Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 8

Jump to: navigation, search

An example of a demand curve shifting


In economics, the demand curve is the graph depicting the relationship between the price of a
certain commodity, and the amount of it that consumers are willing and able to purchase at that
given price. It is a graphic representation of a demand schedule.[1] The demand curve for all
consumers together follows from the demand curve of every individual consumer: the individual
demands at each price are added together. Despite its name, it is not always shown as a curve,
but sometimes as a straight line, depending on the complexity of the scenario.
Demand curves are used to estimate behaviors in competitive markets, and are often combined
with supply curves to estimate the equilibrium price (the price at which sellers together are
willing to sell the same amount as buyers together are willing to buy, also known as market
clearing price) and the equilibrium quantity (the amount of that good or service that will be
produced and bought without surplus/excess supply or shortage/excess demand) of that market.[2]
In a monopolistic market, the demand curve facing the monopolist is simply the market demand
curve.

Contents
[hide]
• 1 Characteristics
• 2 Demand schedule
• 3 Linear demand curve
• 4 Shift of a demand curve
○ 4.1 Demand shifters
○ 4.2 Changes that increase demand
○ 4.3 Changes that decrease demand
○ 4.4 Factors affecting market demand
• 5 Movement along a demand curve
• 6 Discreteness of amounts
• 7 Units of measurement
• 8 Price elasticity of demand (PED)
• 9 Taxes and subsidies
• 10 See also
• 11 References

[edit] Characteristics
According to convention, the demand curve is drawn with price on the vertical axis and quantity
on the horizontal axis. The function actually plotted is the inverse demand function.
The demand curve usually slopes downwards from left to right; that is, it has a negative
association (for two theoretical exceptions, see Veblen good and Giffen good). The negative
slope is often referred to as the "law of demand", which means people will buy more of a service,
product, or resource as its price falls. The demand curve is related to the marginal utility curve,
since the price one is willing to pay depends on the utility. However, the demand directly
depends on the income of an individual while the utility does not. Thus it may change indirectly
due to change in demand for other commodities.
[edit] Demand schedule
See also: Market demand schedule
A demand schedule is a table that lists the quantity of a good a person will buy at each different
price[1] The demand curve is a graphical depiction of the relationship between the price of a good
and the quantity of the good that a consumer would demand under certain time, place and
circumstances. The demand relationship can also be expressed mathematically: Q = f(P; Y, Prg,
Pop, X) where Q is quantity demanded, P is the price of the good, Prg is the price of a related
good, Y is income, Pop is population and X is the expectation of some relevant future variable
such as the future price of the product. The semi-colon means that the arguments to its right are
held constant when the relationship is plotted two-dimensionally in (price, quantity) space. If one
of these other variables changes the demand curve will shift. For example, if the population
increased then there would be an outward (rightward) shift of the demand curve, since more
consumers would mean higher demand. This shift is referred to as a change in demand and
results from a change in the constant term. Movements along the demand curve occur only when
quantity demanded changes in response to a change in price.
[edit] Linear demand curve
The demand curve is often graphed as a straight line of the form Q = a - bP where a and b are
parameters. The constant “a” “embodies” the effects of all factors other than price that affect
demand. If for example income were to change the effect of the change would be represented by
a change in the value of a and be reflected graphically as a shift of the demand curve. The
constant “b” is the slope of the demand curve and shows how the price of the good affects the
quantity demanded. [3]
The graph of the demand curve uses the inverse demand function in which price is expressed as a
function of quantity. The standard form of the demand equation can be converted to the inverse
equation by solving for P or P = a/b - 1/bQ.[4]
More plainly, in the equation P = a - bQ, "a" is the intercept where quantity demanded is zero
(where the demand curve intercepts the Y axis. "b" is the slope of the demand curve. "Q" is
quantity. "P" is price.
[edit] Shift of a demand curve
The shift of a demand curve takes place when there is a change in any non-price determinant of
demand, resulting in a new demand curve.[5] Non-price determinants of demand are those things
that will cause demand to change even if prices remain the same—in other words, the things
whose changes might cause a consumer to buy more or less of a good even if the good's own
price remained unchanged.[6] Some of the more important factors are the prices of related goods
(both substitutes and complements), income, population, and expectations. However, demand is
the willingness and ability of a consumer to purchase a good under the prevailing circumstances;
so, any circumstance that affects the consumer's willingness or ability to buy the good or service
in question can be a non-price determinant of demand. As an example, weather could be a factor
in the demand for beer at a baseball game.
When income rises, the demand curve for normal goods shifts outward as more will be
demanded at all prices, while the demand curve for inferior goods shifts inward due to the
increased attainability of superior substitutes. With respect to related goods, when the price of a
good (e.g. a hamburger) rises, the demand curve for substitute goods (e.g. chicken) shifts out,
while the demand curve for complementary goods (e.g. tomato sauce) shifts in (i.e. there is more
demand for substitute goods as they become more attractive in terms of value for money, while
demand for complementary goods contracts in response to the contraction of quantity demanded
of the underlying good).[5]
[edit] Demand shifters
• Changes in disposable income
• Changes in tastes and preferences - tastes and preferences are assumed to be fixed in the
short-run. This assumption of fixed preferences is a necessary condition for aggregation
of individual demand curves to derive market demand.
• Changes in expectations.
• Changes in the prices of related goods (substitutes and complements)
• Population size and composition
[edit] Changes that increase demand
Some circumstances which can cause the demand curve to shift out include:
• increase in price of a substitute
• decrease in price of complement
• increase in income if good is a normal good
• decrease in income if good is an inferior good
[edit] Changes that decrease demand
Some circumstances which can cause the demand curve to shift in include:
• decrease in price of a substitute
• increase in price of a complement
• decrease in income if good is normal good
• increase in income if good is inferior good
[edit] Factors affecting market demand
Market or aggregate demand is the summation of individual demand curves. In addition to the
factors which can affect individual demand there are three factors that can affect market demand
(cause the market demand curve to shift):
• a change in the number of consumers,
• a change in the distribution of tastes among consumers,
• a change in the distribution of income among consumers with different tastes.[7]
[edit] Movement along a demand curve
There is movement along a demand curve when a change in price causes the quantity demanded
to change[5]. It is important to distinguish between movement along a demand curve, and a shift
in a demand curve. Movements along a demand curve happen only when the price of the good
changes.[8] When a non-price determinant of demand changes the curve shifts. These "other
variables" are part of the demand function. They are "merely lumped into intercept term of a
simple linear demand function." [8] Thus a change in a non-price determinant of demand is
reflected in a change in the x-intercept causing the curve to shift along the x axis.[9]
[edit] Discreteness of amounts
If a commodity is sold in whole units, and these are substantial for a consumer, then the
individual demand curve can hardly be approximated by a continuous curve. It is a step function
of the price, defined by a price above which no unit is bought, a price range for which one is
bought, etc.
[edit] Units of measurement
If the local currency is dollars, for example, then the units of measurement of the variable "price"
are "dollars per unit of the good" and the units of measurement of "quantity" are "units of the
good per time (e.g., per week or per year). Thus quantity demanded is a flow variable.
[edit] Price elasticity of demand (PED)
Main article: Price elasticity of demand
PED is a measure of the sensitivity of the quantity variable, Q, to changes in the price variable,
P. Elasticity answers the question of how much the quantity will change in percentage terms for
a 1% change in the price, and is thus important in determining how revenue will change.
The elasticity of demand indicates how sensitive the demand for a good is to a price change. If
the PED is between zero and 1 demand is said to be inelastic, if PED equals 1, the demand is
unitary elastic and if the PED is greater than 1 demand is elastic. A low coefficient implies that
changes in price have little influence on demand. A high elasticity indicates that consumers will
respond to a price rise that buying a lot less of the good and that consumers will respond to a
price cut by buying a lot more.
[edit] Taxes and subsidies
A sales tax on the commodity does not directly change the demand curve, if the price axis in the
graph represents the price including tax. Similarly, a subsidy on the commodity does not directly
change the demand curve, if the price axis in the graph represents the price after deduction of the
subsidy.
If the price axis in the graph represents the price before addition of tax and/or subtraction of
subsidy then the demand curve moves inward when a tax is introduced, and outward when a
subsidy is introduced.
[edit] See also
Wikimedia Commons has media related to: Supply and demand curves

• Demand (economics)
• Supply and demand
• Effect of taxes and subsidies on price
• Price point
• Wikiversity:Building the demand curve
• Inverse demand function
[edit] References
1. ^ a b O'Sullivan, Arthur; Steven M. Sheffrin (2003). Economics: Principles in action. Upper
Saddle River, New Jersey 07458: Pearson Prentice Hall. pp. 81–82. ISBN 0-13-063085-3.
http://www.pearsonschool.com/index.cfm?
locator=PSZ3R9&PMDbSiteId=2781&PMDbSolutionId=6724&PMDbCategoryId=&PMDbProg
ramId=12881&level=4.
2. ^ Krugman, Paul, and Wells, Robin. Microeconomics. Worth Publishers, New York. 2005.
3. ^ Besanko and Braeutigam (2005) p/ 91.
4. ^ Besanko and Braeutigam (2005) p/ 91.
5. ^ a b c Case, K.E., Fair, R.C. (1994). 'Demand, Supply, and Market Equilibrium', Chapter 4 in
Principles of Economics, 3rd ed., Prentice Hall Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey
6. ^ http://www.harpercollege.edu/mhealy/eco212i/lectures/s&d/s&d.htm
7. ^ Binger, B & Hoffman, E.: Microeconomics with Calculus, 2nd ed. Addison-Wesley 1998. A
change in relative price changes the distribution of income which in turn changes the demand
curve.
8. ^ a b Underwood, Instructor’s Manual, Microeconomics 5th ed. (Prentice-Hall 2001) at 5.
9. ^ The x intercept is affected because the standard diagram uses the inverse demand function
[hide]
v•d•e
Microeconomics

Major Aggregation · Budget · Consumer · Cost · Equilibria · Elasticity ·


topics Exchange · Expected utility · Externality · Firms · General equilibria ·
Information · Intertemporal choice · Market failure · Market structure ·
Monopoly · Monopsony · Oligopoly · Opportunity cost · Preferences ·
Prices · Production · Profit · Public goods · Risk · Scarcity · Shortage ·
Supply & demand · Surplus · Uncertainty · Utility theory · Welfare

Behavioral · Business · Decision theory · Econometrics · Experimental ·


Game theory · Industrial organization · Mathematical economics ·
Related
Microfoundations of Macroeconomics · Managerial · Operations research ·
Optimization
Retrieved from "http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Demand_curve"
Categories: Economics curves
Personal tools
• New features
• Log in / create account
Namespaces
• Article
• Discussion
Variants
Views
• Read
• Edit
• View history
Actions
Search
Top of Form
Special:Search

Search

Bottom of Form
Navigation
• Main page
• Contents
• Featured content
• Current events
• Random article
• Donate
Interaction
• About Wikipedia
• Community portal
• Recent changes
• Contact Wikipedia
• Help
Toolbox
• What links here
• Related changes
• Upload file
• Special pages
• Permanent link
• Cite this page
Print/export
• Create a book
• Download as PDF
• Printable version
Languages
• Deutsch
• Eesti
• Español
• ‫فارسی‬
• Galego
• Italiano
• Lietuvių
• Norsk (bokmål)
• Polski
• Simple English
• తలుగు
• Türkçe
• 中文
• This page was last modified on 21 October 2010 at 02:34.
• Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License;
additional terms may apply. See Terms of Use for details.
Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc., a non-profit
organization.
• Contact us
• Privacy policy
• About Wikipedia
• Disclaimers

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi