kids and Teens Television, Nickelodeon, Nick 2, Nick Toons, Noggin (2-5 years), The N Channel (9-14 years), PBS Kids Sprout,
Showtime Family Zone, Starz! Kids & Family, Toon Disney, Varsity TV, WAM (movies for 8-16-year-olds)
African-American: BET, Black Starz! Black Family Channel
Foreign / Foreign Language: Telemundo (Spanish), Univision (Spanish), Deutsche Welle (German), BBC America (British), AIT: African
Independent Television, TV Asia, ZEE-TV Asia (South Asia) ART: Arab Radio and Television, CCTV-4: China Central Television, The
Filipino Channel (Philippines), Saigon Broadcasting Network (Vietnam), Channel One Russian Worldwide Network, The International
Channel, HBO Latino, History Channel en Espanol
Religious: Trinity Broadcasting Network, The Church Channel (TBN), World Harvest Television, Eternal Word Television Network
(EWTN), National Jewish Television, Worship Network
Music: MTV, MTV 2, MTV Jams, MTV Hits, VH1, VH1 Classic, VH1 Megahits, VH1 Soul, VH1 Country, Fuse, Country Music
Television, Great American Country, Gospel Music Television Network
Movies: HBO, Showtime, Cinemax, Starz, Encore, The Movie Channel, Turner Classic Movies, AMC, IFC,
Flix, Sundance, Bravo (Action, Westerns, Mystery, Love Stories, etc.)

148 Engage: Volume 9, Issue 2


Not only is programming
diverse, so, too, is the universe
of programmers. While the FCC
and cable industry critics have
often expressed concern about
vertical integration between cable
operators on the one hand and
programmers on the other, the
reality is that vertical integration
in the video marketplace has
plummeted. Since 1990, the
number of cable-owned or
affiliated channels has increased
only slightly, while the number
of independently-owned and
operated video networks has
exploded. Thus, as shown in
Exhibit 2 (top), the percentage
of cable channels owned and
operated by cable operators has
dropped from 50% in 1990 to
just 14.9% today.
Competition is also
growing on the program
delivery front. While local
cable operators were once
monopolies, competition from
satellite, cable overbuilders,
and, most recently, telephone
companies like AT&T and
Verizon is cutting deeply
into cable’s market share. As
shown in Exhibit 3 (bottom),
competition in the program
delivery market is increasing
rapidly.
Growing competition is
not only offering consumers
more choice, but also increased
quality. Cable, satellite, and
telephone companies have
invested hundreds of billions
of dollars in recent years to
provide more channels, digital delivery, video-on-demand, and, people could choose not to buy certain channels, they would no
most recently, high-definition. As the FCC itself concluded in longer be forced to subsidize programming (particularly “racy”
its most recent report on the video programming marketplace, programming) of which they disapprove. Thus, an a la carte
“competition in the delivery of video programming services mandate is presented as both economic regulation, designed
has provided consumers with increased choice, better picture to reduce prices, and social regulation, designed to “clean up
quality, and greater technological innovation.”5 the airways.”
Given these results, what is the case for regulation? II. A La Carte as Economic Regulation
Proponents of an a la carte mandate suggest that they can
improve on the market in two primary ways. First, since people The economic case for an a la carte mandate rests on two
would no longer be forced to pay for channels they do not premises. First, it is argued, cable prices are rising faster than
watch, they would pay less for cable television. Second, since inflation, and government action is therefore appropriate to
give consumers lower prices. Second, a la carte regulation would
................................................................... reduce the prices people pay for cable programming. Neither
* Jeffrey Eisenach is Chairman of Criterion Economics and Adam Thierer premise withstands scrutiny.
is a Senior Fellow with the Progress & Freedom Foundation.

June 2008 149


If cable prices were rising faster than inflation, there might the other is willing to pay only $4 for sports, but will pay $7
well be a strong political (though not an economic) case for for business. If the two channels are offered separately, there
regulation. Indeed, much of the case for a la carte has been is no price at which demand will be sufficient to cover cost: if
premised on this notion, with advocates pointing, for example, each is offered for $10 (its cost), no one buys either channel;
to the most recent FCC report on cable prices, which shows if each is offered at $7 and is purchased by one consumer,
that the average price paid for the basic tier of cable channels revenue is $7 and each channel loses $3; and, if each is offered
rose 93% over the ten-year period between 1995 and 2005, at $4 and purchased by both consumers, revenue is $8, and
compared with the consumer price index, which increased only each channel loses $2. In short, in an a la carte world, neither
28%. But there are two problems with this data. channel is produced.
First, the FCC’s data is three years old. More recent If bundling is permitted, on the other hand, the two
data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics shows that cable channels can be offered together for $10, and both consumers
price increases have moderated and, indeed, that cable prices (each of whom values the two channels at a total of $11)
in 2007 and 2008 have actually risen less rapidly than the will purchase. Revenues are now $20, covering the costs of
Consumer Price Index (CPI). Perhaps this change is due both channels, and each consumer receives $1 in consumer
to increased competition, or to efficiencies associated with surplus.
the increasing ability of cable companies to spread the fixed This argument is only one of several that explain why
costs of their infrastructures over multiple services, such as bundling of cable TV channels is economically efficient.
broadband and telephony. Whatever the reason, cable price Bundling also provides a means for cable channels to expand
increases have slowed, and the political case for regulation has their distribution, thereby increasing advertising revenues (and
thus weakened. defraying costs that would otherwise be passed on to consumers
The second problem with the price increase argument is in the form of higher subscription fees); it allows consumers
more fundamental, and ultimately more important: the price to sample cable channels, thereby reducing marketing costs;
increase figures cited by a la carte advocates fail to account for and, it reduces transactions costs by avoiding the need for
changes in quality, which can be captured by taking into account cable operators to constantly add and subtract channels from
either the number of television channels included in the basic individual consumers’ feeds.10
tier or the time people spend watching cable TV. When cable Economists also recognize that bundling can, in certain
prices are looked at in terms of the price per channel, the real (very limited) circumstances, be a sign of market power, and a
price of pay television has fallen throughout the past decade.6 la carte advocates have suggested this is the case in cable TV.11
And because television viewing overall is increasing, and cable’s But they have failed miserably to prove their case. Indeed, as
share of viewing hours is also going up (relative to over-the-air noted above, competition in pay TV is growing: virtually
TV), the price paid per viewing hour has actually declined even all consumers now have a choice among at least one cable
in nominal terms.7 Thus, the basic underlying political argument TV provider and two satellite providers, and many can also
for economic regulation of cable is, to be blunt, a lie: by the choose to get their service from cable overbuilders or telephone
most accurate measure, cable prices are not only not rising faster companies. If a la carte was an economically efficient business
than inflation, they are actually going down! model, we would expect to see at least some of the firms in a
Most people would agree, of course, that rising prices— competitive market to offer it voluntarily, yet none have done
even if they were rising—would not by themselves constitute so.
a basis for regulation. Rather, regulation should be considered Back in 2004, when the FCC first considered (and
only if a case can be established for market failure—in which rejected) a la carte regulation, a group of respected economists
case it might be possible, at least in theory, for regulation to wrote to the agency’s Media Bureau warning that the proposal
improve on the market outcome and lead to lower prices in the would not achieve its purported objectives. Their conclusion:
long run. But a la carte advocates have failed to demonstrate “(1) mandatory a la carte distribution would very likely raise
that bundling constitutes a market failure of any sort. overall prices; (2) consumers’ viewing decisions would very
Bundling is, course, pervasive throughout the economy, likely be distorted and their ability to sample alternative
and while the economics of bundling are complex, economists networks and shows would very likely be suppressed; and
universally agree that it is generally efficient and beneficial (3) mandatory a la carte distribution would very likely harm
to consumers. Bundling improves economic efficiency in a new and niche networks, which would result in fewer viewing
variety of situations, including when there are economies options for consumers.”12
of scope and scale. One particularly significant and relevant In short, when it comes to a la carte, the economics of cable
efficiency motivation, advanced many years ago by Nobel TV are clear: Rather than reducing prices and increasing choice,
Prize winner George Stigler,8 occurs when there are high fixed as proponents hope, it would do precisely the opposite.
costs of production and consumers have differing preferences III. A La Carte as Social Regulation
for various “flavors” of a product. A simple example illustrates
the point.9 A la carte proponents point to another supposed benefit
Suppose there are two cable TV channels, “sports” and of regulation: it could help “clean up” the character of pay TV.
“business,” each of which costs $10 to produce. Suppose further Many policymakers have expressed a desire to extend content
that there are two consumers, one of whom is willing to pay $7 controls to cable and satellite TV, but realize that direct efforts
for the sports channel and $4 for the business channel, while to regulate subscription-based media platforms would likely
be held to be in violation of the First Amendment.13 A la carte

150 Engage: Volume 9, Issue 2


regulation has been pitched by some of those lawmakers as an Endnotes
indirect method of accomplishing that same objective.14 But
will it really work? It is highly unlikely, at least in the fashion 1 See generally F.A. Hayek, The Fatal Conceit, ().
many lawmakers and family groups hope for. 2 See generally Milton Friedman, Capitalism and Freedom ().
The reason is two-fold. First, as made clear above, a la carte 3 “FCC Adopts 13th Annual Report to Congress on Video Competition and
regulation threatens the wonderful diversity of programming on Notice of Inquiry for the 14th Annual Report,” Fed. Commc’ns Comm’n,
Press Release, Nov. 27, 2007, at 3, http://hraunfoss.fcc.gov/edocs_public/at-
television today. That also explains why a la carte proponents tachmatch/DOC-278454A1.pdf.
are wrong when they suggest that it would “clean up” pay 4 Fed. Commc’ns Comm’n, In the Matter of 2002 Biennial Regulatory Re-
TV and allow us to purchase just the “good stuff.” The “good view – Review of the Commission’s Broadcast Ownership Rules and Other Rules
stuff” is not likely to survive in a world of mandatory a la carte Adopted Pursuant to Section 202 of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, FCC
regulation. Most family-focused/children’s networks, female- 03-127, June 2, 2003, at 48-49, http://hraunfoss.fcc.gov/edocs_public/at-
tachmatch/FCC-03-127A1.pdf.
oriented channels, and religious programmers oppose a la carte
5 See Fed. Commc’ns Comm’n, In the Matter of Annual Assessment of the Sta-
mandates for this reason. They understand that their programs tus of Competition in the Market for the Delivery of Video Programming, Twelfth
attract only a small subset of the overall universe of viewers. If Annual Report, MB Docket No. 05-255 (Mar. 3, 2006), at ¶5.
their networks are not bundled alongside other channels, they 6 See, e.g., Jeffrey A. Eisenach & Douglas A. Trueheart, “Retransmission
might disappear entirely. Colby May, director of the Faith Consent and Cable Television Prices,” The CapAnalysis Group, LLC ( March
and Family Broadcasting Coalition, which represents religious 2005).
broadcasters, last year called a la carte regulation “a dagger 7 See Steven S. Wildman, Assessing Quality-Adjusted Changes in the Real Price
of Cable Service, Mich. St. Univ. (Sept. 10, 2003).
aimed at the heart of religious broadcasting in America,” and
predicted that it would “decimate religious broadcasting and 8 George J. Stigler, A Note on Block Booking, in The Organization of In-
dustry ().
the wholesome, family-oriented programming carried on niche
9 For a more complete discussion, see Jeffrey A. Eisenach & Richard Lud-
cable channels.”15 wick, The FCC’s Further Report on A La Carte Pricing of Cable Television, The
Second, the channels that some lawmakers want driven CapAnalysis Group, LLC (March 6, 2006).
off basic cable—MTV, F/X, Comedy Central, Spike, and so 10 For an excellent discussion of the economic efficiency rationales for cable
on—will likely continue to do just fine. They are all among bundling, see Federal Communications Commission, Report On the Packag-
the Top 20 networks on cable and satellite TV today and have ing and Sale of Video Programming Services to the Public (December 2004)
at 20-26.
a strong following on DVD and the Internet. Even under a
11 For example, Chairman Martin has suggested that bundling might con-
new regulatory regime, people will still flock to these networks stitute an illegal “tying” arrangement. Ted Hearn, Martin: Expanded Basic a
in fairly large numbers. Tying Arrangement, Multichannel News, Sept. 14, 2006.
So the “choice” consumers will be left with in a world 12 Joint Economists Letter to Kenneth W. Ferree, MB Docket 04-207, No-
encumbered by a la carte regulation is one of fewer choices of vember 4, 2004.
television programming. If smaller, niche-oriented networks 13 See Adam Thierer, “Thinking Seriously About Cable and Satellite Censor-
begin to disappear, lawmakers will be dismayed obviously, but ship: An Informal Analysis of S. 616, The Rockefeller-Hutchison Bill,” Progress
they will be absolutely furious if the channels that they really & Freedom Foundation Progress on Point no. 12.5, Apr. 2005, http://www.pff.
org/issues-pubs/pops/pop12.6cablecensorship.pdf; Robert Corn-Revere, “Can
wanted to see vanish end up surviving anyway. Broadcast Indecency Regulations Be Extended to Cable Television and Satel-
Again, wishful thinking cannot change the basic rules of lite Radio?” Progress & Freedom Foundation Progress on Point 12.8 (Progress
markets and economics. Policymakers might like to see “racy” and Freedom Foundation May 2005), http://www.pff.org/issues-pubs/pops/
programming disappear and “family” programming rule the pop12.8indecency.pdf.
“airwaves,” but imposing a la carte regulation would likely have 14 See, e.g., Chairman Martin’s remarks at “Open Forum on Decency,” in
the Senate Commerce Committee in November 2005 (http://hraunfoss.fcc.
precisely the opposite effect.16 gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/DOC-262484A1.pdf ) as well as his com-
CONCLUSION ments on Capitol Hill on June 14, 2007 applauding the introduction of an
a la carte legislative proposal (http://hraunfoss.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attach-
From a policy perspective, a la carte regulation is worse match/DOC-274169A1.pdf ).
than a solution in search of a problem; it is a problem waiting 15 “Religious Broadcasters Oppose FCC Chairman’s Call for Pay-Per-Chan-
to happen. As prices rose and programming became less nel Legislation,” Press Release, Faith and Family Broadcasting Coalition, April
diverse in the wake of an a la carte mandate, policymakers 17, 2007, http://www.ncta.com/DocumentBinary.aspx?id=575. The late the
would find themselves besieged by consumers and interest Rev. Jerry Falwell also opposed a la carte regulation for the same reason, saying
“Though well-intentioned, the fact is that a la carte would threaten the very
groups demanding yet another “solution.” Perhaps they would existence of religious broadcasting and the vital ministry conducted over the
frankly admit error and reverse course, repealing the misguided television airwaves.” Quoted in Ted Hearn, “Falwell’s 11th Commandment:
policy they had so recently put in place. On the other hand, No a La Carte,” Multichannel News, Nov. 17, 2004, http://www.multichannel.
it is just possible that they would proffer still more regulatory com/article/CA481169.html.
solutions—price controls, for example—which would be 16 The better approach would be to encourage the continued development
of even more family-friendly and educational fare and then let parents sim-
politically attractive on the surface, but equally flawed in their
ply block those channels they do not desire with the parental control tools
underlying economics. No doubt the new rules would also be available in every set-top box today. That’s a win-win strategy that demands
motivated by the best of intentions. no further regulation of pay TV markets while ensuring parents access to an
expanding array of enriching programming for themselves and their children.
See Adam Thierer, “Parental Controls and Online Child Protection: A Survey
of Tools & Methods,” Progress & Freedom Foundation Special Report, Version
3.0, Spring 2008, http://www.pff.org/parentalcontrols.

June 2008 151

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi