Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 18

r The Academy of Management Perspectives

2015, Vol. 3015, No. 1, 30–46.


http://dx.doi.org/10.5465/amp.2011.0091.test

A R T I C L E S
TOP MANAGEMENT TURNOVER FOLLOWING MERGERS AND
ACQUISITIONS: SOLID RESEARCH TO DATE BUT STILL
MUCH TO BE LEARNED
JEFFREY A. KRUG
Loyola University New Orleans

PETER WRIGHT
The University of Memphis

MARK J. KROLL
University of Texas at Brownsville

It is commonly believed that retaining target company executives is an important de-


terminant of post-acquisition success. We review existing research, paying particular
attention to the different micro-, group-, meso-, and macro-level factors that motivate
acquisitions. We conclude that the link between turnover and post-acquisition perfor-
mance is more complex than implied by existing studies. Retaining executives may lead
to higher performance in some acquisitions, as existing studies suggest. However, there
are good theoretical arguments for the opposite view; namely, replacing executives may
be an equally important source of value creation in other acquisitions. We develop
a framework that provides guidelines for understanding when and under what con-
ditions retaining or replacing target executives may contribute to acquisition success. A
research agenda that considers acquisition context and the short-, intermediate-, and
long-term performance consequences of leadership instability in acquired firms is
suggested as a means of moving this research domain forward. The decision to retain or
replace target executives is largely a matter of context. Existing studies have not yet
captured this complexity.

I can only describe the entire merging process as This quote captures the feelings of many involved
being full of secrets, lies, tricks, and games with little in an acquisition. Indeed, many acquisitions fail
or no consideration for the very excellent manage- because acquirers do not effectively integrate the
ment team that made this a valuable business. They acquired firm, often by alienating target firm man-
did not explore synergies or mutual growth but went agers. Research suggests that retaining target execu-
straight for dominance and control. They pretty tives is an important part of a successful integration
much left it up to empire-building subsidiary man- strategy. The reason given is that executives may
agers less qualified than our own managers to man- have embedded knowledge of their firm, industry
age the business. (Krug, 2009, p. 17)1 experience, and established relationships with
stakeholders that acquiring firms find difficult to
quickly replicate. This view has been widely ac-
The authors express their gratitude to Timothy
M. Devinney, Donald S. Siegel, and Paul M. Vaaler for cepted by both researchers and practitioners alike.
their comments and insights, which greatly improved the Indeed, leading consulting firms involved in M&A
quality of this paper. engagements commonly view minimizing executive
1
Quotes by executives in interviews with authors fol- turnover as an important objective during the in-
lowing their company’s acquisition. tegration process (Adolph & Pettit, 2009; de Souza,
30
Copyright of the Academy of Management, all rights reserved. Contents may not be copied, emailed, posted to a listserv, or otherwise transmitted without the copyright holder’s express
written permission. Users may print, download, or email articles for individual use only.
2015 Krug, Wright, and Kroll 31

Adolph, Gemes, & Marchi, 2007; Fubini, Price, & boardrooms to produce additional insights. For ex-
Zollo, 2006; Shill & Mackenzie, 2005). ample, research has focused primarily on acquis-
Despite this focus on retaining target executives, itions of public companies. Most target companies,
we believe this view is limiting. Indeed, in many however, are privately held, family controlled, new
acquisitions, replacing executives may be an im- ventures, or subsidiaries or divisions of other
portant source of value creation (e.g., to achieve firms. This fact leads to an important question: Do
cost savings or eliminate resistance to the acquisi- turnover—performance linkages differ for acquis-
tion), and there are good theoretical and empirical itions of these other organizational forms? Recent
arguments for both views. The decision to retain or research also suggests that the timing of a firm’s
replace target executives, therefore, is largely con- acquisition—whether at the beginning, height, or end
textual and depends on individual, group, firm, of a merger wave—leads to different performance
industry, and country factors that motivate each outcomes. Again, this new research leads to more
acquisition. questions: Does the timing of an acquisition during
To examine these issues in greater detail, we first a merger wave imply different strategies for inte-
consider the findings of studies on executive turn- grating executive teams? Given recent globalization
over and its link to post-acquisition performance. trends, how do performance effects vary in other
Existing research is then placed in a broader con- regions of the world? These are only a few of the
text. Multiple theoretical perspectives provide dif- many avenues for new insights that might link this
ferent, often contradictory, guidelines about when research domain with the larger issues of globali-
executive turnover is a desirable or undesirable ac- zation, technological change, and new venture for-
quisition outcome. For example, micro-level factors mation that will affect management scholarship and
related to the psychological attributes of executives practice in the 21st century.
as well as group-level factors related to the com-
position of top management teams vary managerial
SOLID THEORETICAL AND EMPIRICAL
perceptions of the potential value of a given acqui-
RESEARCH BASES: A BRIEF
sition. Meanwhile, meso-level factors related to the
LITERATURE REVIEW
acquirer’s industry, markets served, level of corpo-
rate diversification, and ownership structure also The new owners wanted to bring in their own
influence motivations. Even larger macro-level fac- management and as president, I was expected to
tors shape motivations. For example, a firm’s country leave. (Krug & Nigh, 2001, p. 94–95)
of domicile and degree of internationalization in-
fluence its selection of markets, entry strategy, and
Executive Turnover Following an Acquisition
method of integrating acquired foreign assets, plants,
and human resources. Walsh (1988) offered the first empirical evidence
We then develop a framework that relates these that target executives depart at significantly higher
different theoretical perspectives to prescriptions rates than normal following an acquisition. On av-
for integrating target executive teams. These points erage, target companies lose an average of about
are illustrated using four case studies from the au- one-quarter of their executives in the first year after
tomobile industry: Daimler-Benz AG and Chrysler acquisition—a turnover rate close to three times
Corporation’s merger in 1998, Renault’s partial ac- higher than normal. Within five years, they lose an
quisition of Nissan in 1999, DaimlerChrysler’s par- average of 60% or more of the executives present
tial acquisition of Mitsubishi in 2000, and Fiat’s at the time of the acquisition. Subsequent studies
acquisition of Chrysler beginning in 2009. Each vi- have found similar results (Furtado & Karan, 1990;
gnette illustrates how multiple motivations drive Hambrick & Cannella, 1993; Krishnan, Miller, &
many acquisitions and how different motivations Judge, 1997; Krug & Hegarty, 1997; Martin &
require different approaches for effectively integrat- McConnell, 1991; Walsh, 1989; Walsh & Ellwood,
ing target assets and executive teams. 1991).
We conclude by suggesting avenues for future These studies generated interest in understanding
research and practice. While existing research pro- the underlying causes of post-acquisition turnover.
vides a good starting point for understanding the Theory on acquisitions through the early 1990s was
effect of M&As on acquired executive teams, there largely driven by agency theory and the market for
are significant opportunities for universities and corporate control (Manne, 1965). When boards fail
research institutes, consulting firms, and corporate to correct poor firm performance, outside firms will
32 The Academy of Management Perspectives January

bid for control of the firm and improve performance Yet another factor in post-acquisition turnover
by replacing incompetent executives. This perspec- is executive seniority. From the acquirer’s point of
tive remained a dominant but untested view of view, replacing senior executives may have posi-
acquisitions for more than 25 years. As a result, tive symbolic effects by sending signals to target
many viewed executive turnover as an acceptable— employees that they are in charge. From the target’s
indeed, desirable—acquisition outcome. Subsequent point of view, senior executives are generally more
research, however, has largely debunked this view. accustomed to discretion and autonomy than less-
For example, Davis and Stout (1992) found that senior executives. As such, they may respond more
target companies generally outperform their com- negatively to the loss of status and autonomy and
petitors before acquisition, an indication that firms depart more quickly. In a survey of executives in-
acquire other firms because they have something volved in an acquisition, Krug and Nigh (2001)
they value. Walsh and Kosnik (1993) found similar found that a full one-third departed for subjec-
results in an analysis of corporate raiders and con- tive reasons that include fear of termination, alien-
cluded that there is “only evidence of market dis- ation, exclusion from the decision-making process,
cipline among target firms and competitors with lower status, and lost autonomy.2 In sum, psycho-
sustained histories of poor performance” (p. 671). logical perceptions have a great deal to do with
While poor performance is associated with higher the acquirer’s decision to retain or replace target
post-acquisition executive turnover, turnover is executives—and the executive’s decision to stay
generally high in targets with both good and bad or leave.
performance records. Poor pre-acquisition perfor-
mance, however, falls short of explaining why
The Link Between Executive Turnover and
executives depart at such high rates after acquisition.
Post-Acquisition Performance
Turnover may best be understood by looking
at executives’ psychological attributes and percep- Despite the widely accepted premise that execu-
tions of the acquisition. Acquiring firms may, for tive turnover leads to lower post-acquisition per-
example, replace executives to minimize resistance formance, support for this premise comes primarily
during the integration process, especially follow- from two empirical studies. The first, by Cannella
ing a hostile takeover (Cannella & Hambrick, 1993; and Hambrick (1993), surveyed acquiring firm
Walsh, 1989). Replacing executives may also mini- executives and analysts about their perceptions of
mize uncertainty and increase the perception of post-acquisition performance in 96 large, publicly
control. Psychological attributes and perceptions traded U.S. companies acquired between 1980 and
of the acquisition also appear to weigh heavily in 1984. They found that high executive turnover
cross-national transactions, with executive turnover rates were related to perceptions of lower post-
significantly higher in firms acquired by a foreign acquisition performance, and they concluded that
multinational (Krug & Hegarty, 1997). This may be “executives from acquired firms are an intrinsic
a consequence of cultural differences, which have component of the acquired firm’s resource base, and
been linked with both higher executive turnover their retention is an important determinant of post-
and lower post-acquisition performance (Chatterjee, acquisition performance” (p. 169). A second study,
Lubatkin, Schweiger, & Weber, 1992). Replacing by Krishnan and colleagues (1997), examined a
executives may minimize communication problems sample of 147 of the largest publicly traded U.S.
and cultural conflicts in cross-national transactions firms acquired between 1986 and 1988. They found
(Krug & Nigh, 1998, 2001). Another factor explain- that higher executive turnover was associated with
ing this turnover is the target executive’s reaction lower post-acquisition performance in their sample.
to the acquisition. Executives are more likely to They explained this by noting that “turnover in the
leave when they have negative perceptions of the acquired firm will also affect the performance of
long-term professional and personal effects of an the parent firm because the parent management
acquisition (Krug & Hegarty, 2001). Executives also will have to devote more of its time and resources
depart more quickly when they lose job status to achieve integration” (p. 365). These studies sup-
immediately after the acquisition (Hambrick & port a resource-based view that has now become
Cannella, 1993). Perceptions of lost autonomy have
more enduring effects that cause executives to 2
In the same study, Krug and Nigh found that one-third
leave several years later (Lubatkin, Schweiger, & were terminated, and the other third left for non-
Weber, 1999). subjective reasons.
2015 Krug, Wright, and Kroll 33

common: Target executives are valuable resources, performance records because they have something
and their retention leads to higher post-acquisition they value. Even corporate raiders, who publicly
performance (Butler, Perryman, & Ranft, 2012). proclaim that their mission is to buy underper-
forming firms and rid them of incompetent execu-
tives, are more likely to buy firms that outperform
THE BROADER CONTEXT: CONNECTING
the market. As Walsh and Kosnik (1993) concluded,
TURNOVER TO MICRO-, GROUP-, MESO-,
“the discipline engendered by the raiders studied
AND MACRO-LEVEL FACTORS
here appears to be very similar to the discipline
MOTIVATING ACQUISITIONS
revealed in firms not subject to external control
The acquiring company’s post-merger strategy challenges” (p. 693). In short, despite the logic of
involved a strong effort to absorb, sublimate, and agency theory and the market for corporate control,
force-fit our company into their corporate mold. poor performance doesn’t appear to be a major de-
They significantly overpaid for our company and terminant of most target firms’ ultimate acquisition.
that led them to push excessive goals and expect- Market theories are limited by the fact that only
ations on our company to improve performance. a small portion of companies acquired each year are
(Krug, 2009, p. 29) publicly traded. Most acquired firms are privately
Multiple theoretical perspectives using differ- held, family controlled, new ventures, or sub-
ent levels of analysis inform us about acquisition sidiaries or divisions of the seller. These firms can
motivations: (1) market (agency theory and market be acquired only with the owner’s consent. Many
for corporate control), (2) top management (empire- private firms have more effective monitoring devices
building, hubris, and upper echelon theories), than public firms because owners assume manage-
(3) industry (theory of merger waves and industrial ment roles that align owner and manager interests
organization), (4) firm (efficiency, diversification, (Li & Aguilera, 2008). In new ventures, many entre-
and resource-based theories), and (5) country preneurs invest their own wealth and rely on fund-
(Uppsala model, internalization theory, eclectic ing from friends and family members (Graebner &
paradigm, and evolutionary view of the multina- Eisenhardt, 2004). Self-monitoring by managers and
tional firm). Each perspective provides insights interactions with investors reduce agency costs and
about acquisition motivations (see Table 1) and link management and owner efforts to the firm’s
suggests guidelines for effectively integrating target success (Gompers & Lerner, 2003). In cross-border
executive teams (see Table 2). M&As, agency costs are affected by differences in
governance systems. Whereas Anglo-American gov-
ernance systems are shareholder driven, European
Market Perspective
and Japanese governance systems are driven by
The market perspective views acquisitions as a large institutional investors and union participation.
mechanism for improving performance in under- These other stakeholder groups often play stronger
performing firms. Based on agency theory and monitoring roles that reduce agency costs. In emerg-
market for corporate control, executives may engage ing countries such as China, governance systems
in activities that maximize their wealth at the ex- have more far-reaching government restrictions that
pense of shareholders (e.g., by investing in high-risk limit the acquirer’s ability to make changes in an
projects that increase bankruptcy risk). Boards often acquired firm’s executive team or employee base.
refuse to correct this behavior because their inter-
ests are better aligned with those of executives than
Top Management Perspective
those of shareholders. This occurs when executives
sit on the board or the CEO also holds the title Two theoretical perspectives, each grounded in
of board chair (Dalton, Hitt, Certo, & Dalton, 2008). agency theory, suggest that executives engage in
If boards refuse to take action, outside firms theo- M&As for personal reasons that destroy shareholder
retically intervene by acquiring the firm, firing its value. Empire-building theorists argue that execu-
executives, appointing outside directors, and sepa- tives acquire other firms to maximize firm size to
rating the CEO and chair roles (Nyberg, Fulmer, enhance their status and future compensation
Gerhart, & Carpenter, 2010). Empirical evidence, (Hope & Thomas, 2008). Hubris theorists argue that
however, indicates that market discipline is not a executives’ past acquisition successes cause them
driving force behind most acquisitions. Quite the to overestimate their ability to successfully integrate
contrary, most acquirers buy firms with good future acquisitions (Hayward, Shepherd, & Griffin,
TABLE 1
Theoretical Perspectives on Acquisition Objectives and Source of Value Creation
Perspective Theory Acquisition objective Metric Relevant articles

Market 1 Agency theory Realign shareholder and management Target firm risk Miller & Sardais (2011); Nyberg and
goals colleagues (2010)
2 Market for corporate control Replace incompetent target Target firm performance Martin & Combs (2009)
executives
Top management 3 Empire-building theory Increase executive status and future Firm growth and size Hope & Thomas (2008); Masulis,
compensation Wang, & Xie (2007)
4 Hubris theory Increase size and scope of the firm Firm growth and size Aktas, de Bodt, & Roll (2011);
Martin & Davis (2010)
Industry 5 Theory of merger waves Decrease industry turbulence Acquirer financial stability and Bruner (2004); McNamara and
performance colleagues (2008)
6 Industrial organization (IO) Increase firm size, market power, and Firm size, market share, and pricing Ellis, Reus, Lamont, & Ranft (2011)
entry barriers power
Firm 7 Efficiency theory Scale and scope efficiencies Firm size, economies of scale and Krishnan and colleagues (2009);
(synergies) scope Siegel & Simons (2010)
8 Diversification theory Firm growth Growth in revenues, profits, and Makri and colleagues (2010);
margins Zhou (2011)
9 Resource-based theory of the Acquire or leverage firm resources Competitive advantage and Barney, Ketchen, & Wright (2011)
firm and capabilities performance of combined firms
Country 10 Uppsala model Minimize firm risk Entry mode strategy, firm risk, Johanson & Vahlne (2009)
international experience
11 Internalization theory Protect internal investments in Entry mode strategy, firm profitability Buckley & Casson (2009)
knowledge assets
12 Eclectic paradigm and OLI Exploit differences in costs across Mobility of firm-specific assets across Dunning (2009)
model national markets national borders
13 Evolutionary view of the Create and transfer capabilities across Firm capabilities Kogut & Zander (2003)
MNE national borders, organizational
learning
TABLE 2
Integration of Theoretical Perspectives and Prescriptions for Integrating Target Company Top Management Teams
Perspective Theory Executive retention desired Executive replacement desired Theoretical links

Market 1 Agency theory Inside directors Separation of ownership and


Chair (separate CEO and chair control in public firms
positions)
2 Market for corporate control Poor performers, especially more-senior Agency theory
executives
Top management 3 Empire-building theory Empire-building CEO and chair Agency theory
4 Hubris theory Incompetent executives Agency theory
5 Upper echelons theory Executives with compatible traits Executives with non-compatible traits Organizational fit
6 Top management team Executives with complementary Executives with redundant skill sets Strategic fit
complementarity skill sets
Industry 7 Theory of merger waves Increase global efficiencies, restructure Empire-building theory,
assets, and consolidate capacity hubris theory, bandwagon
effects
8 Industrial organization High-growth industry, local industry Mature industry, global industry Hubris theory, industrial
structure structure organization, efficiency
theory
Firm 9 Efficiency theory Industry maturity, industry Theory of merger waves, industrial
consolidation organization
10 Diversification Acquirer executives lack knowledge Acquirer has adequate supply of Efficiency theory, resource-based
to integrate the target firm executives to operate the target firm theory, upper echelons theory
using its own executives
11 Resource-based theory of the firm Target executives have idiosyncratic Objective is to leverage acquirer Theory of the growth of the firm
knowledge and capabilities capabilities to improve target
performance
Country 12 Uppsala model Acquirer lacks international Acquirer has significant international Transaction cost theory
experience experience
13 Internalization theory Protect investments in knowledge assets Transaction cost theory
by transferring knowledge using
acquirer’s executives
14 Eclectic paradigm and OLI model Country-specific assets or Acquired assets support global Locational economics
government regulations require efficiencies through consolidation
local knowledge and rationalized production
15 Evolutionary view of the MNE Target executives support Resource-based theory
organizational learning and
transfer of knowledge
36 The Academy of Management Perspectives January

2006). Executives often overpay for acquisition tar- underperforming assets and employees and by up-
gets and engage in excessive acquisitions that grow grading plant capabilities (Siegel & Simons, 2010).
the firm beyond its optimal size. Hubris among Effectively merging firms is a process of combining
founders in private firms and new ventures is es- complementary assets, resources, and executive
pecially destructive because smaller firms may lack capabilities in ways that improve performance. The
financial resources to recover from bad investments. decision to retain certain executives and replace
Both theories imply that self-serving executives others is highly contextual. It depends on top man-
should be removed. However, it is often difficult to agement team characteristics and their expected
attribute merger failure to self-interested executive contributions to acquisition objectives.
behavior, especially when executives tout multiple
acquisition objectives.
Industry Perspective
Upper echelons theory may offer better insights
into how acquiring firms integrate target execu- Mergers frequently occur in waves that are driven
tive teams. Executives make decisions based on by economic, regulatory, or technological shocks that
personalized interpretations of strategic events. motivate the restructuring of an industry’s assets
Their interpretations are a function of their unique (Bruner, 2004). McNamara, Haleblian, and Dykes
experiences, values, and functional backgrounds (2008) found that performance is higher for acquir-
(Hambrick, 2007). An acquirer’s interpretation of ers making acquisitions at the beginning—but lower
target executives should, therefore, influence its for acquirers making acquisitions at the height—of
decisions about who stays and leaves. Heteroge- a merger wave. Early movers may have asymmetri-
neous executive teams, for example, frequently ex- cal information that enables them to identify high-
perience sociocognitive conflict that undermines value targets at lower cost, lock in valuable assets,
cooperation. To minimize conflict, acquirers may be and preempt competition. In contrast, bandwagon
more likely to retain executives who have similar effects cause other firms to enter the market later in
management styles and a shared understanding of a merger wave when only lower-value targets are
acquisition objectives. In cross-border acquisitions, available at higher cost (Fiol & O’Connor, 2003).
large cultural differences can exacerbate conflicts. Many late movers also engage in less-comprehensive
Acquirers may attempt to minimize this conflict by analysis and are more likely to commit to an ac-
integrating the foreign firm using their own execu- quisition despite lower expected returns (Vaaler &
tives (Sekiguchi, Bebenroth, & Li, 2011). In contrast, McNamara, 2004). This may cause performance
heterogeneous executive teams are better at manag- pressures that motivate firms to restructure target
ing complexity (Carpenter, 2002). When an acquirer assets or downsize the employee base in an effort
faces stagnant sales or declining market share, in- to improve profitability. Target executives may fall
tegration success may hinge on the retention of victim to such efforts.
executives who have diverse backgrounds and per- Early research in industrial organization viewed
spectives that contribute to strategic change. firm size as a primary acquisition objective. When
Krishnan and colleagues (1997) supported this firms compete on the basis of homogeneous prod-
view. They analyzed the performance effects of top ucts and similar strategies, acquisitions are a means
management team complementarity, which they to increase pricing power and lower costs through
defined as differences in the functional backgrounds scale and scope efficiencies. Later work by evolu-
of executives from the acquiring and target firms. tionary economists viewed firm growth and market
Complementary top management teams were di- power as a natural outcome of a firm’s cumulative
rectly linked to both lower turnover and higher investments in innovation, which stimulate demand
post-acquisition performance. In essence, one firm’s and increase pricing power (Knott, 2003). In both
strengths offset the other firm’s weaknesses, and cases, acquisitions are a rational strategy for growing
vice versa. Differences in functional backgrounds the firm and leveraging firm size to achieve greater
are more easily integrated and contribute to the or- economies of scale and scope (Mata & Portugal,
ganizational learning process. When merging exec- 2002). Thus, an industry’s stage of growth may de-
utive teams have similar functional backgrounds, termine whether target executives are retained or
synergies are created by eliminating redundant ex- replaced. In mature industries, acquisitions can be
ecutive positions. A similar process occurs in partial used to consolidate industry cafici e ncies arec share
acquisitions, which enable an acquirer to improve by eliminating competition. Efficiencies are created
an acquired plant’s productivity by eliminating by eliminating redundant target assets, including
2015 Krug, Wright, and Kroll 37

redundant executive positions. In contrast, acquis- redundant assets are theoretically greater when
itions are a means of more rapidly bringing products merging firms operate in the same industry. This
to market compared to internal development. In new suggests that acquirers are more likely to replace
or high-growth markets, firms can use acquisitions executives when they acquire firms in the same in-
to more rapidly grow their market share and reve- dustry. Existing studies, however, indicate that re-
nue base. Retaining target executives may become latedness is a weak predictor of executive turnover.
an important goal that supports firm growth, espe- Studies have generally measured relatedness
cially when the acquirer lacks an adequate supply of based on product and market similarities across
executives to supply newly acquired firms. businesses using coarse measures such as product
Industry structure also plays an important role in SIC codes (Robins & Wiersema, 2003). Product or
shaping integration mechanisms in cross-border market similarities, however, may be insufficient for
acquisitions. Krug and Nigh (1998) found that tar- synergy creation. Synergies may require more fine-
get executives are more likely to be retained when grained commonalities within specific value-chain
the firm is acquired by a multinational firm that activities (e.g., production and marketing com-
competes in a multi-domestic industry such as plementarities between and within businesses).
metals, beverages, glass products, consumer prod- These commonalities are critical in technology-
ucts, or processed foods. Differentiated consumer intensive industries, where value is created when
tastes, fragmented distribution channels, and high firms acquire scientific and technological knowledge
transportation costs make it more difficult for firms that is complementary to their own (Makri, Hitt, &
to benefit from product standardization and globally Lane, 2010). Even when synergy opportunities exist,
rationalized production. Retaining local executives they are not always easy to capture, especially when
with in-depth knowledge of the local market may be firms have different perceptions of the source of
an important source of value creation. The opposite relatedness or disagree on acquisition objectives.
likely occurs in global industries such as automo- Executives’ perceptions of relatedness are multidi-
biles, electronics, computers, and farm machinery. mensional and judgmental. They include factors that
Technological intensity and standardized consumer are not always easy to capture using coarse measures
tastes allow firms to increase worldwide sales vol- of relatedness based on product-market, resource,
ume and lower costs through large-scale produc- and value-chain similarities (Pehrsson, 2006).
tion. Subsidiaries no longer operate as autonomous Resource-based theory (RBT) focuses on the firm’s
entities; rather, they become part of the firm’s ability to establish competitive advantages by com-
worldwide network that supports rationalization of bining complementary resources in unique ways
the firm’s global value-chain activities. Local market not possible without a combination (Zhou, 2011).
knowledge is less likely to be critical to the firm’s Target executives may possess unique capabilities
long-term success. and knowledge critical to the target’s long-term suc-
cess. Negative performance effects are heightened
when more-senior executives, who have embedded
Firm Perspective
knowledge of the firm and industry, depart (Cannella
The firm perspective views acquisitions as a value- & Hambrick, 1993). A senior executive’s positional
enhancing strategy that increases efficiencies and rank, however, may be less important than tenure
supports value creation and transfer. Efficiency the- insofar as rank may not capture variations in posi-
ory, for example, suggests that acquisitions are a tions across firms or instances where executives are
means of achieving financial, operational, and man- hired from the outside. Indeed, Bergh (2001) found
agerial synergies (e.g., by combining units to achieve that acquired firms are more likely to be divested
scale and scope efficiencies) (Krishnan, Krishnan, & five years later when their longest-tenured execu-
Lefanowicz, 2009). Like empire-building theory and tives depart shortly after the acquisition. Therefore,
industrial organization, firm size is a primary source an executive’s organizational tenure may be a more
of value creation. The objective, however, is effi- effective measure of imbedded capabilities than
ciency and cost reduction rather than revenue en- simple seniority of titular status.
hancement. Efficiencies achieved by combining
assets imply that value is created when executives
Country Perspective
are replaced, often when the acquirer converts a
stand-alone target to a division. Opportunities to The country perspective examines the foreign
create efficiencies by combining units or eliminating direct investment (FDI) activities of multinational
38 The Academy of Management Perspectives January

enterprises (MNEs). The Uppsala model provided ILLUSTRATIVE CASES FROM THE
early insights into the firm’s internationalization AUTOMOBILE INDUSTRY: HOW ACQUISITION
process (Johanson & Vahlne, 2009). When firms MOTIVATIONS SHAPE
lack international experience, they minimize cul- EXECUTIVE TURNOVER
tural differences by entering markets through
DaimlerChrysler Merger (1998)
exports or licensing. As firms gain experience, they
increasingly commit assets to foreign markets by The Germans tended to be more dictatorial. They
establishing wholly owned subsidiaries. Later, in- were very structured and did more detailed analy-
ternalization theory suggested that MNEs prefer sis. Much slower at decision making. Morale went
to enter markets using wholly owned subsidiaries downhill fast. (Krug & Nigh, 2001, p. 89)
because they subject the firm’s investments in The 1998 DaimlerChrysler (DCX) merger illus-
knowledge assets to lower risk of appropriation trates how multiple perspectives drive M&A activ-
(Buckley & Casson, 2009). The eclectic paradigm ity and influence integration processes (Bruner
and OLI model extended internalization theory et al., 2001; Bruner, Christmann, & Spekman, 2006;
by explaining MNEs’ FDI decisions based on Morosini & Radler, 2003). It was touted as a “merger
three factors: ownership advantages (O), locational of equals,” and Jiirgen Schrempp (CEO at Daimler)
advantages (L), and internalization of ownership and Robert Eaton (CEO at Chrysler) initially served
advantages in overseas production (I). Locational as co-chairmen and CEOs. While they shared some
advantages arise when MNEs move mobile firm- goals, they had different views about the potential
specific assets across national markets to exploit benefits of the merger. Eaton wanted to reduce
cost differences (Dunning, 2009). Last, the evolu- Chrysler’s dependence on the North American
tionary view examines the MNE as a mechanism market, improve efficiencies, and increase Chrysler’s
for developing cross-national capabilities (Kogut & size to minimize bankruptcy risk. Schrempp wanted
Zander, 2003). Whereas internalization theory fo- to build a global industry leader with a presence
cuses on the one-directional transfer of intangible in the U.S. market, expand Daimler’s brand down
assets into markets using FDI, the evolutionary market, and exploit product and market comple-
view focuses on the two-directional combination of mentarities. Whereas .Daimler competed primarily
capabilities across national borders using different in North America, Daimler competed primarily in
entry mode strategies. Europe. Whereas Chrysler focused on trucks, vans,
Executive turnover is intensified in cross- and smaller cars, Daimler focused on premier cars
border acquisitions (Krug & Aguilera, 2005). The and heavy trucks. It was in this light that Schrempp
acquirer’s use of parent or local executives to in- considered the merger to be “synergistic.”
tegrate an acquisition is influenced by a range The creation of a single organization created op-
of factors. Investing in culturally distant markets portunities to drive cost savings through purchasing
creates higher management costs and can create economies, consolidation of facilities, exchange of
tensions that hinder integration efforts. The ac- components and technology, and shared distribution.
quirer’s objective may also be to transfer inter- Schrempp promised annual savings of $3 billion.
nally developed competitive advantages into the The merger agreement, however, required a clear
foreign market. Many MNEs may use their own separation between brands and prohibited shared
executives to aid the transfer of capabilities, platforms and combined dealerships. Another prob-
maintain control over knowledge assets, and mi- lem was that the formation of a Chairmen’s Inte-
nimize the negative effect of cultural differences. gration Council left senior executives at Chrysler
Other acquisitions are motivated by a desire to feeling locked out of the decision-making process.
acquire technology and local capabilities (Anand Most of Chrysler’s top executives departed within
& Delios, 2002). In high-growth industries, or two years after the merger, including Bob Eaton,
when a firm lags competitors, MNEs may prefer who departed in 2000. Chrysler’s new president,
partial acquisitions or joint ventures over full Tom Stallkamp, complained of communication
acquisitions to speed market entry or avoid esca- problems created by Schrempp’s physical distance
lating rivalry with local competitors (Chen, 2008). from Chrysler. Culture clashes between German and
Local executives may play a more critical role U.S. employees exacerbated cooperation problems.
because they have idiosyncratic knowledge of the The German governance structure also slowed
local market that aids capabilities transfer and orga- the integration process. Daimler’s supervisory
nizational learning. board included union representatives who resisted
2015 Krug, Wright, and Kroll 39

cost-cutting measures that reduced employment. Mitsubishi executives. The German team refused to
In addition, institutional investors held close to involve Mitsubishi managers in the planning pro-
one-half of Daimler’s shares. Daimler’s largest cess and restricted communications with employees.
shareholder, Deutsche Bank, was known for influ- Few employees knewDCX’s intentions, and unclear
encing strategy and appointments to the management goals heightened uncertainty. To make matters
board. Whereas Schrempp supported a shareholder worse, Eckrodt did not have a direct reporting re-
approach that focused on short-term stock price, lationship with Schrempp, which slowed decision
institutional stakeholders focused on long-term making and sent signals to Mitsubishi managers
growth. Shareholders and analysts were both cri- that the German integration team was not in charge.
tical of Schrempp’s leadership. Many believed his Consequently, DaimlerChrysler wasn’t able to es-
real goal was to increase Daimler’s market power tablish legitimacy, break through communication
and enhance his own wealth and status. In the end, barriers, or gain the acceptance of Mitsubishi exec-
few synergies were ever realized. Losses mounted utives and employees. By 2003, falling sales, high
until DaimlerChrysler’s falling stock price forced default rates, and rising debt led to a sharp decline
Schrempp to resign in 2005. Two years later, in Mitsubishi’s stock price to roughly one-quarter its
Daimler sold Chrysler to Cerberus Capital Manage- value at the time of DCX’s acquisition. DCX refused
ment, paying Cerberus close to $650 million to to financially support Mitsubishi, which was forced
assume its liabilities. The result—a $36.7 billion to seek a second external rescue package. Eckrodt
loss in five years—remains one of the worst merg- resigned as CEO one year later. Additional revela-
ers in history. tions of auto defects led to continuing losses and a
third rescue package that diluted DaimlerChrysler’s
interest from 37 to 12%. DaimlerChrysler finally sold
Renault-Nissan (1999) and DaimlerChrysler-
its remaining interest in 2005 for $1.1 billion—a loss
Mitsubishi (2000)
of $1.4 billion in four years.
The partial acquisitions of Nissan by Renault Like Mitsubishi, Nissan had suffered sustained
(37%) in 1999 and Mitsubishi Motors by Daimler- losses, high debt, and declining global share in the
Chrysler (34%) in 2000 provide good examples of decade leading up to Renault’s partial acquisition
acquisitions that had similar starting conditions but in 1999. Nissan had a bloated bureaucracy, multiple
widely divergent outcomes (Froese & Goeritz, 2007). management layers, a weak performance culture,
Both Japanese companies had long histories of poor and 3,000 suppliers supporting 25 different plat-
performance. Their survival depended on partner- forms and 43 models, only four of which were
ships that helped each firm increase sales, lower profitable. Carlos Ghosn, who had led turnarounds
costs, and reduce debt. Schrempp approached at Michelin, Uniroyal, and Renault, was named
Nissan about an acquisition in 1999 but withdrew Nissan’s COO and charged with its turnaround.
after his management board expressed concern Yoshikazu Hanawa continued as Nissan’s CEO. In
about Daimler’s ability to manage another acquisi- contrast to Daimler’s centralized management style,
tion so soon after its merger with Chrysler. Renault Renault created an executive committee composed
quickly stepped in to acquire interest in Nissan of Renault and Nissan executives who jointly
instead. One year later, Schrempp approached searched for synergies and formulated strategy.
Mitsubishi with an offer. Shortly after, it was Eleven cross-functional teams were created to in-
revealed that Mitsubishi had covered up defects in clude Nissan employees in the integration process.
its automobiles. A massive product recall and de- Nine cross-functional teams were formed to en-
cline in Mitsubishi’s share price followed. Never- hance participation and communication.
theless, Schrempp proceeded with the acquisition, By including Nissan managers and employees
which supported his vision of a global market in the decision-making process, Renault was able to
player (“Welt AG”) with presence in Asia, North establish a culture of mutual respect that created
America, and Europe. strong employee commitment and a speedier in-
The acquisition of Mitsubishi was plagued with tegration process. By the end of the first year, Nissan
problems. DCX sent an executive team led by Rolf had reduced its debt by 50% and tripled operating
Eckrodt to lead turnaround efforts at Mitsubishi. margins. Of 38 models, 18 became profitable. By the
However, it wasn’t until two years later that Eckrodt end of the second year, Renault and Nissan began
was officially named Mitsubishi’s CEO. As a result, to jointly develop new platforms. Integration efforts
Eckrodt’s authority was never fully accepted by were so successful that Renault increased its interest
40 The Academy of Management Perspectives January

in Nissan to 44%. In turn, Nissan acquired a 15% first Fiat 500 was sold in the United States in late
interest in Renault. In short, Renault’s success was 2011. The Fiat-Chrysler alliance was so successful
largely a result of its ability to successful integrate that Fiat increased its share in Chrysler to 58.5% in
Nissan’s human resources early in the integration 2012 and announced that the two companies would
process. DaimlerChrysler was unable to achieve the merge by 2014.
same results.
MUCH WORK TO DO: WHERE TO BUILD ON
Fiat’s Acquisition of Chrysler (2009) SOLID RESEARCH BASES
After Cerberus Capital assumed Chrysler’s assets We were “metamorphosed” from a publicly
from Daimler in 2007, it terminated 12,000 Chrysler traded U.S. Fortune 500 company to the U.S. sub-
workers and borrowed heavily to meet cash flow sidiary of a Swedish multinational. The elimination
needs. Poor sales and debt eventually forced it to of major departments and location issues had to be
turn to the U.S. government for $5.5 billion in loans addressed at an early stage and continued to be a
to prevent Chrysler’s bankruptcy (Fritz, Spekman, & problem long after the acquisition. I admired the
Murphy, 2009). Chrysler, however, continued to Swedish global management style. They gave us
falter. In early 2009, it filed for bankruptcy and se- greatly expanded professional responsibilities in
cured an additional $4 billion bridge loan from the M&A area but also gave us a lot of professional
the U.S. government. Four months later, Chrysler independence. (Krug, 2009, p. 87)
emerged from bankruptcy with an agreement with Existing studies provide a good foundation of
Italian carmaker Fiat to assume Chrysler’s assets. knowledge on the effects of M&As on acquired top
Fiat received an initial equity interest of 20%, with management teams. It is clear that acquisitions
the remaining shares held by the United Auto create conditions that motivate many executives to
Workers (UAW) and U.S. and Canadian governments depart at high rates after an acquisition. However,
(Foley, Goldberg, & Meyer, 2010; Pisano, Andrews, significant gaps in the literature continue to exist.
& Di Fiore, 2011). Fiat’s CEO, Sergio Marchionne, Perhaps most noteworthy is the focus of existing
assumed the role of Chrysler’s CEO. He immediately studies on executive turnover in small samples of
restructured Chrysler around brand teams to flatten publicly traded firms acquired in the 1970s and
Chrysler’s structure and give Chrysler managers 1980s. Walsh’s comment that “the present investi-
more control over brand decisions. gation suffered from a restriction of range problem”
Flattening Chrysler’s structure made Marchionne (1988, p. 181) characterizes existing work. The use
more accessible to Chrysler executives. In addition of small samples is largely a methodological prob-
to 21 direct reports at Fiat, Marchionne established lem; namely, collecting top management turnover
direct reporting relationships with 25 Chrysler data are difficult and time-consuming. Neverthe-
executives and encouraged frequent communica- less, random samples of M&As indicate that about
tion. DaimlerChrysler’s culture had supported cen- two-thirds of acquired firms are privately held
tralized decision making that restricted information or subsidiaries or divisions of other firms (Zollo &
flow to middle- and lower-level managers. In con- Singh, 2004).
trast, Marchionne demanded complete information It remains unclear whether turnover varies as a
sharing with Chrysler’s executives and employees. function of the target firm’s ownership structure.
In addition, he hired non-U.S. and non-Italian exe- We know that public and private firms are often
cutives to help break down existing binational cul- acquired for different reasons. Information asym-
tural barriers between the two top management metry makes it difficult for acquirers to accurately
teams. Operationally, Marchionne made Fiat’s fuel- estimate the value of private targets (Ragozzino &
efficient engine technology available to Chrysler, Reuer, 2009). As a result, acquirers are more likely
which established a new plant in Michigan to to buy private firms in similar businesses or that
produce Fiat’s FIRE engine. He also gave Fiat’s have geographically concentrated tangible assets
award-winning Alfa Romeo Giulietta platform to that are easier to value (Capron & Shen, 2007). If
Chrysler, which it used to design a new Dodge Dart acquirers have executives with knowledge of the
for the compact sedan market. In addition, he es- target’s business, are executives in private targets
tablished Brand North America, which was located less valuable and more likely to be replaced? In
at Chrysler’s headquarters in Michigan, to jointly public targets, information availability makes it more
redesign the new Fiat 500 for the U.S. market. The difficult for acquirers to identify undervalued firms
2015 Krug, Wright, and Kroll 41

and negotiate acquisition prices that don’t capitalize creation and organizational learning. Bergh (2001)
future cash flow gains from the acquisition (Shen & found that retaining the longest-tenured executives
Reuer, 2005). Consequently, acquirers are more likely leads to more successful outcomes because exe-
to buy public targets when they enter new busi- cutives have idiosyncratic knowledge of the firm.
nesses or the target has geographically dispersed Zollo and Singh (2004) argued that retaining exec-
intangible assets that are more difficult to value. Are utives contributes knowledge to the acquirer and
executives in public targets more valuable in these minimizes “organizational disruption.” Ranft and
transactions and more likely to be retained? More Lord (2000) and Graebner (2004) found that retain-
research is needed to answer these questions. ing target executives minimizes the destruction of
In addition to differences between public and pri- the firm’s knowledge-based resources, supports
vate firms, turnover patterns may also vary within technology transfer, and reduces disruption in or-
private firms based on ownership differences. Unlike ganizational routines. In essence, research has taken
public firms, private firms cannot be acquired with- a resource-based view to argue that executive reten-
out the consent of their owners; therefore, owners tion contributes to acquisition success by support-
are in a better position to negotiate more favorable ing knowledge creation, retention, and transfer.
terms. In family firms, continued family involve- We’ve provided a wide range of alternative theo-
ment is often a condition of sale that may guarantee retical perspectives to show that this may not always
executive retention (Romano, Tanewski, & Smyrnios, be the case. There are good theoretical arguments
2001). In contrast, entrepreneurs often use acquis- that suggest that replacing target executives can be
itions to successfully exit their firm to relieve per- a souice of value creation in many acquisitions.
sonal pressures, eliminate stressful managerial In Table 2, we outlined different conditions under
responsibilities, or achieve financial independence which retaining or replacing target executives may
(Graebner, Eisenhardt, & Roundy, 2010). In other create value. Partial acquisitions, for example, can
cases, entrepreneurs use acquisitions to negotiate be an effective mechanism for reallocating assets
mutually synergistic combinations that support the and resources to more effective uses. The high fail-
firm’s continued growth and ensure long-term sur- ure rate of acquisitions is often attributed to the in-
vival (Graebner & Eisenhardt, 2004). In short, pat- herent difficulty of integrating firms composed of
terns of executive turnover are likely to vary based multiple plants, subsidiaries, and divisions. It is
on the objectives of the acquisition and the psy- generally easier for acquirers to identify, accurately
chological attributes and personal motivations of price, and effectively integrate acquisitions of a sin-
executives who negotiate the deal. gle plant or subsidiary acquired from another firm.
Another important gap in the literature relates Partial acquisitions can enhance plant productivity
to the turnover—performance relationship. As dis- through the “matching of workers and managers
cussed, only two studies have directly measured to firms and industries that best suit their skills”
this relationship in samples of large, public, United (Siegel & Simons, 2010, p. 15). Another example is
States firms acquired during the 1980s (Cannella & industry structure. Using resource-based theory, we
Hambrick, 1993; Krishnan et al., 1997). The findings might argue that retaining target executives con-
of these studies have been widely accepted. It is still tributes value in new or rapidly evolving industries
unclear, however, whether turnover patterns found because executives support technology transfer and
in acquisitions from the 1980s extend to more recent the acquirer’s growing managerial resource needs
acquisitions. Merger waves are driven by different (Ranft & Lord, 2002). Alternatively, we might use
structural phenomena. In addition, the timing of a efficiency theory to argue that replacing target exe-
firm’s acquisition during a merger wave has im- cutives contributes value in mature industries when
portant performance implications that may affect consolidation is used to eliminate industry capacity
when and under what conditions target executives and redundant assets.
are retained or replaced (Haleblian, McNamara, In cross-border acquisitions, executive turnover
Kolev, & Dykes, 2012). is affected by a wide range of psychological, firm,
These research questions, however, remain largely and industry factors. Cross-national cultural differ-
unaddressed. Instead, recent research has focused on ences have been linked to lower post-acquisition
identifying reasons why executive retention contri- performance (Very, Lubatkin, Calori, & Veiga, 1997).
butes to acquisition success. For example, Krishnan Cultural differences create obstacles to integration
and colleagues (1997) found that merging comple- by increasing resistance to the acquisition and re-
mentary executive teams contributes to synergy ducing cooperation between executive teams. When
42 The Academy of Management Perspectives January

cultural differences exist, multinational firms are in acquired firms—a view that has been widely ac-
more likely to replace local executives with their cepted in both academic and business circles for
own (Krug & Nigh, 1998). The negative effect of close to 20 years. Our analysis shows that signi-
culture is most critical shortly after the acquisition, ficant empirical and theoretical gaps continue to
when the acquirer is most likely to make structural exist in the literature. Three gaps seem particularly
changes in the target. The global structure of the relevant:
acquirer’s industry also influences its decision to
• Turnover as a dependent variable. First, research
integrate an acquired foreign firm using expatriates
has uniformly concluded that acquisitions lead
or local executives. Multinational firms that com-
to higher-than-normal executive turnover shortly
pete in globally integrated industries are more likely
after an acquisition. Studies have almost exclu-
to use expatriates to transfer standardized decision-
sively analyzed turnover among public targets.
making processes into an acquired foreign firm
Most acquired firms, however, are not publicly
(Krug & Nigh, 1998). In contrast, firms competing in
traded before acquisition; rather, they are pri-
locally responsive industries are more likely to rely
vately held, family, entrepreneurial, and new-
on local executives because they have better knowl-
venture firms. We presented numerous examples
edge of local market conditions, customer needs,
of instances where turnover might be higher or
and distribution channels. Do different integration
lower depending on the ownership structure of
mechanisms and patterns of turnover have positive
the acquired firm, such as when a family firm
effects on long-term acquisition performance in
negotiates the continued employ ment of family
cross-border acquisitions?
members as a condition of sale. What are the spe-
Existing research has generally concluded that
cific conditions under which one might expect
the effects of acquisitions are short-lived and that
higher or lower turnover following an acquisi-
executive turnover rates return to normal levels
tion? Analysis of turnover effects of M&As in
within a few years after an acquisition. Recent re-
these other organizational forms, related acquis-
search, however, shows that many acquisitions lead
itions, partial acquisitions, acquisitions involving
to instability in acquired firms that causes execu-
smaller firms, and cross- border transactions are
tives to depart at higher-than-normal rates for 10
among many topics ripe for investigation.
or more years (Krug, 2003; Krug & Shill, 2008). This
• Performance as a dependent variable. Second,
suggests that early turnover motivates higher turn-
we outlined prescriptions for integrating target
over among executives hired several years after the
company top management teams using multiple
acquisition. We still know very little about possible
theoretical perspectives. Our analysis suggests
turnover contagion effects in acquired firms. It is
that executive turnover may have positive or
possible that high executive turnover shortly after
negative performance outcomes depending on
an acquisition creates greater uncertainty among
each acquisition’s idiosyncratic objectives. Table 2
newly hired executives surrounding their manage-
illustrates the myriad of opportunities that exist
rial discretion. This uncertainty may cause newly
to test competing hypotheses about the turnover—
hired executives to leave more quickly (Krug, 2009).
performance relationship between and within dif-
A firm may also use job rotations as a means of
ferent theoretical perspectives. What are the
stimulating organizational change, promoting di-
specific conditions under which positive or neg-
versity in decision making, and training future
ative performance outcomes might be expected
executives. In the Fiat-Chrysler acquisition, Fiat
when target executives are retained or replaced?
hired executives with different national back-
Which executives should be retained or replaced?
grounds to help break embedded cultural barriers
How does the timing of an acquirer’s acquisi-
and promote a global perspective in Chrysler’s new
tion during a merger wave affect the turnover-
executive team. The composition of a newly merged
performance relationship? When and under what
top management team is likely to have significant
conditions does retaining or replacing foreign
long-term performance effects that vary based on a
nationals contribute to performance in cross-
wide range of factors.
border acquisitions?
• Theoretical context. Third, research has almost
CONCLUSION
exclusively used resource-based theory to argue
This paper challenges the one-sided view that that the retention of executives—especially more
high executive turnover leads to lower performance tenured ones—leads to higher post-acquisition
2015 Krug, Wright, and Kroll 43

performance. In Table 1, we examined 13 theo- Negotiations between Daimler and Chrysler (Case
retical perspectives that inform us about acqui- #UV0110). Charlottesville: University of Virginia,
sition motivations. It is evident that acquisitions Darden School Of Business.
are driven by a wide range of often conflicting Buckley, P. J., & Casson, M. C. (2009). The internalisation
micro-, group-, meso-, and macro-level factors. theory of the multinational enterprise: A review of the
Existing research has yet to capture the multilevel progress of a research agenda after 30 years. Journal of
complexities of acquisition motivations or the International Business Studies, 40(9), 1563–1580.
complex link between executive turnover and Butler, F. C., Perryman, A. A., & Ranft, A. L. (2012).
post-acquisition performance using alternative Examining the effects of acquired top management
theoretical explanations. team turnover on firm performance post-acquisition:
A meta-analysis. Journal of Managerial Issues, 12(1),
New theoretical and empirical insights are some- 47–60.
times readily accepted and left unchallenged de-
Cannella, A. A., Jr., & Hambrick, D. C. (1993). Effects of
spite unanswered questions. Earlier, we used the
executive departures on the performance of acquired
example of the market for corporate control (Manne, firms. Strategic Management Journal, 14, 137–152.
1965), which remained an unchallenged view of
merger motivations for close to three decades before Capron, L., & Shen, J.-C. (2007). Acquisitions of private
vs. public firms: Private information, target selection,
research revealed little empirical support (Davis &
and acquirer returns. Strategic Management Journal,
Stout, 1992; Walsh & Kosnik, 1993). A similar fate 28(9), 891–911.
seems to have befallen the phenomenon of exe-
cutive turnover in M&As. The decision to retain or Carpenter, M. A. (2002). The implications of strategy and
social context for the relationship between top man-
replace target company executives is largely a mat-
agement team heterogeneity and firm performance.
ter of context. Future research that considers con-
Strategic Management Journal, 23(3), 275–284.
text and the short-, intermediate-, and long-term
performance consequences of executive turnover is Chatterjee, S., Lubatkin, M. H., Schweiger, D. M., & Weber,
needed to move this research stream forward and Y. (1992). Cultural differences and shareholder value
in related mergers: Linking equity and human capital.
contribute additional insights to executive practice.
Strategic Management Journal, 13(5), 319–334.
Chen, S.-F. (2008). The motives for international acquis-
REFERENCES itions: Capability procurements, strategic considera-
tions, and the role of ownership structures. Journal of
Adolph, G., & Pettit, J. (2009). Making the most of M&A.
International Business Studies, 39(3), 454–471.
Strategy1Business, 55, 1–12.
Dalton, D. R., Hitt, M. A., Certo, S. T., & Dalton, C. M.
Aktas, N., de Bodt, E., & Roll, R. (2011). Serial acquirer
(2008). The fundamental agency problem and its
bidding: An empirical test of the learning hypothesis.
mitigation: Independence, equity, and the market for
Journal of Corporate Finance, 17(1), 18–32.
corporate control. In J. P. Walsh & A. P. Brief. (Eds.),
Anand, J., & Delios, A. (2002). Absolute and relative Annals of the Academy of Management (Vol. 1,
resources as determinants of international acquis- pp. 1–64). New York: Lawrence Erlbaum.
itions. Strategic Management Journal, 23(2), 119–134.
Davis, G. F., & Stout, S. K. (1992). Organizational theory
Barney, J. B., Ketchen, D. J., Jr., & Wright, M. (2011). The and the market for corporate control: A dynamic
future of resource-based theory: Revitalization or analysis of the characteristics of large takeover tar-
decline? Journal of Management, 37(5), 1299–1315. gets, 1980–1990. Administrative Science Quarterly,
Bergh, D. D. (2001). Executive retention and acquisition 37(4), 605–633.
outcomes: A test of opposing views on the influence de Souza, I., Adolph, G., Gemes, A., & Marchi, R. (2007).
of organization tenure. Journal of Management, 27(5), Perils of financial sector M&As: Seven steps to suc-
603–622. cessful integration. Booz and Company Management
Bruner, R. (2004). Applied mergers and acquisitions. Tool Kit (pp. 1–15). New York: Booz and Company.
Hoboken, NJ: John Wiley & Sons, Inc. Dunning, J. H. (2009). Location and the multinational
Bruner, R., Christmann, P., & Spekman, R. (2006). Chrys- enterprise: A neglected factor? Journal of International
ler Corporation: Negotiations between Daimler and Business Studies, 40(1), 5–19.
Chrysler (Case #UV0085). Charlottesville: University Ellis, K. M., Reus, T. H., Lamont, B. T., & Ranft, A. L. (2011).
of Virginia, Darden School Foundation. Transfer effects in large acquisitions: How size-specific
Bruner, R. F., Carr, S., Spekman, R. E., Davies, M., Kannry, experience matters. Strategic Management Journal,
B., & Christmann, P. (2001). Daimler-Benz A.G: 54(6), 1261–1276.
44 The Academy of Management Perspectives January

Fiol, C. M., & O’Connor, E. J. (2003). Waking up! Mind- Johanson, J., & Vahlne, J.-E. (2009). The Uppsala in-
fulness in the face of bandwagons. Academy of ternationalization process model revisited: From lia-
Management Journal, 28(1), 54–70. bility of foreignness to liability of outsidership. Journal
Foley, C. F., Goldberg, L. G., & Meyer, L. N. (2010). of International Business Studies, 40(9), 1411–1431.
Chrysler’s sale to Fiat (Case #9-210-022). Boston: Knott, A. M. (2003). Persistent heterogeneity and sus-
Harvard Business School Publishing. tainable innovation. Strategic Management Journal,
Fritz, J., Spekman, R. E., & Murphy, T. (2009). Fiat and 24(8), 687–705.
Chrysler: Gaining on global automakers? (Case Kogut, B., & Zander, U. (2003). Knowledge of the firm and
#UV2975). Charlottesville: University of Virginia, the evolutionary theory of the multinational cor-
Darden School Of Business. poration. Journal of International Business Studies,
34(6), 516–529.
Froese, F. J., & Goeritz, L. E. (2007). Integration manage-
ment of Western acquisitions in Japan. Asian Business Krishnan, H. A., Krishnan, R., & Lefanowicz, C. E. (2009).
& Management, 6(1), 95–114. Market perception of synergies in related acquisitions.
Academy of Strategic Management Journal, 8, 99–119.
Fubini, D. G., Price, C., & Zollo, M. (2006). The allusive art
of postmerger leadership. The McKinsey Quarterly, Krishnan, H. A., Miller, A., & Judge, W. O. (1997).
4, 28–37. Diversification and top management team comple-
mentarity: Is performance improved by merging
Furtado, E. P. H., & Karan, V. (1990). Causes, consequences,
and shareholder wealth effects of management turn- similar or dissimilar teams? Strategic Management
over: A review of the empirical evidence. Financial Journal, 18(5), 361–374.
Management, 19(2), 60–75. Krug, J. A. (2003). Why do they keep leaving? Harvard
Gompers, P. A., & Lerner, J. (2003). The really long-run Business Review, 81(2), 14–15.
performance of initial public offerings: The pre-Nasdaq Krug, J. A. (2009). Mergers and acquisitions: Turmoil in top
evidence. The Journal of Finance, 58(4), 1355–1392. management teams. New York: Business Expert Press.
Graebner, M. E. (2004). Momentum and serendipity: Krug, J. A., & Aguilera, R. (2005). Top management team
How acquired leaders create value in the integration turnover in mergers and acquisitions. Advances in
of technology firms. Strategic Management Journal, Mergers and Acquisitions, 4, 123–154.
25(8/9), 751–777. Krug, J. A., & Hegarty, W. H. (1997). Postacquisition turn-
Graebner, M. E., & Eisenhardt, K. M. (2004). The seller’s over among U.S. top management teams: An analysis
side of the story: Acquisition as courtship and of the effects of foreign vs. domestic acquisition of U.S.
governance as syndicate in entrepreneurial firms. targets. Strategic Management Journal, 18(8), 667–675.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 49(3), 366–403. Krug, J., & Hegarty, W. H. (2001). Predicting who stays and
Graebner, M. E., Eisenhardt, K. M., & Roundy, P. T. (2010). leaves after an acquisition: A study of top managers in
Success and failure in technology acquisitions: multinational firms. Strategic Management Journal,
Lessons for buyers and sellers. The Academy of 22(2), 185–196.
Management Perspectives, 24(3), 73–92. Krug, J. A., & Nigh, D. W. (1998). Top management
Haleblian, J., McNamara, G., Kolev, K., & Dykes, B. J. departures in cross-border acquisitions: Governance
(2012). Exploring firm characteristics that differenti- issues in an international context. Journal of In-
ate leaders from followers in industry merger waves: ternational Management, 4(4), 267–287.
A competitive dynamics perspective. Strategic Man- Krug, J. A., & Nigh, D. W. (2001). Executive perceptions
agement Journal, 33(9), 1037–1052. in foreign and domestic acquisitions: An analysis
Hambrick, D. C. (2007). Upper echelons theory: An update. of foreign ownership and its effect on executive fate.
Academy of Management Review, 32(2), 334–343. Journal of World Business, 36(1), 85–105.
Hambrick, D. C., & Cannella, A. A., Jr. (1993). Relative Krug, J. A., & Shill, W. (2008). The bit exit: Executive
standing: A framework for understanding departures churn in the wake of M&As. The Journal of Business
of acquired executives. Academy of Management Strategy, 29(4), 15–21.
Journal, 36(4), 733–762. Li, Y., & Aguilera, R. V. (2008). Target director turnover
Hayward, M. L. A., Shepherd, D. A., & Griffin, D. (2006). A in acquisitions: A conceptual framework. Corporate
hubris theory of entrepreneurship. Management Sci- Governance, 16(6), 492–503.
ence, 52(2), 160–172. Lubatkin, M. H., Schweiger, D. M., & Weber, Y. (1999).
Hope, O.-K., & Thomas, W. B. (2008). Managerial empire Top management turnover in related M&As: An ad-
building and firm disclosure. Journal of Accounting ditional test of the theory of relative standing. Journal
Research, 46(3), 591–626. of Management, 25(1), 55–73.
2015 Krug, Wright, and Kroll 45

Makri, M., Hitt, M. A., & Lane, P. J. (2010). Complementary Ranft, A. L., & Lord, M. D. (2002). Acquiring new tech-
technologies, knowledge relatedness, and invention nologies and capabilities: A grounded model of
outcomes in high technology mergers and acquis- acquisition implementation. Organization Science,
itions. Strategic Management Journal, 31(6), 602–628. 13(4), 420–441.
Manne, H. G. (1965). Mergers and the market for corporate Robins, J. A., & Wiersema, M. F. (2003). The measurement
control. Journal of Political Economy, 73(2), 110–120. of corporate portfolio strategy: Analysis of the content
Martin, J. A., & Combs, J. G. (2009). Punishing managers validity of related diversification indexes. Strategic
for bad acquisitions: Does firm size matter? The Management Journal, 24(1), 39–59.
Academy of Management Perspectives, 23(3), 92–93. Romano, C. A., Tanewski, G. A., & Smyrnios, K. X.
Martin, J. A., & Davis, K. J. (2010). Learning or hubris? (2001). Capital structure decision making: A model
Why CEOs create less value in successive acquis- for family business. Journal of Business Venturing,
itions. The Academy of Management Perspectives, 16(3), 285–310.
24(1), 79–81. Sekiguchi, T., Bebenroth, R., & Li, D. (2011). Nationality
Martin, K. J., & McConnell, J. J. (1991). Corporate perfor- background of MNC affiliates’ top management
mance, corporate takeovers, and management turn- and affiliate performance in Japan: Knowledge-
over. The Journal of Finance, 46(2), 671–687. based and upper echelons perspectives. International
Journal of Human Resource Management, 22(5),
Masulis, R. W., Wang, C., & Xie, F. (2007). Corporate
999–1016.
governance and acquirer returns. The Journal of Fi-
nance, 62(4), 1851–1889. Shen, J.-C., & Reuer, J. J. (2005). Adverse selection of
acquisitions of small manufacturing firms: A com-
Mata, J., & Portugal, P. (2002). The survival of new do-
parison of private and public targets. Small Business
mestic and foreign-owned firms. Strategic Manage-
Economics, 24(4), 398–407.
ment Journal, 23(4), 323–343.
McNamara, G. M., Haleblian, J., & Dykes, B. J. (2008). The Shill, W. E., & Mackenzie, D. W. (2005). How to build
performance implications of participating in an ac- value into a merger. Accenture Outlook Journal,
quisition wave: Early mover advantages, bandwagon 25(3), 66–71.
effects, and the moderating influence of industry Siegel, D. S., & Simons, K. L. (2010). Assessing the effects
characteristics and acquirer tactics. Academy of of mergers and acquisitions on firm performance,
Management Journal, 51(1), 113–130. plant productivity, and workers: New evidence from
Miller, D., & Sardais, C. (2011). Angel agents: Agency matched employer-employee data. Strategic Man-
theory reconsidered. The Academy of Management agement Journal, 31(1), 903–916.
Perspectives, 25(2), 6–13. Vaaler, P. M., & McNamara, G. M. (2004). Crisis and
Morosini, P., & Radler, G. (2003). DaimlerChrysler: competition in expert organizational decision mak-
The post-merger integration phase (Case #IMD121). ing: Credit-rating agencies and their response to
Lausanne: International Institute for Management turbulence in emerging economies. Organization
Development (IMD). Science, 15(6), 687–703.
Nyberg, A. J., Fulmer, I. S., Gerhart, B., & Carpenter, M. A. Very, P., Lubatkin, M., Calori, R., & Veiga, J. (1997).
(2010). Agency theory revisited: CEO return and Relative standing and the performance of recently
shareholder alignment. Strategic Management Jour- acquired European firms. Strategic Management
nal, 53(5), 1029–1049. Journal, 18(8), 593–614.
Pehrsson, A. (2006). Business relatedness and perfor- Walsh, J. P. (1988). Top management turnover following
mance: A study of managerial perceptions. Strategic mergers and acquisitions. Strategic Management
Management Journal, 27(3), 265–282. Journal, 9(2), 173–183.
Pisano, G., Andrews, P., & Di Fiore, A. (2011). Fiat- Walsh, J. P. (1989). Doing a deal: Merger and acquisition
Chrysler alliance: Launching the Cinquecento in negotiations and their impact upon target company
North America (Case #9-611-037). Boston: Harvard top management turnover. Strategic Management
Business School Publishing. Journal, 10(4), 307–322.
Ragozzino, R., & Reuer, J. J. (2009). Contingent earnouts in Walsh, J. P., & Ellwood, J. W. (1991). Mergers, acquis-
acquisitions of privately held targets. Journal of itions, and the pruning of managerial deadwood: An
Management, 35(4), 857–879. examination of the market for corporate control.
Ranft, A. L., & Lord, M. D. (2000). Acquiring new knowl- Strategic Management Journal, 12(3), 201–217.
edge: The role of retaining human capital in acquis- Walsh, J. P., & Kosnik, R. D. (1993). Corporate raiders and
itions of high-tech firms. The Journal of High their disciplinary role in the market. Academy of
Technology Management Research, 11(2), 295–319. Management Journal, 36(4), 671–700.
46 The Academy of Management Perspectives January

Zhou, Y. M. (2011). Synergy, coordination costs, and di- teams, corporate governance, and mergers and
versification choices. Strategic Management Journal, acquisitions.
32(6), 624–639.
Peter Wright (pwright@memphis.edu) is a professor of
Zollo, M., & Singh, H. (2004). Deliberate learning in cor- management and holds the Chair of Excellence in Free
porate acquisitions: Post-acquisition strategies and Enterprise Management at The University of Memphis.
integration capability in U.S. bank mergers. Strategic He received his PhD in business administration from
Management Journal, 25(13), 1233–1257. Louisiana State University. His research interests in-
clude corporate governance and the valuation of firm
investments.
Mark Kroll (mark.kroll@utb.edu) is dean of the School of
Jeffrey A. Krug (jakrug@loyno.edu) is associate dean of Business at the University of Texas at Brownsville. He
graduate programs, a professor of strategic management, received his DBA from Mississippi State University. His
and holds the Jack and Vada Reynolds Chair in In- research interests include firm governance and strategic
ternational Business at Loyola University New Orleans. leadership of entrepreneurial firms.
He received his PhD in management from Indiana Uni-
versity. His research interests include top management
Copyright of Academy of Management Perspectives is the property of Academy of
Management and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a
listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print,
download, or email articles for individual use.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi