2015 Edition
Amundi’s research capabilities ranked 2nd
Earning in Europe by Extel*
your confidence Once again our first-class equity research and
analysis has been acknowledged in the Extel 2014
Pan-European Survey:
also means providing 14 of Amundi’s financial analysts place amongst
the top 100 European analysts,
equity analysis rivalling Amundi is in the top 5 for 20 of the 23 sectors
analysed.
the best in Europe. Another illustration of our commitment to serving
you by ensuring our investment teams have access
to the highest quality analysis and research available.
* Survey conducted among sellside, buyside and corporates between March 2014 and May 2014. 532 brokerage houses and 881 corporates took part in the Survey. Out of those
voted, 167 sellside firms and 479 corporates nominated buyside firms and individuals. The methodology and the full results are on the Extel website, www.extelsurveys.com.
This document in no way constitutes a purchase offer or sales solicitation and should not be construed as a solicitation which might be deemed unlawful nor as investment advice.
Amundi shall not be held directly or indirectly liable in connection with the use of the information contained in this document. Under no circumstances shall Amundi be held liable for
any decision taken on the basis of this information. The information contained in this document may not be copied, reproduced, modified, translated or distributed, without the prior
written approval of Amundi, to any third person or entity in any country or jurisdiction which would subject Amundi or any of its funds to any registration requirements within these
jurisdictions or where it might be considered as unlawful. The information contained in this document is deemed to be accurate as at 28 July 2014 and may be altered without notice.
Amundi, société anonyme with capital of €596,262,615 - Portfolio management company approved by the AMF under no. GP 04000036 - Registered office: 90 boulevard Pasteur,
75015 Paris - France - 437 574 452 RCS Paris. Photo: Getty Images. |
Note of the editors
Foreword
- Amundi Research: a multifaceted and a client-oriented business-line p. 9
- Amundi Research in a nutshell p. 14
- Amundi Research Center p. 15
- Cross Asset Line p. 16
O ver the past few years, Amundi has chosen to expand its research
teams and to get them implicated in its investment decisions. Our
approach has consisted in expanding both our top-down and bottom-
up resources and involving them with the management teams and asset
allocation decisions on a regular basis. Research teams also participate
in the various investment committees and help promote new investment
processes. All this makes portfolio investment returns a shared objective.
This has also helped enhance Amundi’s visibility worldwide. It is important
to provide guidelines that explain and publicise Amundi’s views both
externally and internally. The new line of research products (the cross-asset
line) has made a big contribution to improving this “ duty to explain”. In
such a way, research work promotes the group’s investment strategies and
themes at all times.
Amundi has also organised its research team to achieve the key objective
of remaining close to the academic world. Publishing working papers and
financing research chairs, resulting in conferences and calls for papers,
help achieve this objective.
Amundi has therefore provided the research team with the resources
to foster the role that we have given it. In addition to proximity with
the management teams and clients, the team offers a broad diversity of
profiles and publications. This book shows clearly, if there was a need, how
important research is in Amundi’s set-up, as well as the depth and variety
of our research capabilities. It highlights both the role of research within the
investment process and its ability to make lasting analyses that form the
basis of future action.
5 main strengths
QU
ANT
Forex,
Fixed income, research, equity research,
Credit, Equities,
Real estate socially responsible investment
research, quantitative research,
real estate research, and
N
A
AL
YS I contributes on advisory activities,
IS SR
BO
partnerships with universities,
TTOM CH
UP RESEAR training programmes...
According to the 2014 Extel survey (which ranks firms based on the quality
of equity analysis services), Amundi Equity Research is ranked #2 in Europe.
This study brings in over 15,000 votes (banks, brokers and companies) on
more than 100 asset managers, a sample set of more than 2,500 analysts. Past
years’ rankings in Europe: #13 in 2010, #8 in 2011, #4 in 2012, #2 in 2013 and
2014. In addition, all the analysts’ rankings went up, and now 14 analysts (8
last year and 5 the year before), all sectors combined, are considered to be
among the top 100 European analysts. 20 of the 23 sectors covered are now in
the European top 5, and 12 in top 3.
All sectors combined, the 12 best analysts in France are all part of the Amundi
research team (the sample included just over 325 analysts).
These results are an asset for Amundi with regard to its clients. They solidify
all our efforts to raise our profile and garner recognition - goals that have
been top priorities.
12
130 Nationalities
Stockholm
Amsterdam Helsinki
Brussels Frankfurt
Luxembourg
London Warsaw
Montreal Paris Prague
Geneva Zurich
Yerevan Beijing
Milan
New York Madrid Seoul
Durham Tokyo
Athens
Shanghai
Casablanca
Hong Kong Taipei
Abu Dhabi
Bangkok
Mumbai Brunei
Kuala
Lumpur
Singapore
Santiago 20 Sydney
Spoken languages
150+ 2000+
Number of conferences each year Meetings with portfolio managers
each year (both bottom up and top
down research): sector reviews,
portfolio reviews, weekly meetings…
2000+
Meetings with clients each year
in more than 40 countries
35+
Number of Working Papers published in
academic reviews in the past 4 years
(Applied Economics, Bankers
Markets & Investors, Economic
Policy, European Financial
Management, Finance, Financial
Analysts Journal, Journal of
Alternative Investments, Journal
of Asset Management, Journal
of Banking and Finance, Journal of
Business Ethics, Journal of Finance and Risk Perspectives, Journal of
Fixed Income, Journal of International Money and Finance, Journal
of Investment Strategies, Journal of Portfolio Management, Research
in International Business and Finance, Revue Française d’Economie…)
Cross asset
investment
strategy # 03
Letter finalised at 3pm Paris time March 16 - 20, 2015
Research, Strategy and Analysis MONTHLY
Highlights of the week
March 2015 Ɣ Eurozone: Total employment rose slightly in 2014, but payroll costs decelerate. Good signals still coming from Ger-
many.
Ɣ United States: Figures on industry and real estate are disappointing.
Ɣ Markets: The Fed triggered a strong downturn in bond yields in the developed countries and stops dollar appreciation.
US credit markets have performed in recent days and the climb continues for equities.
Key focus
It is no surprise that the Fed is retreating. In the past, we have regularly listed the reasons for doing so: a strong real appreciation of
the US dollar, weak inflation, low wages, a persistent slack on the labour market,
and faster-than-anticipated slowdown of China. If there is anything new in the The FOMC members' ("dots")
signals the Fed is sending, it is that the Fed is really being destabilised by
Asset Allocation how weak the impact of the improved labour market conditions has been on
projections vs. market expeta-
wage trends and therefore inflation: while FOMC members set their projection tions
ECB of the unemployment rate in the long run at around 5.3/5.4% for the whole year
2014, they have just abruptly lowered it to 5.1%. As certain FOMC members had
said in speeches recently, the unemployment rate below which inflation acceler-
4
3.5
3
ates is probably lower than it was in the past. While unemployment stood at 5.5%
Oil in February, there is still a bit further to go. 2.5
2
China In its statement, the FOMC explains that it will raise interest rates "when it has
seen further improvement in the labour market and is reasonably confident that
inflation will move back to its 2% objective over the medium term." This is a key
1.5
1
0.5
Quantitative point: whether or not the Fed begins its fed funds tightening in 2015, it will 0
Spot
JAN 16
MAR 16
JAN 17
MAY 15
JUL 15
SEP 15
NOV 15
MAY 16
JUL 16
SEP 16
NOV 16
MAR 17
MAY 17
JUL 17
SEP 17
NOV 17
need much more time to truly be confident that the inflation trend will return
easing to normal. Some of the best evidence is that the underlying inflation (i.e. the core
PCE) forecast has been adjusted downward for 2015 and 2016 (respectively to
1.3% and 1.7%). Now, inflation will be the key variable. Dots December 2014
Yuan Dots March 2015
Market expections 19 March 2015
Thus, the FOMC is giving the markets a little air, the US dollar has lost a little Market expections 13 March 2015
Fed ground, and US long-term yields have fallen a little. It's as if the American central Source : Bloomberg, Amundi Research
bankers had heard Christine Lagarde's warnings about the disastrous effect a Market expectations are proxied here by the fed
too-sudden monetary tightening would have on the emerging countries. funds futures.
Russia
Emerging countries
Luxury market
Document for the exclusive use of professional clients, investment service providers and other financial industry professionals. 1
Document finalised at March 9, 2015
Document for the exclusive attention of professional clients, investment services providers and any other professional of the financial industry
Monthly Weekly
This publication documents the outlooks, This publication provides a four-page
macroeconomic and financial forecasts, summary of the past week’s highlights,
risk factors, strategies and asset featuring an in-depth editorial on a
allocation of Amundi, covering equities, key development. It is not a listing of
debt and dive rsified portfolios. It also events, but a report on how some of
reports on the outcomes and topics of the events may impact our forecasts,
discussion from Amundi’s investment Amundi’s asset allocation and changes
committee. These topics are given special in risk factors identified to date. A
coverage in this monthly publication. quick overview of important events,
auctions and key indicators is provided
at the end of the publication.
ECB QE Monitor – March 24, 2015
The document you are reading is the first issue of a new publication which is aimed at monitoring the
ECB’s QE.
On credibility, the announcement of QE was a resounding success. Its scale, comprehensiveness and
suitability did not disappoint. The financial markets responded positively, as reflected in the fall in short
and long rates and the advance of asset classes such as Eurozone equities.
Implementation seems like a simple matter, at least in principle. The ECB will nonetheless be faced
with the challenge of purchasing €60 billion in securities each month in illiquid markets that are short of
willing sellers. QE encourages market players to buy or hold on to assets rather than selling them.
Meanwhile, the banks, which are major holders of government debt, retain these assets in portfolios for
regulatory purposes or simply out of liquidity considerations, as the securities can be used as collateral.
Given this backdrop, unless there is an explosion in issuance by governments, a rapid change in
regulators’ policy or “forced” sales by public funds (is this not what Japan demanded of public pension
ECB QE Monitor
funds?), the ECB’s drive to establish this programme will inevitably run into the realities of the market,
which will undoubtedly push down short and long-term interest rates even further. There will be at least
seven major impacts from this:
- The euro will be under downward pressure, partially counterbalanced by current account
surpluses;
- The long-term rate spectrum will see heightened contagion. Like the two-year and five-
year yields before it, the German seven-year yield has fallen into negative territory. Long-term rates will
inevitably stay very low;
- Government bond spreads will tighten from already exceedingly low levels. While they
can now offer little protection against a potential growth downturn or troubles in public debt or the
political situation, they are in the hands of the ECB, which is reassuring, at least in the short term;
This monthly publication is aimed at monitoring the
- Corporate bond spreads will tighten;
- US long rates will remain low, all other things being equal: the slope of the curve, rate
ECB’s Quantitative Easing programme.
levels and the attractiveness of the USD are convincing arguments in favour of the US bond market.
Whereas the emerging markets were able to attract 20% of the liquidity from US QE, the US market
Ultimately, if everything proceeds as anticipated, the Eurozone can look forward to a more growth-
friendly environment. The final step for Mario Draghi involves the matter of effectiveness.
We have already alluded to the importance of transmitting QE to the real economy. Several transmission
Document for the exclusive use of professional clients, investment service providers and other financial industry professionals. 1
economy.
DP-08-2014
November 2014
January 19 2015
2 Announcement
R Will the ECB announce a phased QE, a bit like in the US (Q1, Q2 and then Q3)... or
would it quickly announce a large-scale QE? In the first case, there could be some
disappointment (too little, too late). In the second, the hope of renewed optimism on
growth and a significant impact on equities, interest rates and spreads.
Amundi views: the announcement of a large QE is by far much better, taking into
䇾 Do not consider QE as a tool to
solve debt problems, but as a tool
to fight deflation
䇿
account the stakes, and market expectations. A EUR 500bln is highly likely.
Document for the exclusive attention of professional clients, investment services providers and any other professional of the financial industry
For professional investors only
Working Papers
Amundi Working Paper
Long cycles
and the asset markets
ÉRIC MIJOT,
Head of Strategy Research, Amundi
May 2015
1.1 The first “law” pertains to inventions: they take place about 20
years before actually being rolled out on a large scale
The birth of new technologies deeply changes our way of life. Since the
investments required for their development are substantial and have to be made
profitable, the lobbies for these powerful industries work to make the movement
last. The associated changes gradually take shape and become the rule once
economic necessity and financial resources are combined, often after pushing
the previous state of affairs well beyond the acceptable limit. More than the
inventions themselves, it is the democratisation of these technologies - often
through “secondary” inventions - that truly shakes up the status quo.
Below are just a few major inventions or discoveries that marked the four past
Kondratiev cycles and hint at what’s to come in the next.
tCycle I (1783-1842): Coal - Steam Engine
James Watt invented the separate condenser in 1769 and the crankshaft in
1780, which enabled the widespread use of the steam engine. In addition, the
first power loom developed by Edward Carthwright in 1787 spread throughout
England in the 1830s.
tCycle II (1842-1896): Iron and Steel - Railway
Progress achieved in the use of coke to produce cast iron - a process established
in 1709 but not put into practice until the 1850s and 1860s - was the catalyst
for the technological revolution in this cycle. George Stephenson invented the
first steam locomotive engine in 1813 and the first railway was opened in 1830
between Manchester and Liverpool.
tCycle III (1896-1949): Electricity - Automobile
The first electricity transmission took place in 1883, between the cities of Vizille
and Grenoble, thanks to Marcel Deprez, and Thomas Edison invented the
incandescent light bulb, demonstrated in 1879. As for the internal combustion
engine, it owes its development to the designs of Beau de Rochas in 1862. After
an initial model was manufactured by German Nikolaus Otto, which was then
miniaturised by Frenchman Jules-Albert de Dion, German inventor Carl Benz
was able to create the first gasoline-powered automobile in 1886.
1.2 The second “law” concerns social movements, revolutions and wars:
their frequency increases at cycle extremities
Wars can sometimes be stimulating for economies, when they are not being fought
within the country’s borders, because preparing for war gives a boost to industry.
No matter what the circumstances, however, they distort the economy and it
takes a post-war recession to purge the resulting artificial effects. This shows that
reversing a decades-long established order and direction calls for one or more
powerful catalysts, takes time and does not happen without tension.
Conflicts at the peak of long cycles lengthen expansion phases and are hegemonic
in nature. Examples include:
t the Napoleonic Wars in 1803-1815 (British continental embargo starting in
1806), the War of 1812,
1.3 The third “law” refers to the overlapping of long and short cycles
During the upward phase of a long cycle, short cycles have a longer expansion
phase then the subsequent correction. The opposite takes place during the
downward phase of a long cycle.
Each long cycle contains several short cycles, to which it gives a logical order. This
is not a deterministic statement, but rather the observation that each cycle has an
influence on the next. On the one hand, major recessions are ultimately regenerating.
On the other, growth cannot be exponential. It is also clear that trend reversals in
long cycles are naturally more complicated because the logic has to be reversed.
Long cycles can therefore be broken down into four phases, which will be the focus
of the next several pages: an upward phase, a more complex downturn phase,
then a downward phase and finally a more complex upturn phase.
1 - The principle
Interest
Rates
Equities
Share prices are presented in six different ways in the following charts p 12 and
p 13: nominal value, deflated by consumer prices, government bond prices, real
estate prices, gold prices and industrial commodity prices. The transition points
from one cycle to another are very consistent. Each approach sheds slightly
different light that helps validate the change in “season” when the time comes.
14
625
12
ond ields
125 10
8
25 6
S P
4
5
2
1 0
1800 1814 35 1842 52 66 73 1896 07 20 29 1949 66 81 2000
14
12
250
ond ields
10
8
6
50
4
2
S P
10 0
1800 1814 35 1842 52 66 73 1896 07 20 29 1949 66 81 2000
14
625 12
ond ields
10
125
8
25 6
S P
4
5
2
1 0
1800 1814 35 1842 52 66 73 1896 07 20 29 1949 66 81 2000
These three charts show trends in long rates and equities during long cycles.
Equities are presented in three different ways: nominal value (chart 2), deflated by
consumer prices (chart 3) and by government bond prices (chart 4). Long rates
rise during the first two phases (spring and summer) of each long cycle (labelled
I, II, III and IV), then decline during the next two phases (autumn and winter).
Equities alternate between rallies and downturns. They rise in spring and autumn
and fall in summer and winter.
14
12
8
ond ields
10
(log)
8
4
6
2 4
S P
2
1 0
1800 1814 35 1842 52 66 73 1896 07 20 29 1949 66 81 2000
ond ields
(in US$, log)
1.0 10
8
6
S P
0.3
4
2
0.1 0
1800 1814 35 1842 52 66 73 1896 07 20 29 1949 66 81 2000
odities
6.3 64
Industrial
odities (log)
32
onds (log)
1.3
16
Industrial co
0.3 8
4
0.1
S P
co
0.0 1
1800 1814 35 1842 52 66 73 1896 07 20 29 1949 66 81 2000
In this series of three charts, equities are deflated by real asset prices, by real estate
prices (chart 5), gold prices in USD (chart 6), then industrial commodity prices
(chart 7). The last chart also shows industrial commodity prices compared to
government bond prices. What we learn is that particularly in winter, commodities
outperform equities (excluding dividends) and that equities come out on top again
in spring. Similarly, commodities underperform bonds in winter and outperform
in spring.
Real returns on the main asset classes during the four seasons
of long cycles for investors in USD
8- Real returns during cycles I, II III, IV (yearly averages)
Spring
Printemps
Spring Summer
Summer
Été Autumn
Automne
Autumn Winter
Winter
Hiver
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%
-5%
Actions
Equities
Equities Oblig.
Corp. d'entreprises
Corp. Bonds
Bonds Gov. Oblig. d'Etat
Gov.Bonds
Bonds Money Monétaire
MoneyMarket
Market GoldOr
Gold Immobilier
Real
Real Estate
Estate
Source: Shiller, GFD, Kondratieff, omer S lla, ood s, Fed, Datastream, Amundi Research
The colours represent economic seasons. Returns are shown corrected for
inflation and as “total return” (dividends reinvested). Government and corporate
bonds are deemed to have a constant duration (7 and 5, respectively). Real estate
returns are deemed stable and equivalent to two-thirds of returns on equities
(expenses are considered to account for one-third of rent) and reinvested. Using
only Cycles III and IV (chart 9) gives more assets for our comparison.
12 12
(5 year average, in %)
8 8
ond ield
PI
4 4
0 0
-4 -4
-8 -8
1800 1814 35 1842 52 66 73 1896 07 20 29 1949 66 81 2000
140
I II III IV 15
120 10
Pu lic e t
100
(% of GDP)
0 -15
1800 1814 35 1842 52 66 73 1896 07 20 29 1949 66 81 2000
400
I II III IV
250
200
150
100
50
0
1800 1814 35 1842 52 66 73 1896 07 20 29 1949 66 81 2000
Source: Shiller, GFD, Fed, S ureau of ensus, us o ernmentdebt us, Amundi Research
These charts show long rates and inflation (average consumer prices over 5 years, a
proxy for inflation expectations), real interest rates and public sector debt relative to
GDP and, finally, public and private sector debt. We can see that the transitions from
winter to spring coincide with an upward reversal of inflation expectations during the
first two cycles. World War II changed the game completely, triggering exceptional
consumer price inflation at the end of Cycle III. This time around (end of Cycle IV), the
Fed may have triggered exceptional asset price inflation. Furthermore, the transition
for spring coincides with a long-term downward reversal of public sector debt relative
to GDP with private sector debt taking up the baton.
100000
II III IV
10000
(log scale)
1000
100
S P
10
average
1
1881 1896 1907 1920 1929 1949 1966 1981 2000
48
24
Pro its
12
6
average
3
1881 1896 1907 1920 1929 1949 1966 1981 2000
80
II III IV
clicall Ad PER
40
20
10
5
--- average + ou - 1 standard deviation
3
1881 1896 1907 1920 1929 1949 1966 1981 2000
The trend in the equities market performance based on real data with dividends
reinvested is around +6.5% per year, with weaker phases in summer and winter
and stronger ones in spring and autumn. Dividend reinvestment evens out this
performance. Profits mainly climb in spring and autumn, following short cycles
within the long cycles. Cycle-adjusted PER coincides fairly well with seasonal
turnarounds.
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
--- average + ou - 1 standard deviation
0.0
1896 07 20 29 1949 66 81 2000
1.6
1.4
1.2
Mar et ap
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2 --- average + ou - 1 standard deviation
0.0
1896 07 20 29 1949 66 81 2000
15
10
5
0
-5
--- average + ou - 1 standard deviation
-10
1896 07 20 29 1949 66 81 2000
Tobin’s Q and market cap relative to GDP are at high levels, as is the cycle-
adjusted PER. Only the risk premium is currently close to its historic average.
This state of affairs can be attributed to the absence of inflation, low interest
rates and the Fed’s credibility.
Longest track record. Leading country in the first two industrialisation cycles.
UK
Colonial empire. Winner of two World Wars that did not take place within its borders.
Track record for best quality, most documented. Leading country in the last two
US long cycles. Winner of two World Wars that did not take place within its borders.
Imperial power.
On the winning side of two World Wars, but which took place within its borders.
France France has long been the most highly populated country in Europe. It suffered
massive population losses in both World Wars. Colonial empire.
Three countries that arrived on the international stage during the economic winter
at the end of the 19th century:
Truly unified in 1871 after its victory over France. Lost two World Wars with massive
Germany
destruction of property. Hyperinflation. Cut off from its colonies.
Reign of Emperor Meiji and industrialisation both began in 1867. Winner in World
Japan War I and loser in World War II. Supported the United States in the Vietnam War
(1964-1975).
Unified in 1861. On the winning side of World War I and the losing side of World
Italy
War II.
Two former British colonies that have long been part of the Pound Sterling
area:
Canada Former British colony. Close to the United States. Commodity-producing country.
European oil-producing country. United with Sweden from 1814 to 1905. Neutral
Norway
during World War I. Occupied by the Germans during World War II.
As for the United States, there are periods that are repeated in many other
countries, despite a number of distinctive features. Europe, for example, was
beset by hyperinflation, a plague that hit Germany hardest. The collapse of the
Japanese equities market in the wake of Hiroshima and Nagasaki is also a prime
example of a rare phenomenon. Australia is another special case, one that is able
to come out on top in commodity-supportive periods (summer and winter).
1 - United in do
I II III IV 16
3200
14
Real Equit Index
12
(100:1783, log)
800
ond ields
10
8
200 6
4
50 2
1783 93 1815 25 1842 52 63 73 1893 12 20 29 1952 68 81 2000
- rance
II III IV 18
800 16
Real Equit Index
14
ond ields
(100:1848, log)
400 12
10
200 8
6
100 4
2
50 0
1840 51 63 71 81 1896 12 26 29 1950 62 81 2000
625
III IV 12
10
125
Real Equit Index
ond ields
(100:1915, log)
25 6
4
5
2
1 0
1915 1924 1937 1947 1972 1981 1989
- anada
III IV 16
800
14
Real Equit Index
12
400
ond ields
(100:1913, log)
10
8
200
6
100 4
2
50 0
1913 1922 1929 1944 1963 1981 2007
- Australia
II III IV
18
625 16
Real Equit Index
10
25 8
6
5 4
2
1 0
1850 1858 1873 1893 1912 1920 1937 1952 1968 1982 2007
- Ital
125
III IV 22
20
Real Equit Index
18
(100:1906, log)
25
ond ields
16
14
5 12
10
8
1
6
4
0.2 2
1929 1949 1961 1981 2000
Source: Australian Stoc chan e, GFD, omer S lla, Datastream, Amundi Research
11
ond ields
(100:1920, log)
90 9
7
30 5
3
10 1
1900 1917 1921 1937 1953 1961 1982 2007
- S eden
III IV 16
14
270
Real Equit Index
12
(100:1906, log)
10
ond ields
90 8
6
30 4
2
10 0
1887 1913 1921 1929 1949 1965 1981 2000
- Ger an e ore 1 1
150
II III 7
Real Equit Index
120
6
ond ields
(100:1856)
90
5
60
4
30
0 3
1856 1867 1873 1893 1905 1921
- Ger an a ter 1
III IV
4
10
Real Equit Index
3
ond ields
8
(100:1856)
6
2
4
1
2
0 0
1924 1929 1949 1961 1981 2000
RU
1
1
Supercycle I
USA 1 1 Coal
1 1 Steam engines
1 1
1 1 RA
1 1
1 1 1 Supercycle II
1 1 1 1 GER Steel
1 Railways
1 1 1 1 1 1
AUS 1 1 1 1
1
1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 SWE NOR
Supercycle III
1 1 1 1
AN 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 AP Electricity
Automobile
1 1
1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 ITA
1
1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 Supercycle IV
1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 Oil
Electronic
The war indemnity paid by France from 1871 to 1873 enabled the now-incontestable
German empire to develop its industry so fast that it ended up causing a major
320
I II III IV USA
illions
160
apan
Ger an
80
(log scale)
rance
Population in
U
40
20
10
1820 35 1842 52 66 73 1896 07 20 29 1949 66 81 2000
1- Acti e population ro th in
WORLD
- Equit share in the inancial assets and the proprtion o - ear old
35% 41%
39%
30%
37%
25% 35%
20% 33%
31%
15%
29%
10% 27%
1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030
The previous generation (40-59s) does the most saving, so it’s not surprising to
see consistency with the proportion of equities in financial assets.
The 40-59 age bracket can be split into two: The 50-59s, who are actively saving
in preparation for retirement: individuals who continue to work in their fifties
dramatically increase their financial assets, on average. And the 40-49s, who are
at the peak in terms of consumption capacity, but also in terms of productivity: as
such, it is this generation that drives effective growth the most.
The chart 35 highlights the substantial increase in the number of Japanese 40-
49s starting in the 1960s (“Japanese Miracle”) followed by the sharp drop in
this age bracket as from the 1990s (real estate and stock market crash, start
of economic winter). Similarly in the United States, the decline in this age group
in 1966 coincided with the beginning of economic summer. Then the gradual
transition of the baby-boomers into this bracket marked the beginning of
economic autumn (as from 1981), while the peak in 2000 coincided with the dot-
com crash. The same thing happened in Europe, but further down the road, as
the European baby boom took place later and was less pronounced than in the
United States. Though it started in the US, the subprime crisis hit the euro zone
hard, just as the population of 40-49s had begun to decline.
- Proportion o the - ear old in the ore than ear old population
1
22%
Europe
21%
USA
USA
20%
Japan
19%
18%
17%
16%
15%
14%
1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030
It was thus necessary for new powers to emerge in order to maintain global
growth at a decent level. At the end of the 19th century, during its winter phase,
the United Kingdom already had to make room for the rise of other economic
powers, beginning with Germany and the United States. With access to existing
technologies while initially skipping the fastidious innovation phase, these new
economies developed very quickly. This was the case for Japan from the end
of World War II to the 1980s, and for the Asian “tigers” (South Korea, Hong
Kong, Singapore and Taiwan) as from the 1970s; the increase in Per capita GDP
(see chart 37), which measures both wealth and productivity, was unequivocal.
Other countries followed suit: Thailand, Malaysia, Indonesia and the Philippines
all made strides in the 1980s, the Chinese cities of Shenzhen and Shanghai took
off in the 1990s, and Vietnam for example in the 2000s.
15,100
10,100
5,100
100
1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000
25,000
20,000
15,000
10,000
5,000
0
0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0 4.5
R&D (%GDP)
Western Europe North America, Aust.,N.Z.
Eastern Europe Ex-USSR
Latam Eastern Asia
Middle East-Western Asia Africa
25,000
20,000
15,000
10,000
5,000
0
0 20 40 60 80 100
Urbanisation rate (in %)
Western Europe North America, Aust.,N.Z.
Eastern Europe Ex-USSR
Latam Eastern Asia
Middle East-Western Asia Africa
R&D stimulates the structural productivity of the economy. The lion’s share of
this effort is made by developed countries; this role is filled by urbanisation in
emerging countries.
0.8
(3) Ireland
0.6 (1)
Active population growth
0.4
New Zealand
0.2
UK Australia
0.0
Norway USA Sweden
-0.2 France
Denmark
-0.4 Spain Belgium
Netherlands Finland
-0.6 Portugal Japan
Canada Switzerland
Greece Italy Republic of Korea
-0.8 Austria
Singapore
-1.0 (4) Germany (2)
-1.2
0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0 4.0 5.0
R&D (% GDP)
(1) Above average dynamism of the active population and more powerful R&D
(2) Below average dynamism of the active population but more powerful R&D
(3) Above average dynamism of the active population but less powerful R&D
(4) Below average dynamism of the active population and less powerful R&D
2.5
Philippines
(3) (1)
Active population growth (in %)
Asia may well monopolise the first part of the table, but China only makes an appearance
toward the bottom of the Top 10, mainly because of its demographics. Three Latin
American countries (Peru, Mexico and Columbia) manage to slip in thanks to their
demographic momentum. At the bottom of the table, Eastern Europe, which is already
urbanised, is penalised by declining demographics. Russia comes in dead last.
100%
Africa
90%
Middle East
80%
Japan
70% India
60% China
50%
Latam
Ex USSR
40%
USA
30%
UK
20%
Italy
10% Germany
0% France
1500 1550 1600 1650 1700 1750 1820 1870 1913 1950 2000
If history does repeat itself, however, it will take several decades before China
achieves total supremacy and the road to this achievement is sure to be chaotic.
The United States surpassed the United Kingdom industrially in the 1890s, during
the winter of Cycle II, but only really consolidated its leadership in the following
winter with the advent of World War II (see Per capita GDP chart 37). It had already
taken a big step forward in summer with World War I, but was hit much harder than
the UK by the 1929 Stock Market Crash. And let’s not forget that US demographics
are expected to become more buoyant again in 2020-2025, which is not the case
for China. Finally, Japan - a key ally of the United States in Asia since World War
II - began to rival it on the economic front in the 1980s. After a decline of more than
20 years, Japan can no longer claim to rival the US, which has every interest in
promoting the balance of economic forces in Asia.
100
Saoudi Arabia
90
(per thousands of inhabitants and per day)
80
Number of barels of oil consumption
USA
70 Canada
60 Netherlands
Reallocating savings
to investment:
The new role of asset managers
Y VES PERRIER,
Chief Executive Officer, Amundi
February 2015
Introduction
How do we encourage productive investment? This is undoubtedly one
of the critical questions of the current economic climate. The following text
puts the current environment into perspective and develops solutions, as seen
by an asset manager in conjunction with long-term national and international
investors.
1 - Corporate investment:
twofold challenge - growth and jobs
Excess debt and deficits led Japan, then the United States and Europe to
implement highly expansionary monetary policies as well as very restrictive
budgetary and fiscal policies. Overall, budget austerity and monetary largesse
brought tranquillity to the financial world, but exposed weaknesses in the
economic realm:
t Unsustainable growth models, particularly with excess credit;
t Wide variations between countries, in a eurozone where convergence
should be the benchmark;
Without the leverage provided by credit for over a decade, reality has sunk
in, and it is not exactly pleasant:
t Investment is in the doldrums pretty well everywhere in the eurozone.
t Potential growth has been revised downward nearly everywhere: in the
US, Japan, the UK, Germany, France, the eurozone, and even China. It is
now 1% in the eurozone and Japan and a little over 2% in the United States;
t The unemployment rate remains high in Europe because there is not
enough economic growth;
Conclusion
Returning to growth and reaching full employment levels are undoubtedly the top
issues for the eurozone. For the sake of greater eurozone uniformity and to make
it possible to execute common policies more effectively, it is also necessary to
reduce the current unprecedented economic divergences:
t Different growth models, which led to the excesses of the 2000s;
t Different growth drivers (exports in Spain and Germany, consumption in
Germany, and public spending in France, etc.);
t Stark variations in terms of competitiveness;
t Solid budget balancing in Germany, but fragile in peripheral countries
and deteriorated in France;
t Public debt under control (Germany), fragile (France) or still vulnerable
(Spain, Italy, etc.);
t Current account surpluses everywhere but France, but which reflect
different realities: excess savings in the Northern eurozone and lack of
investment in the South. Worse still is the eurozone’s inability to recycle
excess savings from the North toward the investment deficits of the South.
The ECB cannot solve everything. Through its actions and statements, it
has been able to ease the financial crisis and to ensure much of the financial
convergence.
Governments as well as budget and fiscal policies must be the drivers in terms of
economic convergence. Three major levers should be used:
Lever 1: cost of labour: reducing and harmonising this will allow the eurozone’s
cost-competitiveness to grow. Reducing public spending to reduce taxes on
labour would kill two birds with one stone: improve public finances on one hand,
and restore competitiveness and employment on the other.
Lever 2: technological competitiveness: without setting the new and old
economies against each other, economic development is always achieved
through technological advances that must be harnessed effectively in order to
November 2014
Introduction
Asset allocation traditionally refers to the way a portfolio is divided between equity,
fixed income and money market products, but the investment universe used to
build an institutional asset portfolio has expanded over the past few years to so-
called alternative investments: investments in hedge funds and unlisted assets
- direct real estate investment, private equity, loans or infrastructure projects-.
High-net-worth private investors, as well as certain pension funds and American
university foundations, have pioneered this type of assets, which have more
recently been the subject of increasing interest from supranational investors and
sovereign wealth funds. For example, large sovereign investors like the ADIA or
GIC devote 20% (half in real estate) and 26% of their asset allocation to alternative
investments, respectively. The graph below gives more details on the GIC’s
allocation as of late 2013:
7% 11% 7%
23% 27% 26 %
26% 17% 21 %
44% 45% 46 %
1 See Hauss for a quantification of systemic risk's share in the total risk of real estate
investments
2 See Gianni Pola: Rethinking strategic asset allocation in terms of diversification across
macroeconomic scenarios, Cross Asset Investment Strategy Special Focus, May 2013.
S
Amundi Investment Strategy Collected Research Papers 83
of market risk, because especially in the world of hedge funds, the extreme risks
that are observed are substantially greater than those of conventional assets with
equivalent volatility, making the assumption of symmetrical returns required for
the estimate unsuitable. Performance-related fees also contribute to asymmetry
in the return distribution of these assets.
20
15
IRR PE und
10 IRR PE fund
5 Equity IRR
0
-10 -5 0 5 10 15 20 25
-5
-10
IRR equit Source: Amundi Research
Note that, particularly in the event that the return of the equities is high, the cash
drag and more importantly the variable management fees substantially reduce
the investors’ share of that profit.
Lastly, before using these return forecasts in a risk/return optimisation, we must
check their consistency with those of conventional listed asset classes and based
on the risk adjusted return used in the optimisation. Otherwise, in the absence of
a uniform method for estimating returns among different asset classes, experts’
degree of optimism or realism will constitute the primary foundation for the asset
classes’ apparent attractiveness.
8 Gilfedder and Sheperd show the usefulness of looking at similar listed securities to
represent the risk of infrastructure investments
ESTIMATED
EIOPA CORRELATION MATRIX ASSET CORRELATIONS
WITH REAL ESTATE
Correlation
Interest Real
Equity Spread Currency with real
rate estate
estate
Government bonds
Equity 0 1 0,75 0,75 0,25 0
Eurozone
Credit IG bonds
Real estate 0 0,75 1 0,5 25 0,43
Eurozone
Emerging bonds
Currency 0,25 0,25 0,25 0,25 1 0,47
hard currency
Equities 0,75
Source: EIOPA, Amundi Insurance Solutions
Ang A., Kaplan A., Columbia Business School and NBER, Estimating Private Equity Returns
from Limited Partner Cash Flows, Netspar, January 2014
Ang A., Sorensen M., Risk, returns and optimal holdings of private equity : a survey of
existing approaches, Netspar panel paper 39
Buscombe T., McNally S., Mercer, Spending your Illiquidity Budget, Presentation to Global
Investment Forums, 2014
Cremers M., The Performance of Direct Investments in real Assets : Natural Resources,
Infrastructure and Commercial Real-Estate, Deutsche Asset and Wealth Management Global
Financial Institute, June 2013
De Jong F., Driessen J., The Norwegian Government Pension Fund’s Potential for capturing
illiquidity premiums, Report to the Norwegian Ministry of Finance, February 2013
De Laguiche S., Blanchard C., Russo A., Physical real estate in long-term asset allocation:
the case of France, Amundi Discussion Paper, September 2014
De Laguiche S., Pola G., Unexpected Returns : Methodological Considerations on Expected
Returns in uncertainty, Amundi Working Paper 032-2012, November 2012
Gilfedder N., Shepard P., Stocks, Bonds and Airports : Infrastructure Assets in Pension
Plan Portfolios, MSCI Market Insight, January 2014
Government of Singapore Investment Corporation, GIC’s New Investment Framework,
2012-2013 Annual report
Hauss H. The Role of International Property Investments in the Global Asset allocation
Process, University of South Australia
Jagger S, A few caveats attached to private equity statistics, FT, October 2012
Kinlaw W., Kritzman M.,Turkington D., Liquidity and Portfolio Choice : A Unified Approach,
The Journal of Portfolio Management, Winter 2013
Lezmi E., Lou K., Zhao S., Hedge Funds Replication : Factor models, Amundi internal
document, November 2013
Pedersen N., Page S., He F. 2014, Asset Allocation : Risk Models for Alternative Investments,
Financial Analysts Journal, May-June
Phalippou L, Gottschalg O, The performance of private equity funds, The Review of
financial studies vol 22 issue 4, April 2009
Pola G., Managing uncertainty with dams. Asset segmentation in response to macroeconomic
changes, Amundi Working paper, May 2013
Santiso J., Sovereign Wealth Funds, 2013 Report, ESADE Business School
Santiso J., Sovereign Funds 3.0, Asset allocation strategies, 2010-2020, Report to Amundi
Shephard P and Liu Y, The Barra Private Equity model, MSCI Research note, August 2014
Sung C. C., Trends in Sovereign Wealth Management : Emergence of New Investment
Models, presentation to Nomura Central Bank Seminar, April 2014
We would like to thank all of our colleagues at Amundi, in particular from Amundi
Insurance Solutions, Amundi Real Estate and Amundi Private Equity, whose insights
helped enhance these analyses. Bernard Arock’s comments on Private Equity were
particularly useful to us in fleshing out the sections related to such assets.
October 2014
Sectors
Investment Telecommunication
and Technology Phase ii Phase iii and Public Utilities
GDP
trend
Phase i Phase iv
GDP
Cyclical Banking
consumption and Insurance
Strategies
Contrarian Protection
Let us now break down these four phases more finely, highlighting for each of them:
the market behaviour, the indicators that prefigure this phase, the most appropriate
forms of analysis, opportune investment strategies and an initial asset allocation
approach.
T Asset performance
This initial phase of the cycle is favourable to equities generally and particularly to
pro-cyclical stocks and markets. With the worst having been avoided in economic
terms, we are ready to take more risks and even to invest in less liquid assets.
After collapsing, small-cap stocks, for example, now start to soar. In terms of
sectors, sectors that are the most sensitive to a decline in interest rates and a
decline in energy prices, now on a real downtrend, are the first to pick up. This is
the case of the banks and more generally financials, stocks related to residential
construction, transport and automobile stocks.
Corporate bonds, which react positively to the reduction in the default risk, rally
before equities, which prevail in the end due to hopes of a resumption in growth.
Government bonds underperform equities, even if their prices do not necessarily
decline. Commodities, which are very volatile, have sometimes reached their low
point before equities but are generally still very risky.
T Indicators
At this stage, the flow of bad news is at its peak. Companies, battling with
recession, deliver cautious or even gloomy messages on their prospects. Financial
analysts therefore downgrade their company earnings forecasts.
Investor sentiment in surveys is at its most pessimistic. Individual investors throw
in the towel and sell their shares to well-informed professionals who decide to look
beyond the valley which is now not very far away. We notice, consistently over
time, that the low point of the US equity market is situated two quarters before the
low point of economic growth, as defined by the NBER. However, unfortunately
we notice it a posteriori! Investor doubts, related to the previous crisis (excessive
debt, overinvestment, overstocking, etc.) end up clearing at the same time as
the rise in share prices, and subsequently the gradual improvement in company
results. We therefore say that the market climbs “the wall of worries”.
The decline in the central bank’s interest rates accelerates. The decline in short
rates is now faster than for long rates. The steepening of the yield curve enables
banks, which finance a large part of the economy, to recover their health. This
is essential to ensure the sound and sustainable resumption of a new growth
cycle. If short rates go below the level of inflation, monetary policy becomes very
“accommodative” and that generally constitutes a good signal to return to equities.
The pick-up in bank loans constitutes confirmation, therefore a posteriori, that
3200
1600
800
400
200
100
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
Oct. 1974 Oct. 1982 Feb. 1993 Sept. 2001 Nov. 2008
The accelerated decline in interest rates is a powerful buy signal with regard to
equity markets, especially when the decline is synchronised at a global level.
3200
1600
800
400
200
100
10
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
Oct. 1974 Oct. 1982 Feb. 1993 Sept. 2001 Nov. 2008
The accelerated decline in interest rates is a powerful buy signal with regard to
equity markets, especially when the decline is synchronised at a global level.
T Relevance of analyses
In this phase, the market is more governed by the psychology of investors than
by the fundamentals of economies. Consequently, the technical analysis will be
essential to pinpoint a reversal pattern in equity markets and therefore help in the
timing for re-weighting them. Stocks that rise fastest are also initially simply those
that have fallen the most previously (hedging of short positions), whatever their
quality. Financial analysis will gradually become more relevant for pinpointing
deep value stocks that the patient investor can include in their portfolio. On the
other hand, quantitative analysis is generally ineffective in this market phase,
which is difficult to pinpoint through modelling.
T Asset allocation
In terms of asset allocation, an allocation predominantly invested in equities is
essential. Indeed, most of the performance of equities takes place during the
rebound phase. Given the strong volatility, we will gradually switch to equities
when the reversal pattern is validated. During the construction phase of this
pattern we will tend to be invested evenly between equities and fixed income
products. Credit, which is inexpensive (the spreads are very high) and less volatile
than equities is a good way of starting to re-weight portfolio risk.
T Asset performance
This phase is still favourable for equities. The rise becomes widespread. There are
fewer and fewer discounted small-cap stocks. While their margins have already
been rebuilt, companies are also more confident and will have to invest in order
to, in the future, satisfy this demand, which is in the process of exceeding their
production capacity. As a result, investment-related stocks gain the upper hand
over those related to consumption. Those that have the best pricing power, such
as luxury goods stocks, remain in the running longer. Finally, mining companies and
more generally companies related to raw materials end up outperforming due to the
general increase in commodity prices.
With economic growth now exceeding its potential, demand for commodities exceeds
supply and they even end up doing better than equities. Within commodities, oil
and pro-cyclical industrial metals such as copper, zinc and nickel perform better
than gold (except in cases of hyperinflation). Among the precious metals, silver
outperforms gold.
Generally, safe haven stocks underperform. This is the worst phase for government
bonds. Within fixed income markets, corporate bonds with higher yields remain
attractive longer while company default rates tend to diminish. The pick-up in
corporate debt to finance investment or mergers and acquisitions increases paper
supply but the very strong demand from yield-seeking investors results in a maximum
reduction in spreads. The spreads of Investment Grade credit are the first to shrink,
in parallel with bond volatility. The spreads of high-yield bonds tend rather to reflect
equity volatility, which also remains contained.
T Indicators
The Fed ends up raising its rates, always after the unemployment rate has reached
its peak and before corporate margins have finished increasing. Since 1950, the
median top margin occurs 18 months before the top of the economic cycle (see
graph and table).
The accelerated rise in bond yields anticipates the reversal in monetary policy and
the outperformance of industrial commodities in relation to government bonds
constitutes an excellent confirmation of the transition to phase ii. This is an initial
major warning sign for risky assets. However, there is no need to worry unduly. It
is not a sufficient obstacle to halt the rise of equities, at least apart from extreme
periods of hyperinflation or deflation.
T Relevance of analyses
As for the forms of analyses, they all function well in this phase. Financial analysis
is very relevant to forecast profits growth and provide a fundamental valuation of
companies, which also helps to further reassure investors. Quantitative analysis,
which systematises the fundamental approach of financial analysts also comes into
its own and is at its height. Often, a few well calibrated ratios are sufficient to pinpoint
cheap stocks. Technical analysis, which excellently captures the momentum of
prices, also works very well. The leitmotif of technical analysts therefore becomes
“the highest highs are bullish”.
T Asset allocation
In terms of asset allocation, bonds can make way for commodities. Since commodities
are very volatile, they will nevertheless be contented with a smaller percentage.
2400 17%
15%
1200 13%
600 11%
9%
300
7%
150 5%
1950
1953
1957
1960
1963
1967
1970
1974
1977
1980
1984
1987
1991
1994
1998
2001
2004
2008
2011
DOW JONES Gross margin Recession
(scale. L) (scale. R) Source: Datastream, Amundi Research
The median companies’ margin decline occurs 18 months before the recession.
When margins decline, the equity market continues to rise. It ends up capitulating
only one quarter before the recession.
T Asset performance
Growth is still apparently abundant but valuations tend to converge, whatever the risk
of the underlying assets. The performance of equities in relation to volatility begins
to decline. Small-cap stocks have more difficulty than large-cap stocks. In terms
of sector, the leading sectors of this cycle no longer outperform; more defensive
T Indicators
In addition to this symptomatic behaviour which raises questions, it is worth noting
that investors are often hypnotised by the very low volatility and think that the growth
of the last few months is sustainable; it is the calm before the storm. Optimism is at
its height. We therefore hear comments that “this time is different!”. However, if the
central bank stops raising its rates, it undoubtedly has good reason for doing so,
even if it is not infallible. It is a difficult phase for the central bank as well: inflation,
which is a belated function of economic growth, continues to rise and deserves
all its attention. Conversely, the central bank risks causing a recession if it waits
too long to lower its guard. Moreover, the rate of growth of bank loans is already
starting to fall.
T Relevance of analyses
At this stage, financial and quantitative analyses become less relevant. Companies
rarely see the economic downturn looming and guide analysts towards a continuing
increase in profits. The consensus adopts these data and the quantitative analysts
that refer to it often get caught by the downturn that will follow. Technical analysts
that are too focused on the continuing momentum are also partially blinded, but
others notice signs of trend exhaustion and securities’ less consistent participation
in the rise and then gradually detect reversal patterns: double or triple top or even
a head and shoulders.
T Asset allocation
Consequently, in terms of allocation, it is wise to give priority to money market
investments and inflation-indexed bonds: the latter will benefit from the fall in real
rates in the phase iv to come. This is the time to be invested as far as possible in
cash, while waiting to see which way the wind blows. The share of risky assets
should be reduced or even sold before the next phase.
FED RATES
20
p of Penn
Collapse
Square r Bank
B Collapse
15 + 1 Mex
st
Mexican crisis
M of Continental Illinois
ollapse
s
Collapse
klin National
of Franklin N
Natio Bank
Savings & Loans
10 crisis Internet
Collapse
a o
of
Penn
n Central
t 2nd Mexican bubble
American credit crisis Subprimes
crisis
5 crisiss
0
CBR INDUSTRIALS
700
Emergence
600 of China
500
400
300
200
100
0
US COMPANY PROFITS
125
Vietnam War
Korean War
25
1
1954 1958 1960 1967 1970 1974 1981 1984 1989 1995 2001 2007
The contraction of economic growth is often revealed through a crisis that forces
the Fed to lower its rates, whereas industrial commodity prices have already
passed their cyclical high. This arrives at the top of corporate profits which are a
lagging cycle indicator.
T Asset performance
The most risky assets decline or even collapse. They involve industrial commodities,
high-yield bonds, convertibles, equity markets generally and in particular less
liquid stocks and stocks that were fashionable in this cycle and whose valuation
has become too generous. In terms of sectors, telecommunications and services
utilities prove more resilient to the decline in the markets. These stocks are very
liquid, less sensitive to economic activity. Often indebted, they even profit from
the decline in rates under way. Finally, they often have a more domestic profile,
which is reassuring. The other defensive sectors such as food processing and
pharmaceuticals also perform very well relative to the rest of the market.
T Indicators
The contraction of economic growth is often revealed through a crisis that forces
the Fed to lower its rates (first graph). This corresponds to the top of US company
profits (third graph) which is often only detected a posteriori. The central bank only
accelerates its rate decline when it is certain that the supply/demand equilibrium has
been broken. In this respect, the decline in industrial commodity prices provides an
invaluable indication (second graph). The shaded periods on the following graphs
correspond to periods of war (Korea and Vietnam) which are slightly less relevant
in terms of analysis. It is worth noting that in 2007, the emergence of China and
speculation on the shortage of commodity prolonged the rise in commodity prices
and sent a false signal to central banks.
T Relevance of analyses
During phase iv, the financial or quantitative analyses of companies no longer
function. The lack of liquidity accentuates volatility, which is at its height. Investors
that have held out until now reduce their risks. Markets are grappling with a
psychology that is very rapidly deteriorating. Technical analysis, which takes
account of psychological effects, is again one of the most effective approaches
for analysing this phase of the asset cycle. It is often impressive to observe how,
during their decline, markets “stop off” at levels corresponding to Fibonacci ratios.
Then, when share prices have finished declining, they do not really pick up either.
T Asset allocation
The exposure on the money market should have been reduced in favour of
government bonds. Equities will only gradually be re-weighted when market
sentiment is at its gloomiest, ideally during the reversal pattern that marks the
transition to the next phase.
20% 10%
5%
15%
0%
10%
- 5%
5%
- 10%
0% - 15%
- 5% - 20%
S&P500 real RI CRB Industrial ‐ Government bonds
10%
10%
8%
5%
6%
4% 0%
2%
5%‐
0%
- 10%
- 2%
- 4% - 15%
Sovereign Bonds real RI CRB Index - Gold
Corporate bonds real RI
Money Market real RI Source: Datastream, F D, GlobalFinancial Data, Shiller data set, Amundi Research
Performance of style, size and sector indices from the equity low point
in the cycle and the Fed rate position since 1950
SMALL - LARGE VALUE - GROWTH
Equity increase last increase Decline Equity increase last increase Decline
25% low point in Fed rates in short rates in Fed rate 25%
low point in Fed rates in short rates in Fed rate
20% 20%
15%
15%
10%
10%
5%
5%
0%
-5% 0%
-10% -5%
Petites-Grandes valeurs Value-Growth
50% 10%
5%
40%
0%
30%
-5%
20%
-10%
10% -15%
0% -20%
-10% -25%
-20% -30%
Financial, Durable consumption Tech, Manufacturing, Energy Defensives Industrials - Durable consumer
50% 10%
40% 0%
30%
-10%
20%
-20%
10%
-30%
0%
-10% -40%
-20% -50%
Non durable - Durable consumption
Financial Tech, Industrial
Energy Non cyclical consumption
Telecom, Utilities Source: Fama French data set, Amundi Research
To avoid overload, we have removed references to the economic cycle, which are
no longer represented except through the name of phases i,ii,iii,iv. Similarly, we
have not included strategies within commodities either, given that oil and industrial
commodities tend to outperform precious metals including gold in phase i and ii,
while conversely precious metals, which are more defensive, outperform in phase
iii and iv.
LOW VOLATILIT
RELATIVE SE URE
VALUE STRATEGIES RETURN STRATEGIES
RELATIVE E ENSIVE
E UITIES ON S
SPREA S STEEPENING LATTENING
LI ALS RESERVE
HIGH VOLATILIT
At the bottom of the investment cycle (bottom of the diagram), volatility is strong. It
is necessary to be contrarian. Phase i is the phase where the annual return of risky
assets will be the highest. Subsequently (phase ii), it is necessary to be more subtle
and implement “relative value” strategies. When volatility becomes very low, returns
have to be made even more secure (phase iii). Finally, whereas the return of risky assets
continues to weaken, it is necessary to have switched to “protection” mode (phase iv).
The sequence of these four phases is very consistent. However, they can be longer
or shorter according to the cycles. Therefore, we are now going to focus on the
duration of short investment cycles, observing firstly economic cycles, and then
stock market cycles.
T Firstly, the cycles and the idea we have of them have changed over time
The biggest rupture since industrialisation was marked by the Second World War.
The majority of studies date back to this period which has the attraction of being
much better supplied in terms of statistics. However, observing previous cycles is
not devoid of interest:
Prior to the Second World War, cycles were much more marked, both upwards
and downwards. Shocks concerned first and foremost infrastructures. After the
Second World War and the increasing momentum of our consumer society, shocks
mainly marked durable consumer goods. Moreover, they subsided. The expansion
from 1961 to 1969 was, at the time, the longest in history; so much so that during
the 1960s, some observers even began to doubt that the cycles still existed. The
same phenomenon appeared during the 1990s. In both cases, the absence of
prolonged volatility in economic activity was nevertheless ultimately transformed
into recession!
In 1969, Mintz (NBER) gave birth to a new concept: “growth recession”, i.e. a
slowdown in growth in relation to its trend, but which did not turn into recession.
One, or even two re-accelerations occur, prolonging the cycle accordingly. However,
the outcome is always the same: recession. This therefore involves considering
cyclical movements in relative terms and no longer in absolute terms. Monetary
policy espouses these cyclical movements, or even provokes them; monitoring
its different stages (rise in rates, stability on a plateau, decline, new stability) is
therefore fundamental.
An economic cycle as defined by the NBER lasts 47 months, based on the median
since 1854. Changes since the Second World War have been greatest within the
cycle. They have related to the extension of the expansion period and the reduction
of the consolidation period. The duration of the consolidation has become more
uniform. As for expansion phases, they have become more complex and can
include “Growth Recessions”.
1900
1903
1907
1910
1914
1917
1921
1926
1932
1935
1949
1953
1957
1962
1966
1970
1974
1978
1982
1987
1990
1994
1998
2003
2006
50
40
30
20
10
0
1896
1900
1903
1907
1910
1914
1917
1921
1926
1932
1935
1949
1953
1957
1962
1966
1970
1974
1978
1982
1987
1990
1994
1998
2003
2006
As for the extent of the movements, the majority of the time, the rise in a S&P
500 cycle ranges between +50% and +100%, whereas the average correction
is around -25%. These proportions are very similar to the figures we observe on
average on corporate profits.
The high point of the stock market cycle can be situated at the end of 2, 3 or 4
rising waves. We therefore notice 2 phenomena:
The first is easy to understand. The more bullish the cycle, the more upward
stages the market goes through. It is a little like a diver who has to return to the
surface in stages.
The second is counter-intuitive and full of information. The more bullish the cycle,
the more the correction that follows is limited. This can be explained by the duration
of the stock market cycle. The fourth upward phase, when it occurs (profile 3),
anticipates the continuation of a favourable profits or valuation movement; the
following cycle having at least 2 rising legs. In contrast, if the cycle has only 2
rising legs (profile 2), the correction is therefore the strongest. Moreover, it is
frequent for cycles that have only 2 rising legs to occur after cycles with 4 rising
legs, such as during the formation and bursting of bubbles;1998-2003 and 2006-
2009 are good examples of this situation.
R The economic cycle extends from one recession to another. In the United
States, the NBER is responsible for dating recessions. An economic cycle
defined accordingly can contain several “growth recessions” and therefore
several investment cycles.
R The stock market cycle is also determined by us. It starts with a major
low point, below the 200-day moving average, and ends with the last major
high point before a significant break in the 200-day moving average. It is a
tremendous addition to the analysis of central banks’ monetary policies in order
to find our way around the investment cycle.
i i ii iii i i ii iii i i ii
7
6 ed und rates
5
0
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
i i ii iii i i ii iii i i ii
8000
E er in ar ets
4000
S all-cap stoc s
2000
S P
1000
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2000
i i ii iii i i ii iii i i ii
1800
1600
1400 Gold
1200
1000
800
600
400 R Industrials
200
0
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
1350
DS Marchés Emergents
1150
orporate onds
E er in Mar et onds US
950 e i es a eurs
Go ern ent
onds
750
350
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
Source: Amundi Research
The first investment cycle (October 2002-March 2009) starts during the decline in
Fed rates. It develops fairly classically and corresponds to Fed rate movements,
except that it results in the subprime bubble. The second (March 2009-October
2011) is more unusual since it corresponds to quantitative easing and no longer to
interest rate phases. However, the sequence of asset class performance clearly
complies with our past observations.
The last two investment cycles’ common points with our roadmap
Phase i is logically marked by a very sharp equity recovery and phase ii by an
acceleration in the price of commodities whereas bonds pale into insignificance.
Phase iii is characterised by a decline in the return of risky assets and less dispersion
of returns. Lastly, phase iv is particularly destructive of value. Government bonds
and gold are therefore the best safe haven investment. Finally, volatility decreases
in the first 2 phases and increases during the last 2; we note, in passing, that this
is valid for the volatility of both equities and bonds.
If we go into more detail, the best phase for the dollar is phase iv where it serves
as a safe haven currency and the worst is phase ii when volatility is weakest.
Silver beats gold in phase i and ii, and then it is the reverse in phase iii and iv. The
same is true for small-cap stocks which outperform large-cap stocks in phases i
and ii and conversely underperform in phases iii and iv. Idem for value stocks in
relation to growth stocks.
60%
40%
20%
0%
-20%
-40%
-60%
S&P 500 VIX MOVE Source: Datastream, Amundi Research
RAW MATERIALS
i ii iii iv
100%
Oct 2002 - June 2004 June 2006 - Aug 2007 Jan 2001 - Oct 2002
80% March 2009 - June 2010 March 2011 - July 2011 Août 207 - Mars 2009
July 2011 - Oct 2011
60%
40%
20%
0%
-0,2
Money Market Bond Gov Credit IG Bond IL Bond EM Credit HY Source:Datastream, Amundi Research
0,1
0
Oct 2002 - June 2004
-0,1 March 2009 - June 2010
-0,2
Cyclicals-Defensives Source:Datastream, Amundi Research
60%
40%
20%
0%
-20%
-40%
-60%
S&P 500 VIX MOVE Source: Datastream, Amundi Research
RAW MATERIALS
i ii iii iv
100%
Oct 2002 - June 2004 June 2006 - Aug 2007 Jan 2001 - Oct 2002
80% March 2009 - June 2010 March 2011 - July 2011 Août 207 - Mars 2009
July 2011 - Oct 2011
60%
40%
20%
0%
Geoffrey H. Moore et Victor Zarnowitz (1986): “ The development and role of the NBER’s
Business Cycle Chronologies”- NBER Studies in Business Cycle Vol 25
Deborah Owen and Robin Griffith (2006): “ Mapping the Markets”, Bloomberg Press
Éric Mijot (2009): “Où en est-on dans le cycle d’investissement ?”, Investir, 8 March
Éric Mijot (2009): “Comment réagissent les secteurs au cours du cycle d’investissement ?”,
Investir, March 29
Éric Mijot (2009): “Quel est le comportement des actions au cours des cycles longs”,
Investir, 21 March
Andrew Garthwaite (2011): “Margins: higher for longer” Credit Suisse Research, May 6
Éric Mijot (2013): “Une hirondelle annonce le printemps mais le ne fait pas !”, Amundi Cross
Asset Invesment Strategy,June
Dough Peta (2013): “ Stocks and the Fed Fund rate Cycle”, BCA Research, December
Mark McClellan (2014): “Bonds and the Fed Funds rate Cycle”, BCA Research, May
September 2014
Introduction
The benefit of an asset class is explained by the expected return given its risk,
as well as its impact on the total risk of the portfolio via diversification. It is hard
to extrapolate from past returns, but observing historical series is helpful for
quantifying risk and correlations. Here, we are interested in the risk of physical real
estate and its correlation with the listed assets to be taken into account for long-
term allocation in the case of France.
1.1 – CBRE
CBRE, a real estate broker, offers a contribution index based on rent and yield rate.
This indicator provides long series, which are updated quarterly and therefore more
often than the IPD index, for example. However, it exists in this form only for the
so-called “prime” segment of the office space market. Its restriction to this specific
market area means it does not necessarily have the same ability to benefit from the
diversification specific to the real estate asset class, in terms of both products and
geographic locations.
It therefore represents the rent achievable for available office surface area in an
office building with particularly good technical assets when leased by a user for
the long term (nine years in France). This index is an estimate for this specific and
especially narrow market segment over a given period of time.
Given their frequency, the CBRE data set is nonetheless the only one that can be
used to estimate correlations with other assets, but it remains much more volatile
than the office market as a whole.
1.2 – IPD
II - Long-term risk
When estimating the risk associated with a real estate investment, available data
must be used carefully. Depending on the type of indices used, the orders of
magnitude observed for volatility may be quite different. The graph shows volatilities
in yearly data for reconstructed index series from the providers listed in section 1.
20%
15%
10%
5%
0%
IEIF Edhec IPD offices IPD residential IPD golden Equities Equities Reits
triangle SBF250
Source: Amundi Research
Note that depending on the index type, CBRE, Edhec or IPD, the apparent volatility
is different and substantially stronger for CBRE than for the series drawn from IPD.
Naturally, some of this can be explained by the fact that the CBRE data is drawn
from observations of the prime market in Paris, the Golden Triangle, which is more
volatile, but even in this segment, the IPD data is much less volatile, a sign that a
significant share of the difference in volatility is due to the indices’ different natures:
the IPD data is much smoother. It should also be noted that when examining the
IPD data, residential is 30% less volatile on average than office. Although the orders
of magnitude of IPD volatilities are excessively low, it appears interesting to us to
consider the hierarchy between the risk levels available through the IPD data.
1 EDHEC IEIF Immobilier d’Entreprise France index rules, EDHEC-RISK Institute, September
2012.
Annualised volatility
according to frequency of observations
0,25
0,2
0,15
0,1
0,05
0
quaterly semiannual annual biennial
CBRE real estate Equity Reits Source: Amundi Research
ƌĞĂůĞƐƚĂƚĞZĂŶĚďŽŶĚƐ
Real estate has positive correlations with equities, and negative with government
bonds. As with volatility, extending the frequency exacerbates these correlations,
which are therefore more significant in the long than in the short term.
Smoothing causes an apparent reduction in risk, but also a delaying effect,
because the index’s value on a date includes average price indications for a
previous period. Additionally, the information transmission period also creates
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
-10%
Looking just at synchronous correlation, it is around 40% today, but in the past, it
was practically zero. However, this is deceptive, because in the past the delayed
correlations were also on the same order, between 30% and 40%. This is therefore
a relatively stable correlation if time lags are taken into account, but those lags
have gotten smaller. To estimate a correlation over long time periods, the existence
of variable time lags has only a moderate effect. This may explain why computing
the figure using a biennial frequency gives a substantially higher result than when
using a quarterly frequency, if examining the period as a whole. Based on these
findings, we believe that over a long time period, the equities-real estate correlation
should be considered significantly positive. However, it is conceivable that working
with CBRE indices that only cover the “prime” Paris segment exacerbates this
correlation as a result of the increased sensitivity of this particular real estate
segment to economic conditions.
We shall start with an initial allocation of 25% equities and 75% government bonds,
and examine the impact of an increase in the riskiest asset classes (equities
and physical real estate) and reduction in bonds. To begin with, we increase the
share of equities by 10%. Next, instead of changing equities, we add 12.5% real
estate. This 12.5% figure was calculated in such a way as to take into account the
difference in volatility between the two asset classes (calculated based on the
average volatilities over both frequencies).
10%
9%
8%
7%
6%
5%
4%
3%
2%
1%
0%
quarterly biennial
initial 25% equity-75% bonds +10% equity +12,5% real estate Source: Amundi Research
Note that the increase in risk is much smaller for real estate than for equities; the
result is somewhat less clear-cut with respect to the biennial frequency than for the
annual frequency. The diversifying power of physical real estate therefore appears
attractive, but is it being overestimated?
We have examined the impact on risk when 10% cash is replaced with 10% real
estate. The results are different depending on the starting allocation and the
frequency.
100% cash
Doing this with an initially 100% cash portfolio does not show the effects of
interaction with other asset classes. The volatility increase represents 10% of the
volatility of the added class. In other cases, the increase of risk that is obtained is
always significantly lower, because the risk that is introduced is diluted by the effect
of correlations. For bond-heavy portfolios, adding physical real estate might even
reduce long-term risk. Note that a simplistic calculation based on quarterly data
Conclusion
Physical real estate is a diverse asset class in which the risk and interaction with
other classes must be measured carefully. The results are very sensitive to the
types of historical data: expert valuation, or broker estimate. Due to the smoothing
and lags present in physical real estate indices, long-term risk is higher than a
typical volatility-based calculation would imply. The dependency with listed asset
classes is also more pronounced in the long term. The long-term risk of the “prime”
office segment in Paris is comparable to that of equities. It is lower for other offices,
and especially for residential. The correlation with equities is positive, and is
negative with government bonds. In allocating assets, the diversifying power of real
estate is most pronounced for bond-heavy portfolios in which adding real estate
may actually lower long-term risk. In equity-heavy portfolios, the positive long-term
correlation between real estate and equities greatly reduces the benefits in terms
of diversification. However, the smoothed valuation method of physical real estate
creates a favourable optical effect on short-term risk.
JULIEN MOUSSAVI,
Ph.D. Student, Strategy and Economic Research, Amundi
April 2015
Since the early 2000s and the bursting of the internet bubble, global liquidity has
experienced very strong growth and became excessive. We distinguish two different regimes
of global excess liquidity. Firstly, the saving glut in Emerging Markets (EMs) has fuelled
global excess liquidity, notably via the large accumulation of foreign exchange reserves.
Secondly, and in response to the global financial crisis of 2007-08 and the European
sovereign debt crisis of 2010, the central banks of the main Developed Markets (DMs) have
considerably eased their monetary policies by lowering interest rates and through successive
rounds of quantitative easing, mainly undertaken by the Federal Reserve (Fed), the Bank of
England (BoE) and the Bank of Japan (BoJ). More recently, the European Central Bank
(ECB) has also decided to increase the size of its balance sheet, to stop sterilising its
Securities Markets Programme and to launch its own quantitative easing. Global excess
liquidity has not resulted in a resurgence of inflation on a global scale, but rather in the
increase in the size of cross-border capital flows, especially towards EMs. However, these
capital flow surges, linked to global excess liquidity, are reversible and often end up in
sudden stops. Moreover, the risks of macroeconomic and financial imbalances in EMs have
been raised by many economists including Christine Lagarde1, the current IMF’s Managing
Director:
In the monetary sense, global liquidity is defined by the Bank for International Settlements
(BIS, CGFS, 2011) as the funding provided unconditionally to settle claims through the
monetary authorities. Excess liquidity can be measured by different aggregates such as the
money supply, domestic credit or also the foreign exchange reserves in excess of GDP.
Global excess liquidity appears to play a buffer role in the DMs’ deleveraging and is a
catalyst for growth in EMs. In the post-Lehman era, the Zero Interest Rate Policies (ZIRP)
1
Annual Meeting of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank in Tokyo, World Economic
Outlook, October 2012.
In this paper, we explore how best to deal with global excess liquidty and to what extent it has
caused a rise in equity prices, a larger decline in EMs real interest rates than in the United
States, i.e., a spread compression, and a real appreciation of exchange rates, which is a new
issue that has not yet been discussed for EMs. Most studies have focused on the DMs and on
the impact of monetary expansion on GDP growth, consumer price inflation, short-term
interest rates or equity prices (Baks and Kramer, 1999; Gouteron and Szpiro, 2005; Rüffer
and Stracca, 2006; Giese and Tuxen, 2007; Sousa and Zaghini, 2007 and 2008; Belke et al.,
2010b). Some of them have broadened the scope to include more assets, e.g., bond, real
effective exchange rate, commodity or real estate markets (Sousa and Zaghini, 2008; Belke et
al., 2010a and 2013). More recent literature has transposed this issue to EMs (Rüffer and
Stracca, 2006; Hartelius et al., 2008; Brana et al., 2012). The large majority of authors who
have worked on this topic have used Vector AutoRegressive (VAR) models to analyse the
links between global excess liquidity and asset prices. They also have studied the Impulse
Response Functions (IRFs) to know more precisely how a shock on global liquidity could
affect asset prices.
Our first contribution is to build three different global excess liquidity aggregates to better
understand the contemporary relationship between global excess liquidity and asset prices.
Our second and main contribution is to analyse the impact of the rise in global excess
liquidity on different asset classes such as equities, interest rates, spreads, exchange rates and
some commodities, within VAR and Vector Error Correction (VEC) frameworks. Regarding
the results, according to the global excess liquidity aggregate and the models held, the IRFs
analysis leads us to conclude that there is a genuine link between global excess liquidity and
The paper is organised as follows: As background, Section 2 focuses on the existing literature
pertaining to global excess liquidity, its measures and its links with the asset prices. Section 3
introduces the economic and financial data as well the different indices of global excess
liquidity we use. Section 4 presents our main findings, interprets them, and briefly points to
some robustness checks. We conclude our study in Section 5.
2. Literature review
Here, we address both theoretical and empirical foundations of global liquidity, its
excess as well as the links that may exist between global excess liquidity and asset prices.
Global liquidity is a multifaceted and complex concept, which has often been suggested as an
explanation for financial developments. Here, we lean on two definitions of global liquidity
which are relevant both for policy makers and asset managers:
(i) Monetary liquidity, which is defined as the ease of converting monetary assets into
goods and services;
(ii) Financial market liquidity, which is defined as the ease with which large volumes of
financial securities can be bought or sold without affecting the market price.
According to the BIS (CGFS, 2011), monetary liquidity refers to the concept of “official” or
“public” liquidity and is defined as the funding provided unconditionally to settle claims
through the monetary authorities, comprising central bank money and foreign exchange
reserves. Concerning financial market liquidity, it refers to the concept of “private” liquidity,
The academic literature on this topic allows us to identify several indicators of global
liquidity. The most commonly used measures are the monetary and credit aggregates. In this
line, Baks and Kramer (1999) as well as Sousa and Zaghini (2007) propose different global
measures based on narrow (M1) and broad (M2 and M3) monetary aggregates for the G7 and
G5 countries respectively. Gouteron and Szpiro (2005) and Alessi and Detken (2011) suggest
using the domestic credit as it can be viewed as the main counterpart of monetary creation.
Another stream of the literature focuses on the foreign exchange reserves to assess global
liquidity. Indeed, this measure takes into account the increasing role of the liquidity created
by EMs (De Nicolo and Wiegand, 2007; Darius and Radde, 2010). Beyond these quantitative
indicators, price indicators can be used. Gouteron and Szpiro (2005) propose measuring
global excess liquidity from the short-term real interest rate (three-month interbank rate)
minus the natural interest rate3 and also from risk premiums4. However, we do not pursue
these price indicators further, because we prefer to use volume-based measures to explain
changes in asset prices.
2
Glocker and Towbin (2013) suggest that private liquidity shocks have a substantially larger effect on key
financial and macroeconomic variables, than public liquidity shocks. Moreover, they also show that global
liquidity shocks are more important on a medium-term horizon, than domestic liquidity shocks
3
The natural interest rate may be defined as the interest rate that establishes the equilibrium between supply and
demand on the goods and services market. It may notably be measured by the long-term economic growth.
4
The thinking behind this proposal is that excess liquidity could reduce the investors' risk aversion. Thus, the
spread between government and corporate bonds would constitute a measure of liquidity conditions.
ܯ ͳ (1)
ܯήܸ ൌܲήܳ ൌ ൌ ݇
ܲήܳ ܸ
௧ ൌ ݉௧ െ ݃௧
݉ (2)
5
The quantity theory of money specifies the causal relationship between the quantity of money in circulation and
the general price level. The first formulation of this theory goes back to the work of Jean Bodin in 1568 in which
he studied the inflationary effects of the large influx of gold from Latin America; this influx caused a price
increase across the European continent. The formalisation of this assumption is made in 1907 by Irving Fisher
who, through an accounting identity, linked the money supply, its velocity, the general price level and the
volume of transactions of goods and services. This theory is based on two presuppositions: (i) the change in the
quantity of money induces price changes in nominal terms. In other words, the source of inflation is
fundamentally derived from the growth rate of the money supply; (ii) Economic agents are supposed to be
rational, i.e., they know relative prices and are concerned only slightly in nominal prices. The accounting identity
is written as follows: ܯή ܸ ൌ ܲ ή ܳ where ܯis the total amount of money in circulation on average in an
economy during a period, ܸ is the velocity of money in final expenditures, ܲ is the general price level and ܳ is
the real output which equals real expenditures in macroeconomic equilibrium.
By analogy with the quantity theory of money, we may reasonably assume that a surplus
of money that is not spent on the market of goods and services is highly likely to be spent on
the financial markets. However, even if we have clarified the concept of global excess
liquidity, the existence of links between rising global liquidity and rising asset prices via
higher transactions remains to be demonstrated. In addition to the quantity theory of money,
we need to find out more evidence on the links between monetary liquidity, funding liquidity6
and financial market liquidity. The following theories could explain these links:
According to Keynesian theory (Keynes, 1936), money demand satisfies three motives.
Transactions and precautionary motives are an increasing function of the income and
speculative motive is a decreasing function of the interest rate. Speculation takes the form of a
trade-off between holding money and holding long-term bonds. Incurring debt to buy
securities is particularly revealing of a process feeding bullish self-fulfilling expectations on
asset prices. Based on this assumption, the existence of a positive relationship between
liquidity and asset prices might seem almost trivial. With this in mind, we can easily realise
that the credit channel is a financial accelerator encouraging all the agents to indebtedness,
causing a cumulative process characterised by an increase in prices and debt especially to
acquire assets. In other words, we can establish that liquidity promotes the dynamics of
accumulation and thus the valuation of assets.
As stated by Stiglitz and Weiss (1981), the role of money may also be studied through its
counterpart of credit granting to the economy. Within this framework, a situation of abundant
liquidity is equivalent to low interest rates. Given that interest rates represent the cost of
capital, when interest rates are low, profitability is low and investors are willing to invest in
riskier assets resulting, de facto, in an increase of the price of these assets. This allows us to
establish that there is a negative relationship between interest rates and asset prices, and thus a
positive relationship between liquidity and asset prices.
6
Funding liquidity is defined as the ease with which market players can obtain funding.
Furthermore, a common factor may lead to a simultaneous trend in monetary aggregates and
asset prices. This shock, whether positive or negative, is viewed as a signal, e.g., better
economic prospects lead to better expectations about future profits (Baks and Kramer, 1999).
Thus, the link between lower interest rates and an increase in the fundamental value of asset
prices follows from all the monetary policy transmission channels. Indeed, an accommodative
monetary policy informs agents on the willingness of financial authorities to support growth.
Investors therefore see this as a better outlook for future profits and start buying greater
amounts of risky assets.
Finally, Brunnermeier and Pedersen (2009) show that, under certain conditions (mainly boom
vs. bust cycles and monetary easing vs. tightening), financial market liquidity and funding
liquidity are mutually reinforcing, leading to liquidity spirals. They empirically explain that
market liquidity (i) can suddenly dry up, (ii) has commonality across securities, (iii) is related
to volatility, (iv) is subject to “flight to quality”, and (v) co-moves with the market. Without
loss of generality and given the link between the different liquidity concepts, we can
extrapolate these procyclical stylised facts to monetary liquidity.
In recent years, global excess liquidity has been mostly induced by ultra-
accommodative and non-conventional monetary policies conducted by the central banks of
the major developed countries, i.e., United States, United Kingdom, Japan and the Eurozone.
These monetary policies have had, inter alia, the effect of lowering the cost of liquidity to
international investors. This has led investors to search for yield by turning towards higher-
return, and therefore riskier, assets as argued by the IMF (2010) and Matsumoto (2011). This
resulted in massive capital inflows towards EMs notably through carry trade operations, with
We may wonder to what extent the abundance of global liquidity is responsible for upward
pressures on asset prices, especially in EMs. Few studies have directly investigated this issue.
Most studies focused on DMs and about the impact of money growth on GDP trends,
inflation, interest rate dynamics and equity prices. More recent literature transposes this
problematic to EMs and broadens the spectrum of the relevant assets, i.e., bonds, real
effective exchange rates and commodities. The vast majority of researchers who have worked
on this topic have used VAR models and have analysed IRFs.
Baks and Kramer (1999) study this issue for the G7 countries and conclude that global excess
liquidity has a negative impact on real interest rates and a positive impact on equity prices.
They also find some evidence for spillover effects from the volatility of money growth to the
volatility of equity prices across countries. By contrast, Gouteron and Szpiro (2005) find that
there is no common trend in asset prices, which is not supportive of a global effect of excess
liquidity. Rüffer and Stracca (2006) also examine the cross-border transmission channels of
global excess liquidity in fifteen DMs and EMs and find an expansionary effect in the
Eurozone and in Japan, though not in the United States. Furthermore, they highlight that
global excess liquidity is a useful indicator of inflationary pressure at a global level. Giese and
Tuxen (2007) show that the global excess liquidity has a positive impact on real estate prices
but not on equity prices for six major DMs. Sousa and Zaghini (2007 and 2008) identify that a
shock on global liquidity in the G5 countries has a positive impact on real GDP only in the
short term and a positive lagged impact on aggregate prices. They also find a temporary
7
These five EMs are better known by the acronym BRICS.
3. Data
In this study, we gather data for eight countries and one monetary union, representing
nearly 70% of world GDP in Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) in 2014. This set of countries is
composed of the G4 countries, i.e., United States, United Kingdom, Japan and Eurozone, and
the well-known BRICS countries, i.e., Brazil, Russia, India, China and South Africa. The data
are collected for each country or monetary union on a quarterly frequency over a sample
period from Q1 1998 to Q1 2014, or 65 quarters.
We use economic and financial data from different sources across variables and
countries; they include the IMF, the World Bank, the OECD, the Bank for International
Settlements, Eurostat, Oxford Economics and Datastream databases. More formally, the data
we use are:
Some data are seasonally adjusted using the X-12-ARIMA procedure17 if necessary.
Furthermore, we use ex post revised data for most of the economic, monetary and financial
8
Depending on the paper, the weights used to build the aggregates of global excess liquidity are done either with
nominal GDP or with PPP GDP. In this study, we use nominal GDP weights to not underweight EMs in the
aggregates but using PPP GDP weights leads to similar results.
9
Real and nominal effective exchange rates indices (REER and NEER hereafter) are provided by the Bank for
International Settlements and cover 61 economies including individual Eurozone countries and, separately, the
Eurozone as an entity. REER and NEER are calculated as geometric weighted averages of bilateral exchange
rates, adjusted by relative consumer prices in the case of REER. The weighting pattern is time-varying, and the
most recent weights are based on trade from 2008 to 2010.
10
The Morgan Stanley Capital International are the indices most regularly followed by market participants. They
measure the performance of equity markets in countries or the aggregate of countries to which they refer. We
also retain the MSCI BRIC in local currency. This index is a free float-adjusted market capitalisation weighted
index that is designed to measure the equity market performance of the following four EM country indexes as a
whole: Brazil, Russia, India and China.
11
The Emerging Markets Bond Index Global are indices of JPMorgan Chase which track the total returns of debt
securities traded abroad in EMs. The EMBI Global indices are an expanded version of the EMBI+ indices.
12
The Goldman Sachs Commodity Index is an index originally developed by Goldman Sachs and which the
ownership has been transferred to Standard & Poor's. It serves as a benchmark for investment in the commodity
markets and comprises 24 commodities from all commodity sectors.
13
The Commodity Research Bureau is an index of listed commodities on New York Mercantile Exchange,
London Metal Exchange and Chicago Mercantile Exchange. It comprises 24 commodities from all commodity
sectors.
14
The London Metal Exchange Index is the benchmark for the listing of six main nonferrous metals, i.e., copper,
tin, lead, zinc, aluminum and nickel. In recent years, the LME has become a speculative market. Indeed, the
share of commodities actually delivered after establishing a contract on the LME fell below 1%.
15
Gold spot price in USD per ounce.
16
We chose Brent crude oil rather than West Texas Intermediate crude oil because Brent crude oil serves as a
major benchmark price for purchases of crude oil worldwide. It is used to price two thirds of the world's
internationally traded crude oil supplies. However, both kinds of crude oil are traded in a narrow range.
17
The procedure is performed on ex post revised data. Nevertheless, some variables are already seasonally
adjusted. Market data do not need to be seasonally adjusted.
The mechanism we seek to highlight in this study may be interpreted differently depending on
whether we consider the nominal or real terms approach. From a theoretical point of view, the
valuation of assets is related to their nominal incomes, which in turn depend on the level of
prices of produced goods and services. This is the reason why we make this study on real
data. To do this, we multiply the variables of interest by the GDP deflator of the country or
monetary union and over the period being considered18. However, working with nominal data
amplifies the highlights that emerge from this study.
In order to account for global excess liquidity, we proceed in two steps. The first step is to
hold different measures of nationwide monetary liquidity. In a second step, we aggregate
these indices to establish a snapshot of global excess liquidity. We hold three indices of
excess liquidity on criteria such as economic relevance, data availability and homogeneity: (i)
M2 monetary aggregate, (ii) domestic credit and (iii) foreign exchange reserves. Each of these
measures is expressed as a share of GDP in local currencies for the first two indicators and in
USD for the third one. Moreover, each of these aggregate measures were log-transformed to
take into account the liquidity in excess of GDP. The aggregation of national series at a global
level raises some issues from an economic standpoint. Indeed, such aggregate measures
cannot be used for monetary and fiscal policy decisions at a global level19. However, the
purpose of this study is to better understand how monetary liquidity behaves and interacts
globally. There are different methods of aggregation but the non-stationarity of these time
series and structural breaks imply that no optimal aggregation method exists (Giese and
Tuxen, 2007). Nevertheless, Beyer et al. (2001) discuss various criteria in order to get a
18
In order to get real interest rates, nominal interest rates have been deflated by the annual average of domestic
inflation.
19
However, in an environment of global excess liquidity, and thus surges in capital flows, it is important for
EMs to ensure financial and economic stability through improved financial regulation and other policy measures.
Azis and Shin (2014) explore the range of policy options that may be deployed to address the impact of global
liquidity on domestic financial and socio-economic conditions.
The method suggested by Beyer et al. (2001) uses variable weights to aggregate growth rates
and proceeds in the following four steps (cf. Methodological Appendix for more details):
(i) Calculate weights based on the relative share of the country or monetary union as
regards the variable at each date, in a common currency, e.g., in USD in this study;
(ii) Calculate within country or monetary union growth rates of each variable at each date,
in local currency;
(iii) Aggregate growth rates of the second step using weights of the first step;
(iv) aggregate growth rates to obtain aggregate levels. We use the Q1 1998 as the base to
anchor the aggregate measures over time.
In this context, it seems interesting to investigate the potential impacts of global excess
liquidity on EM asset prices, and more particularly in the BRICS countries, as well as on
commodities which are mostly exported by these same EMs. After describing the economic
and financial environment in which this study is conducted, we develop the framework of the
model and look into the main results.
From an economic standpoint, the BRICS countries alone represent more than 28% of
world GDP in PPP in 2014 for more than 3 billion people, almost half of the Earth’s
population. According to the IMF, this group of EMs will account for nearly a third of world
GDP in PPP in 2020. These five EMs, i.e., Brazil, Russia, India, China and South Africa are
respectively the seventh, sixth, third, second and twenty-fifth largest economies in the
world20. Table 1 provides information about the average weights of each country or monetary
union over the whole sample period as a percentage of GDP in PPP in each of the three
aggregates considered. In the light of this table, we can say that China and India are in the
BRICS countries aggregate what the United States and Eurozone are in the G4 countries
aggregate, i.e., the largest contributors to global growth. The GDP per capita of the BRICS
countries is growing very rapidly, but it is expected to remain far below the standards of DMs
even on a very long-term horizon. The BRICS countries are currently strengthening their
economic and financial cooperation. Indeed, we can mention for example the New
Development Bank, formerly referred to as the BRICS Development Bank, which is a
multilateral development bank operated by the BRICS countries as an alternative to the
existing United States-dominated World Bank and IMF. This New Development Bank was
agreed by BRICS countries leaders at the fifth BRICS summit held in Durban, South Africa
on March 2013 and was ratified at the sixth BRICS summit held in Fortaleza, Brazil on July
2014. It is in this way, i.e., by creating multilateral supervisory and regulatory agencies, that
the EMs and, a fortiori, the BRICS countries are becoming the most attractive financial
markets in the world. Brazil and Russia produce and export crude oil and natural gas in large
20
This ranking stems from the IMF list of countries by GDP in PPP in 2013.
Table 1. Average weights of each country or monetary union over the entire sample period
Note: The table provides information about the average weights of each country or monetary union
over the entire sample period as a percentage of GDP in PPP in each of the three aggregates
considered. Standard deviations are in parentheses. In light of this table, we can say that China and
India are in the BRICS countries aggregate what the United States and Eurozone are in the G4
countries aggregate, i.e., the largest contributors to global growth. Moreover, if we look at how the
weights have changed over time, it appears that the weight of the G4 countries have tended to decline
in favour of those of the BRICS countries. Indeed, the weight of China rose from slightly more than
9% in early 1998 to nearly 24% in early 2014. During the same period, the weights of the United
States and the Eurozone fell from about 34% and 26% to 28% and 19%, respectively.
Although the responsibility of central banks in global excess liquidity that has fed speculative
bubbles in the DMs has often been mentioned, it is not trivial that the same phenomenon
occurred in EMs. Indeed, in a global economy with a structurally high savings rate, low
employment rate and where the global excess liquidity has no impact on the prices of goods
The first regime of global excess liquidity is typical of a global economy where distortions in
terms of liquidity are exacerbated. Indeed, during the first regime of global excess liquidity,
i.e., from 2001 to 2008, we see a significant accumulation of foreign exchange reserves. This
increase in the foreign exchange reserves to GDP ratio mainly comes from the BRICS
countries. Over this period, Russia saw its foreign exchange reserves to GDP ratio multiplied
by almost four, China and India by more than three, Brazil and South Africa by around two
and a half. The G4 countries increased their foreign exchange reserves sparingly, Japan at the
top of the list. Japan adopted, through its central bank, a highly accommodative monetary
policy in order to support its own currency.
21
As we have seen before, each variable, other than interest rates, were log-transformed but we deliberately omit
to specify that our variables are transformed for the sake of convenience.
22
The use of several tests to conclude on the nature of stationarity of the studied variables is essential to
disambiguate on some test results. Indeed, the PP unit root tests diơer from the ADF tests mainly in how they
deal with serial correlation and heteroskedasticity in the errors. In particular, where the ADF tests use a
parametric autoregression to approximate the ARMA structure of the errors in the test regression, the PP tests
ignore any serial correlation in the test regression.
Then, to test whether the series are cointegrated and, if so, how many cointegrating
relationships exist, we use the Johansen procedure (Johansen, 1991). After having used
Akaike and Schwarz information criteria to determine the optimal number of lags that would
need to be considered23, we conclude that, in more than 60% of cases, at least one
cointegration relationship exists. Then, we perform Granger non-causality tests (Granger,
1969) on the remaining 40% to find out if the different global excess liquidity aggregates
Granger-cause the different asset prices. According to these tests, in almost 10% of cases,
some short-term relationships exist as opposed to the long-term relationships of cointegrated
models. Finally, in about 30% of cases, we do not estimate any model to avoid spurious
regressions, either because the variables which are integrated of a different order cannot be
cointegrated, or because no causal relationship exists.
In this study, we use the standard time series modelling taking into account the results of the
preliminary tests explained above, i.e., ADF, PP, Johansen cointegration and Granger non-
causality tests. We use two different models to better capture the nature of the relationships
between our time series. In the case where at least one cointegration relationship exists, we
estimate a VEC model as in (3) and in the case where no cointegration relationship exists but
that the global excess liquidity appears to be causal, in the Granger sense, for asset prices, we
estimate a VAR model as in (4):
23
In most cases, minimising Akaike and Schwarz information criteria leads us to conclude that the optimal
number of lags is one. In some cases, this optimal number goes up to two or three.
All in all, over the 123 estimable models24, and according to the preliminary tests results,
more than 70% are indeed estimated. In order to validate the stationarity and stability of these
models, we propose a kind of robustness check. It is well known in the literature on VAR and
VEC models that the stationarity and stability properties depend on the roots of the lag
polynomial. In particular, if all the inverted roots of the lag polynomial are strictly inside the
unit circle, then the VAR process is stationary. For the VEC process, ݇ െ ݎroots should be
equal to the unity and so ݇ሺ െ ͳሻ ݎinverted roots should be strictly inside the unit circle,
where ݇ is the number of endogenous variables, ݎis the number of cointegration relationships
and is the largest lag. According to this robustness check, only one VEC model is unstable
and hence, this estimate is excluded from the study.
Here, we want to highlight the positive impacts of global excess liquidity in some
BRICS’ assets. Depending on the countries and assets, responses to a shock on liquidity have
the expected sign in more than half of cases. Finally, to better identify their sensibility to
some economic and econometric changes, we propose two additional robustness checks. First,
24
The 123 estimable models break down as follows: five EMs, each with seven different assets, plus six
different global assets, i.e., MSCI BRIC, some commodities and some commodity indices, and three different
global excess liquidity aggregates for a total of ሺͷ ή ሻ ή ͵ ൌ ͳʹ͵.
We want to see how the different BRICS’ assets are impacted by the increase in global
liquidity as measured by our three different indicators of global excess liquidity. To do this,
we look at how the assets react to a positive one standard deviation shock on the logarithm of
each liquidity aggregate. We focus on reviewing the Impulse Response Functions (IRFs).
According to the common practices, we estimate the IRFs with their confidence intervals. We
compute these confidence intervals using Monte-Carlo simulations in the case of the VAR
model and using the bootstrap method25 in the case of the VEC model. If confidence intervals
do not contain 0, the IRF is significant. If confidence intervals contain 0, the IRF is not
significant but we keep the sign of the IRF as a result.
25
Theoretically, it is possible to compute analytical confidence intervals using an asymptotic approximation, but
this may lead to misleading confidence intervals because asymptotic formulas are known to give a poor
approximation of the finite-sample properties.
FX Reserves ++ ++ ++ ++
M2
MSCI BRIC26 Credit
FX Reserves ++
M2 - + - - +
10Y Interest Credit - - -
Fixed Income
Rate
FX Reserves - - - -- --
M2 -- -- 0 0 --
EMBI Global Credit - + 0 +
Spread
FX Reserves - + 0 0
M2 - + +
Exchange Rate
Exchange Rate
FX Reserves ++
M2 --
Brent Credit
FX Reserves ++
As we can see in Table 2, global excess liquidity has played an important role in the evolution
of some asset prices. Overall, global excess liquidity pushed up equity prices and exchange
rates, while it brought down the fixed income rates and has more or less tightened the interest
rate spreads depending on the countries. With more granularity, several highlights appear:
26
For the MSCI BRIC, we can only consider the nominal terms approach because it could be difficult and
misleading to deflate an aggregated equity index.
(ii) On the fixed income side, the foreign exchange reserves over GDP aggregate and, to a
lesser extent the M2 over GDP aggregate, contributed to lower sovereign 10-year
interest rates in all the BRICS. According to the M2 over GDP aggregate, spread
compression is significant for Brazil, Russia and South Africa.
(iii) Concerning the foreign exchange markets, the currencies have globally appreciated
against USD and in real effective terms. Except for Brazil, once again, it is the foreign
exchange reserves over GDP aggregate which is the most significant measure of
global excess liquidity for EMs.
(iv) Finally, as for the three different global excess liquidity aggregates, the results for the
main commodity prices, i.e., the GSCI and the Brent, are more mixed. They were
positively impacted during the first regime of global excess liquidity, when EMs
accumulated some large foreign exchange reserves from early 2001 to mid-2008, by
the yardstick of the global financial crisis; whereafter the second regime of global
excess liquidity takes place. In this second regime, the commodity prices started to fall
since the developed central banks have injected significant liquidity until 2015.
While IRFs evaluate the effects of a shock to one endogenous variable on the other variables
in VAR or VEC models, variance decomposition separates the variation in an endogenous
variable into the component shocks to VAR or VEC models. Thus, the variance
decomposition provides information about the relative importance of each random innovation
in affecting the variables in VAR or VEC models. In order to remain consistent in our
approach, we will consider only the variance decomposition for the models we discussed
above.
In order to ensure the robustness of our results, we propose two robustness checks.
First, we follow the same time series methodology replacing data in real terms by data in
nominal terms. Second, we estimate a Panel Dynamic Ordinary Least Squares model (PDOLS
hereafter) with country fixed effects. This PDOLS model, introduced by Kao and Chiang
(2000) and refined by Mark and Sul (2003), involves augmenting the panel cointegrating
regression equation with cross-section specific lags and leads of the explanatory variables in
first difference to eliminate the asymptotic endogeneity and serial correlation.
For our first robustness check, we apply exactly the same methodology to the data in nominal
terms27. The conclusion is that the same aggregates of global excess liquidity lead the same
assets upward or downward whether in real or nominal terms (for more detailed results, cf.
Appendix 3). The main difference between this two estimates is the amplitude of the IRFs to a
shock on global liquidity. Indeed, in the broader sense, global excess liquidity causes a
significant increase in equity and bond prices, an appreciation of exchange rates, a decrease in
10-year sovereign interest rates and a spread compression both in real and nominal terms.
Moreover, the IRFs in nominal terms are more significant than the IRFs in real terms. In the
case of Russia and compared with the real terms approach, a one standard deviation shock on
27
We use non-deflated economic and financial data. For example, for each country and each asset class, we use
the nominal GDP growth, the 10-year nominal sovereign interest rate, the nominal effective exchange rate, etc.
Obviously, our three global excess liquidity aggregates are also used in nominal terms for consistency
Our second robustness check consists in the estimation of a PDOLS model. We chose this
panel model because it has several advantages. First, the panel approach, with its structure in
two dimensions, provides more complete information than in the time series approach. More
precisely, we can better understand our issue and provide a more global answer together with
more granularity on the question of the different global excess liquidity regimes. Second,
according to Kao and Chang (2000) and Mark and Sul (2003), the PDOLS estimators appear
to outperform all other panel estimators for non-stationary panel data, e.g., the Panel Fully
Modified OLS. In order to avoid some statistical bias in the estimates of the links between
global excess liquidity and the EMs asset prices, we add a control variable that reflects the
implied volatility of S&P 500 index options, i.e., the VIX index. Well-known as a “fear
index” for worldwide asset markets, it reflects both stock market uncertainty and a variance
risk premium. The first step of the panel analysis is to investigate the statistical properties of
our stacked data. Hence, we perform some panel stationarity and unit root tests and we
reasonably conclude that our variables are non-stationary in level and ܫሺͳሻ (for more detailed
results, cf. Appendix 4). Then, we perform some panel cointegration tests28 in order to verify
the presence of a long-run relation between the variables in our dataset and we conclude that
our series are cointegrated in more than 85% of cases29. However, we do not find evidence
28
Here, we use the well-known panel cointegration tests proposed by Pedroni (1999).
29
Because of the huge number of cointegration tests and space limitation, the panel cointegration tests results are
not reported but available upon request.
where ݅ denotes the different BRICS countries, ݐdenotes time and ݈ denotes the optimal
number of lags and leads30 with ܮଵ ൌ ሼͳǡʹǡ͵ǡͶሽ and ܮଶ ൌ ሼͳǡʹǡ͵ǡͶሽ. ܻ denotes the different
dependent variables, i.e., the different assets (alternatively equity prices, bond yields, spreads,
exchange rates and some commodity prices). ܺ denotes the ݆ different explanatory variables,
i.e., the real GDP, the VIX index and the global excess liquidity (alternatively one of the three
global excess liquidity aggregates). Country fixed effects are denoted by ܿ and ߝ denotes the
error term. In addition, the short-run dynamics coefficients ߛ are allowed to be cross-section
specific.
Table 3. Summary of PDOLS estimates of the links between global excess liquidity and
asset prices
Note: The table presents the results of the PDOLS estimates in (5) which reflect the links
between global excess liquidity and asset prices. Standard errors are in parentheses. *, **, and
*** denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level of confidence, respectively.
According to the panel cointegration tests proposed by Pedroni (1999), our series are not
cointegrated in only three cases, denoted by “No cointegration”. Regarding the models with a
cointegration relationship, we conclude that the global excess liquidity aggregates are
significant in about 90% of cases and are in the expected direction in all these cases. On the
VIX index, even though it is significant in more than half of cases, we highlight that the VIX
index is rather weakly significant or not significant to explain the changes in BRICS’ asset
prices, i.e., excluding commodity prices. The ܴ ଶ should be interpreted only within the
estimates and we observe that our PDOLS models fit better for equity prices, exchange rates
and commodity prices than for bond prices and spreads.
30
In most cases, minimising Akaike and Schwarz information criteria leads us to conclude that the optimal
number of lags and leads is often the same. In some cases, this optimal number of lags and leads may be
different.
M2 No cointegration
EMBI Global
Dom. Credit No cointegration
Spread
0.432 1.430*** -1.090***
FX Reserves (0.323) (0.341) (0.264)
303 0.81
-0.361** -0.221 0.894***
M2 (0.144) (0.157) (0.325)
307 0.98
Exchange -0.232* -0.133 0.803*
Dom. Credit (0.132) (0.156) (0.420)
297 0.98
Rate vs. USD
-0.386*** 0.175 0.469***
FX Reserves (0.091) (0.115) (0.091)
298 0.99
0.137 0.002 0.484*
M2 (0.109) (0.136) (0.281)
311 0.60
Over the last fifteen years, global liquidity has become overabundant in different forms
and encouraged the search for yield by investors who may have access to this excess liquidity.
In this paper, we have examined the impact of global excess liquidity on asset prices for the
well-known BRICS countries. First, we built three global excess liquidity aggregates based on
the foreign exchange reserves, the M2 money supply and the domestic credit, we estimated
the interaction between global excess liquidity, economic activity and asset prices through
vector autoregressive and error correction models. We focused on a wide range of asset
classes, such as equities, interest rates, spreads, exchange rates for BRICS and some
commodities.
Overall, global excess liquidity pushed up equity prices and exchange rates, while it brought
down the fixed income rates and has more or less tightened the interest rates spreads
depending on the countries. Regarding exchange rates, global excess liquidity is a factor that
explains the appreciation trend both against the dollar and in real effective terms. Moreover,
we found that foreign exchange reserves have a genuine link with asset prices considering the
overall results of this paper. Indeed, this key measure of the first global excess liquidity
regime explains the trend in asset prices in the desired direction in almost two thirds of cases.
The global money supply M2 is the measure of the second global excess liquidity regime and
explains the trend in asset prices in the desired direction in more than four out of ten cases,
while it is only in about one third of cases for the global aggregate of domestic credit. Country
by country, the Brazilian, Russian and Indian assets have been the most impacted by the
global excess liquidity, whatever the regime. For China, the growth of domestic credit and
M2 money supply reflects the excessive monetisation of the financial system and the
indebtedness promoted by the Chinese authorities, notably to control their currency. The
results for South Africa are less eloquent. Last but not least, according to our robustness
checks, the results are broadly weakly sensitive to some economic and econometric changes.
(i) Calculate weights ߱௧ based on the relative share of the country on monetary union ݅
as regards the variable ܻ (݆ ൌ ʹܯǡ ݐ݅݀݁ݎܥܿ݅ݐݏ݁݉ܦǡ )ݏ݁ݒݎ݁ݏܴ݁݊݃݅݁ݎܨat time ݐ,
in a common currency, e.g., in USD in this study:
ܻ௧ (6)
߱௧ ൌ
σଽୀଵ ܻ௧
(ii) Calculate within country or monetary union growth rates ܺ of each variable ܼ (where
ೕ
ܼ ൌ σ ) at time ݐ, in local currency:
ೖసషయ ீೖ
(iv) Cumulate aggregate growth rates to obtain aggregate levels. We use the Q1 1998 as
the base to anchor the aggregate measures over time:
ܻ௧ ൌ ܻ௧ିଵ ൫ͳ തܺ
തതఫ௧
തത൯ (9)
FX Reserves ++ ++ ++ ++ +
M2 +
MSCI BRIC Credit
FX Reserves ++
M2 - + - -- +
10Y Interest Credit - - -
Fixed Income
Rate
FX Reserves - -- - -- --
M2 -- -- 0 0 --
EMBI Global Credit - 0
Spread
FX Reserves -- + 0 0 -
M2 - + +
Exchange Rate
Exchange Rate
FX Reserves ++
M2 --
Brent Credit
FX Reserves ++
Tests
Hadri LLC IPS ADF Fisher PP Fisher
Variables
7.02*** -0.53 -0.97 15.21 16.02*
MSCI
(-0.62) (-17.28***) (-14.84***) (172.30***) (172.04***)
10Y Interest 9.24*** -1.02 -2.67*** 23.96*** 38.62***
Rate (1.76*) (-8.29***) (-11.18***) (123.49***) (106.23***)
EMBI Global 6.00*** -0.83 -1.63* 18.27* 12.66
Spread (-1.15) (-15.95***) (-13.09***) (148.99***) (129.20***)
Exchange Rate 3.45*** -1.67** -3.42** 64.07*** 45.35***
vs. USD (1.80*) (-10.76***) (-10.14***) (109.48***) (107.21***)
8.03*** 0.64 -0.31 11.03 13.20
REER
(0.14) (-14.66***) (-15.31***) (179.21***) (178.32***)
11.61*** -1.76* -0.15 6.89 4.07
GSCI
(-1.29) (-15.72***) (-12.67***) (144.85***) (102.95***)
11.97*** -2.33** -0.69 9.30 5.55
Brent
(0.57) (-14.91***) (-12.97***) (149.07***) (125.26***)
12.98*** -1.04 0.77 6.89 2.81
Real GDP
(-0.62) (-13.47***) (-12.99***) (148.82***) (182.55***)
1.51** -2.10** -1.80** 16.06* 15.98
VIX
(-1.30) (-20.77***) (-17.94***) (214.88***) (230.05***)
12.68*** 1.00 3.87 0.47 0.20
M2 Aggregate
(-0.81) (-1.88**) (-4.26***) (36.15***) (40.19***)
Dom. Credit 12.40*** 0.12 2.75 1.11 1.95
Aggregate (-1.04) (-7.34***) (-8.57***) (86.48***) (92.10***)
FX Reserves 11.76*** -2.31** -1.00 11.25 6.78
Aggregate (3.52) (-6.61***) (-9.71***) (101.67***) (102.00***)
Adrian, T. and H. S. Shin, 2008, “Liquidity, Monetary Policy and Financial Cycles,”
Current Issues in Economics and Finance, Federal Reserve Bank of New-York, Vol. 14(1),
pp. 1-7, February.
Alessi, L. and C. Detken, 2011, “Quasi real time early warning indicators for costly
asset price boom/bust cycles: A role for global liquidity,” European Journal of Political
Economy, Elsevier, Vol. 27(3), pp. 520-533, September.
Artus, P. and M. P. Virard, 2010, “La liquidité incontrôlable : Qui va maîtriser la
monnaie mondiale,” Edition Pearson, February.
Azis, I. J. and H. S. Shin, 2014, “Managing Elevated Risk: Global Liquidity, Capital
Flows, and Macroprudential Policy–An Asian Perspective,” Asian Development Bank and
Springer Ed., December.
Baks, K. and C. Kramer, 1999, “Global Liquidity and Asset Prices: Measurement,
Implications, and Spillovers,” IMF Working Paper No. 99/168, International Monetary Fund,
December.
Belke, A., I. G. Bordon and T. W. Hendricks, 2010a, “Global Liquidity and
Commodity Prices - A Cointegrated VAR Approach for OECD Countries,” Applied Financial
Economics, Taylor & Francis Journals, Vol. 20(3), pp. 227-242, February.
Belke, A., W. Orth and R. Setzer, 2010b, “Liquidity and the Dynamic Pattern of Asset
Price Adjustment: A Global View,” Journal of Banking and Finance, Elsevier, Vol. 34(8), pp.
1933-1945, August.
Belke, A., I. G. Bordon and U. Volz, 2013, “Effects of Global Liquidity on
Commodity and Food Prices,” World Development, Elsevier, Vol. 44(C), pp. 31-43, April.
Beyer, A., J. A. Doornik and D. F. Hendry, 2001, “Constructing Historical Euro-Zone
Data,” Economic Journal, Royal Economic Society, Vol. 111(469), pp. 2-21, February.
Brana, S., M. L. Djigbenou and S. Prat, 2012, “Global excess liquidity and asset prices
in emerging countries: A PVAR approach,” Emerging Markets Review, Elsevier, Vol. 13(3),
pp. 256-267, September.
Brunnermeier, M. K. and L. H. Pedersen, 2009, “Market Liquidity and Funding
Liquidity,” Review of Financial Studies, Society for Financial Studies, Vol. 22(6), pp. 2201-
2238, June.
Chatterjee, U. and Y. Kim, 2010, “Monetary Liquidity, Market Liquidity, and
Financial Intermediation,” Asia-Pacific Journal of Financial Studies, Fifth Annual
Conference on Asia-Pacific Financial Markets, August.
Committee on the Global Financial System (CGFS), 2011, “Global Liquidity -
Concept, Measurement and Policy Implications,” CGFS Papers No. 45, Bank for International
Settlements, November.
April 2015
Another argument that has been frequently put forward is the "original sin". This expression refers to a situation
in which countries need to resort to short-term maturity external debt. In fact, the detention of external debt ties the
hands of the emerging countries’ governments which have to back money creation on foreign currency reserves if they
want to maintain a peg on their exchange rate (or at least some currency stability). If, by contrast, money depreciates,
an asymmetry appears between interest expenditure (essentially in foreign currency) and revenues (in local currency).
This "currency mismatch" explains the importance of exports’ revenues for emerging markets.
However, since the mid 2000s, the hypothesis of a "debt trap" as a consequence of past defaults seems to be
undermined by the historical facts. Indeed, it seems that the share of the emerging countries’ domestic debt over
GDP has slightly increased in the last decade, linked to a better managed debt and their willingness to hedge against
capital flows sudden stops (Mehl and Reynaud, 2005, [10]). Lower inflation and healthier fiscal and monetary policies
(becoming more countercyclical) have helped following this trend (Mohanty, 2012, [9]). Moreover a new risk manage-
ment strategy, taking into account the liquidity inflows from investors (willing to diversify their portfolios by buying
emerging countries’ local debt) have enhanced their financial stability and their integration into the world financial
markets (Blommestein and Santiso, 2007, [4]). On the whole, these changes should have reduced their exposition to
currency risk and lowered rollover risk.
Now, the general conclusions in terms of a typical default behavior must be nuanced, even if we consider the epi-
sodes of defaults since the 1980s. In this paper, we support the idea that, in line with the emerging countries’ diversity,
the origins of the important defaults on sovereign debt have been very heterogeneous across the emerging countries
and over time. Thus, we overcome a drawback of the existing empirical literature by permitting some heterogeneity
in the slope parameters of a model that relates sovereign debt default to several determinants. This allows taking
a step forward with respect to the existing studies by proposing early warning indicators specific to each country,
in spite of the fact that the forewarning indicator is based on panel data. We are able to see which macroeconomic
and financial variables explain the weight of sovereign default, depending on the country’s economic features. And
for the variables that matter, we show that their impact on sovereign default quantitatively differs across countries
and through time. The sources of heterogeneity come from the fact that the variables causing debt default follow
regime-switching dynamics that characterize different degrees of vulnerability. These different vulnerability levels are
defined inherently by threshold values estimated for some highlighted variables.
Moreover, we choose to look beyond the probability of default and consider the amount of default. In fact, we
think that the occurrence of a default isn’t in itself the sole important aspect, as the non-payment of a tiny or of a
large part of one’s debt or debt service commitments are not equivalent at all, notably in terms of market impacts.
This is the reason why we focus, not on the incidence of a default, but on its heaviness compared to the country’s GDP.
More precisely, our contribution to the literature is threefold : i) we use a new database from the Bank of Canada
(2014, [3]) that reports information on outstanding amounts of their debt being in default by countries between 1975
and 2013. We work on the amount of sovereign default for 50 frontier and emerging countries, as of 1980 ; ii) our
empirical analysis is based on a nonlinear panel data model that allows for regime-switching dynamics and hetero-
geneous effects of the determinants on sovereign debt being in default ; iii) we highlight four variables that are able
to determine distinct vulnerability regimes and provide evidence that the variables influencing the amount of debt
default vary across these regimes.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the empirical framework (data and model).
In Section 3 we comment our main results. Finally Section 4 concludes the paper.
Sovereign default data (yit in our regressions) stems from a dataset built by D.T. Beers and J.-S. Nadeau from
the Bank of Canada (2014, [3]). In this database, the authors do not only reference episodes of sovereign default from
1975 to 2013 worldwide (merging data previously published by the Paris Club, the IMF, the World Bank and other
institutions), but also report the amount of debt concerned by the non-payment for each episode of sovereign default,
distinguishing between different types of creditors 4 . They consider "that a default has occurred when debt service is
not paid on the due date (or within a specified grace period), payments are not made within the time frame specified
under a guarantee, or, absent an outright payment default, in [...] circumstances where creditors incur material eco-
nomic losses on the sovereign debt they hold" (including agreements reducing interest rates or extending maturities
on outstanding debt and government exchange offers where existing debt is swapped or re-denominated, leading to
the detention of new debt or equity on less-economic terms). Our aim is to analyse the determinants of the amount of
debt in default using this data (as a share of the country’s GDP), highlighting the existence of different vulnerability
regimes regarding default risk, depending on the country’s economic characteristics.
The variables we make use of to explain the amount of sovereign default and determine the vulnerability regimes are
similar to those used in the literature, which essentially focuses on the linear explanation of default events (whatever
their significance as regards the country’s activity). They consist of :
– capital and current account variables (yearly change in the terms of trade and in the exchange rate, and portfolio
equity flows as a share of GDP) from the World Bank ;
– economic variables (real GDP growth, inflation, gross domestic savings as a share of GDP, total reserves on
short-term external debt, external debt on exports, external debt as a share of general government debt, general
government debt, public balance, interest expenditure as a share of public revenues) from the IMF, the World
Bank and Oxford Economics ;
– institutional variables (World Global Indicators from the World Bank and Corruption perception index from
Transparency International) ;
– financial variables (spreads versus the United States as regards treasury bill interest rates, blended spread
component of the Emerging Market Bond Index, overnight interbank rates, lending minus deposit rates and
Standard & Poor’s ratings) from various sources, even if their availability is not so obvious for some of the
considered countries.
For more details regarding the sources of the data, see Appendix 1, Tables A.2 to A.6.
Note : The reported percentage corresponds to the mean of the amount of debt being in default (as a % of GDP), for
each geographic area. See Table A.1, in Annex, for the repartition of the countries into geographic areas.
In fact, if one looks at the economic characteristics of the countries when they face default and when they do not, it
can be observed that there really is a difference. Table 1 shows that, compared to a country whose situation is sound,
a country being in default is more likely to have a deteriorated economic environment (local currency depreciating
hugely, low equity net inflows, low growth and high inflation), less healthy public finances (high debt burden, high
general government debt), a more fragile financing basis (low domestic savings, high share of external public debt,
less foreign reserves compared to short-term financial commitments), a more stressed financial environment (higher
interest rates) and institutions of lower quality (lower WGI and CPI indicators). This observation strengthens our
belief that a model allowing for heterogeneity can be a good framework to highlight the explanatory factors of the
potential amount of debt being in default.
No default Default
Mean N Mean N
Current Terms of trade (YoY % Change) 0,4 801 0,5 388
account Exchange Rate (YoY % Change) 6,4 982 68,9 450
variables Portfolio Equity Net Inflows (% of GDP) 0,8 673 0,4 219
Real GDP growth (YoY % Change) 4,4 1078 3,0 497
Intern Inflation (YoY % Change) 10,2 1064 110,5 497
economic Central government interest payments (% of general government revenues) 13,3 708 23,3 210
variables General government debt 45,3 711 53,8 173
General government balance -1,9 979 -2,9 343
Domestic Savings (% of GDP) 26,3 1010 19,9 463
External Reserves (% of total short-term external debt) 301,1 671 280,7 445
debt External debt (% of Exports) 126,7 864 231,0 382
variables Share of external debt in General Government debt 40,2 467 47,9 73
Corruption perception Index 45,5 659 28,5 183
Institutionnal WGI Rule of Law 0,3 705 -0,5 195
variables WGI Government Effectiveness 0,3 705 -0,3 195
WGI Control of Corruption 0,2 705 -0,6 195
EMBI 366,3 659 644,7 158
Financial Interbank rate (overnight) 5,2 312 15,0 52
variables S&P Rating 14,3 871 10,3 329
Lending minus deposit rate 7,0 768 24,9 390
Sovereign interest rate spreads (3Months, vs US) 6,0 556 15,8 196
Note : Data stretches from 1980 to 2013, depending on availability for each variable and each country. Means (for the
available observations whose number is mentionned in column N) are computed in two sub-samples : countries not being in
default and countries whose amount of debt being in default is strictly positive. For S&P rating data, notations have been
rescaled, AAA (resp. D) rating being equivalent to 22 (resp. 0). For more details regarding the data, see Tables in Appendix
A.1.
Sovereign risk is often evaluated using vulnerability indicators based on economic fundamentals. These models are
employed to explain the occurrence of extreme events (debt restructuring, sovereign default, late payments episodes,
stress episodes in terms of exchange rate or inflation, banking crises). See, for instance, Reinhart, Goldstein and Ka-
minsky, (2000, [12]).
Many predictors of sovereign default take the form of a z-score (Baldacci, Mc Hugh and Petrova, 2011, [2], Ra-
bobank, 2011, [11]). Early-warning indicators are then resulting from the link done between such indicators and the
occurrence of default events. These warnings trigger once some thresholds are exceeded : that is why they are called
"signals approach". The choice of the threshold (which can for example be based on the minimisation of some "wrong
warnings") favors either predicting more crises correctly (at the expense of more noise) or being less frequently wrong.
Nevertheless, as underlined by Andréou, Dufrénot and alii. (2009, [1]) as regards financial crises, noise due to an
early warning indicator which would trigger more easily is not necessary a bad thing, as it can highlight a very de-
teriorated economic situation (which is an interesting information in itself), even if default does not occur immediately.
Another common way to describe the determinants of sovereign default is to estimate a default probability through
a binary model (logit or probit), with similar explanatory variables as the ones used for early warning indicators
(i.e. macroeconomic variables, fiscal variables, financial variables and institutional variables). Manasse, Roubini and
Schimmelpfennig (2003, [8]), as Cohen and Valladier (2011, [5]) estimate the default probability (including important
IMF supports for the former, and also Paris Club supports and other punctual events regarding debt servicing and
payment arrears for the latter) with a logit model. Cohen and Valladier (2011, [5]) then classify the countries with
respect to the quintile they belong to, in order to differentiate them by risk level. Kraay and Nehru (2004, [7]) resort
to a probit model to highlight the determinants of events relative to payment arrears as regards external debt, Club
de Paris debt rescheduling and non conventional IMF loans.
To the best of our knowledge, the literature seems to have focused until now on models or indicators describing the
origins (economic and financial, but also political and institutional ones) of the occurrence of sovereign defaults (taking
various forms). Most frequently, the developed models are linear, as they assume that all the observations present the
same sensibilities to the explanative variables to explain this default occurence. Finally, they usually derive different
degrees of vulnerability from the distribution of the indicator. We attempt to enrich the existing models by working
with a model that allows for heterogeneity in the response to explanative variables to explain this amount of default.
Moreover, our model enables us to directly identify the different vulnerability regimes, as the thresholds dividing in
different regimes are estimated endogenously, and thus, are inherent to the model.
We consider the panel smooth transition regression model (PSTR proposed by Gonzalez, Teräsvirta, van Dijk, 2005,
[6], henceforth GTD) 5 . It enables us to estimate, for various emerging market countries, the heterogeneous effects on
the amount of debt being in default of the explanatory variables (presented herebefore). The heterogeneous effects,
across time and countries come from threshold variables defining different regimes of vulnerability to sovereign default.
where i = 1, ..., N , t = 1, ..., T , μi corresponds to the country fixed effects, r is the number of transition functions gj
(j)
defined by the threshold variables qit (for j ≤ r) ; cj are the corresponding thresholds, γj are the parameters defining
the degree of smoothness of the transition from one regime to another and uit the error term.
(j) 1
gj (qit ; γj , cj ) = m (j)
(2)
1 + exp(−γj k=1 (qit − cjk ))
with γj > 0, and cj1 < cj2 < .. < cjm the thresholds associated to the transition function gj . m is the number
of returns between the two extreme regimes associated to this transition function, these returns taking place at the
thresholds cj1 , cj2 , .., cjm . In the extreme regimes associated to each transition function, the vectors of parameters take
the values β0 and β0 + βj .
In Equation (1) two important parameters are m and r. m describes the shape of the transition function gj . For
m = 1, the shape is that of a standard logistic function. For m = 2, the transition function is described by a "V curve"
with a middle regime and two identical outer regimes. For m > 2, the transition function has a more complex shape.
5. The estimations were done using the MATLAB code provided by Christophe Hurlin.
Step 1
We test the null assumption of a linear model against a PSTR model (r = 0 against r = 1). This is equivalent to
testing the null assumption of homogeneous effects against heterogeneous effects across countries and years. We test
H0 : γ = 0 or H0 : β1 = 0 against H1 : γ = 0 or H1 : β1 = 0
To overcome the problem of nuisance parameter (β1 is unidentified under H0 and γ is unidentified under H0 ), we
consider the following auxiliary regression, resulting from the first-order Taylor expansion around γ = 0 of Equation
(1) (for r=1) :
m
j
yit = μi + βj∗ xit qit + u∗it (3)
j=0
Step 2
For a given r, we estimate the PSTR model. This is done by applying a non linear least squares estimator after
appropriately subtracting the individual means from the variables in the model (see GTD for details). First, we consi-
der some initial values for the slope parameter γj and the threshold values cj 6 . Next we estimate the slopes β of the
model conditional to these values, by ordinary least squares. Then, we go on iteratively, finding new values for γj and
cj through non linear least squares optimization and then re-estimating the slopes.
3 Results
3.1 Results based on individual variables
We begin applying the PSTR model by showing that several macroeconomic and financial variables are potential
candidates that can explain time-varying and cross section differences in the impact of vulnerability factors on the
amount of potential debt default.
To begin with, we estimate Equation (1) for m = 1 and m = 2 with qit (the threshold variable) being the different
explanatory variables that are potential candidates to explain the amount of the sovereign default. We run as many
regressions as potential candidate variables for qit . For each of them, xit is a vector of qit and a dummy variable
describing past default 7 .
The estimated equation is
Debt in default (% of GDP) = μi + β0 xit + β1 xit g(qit ; γ, cj ) + uit (4)
The results of the tests are shown in Table 2. We also report the p-value corresponding to the Fisher statistic of
the test H0 : r = i against H1 : r = i + 1 focusing on the number of transition functions (see Table 2, columns 4 to
7) 8 . The idea is then to select the regressions accepted with the highest p-value, in order to identify the variables that
could be relevant for splitting observations into regimes differing in the effects of explanatory variables (among which
past default) on the amount of sovereign debt in default.
Then, for the best models, we report the PSTR estimations when the explanatory variables are considered indivi-
dually. The results are shown for m = 1 and for m = 2 (in Table 3). Over the 21 variables originally considered, we
present the results of the estimations making sense (i.e. where there is convergence of the parameter’s estimation and
6. We use the method proposed by GTD, to determine the initial values. It consists in computing the concentrated sum of squared
residuals for a "grid" of possible values for γ and c, finally taking as initial values for the NLS estimation those minimising this target.
7. This dummy equals 1 if sovereign default has occurred within the last 5 years, and 0 otherwise.
8. For m=1 (resp. m=2) we go on until rmax = 3 (resp. rmax = 2).
Note : For each threshold variable tested, the estimation is done for m=1 and m=2 (respectively constraining to rmax = 3
and rmax = 2), and the countries whose required information was available less than 3 years were not taken into account.
The number of observations included is mentionned in column 3. For each threshold variable, we test H0 : r = i against
H1 : r = i + 1 until the p-value of the Fisher Statistic (presented in columns 4, 5, 6 and 7) is superior to α. α is set to 0.05 for
r=0 and divided by 2 at each new iteration, to favour parcimony (doing this, we follow a method suggested by the authors of
GTD). The bold p-values correspond to the estimations the more likely accepted. Moreover, it is worth mentionning that the
estimations do not converge for the following threshold variables : Equity net inflows (m=2), General goverment debt (m=1),
EMBI (m=1), and Spreads (m=2). The results are therefore not presented for these estimations.
The dummy variable capturing past defaults within the recent five years appears to be statistically significant in
almost all regressions. Thus, a country which defaulted in the past is likely to be confronted to a sovereign default
today. However, a default is of particularly high significance, only if the country faces a macroeconomic and financial
environment that becomes more risky. Whether or not the country is more sensitive to past default depends upon
some threshold values taken by the variables in the transition function.
The first column of Table 3 contains the transition variables qit , the second column reports the selected value for
r, columns 3 and 4 show the estimated values of the slope γj of the transition function and of the threshold value cj
for the associated transition variables. In column 6, we write the exogenous variable considered in the left-hand side of
the estimated equation. Columns 7 and 11 show the estimated values of the coefficients in the extreme regimes, while
columns 8 and 12 respectively report the p-value of the estimates to see whether they are statistically significant. In
the last column, we report the share of observations in the first regime 9 (the share of observations in the second regime
is 100 minus the percentage reported for the first regime). The estimates in Table 3 lead to the following conclusions.
Table 3 – First PSTR estimations - Estimations results for m=1 and m=2
Note : Here, we only report the results of the estimations of Table 2 that make sense, i.e. where there is convergence of the parameter’s estimation and where each regime contains enough
observations. For each estimation presented, the number of observations is reported on column 13, the number of transition functions on column 2, the shape γ of the transition function
in column 3 (smooth if γ → 0, abrupt if γ → ∞), the transition thresholds c in column 4 and the number of iterations needed to estimated this parameters in column 5. The slopes
of each explanatory variable are reported on columns 7, 9 and 11 (with the corresponding p-values in columns 8, 10 and 12). βi is the slope corresponding to the explanative variable
xit = (dummy; qit ). For m=1, the observations for which the threshold variable is inferior to the threshold c (whose part in the sample is reported on column 14) are broadly characterized by
the slope β0 , and others by the slope β0 + β1 (slopes corresponding to the extreme observations). For m=2, c is of dimension 2. In this case, the observations for which the threshold variable
189
Countries that are likely to be confronted to a current sovereign default of a higher amount are those which already
defaulted at least once during the 5 preceding years and whose macroeconomic environment is more fragile, i.e. with
the following characteristics (for m=1) :
– a huge depreciation of their currency by more than 43% (changes measured on a year-on-year basis) ;
– a deep recession with a real GDP growth below -3.4% ;
– a fiscal deficit higher than 10.4% ;
– a ratio of debt service over fiscal revenues above 11.3% ;
– a high exchange rate risk (measured by total international reserves as share of total short-term debt below 97%) ;
– a high currency mismatch (with total external debt accounting for more than 337% of total exports) ;
– the external debt representing more than 59% of the sovereign debt ;
– increased short-term interest rate spreads (63.3% above the US three-months rate).
When we consider the estimates with m = 2 (Table 3), three additional variables are able to discriminate into
significantly different regimes : the terms of trade, inflation and interbank rates 10 . Table 3 provides evidence that a
country that was confronted to a default during the past five years is likely to increase the current amount of debt in
default even more if it faces adverse conditions characterized by :
– extreme change in the terms of trade (with either a decrease by more than 5.9% or an increase by more than
6.7%) ;
– extreme inflation conditions (a year on year change of less than -0.3% or above 29%). This finding leads us
to nuance Reinhart and Rogoff’s argument according to which inflation and past default are causes of "serial
defaults" in the emerging countries. Here, past defaults seem to importantly increase the potential of a current
sovereign default, especially if a country experiences a situation of deflation or hyperinflation. Inflation pressures
within a range of moderate inflation rates are a "pushing" factor to a new default, but only to a lesser extent.
It can be seen that, in our sample, only 3% of the observations are in the deflation regime 11 , which means that
hyperinflation is what really matters ;
– low or high interbank rate (below 0.9% or above 8%).
After having confirmed that a PSTR provides a consistent model allowing for heterogeneity in the explanation of the
amount of potential sovereign default, we focus on determining which variables are able to discriminate observations
into distinct vulnerability regimes, in a more comprehensive framework. We therefore consider a combination of
different explanatory variables (instead of determinants taken individually). This gives a better picture of the key
factors that influence the amount of debt default.
Table 4 shows the results of the tests for these four threshold variables, while Table 5 contains our main regressions.
We now comment the main conclusions from Table 5.
10. We do not consider the regressions for which the identification of regimes was meaningless (for example because the estimated
thresholds were very close), because this implied a situation with very few observations in one regime (for example exchange rate, domestic
savings and EMBI). We also neglect the regressions for which the estimated values of γ was small so that they behave like linear homogenous
models (for example, S&P rating)
11. which is characterized by an annual inflation rate inferior to -0.3%.
Note : For each threshold variable tested, the estimation is done for m=1 (constraining to rmax = 3), and the coun-
tries whose required information was available less than 3 years were not taken into account. The number of observations
included is mentionned in column 3. For each threshold variable, we test H0 : r = i against H1 : r = i + 1 until the p-value of
the Fisher Statistic (presented in columns 4, 5, 6 and 7) is superior to α. α is set to 0.05 for r=0 and divided by 2 at each
new iteration, to favour parcimony (doing this, we follow a method suggested by the authors of GTD). The bold p-values
correspond to the estimations the more likely accepted.
The model distinguishes between three regimes : one is characterized by a low level of debt service (which amounts
for less than 9% of fiscal revenues), a regime of high level of debt service (where the latter weighs more than 14%
of fiscal revenues), and an intermediate regime. We indicate below the explanatory variables that seem to be key
determinants of the amount of debt default within each regime :
47% of the observations are located in the low debt burden regime. In this regime, the following factors yields an
increase in the amount of potential sovereign default : a nominal appreciation of the domestic currency, an increase
in inflation, in public debt and in the ratio of external debt as share of total exports, a poor S&P rating. 35% of the
observations are located in the high debt burden regime and there, public debt is the main driver of higher default.
In the intermediate regime (18% of the observations), public debt and the exchange rate are the main determinants
of sovereign default (with for the former an influence that is lower compared to the low debt burden regime). For
the observations in this regime, a currency depreciation induces a currency mismatch which makes it more likely to
default importantly. It is no longer the case once debt service on public revenues is inferior to a certain threshold (in
regime 0). Finally, it is seen from the table above that the number of determinants that significantly affect the amount
of debt decreases as we go from the low to the high debt burden regimes. This illustrates the fact that, when debt
service is under control, the determinants of debt default are clearly identified. This is not the case when debt service
becomes too heavy.
Along the domestic savings’ axis, the three vulnerability regimes and the key determinants of debt default in each
regime can be represented as follows :
44% of the observations in the estimation sample are located in the low savings ratio regime, characterised by a
domestic savings ratio lower than 22% of GDP. In this regime, having a weak S&P rating is the key determinant of
the amount of debt default. 46% of the observations belong to the high savings ratio regime (when the saving ratio is
above 25%) where the following variables are found to rise the amount of sovereign default : a high inflation and debt
ratio, a low external debt over exports ratio, a bad S&P rating. Interestingly, we also find that a country that did
default during the preceding five years tends to decrease its current amount of debt in default. This could illustrate a
"learning process", which goes against the "serial default" view : when they are able to (i.e. when their domestic savings
are high enough), countries having recently defaulted are less inclined to default again because they learn from their
errors. We obtain a similar conclusion for the intermediate regime. Finally, we also see that external debt tends to
increase the amount of potential default when domestic savings are intermediate, but do not anymore once domestic
Regime 0 Regime 1
Reserves lower than 79% of Reserves higher than 79% of
STED STED
Inflation (+)
Public debt (++) Public debt (+)
S&P rating (-)
Here we have two regimes. 12% of the observations are assigned into the regime 0 when the reserve ratio falls below
79%. In this regime, we identify a high debt ratio and a weak S&P rating as the main factors of higher sovereign
default. 88% of the observations lie in the regime 1 (when the international reserves account for more than 79% of
total exports) in which a high inflation rate and public debt ratio are found to increase sovereign debt.
The observations switch between three regimes. A large majority (91%) are classified into a regime in which
the external debt ratio remains below 258%, while a minority (3%) are in the extreme regime characterized by the
highest external debt vulnerability with a ratio jumping above 385%. The remainder 6% are located in an in-between
regime (external debt ratio between 258% and 385%). Comparing the two extreme regimes, the estimates suggest that
more variables matter to impact sovereign default when external debt is high compared to total exports. Specifically, a
currency depreciation, higher inflation and public debt ratio, a poor S&P rating and past defaults during the preceding
five years, all concur to increase the weight of sovereign debt default when external debt ratio exceeds 385%. In the
low external debt regime, only inflation and public debt ratio are key determinants of default (to a lesser extent than
in the other extreme regime).
Figures A.1 to A.4 in Appendix 2 show, for each country, the dynamics of the vulnerability regimes for the four
vulnerability axes presented above. Different numbers (from 0 to 2) 12 and colours (green, orange and red) are used to
signal whether a given year a country was situated in an priori low, medium or high vulnerability regime according to
the vulnerability axes highlighted in the previous section. For each of the four threshold variables, the threshold values
estimated above define the regimes in which each observation can be classified. Here, we consider that a country is "a
priori" more vulnerable (in red) if debt burden (as a share of public revenue) is higher, domestic savings (as a share
of GDP) are lower, international reserves (as a share of short-term external debt) are lower and external debt (as a
12. corresponding to the regime numbers mentioned in Tables 6 to 9.
Considering debt service, it seems that, since 2000, the countries have succeeded in hedging themselves against
states where sovereign debt is less under control (in the sense that the determinants of sovereign default are less iden-
tified). However, there remains some differences in trajectories, with some countries now completely insulated from
high debt burden (for example Chile and Morocco), while others are still in a debt spiral (for instance, Egypt, India
and Israel).
Turning to domestic savings, Figure A.2 strongly suggests that the vulnerability regimes are "absorptive" in the
sense that rarely does a country move durably from a regime to another. Therefore, if a country is highly vulnerable
in terms of having a too low saving rate, it remains stuck to this situation and moves to a less vulnerable situation
very slowly.
Concerning external debt and international reserves, it is seen that only a few countries experience a situation of
high vulnerability that does not improve over the years (for instance, Argentina, Lebanon, Pakistan).
3. Asia 4. Africa
Note : For a given variable, the smaller the surface, the higher the degree of a priori vulnerability in terms of that va-
riable. A country is considered to be a priori more vulnerable if debt burden (as a share of public revenue) is higher, domestic
savings (as a share of GDP) are lower, international reserves (as a share of short-term external debt) are lower and external
debt (as a share of exports) is higher. They are classified on a scale of a priori vulnerability (0 to 2) according to their location
based on the estimated threshold values.
Next, we consider cross-country heterogeneity. Figure 2 portrays the multidimensional aspect of countries’ vulne-
rability, by selecting for purpose of illustration some countries in different geographical areas. For a given variable, the
smaller the surface, the higher the degree of a priori vulnerability in terms of that variable (as defined above). The
countries are classified on a scale of a priori vulnerability (0 to 2) according to their location based on the estimated
threshold values 13 . A graph could be made for each year, but we show here a figure based on the last year of available
observation.
It is noteworthy that, in terms of vulnerability, countries located in the same geographical area do not necessarily
share the same characteristics. For instance, Russia, Hungary and China are not in any of the a priori vulnerability
13. For interest payments and external debt, the values of the regimes have been inversed for this example, so as to have a regime 0
corresponding to the a priori most vulnerable regime and a regime 2 to the a priori less vulnerable one, for each of the four variables of
interest.
These results go in the direction of Reinhart and Rogoff (2013, [14]), who argue that we can’t consider developed
countries to be completely different from emerging ones anymore. In fact, more than the broad classifications that
are currently used ("developed" countries versus "emerging" ones), these vulnerability profiles and the classification
of countries into them shows that what really matters are the economic features of the countries to identify the
determinants of the potential default the country is exposed to.
4 Conclusion
In this article, we contribute to the literature according to three aspects. First, we focus, not only on the occur-
rence, but also on the amount of sovereign debt being in default, relative to the country’s GDP. Second, our empirical
analysis is based on a nonlinear panel data model that allows regime-switching dynamics and heterogeneous effects of
the determinants on sovereign debt being in default, whereas the literature essentially assumes homogeneous effects of
the determinants of sovereign default. Finally, we manage to highlight four variables that are able to determine distinct
vulnerability regimes and provide evidence that the variables influencing the amount of debt default vary across these
regimes.
It appears that, taken together, debt service over fiscal revenues, domestic savings, international reserves on short-
term external debt, and external debt on exports give an accurate insight on the emerging country’s determinants
of sovereign default. These lines of approach allow i) to see if some emerging countries, reinforcing their economic
fundamentals, have succeeded in moving from one regime to another through time, therefore evolving in their behavior
in terms of potential default ; ii) to gather countries together according to their similar profile in terms of sensibilities
to specific economic variables.
Ultimately, this article allows to nuance the conclusions regarding the determinants of sovereign default in emerging
countries. As this "group" of countries precisely stands out through a great diversity, our findings enable to highlight
some subgroup’s specificities. One possible extension to this work could be to investigate further, looking at the reaction
to specific shocks, depending on each group’s features. Some institutional aspects could also be added, as they do not
significantly come out here, also they are one of the important aspects through which emerging countries differ from
developed ones.
199
Note : As some observations were clearly aberrant, we deleted them from the raw data described above. It was for example the
case for observations whose information on GDP growth and GDP was not consistent, and for those where public balance (%
200
Item Source Description => Treat- Definition Time period
ment
Sovereign Bank of Canada Million US$ Estimates of stocks of government obliga- 1980-2013 except for MU (85-13), MC, NG,
debt in de- (David T. Beers and tions in default, including bonds and other CO, EY, KN, LB, PE, TU, UY, VI (88-
fault Jean-Sébastien marketable securities, bank loans, and offi- 13), PO (89-13), TN (13). No default on
Nadeau) cial loans in default, valued in U.S. dollars, this period for CH, CZ, EO, HK, HN, IS,
for the years 1980 to 2013. KO, LN, MY, QA, SP, SI, SX, TW, UA.
International World Bank, Interna- Total reserves (includes Total reserves comprise holdings of mone- 1980-2013 except for CL, NG, VE, UY (80-
reserves tional Debt Statistics gold), Current Prices, tary gold, special drawing rights, reserves 11), CH (82-13), PO (86-08), LN (92-11),
millions USD => % of of IMF members held by the IMF, and hol- BL, UR (92-13), CT (93-08), LV, RS (93-
STED dings of foreign exchange under the control 11), EO, CZ (93-13), SX (93-06), SA (94),
of monetary authorities. The gold com- VI (95-13), SI (96-13), HN (00-13), SP (03-
ponent of these reserves is valued at year- 13), IS (06-13). GR, HK, KW, QA, SJ,
end (December 31) London prices. Data TW, UA non available.
are in current U.S. dollars. Aggregation
Method : Sum. Millions USD except for
UA, SJ, SP, SI, QA, KW, IS, HK, GR, CT,
CZ, EO, HN, SX, PO, KO (US $).
Total short- World Bank, World Debt Outstanding, External Short-term external debt is defined as debt 1980-2013 except for CL, UY (80-11), CH,
term external Development Indica- debt stocks, short-term that has an original maturity of one year or HN (82-13), BL (85-13), PO (86-08), VI
debt (STED) tors (DOD), Current Prices, less. Available data permit no distinction (87-13), RS, LN (92-11), UR (92-13), LV
USD between public and private nonguaranteed (93-11), SX (93-06), CT (93-07), SA (94-
short-term debt. 13). GR, QA, SJ, UA,HK, KW non avai-
lable.
Oxford Economics External debt, short-term, 1992-2013 except for KO, TW (80-13), EO,
millions USD CZ (93-13), SI (96-13), SP (03-13), IS (06-
13).
share of external debt in general government debt was higher than 100%.
External Oxford Economics External debt, total, share of 1980-2013 except for CH, BL (81-13), ID
debt (% of exports (83-13), SA (87-13), PK, MC, NG, CO,
Exports) EY, PE, MU, KN, AA, LB, TU, UY, VI
(88-13), PO (89-13), RS (90-13), HN (91-
13), LV, EO, UR (92-13), SX, CZ, LN, CT
(93-13), IS (95-13), SI (96-13), QA, KW
(97-13), UA (99-13), HK (02-13), GR, SP
(03-13). TN, SJ non available.
General go- Oxford Economics External debt, millions USD For all countries except AA,CO,EY, EO, 1980-2013 except for CH (81-13), PO (89-
vernment => % of General Govern- IS, LV, LN, MU, MC, NG, PE, RM, SP, 13), HN (91-13), RS (92-13), CZ (93-13),
Table A.4 – Sources of data : Economic variables relative to default and external debt
external debt ment debt SX, SJ, TU, UR, and UY. SA (94-13), CT (98-13), BL (99-13), SJ
case for observations whose information on reserves on short-term external debt was not consistent, and for those where the
Note : As some observations were clearly aberrant, we deleted them from the raw data described above. It was for example the
Item Source Description => Treat- Definition Time period
ment
Rule of law in- World Bank, World Rule of Law (RL) : capturing perceptions of the 1996-2013. For 1997, 1999 and 2001,
dicator Development Indica- extent to which agents have confidence in and means of the years before and after
tors abide by the rules of society, and in particular the have been taken for each country.
quality of contract enforcement, property rights,
the police, and the courts, as well as the likelihood
of crime and violence.
Government World Bank, World Government Effectiveness (GE) : capturing per- 1996-2013. For 1997, 1999 and 2001,
effectiveness Development Indica- ceptions of the quality of public services, the qua- means of the years before and after
indicator tors lity of the civil service and the degree of its in- have been taken for each country.
dependence from political pressures, the quality
of policy formulation and implementation, and
the credibility of the government’s commitment
to such policies.
Control of World Bank, World Control of Corruption (CC) : capturing percep- 1996-2013. For 1997, 1999 and 2001,
corruption Development Indica- tions of the extent to which public power is exer- means of the years before and after
indicator tors cised for private gain, including both petty and have been taken for each country.
grand forms of corruption, as well as "capture" of
the state by elites and private interests.
Corruption Transparency Missing values have been replaced by linear in- 1995-2013 except for BL, EO, LV,
Perception terpolation when there was a lack of less than 5 MU, EY, MC, PE, TN, UR (98-13),
Index years. CZ, EY, HK, KN, NG, PO, RS, TW
(96-13), IS, RM, UY, VI (97-13),
TU (98-13), CT, LN, SJ (99-13), SX
(00-13), AA, LB, KW, QA, SI, UA
201
202
Item Source Description => Treat- Definition Time period
ment
Emerging JP Morgan JPM EMBI, blended Bond index. CL is given the Latin America EMBI ; CZ, 1994-2013 except for BR, BL, CH, SA, PO
markets bond spreads EO, GR, LV, LN, RM, SX, SJ, the Europe EMBI ; KN, (95-13), CT, MY, TK (97-13), AA, CL,
index (blen- MU, MC, TU, AA, TN the African EMBI ; QA, UA, IS, CB, CZ, EO, GR, KN, LV, LN, MU, MC,
ded spreads) SI, KW the Middle East EMBI ; and IN, KO, TW, TH, PE, RM, RS, SX, SJ, PH, TN, TH, TU
SP, HK the Asia EMBI. (98-13), HN, IS, KW, LB, QA, SI, UA (99-
13), UR (01-13), EY, PK, UY (02-13), ID
(05-13), VI (06-13).
S&P rating Credit rating, average, (0=D Rating on foreign currency long-term debt. Countries 1990-2013
and 22=AAA) which were first rated only after 1990 get a constant ra-
ting before (corresponding to their first rating). AA gets
the rating of TU, TN the rating of KN, UA the rating of
QA, MU the rating of SA.
Interbank Essentially Natio- Interbank overnight 1988-2013 except for SP (88), PH (90), TH
rates nal/Central Banks (91), CB (92-07), CZ (93), MY, PO (94),
CL, HN, PE (96), ID (97), LV (98), IN,
LN (99), RM (00), CH (02), BL (04), HK
(06), CT, TK, EY (07), IS (08). AG, BR,
EO, GR, KN, KO, MU, MX, MC, PK, QA,
RS, SX, SJ, SA, UA, VE, SI, LB, KW, AA,
TU, UY, VI non available.
Lending rate World Bank, World Interest Rates, Lending in- Missing values have been replaced by linear interpolation 1980-2013 except for GR (80-03), MC (80-
Development Indica- terest rate (%) => lending when there was a lack of less than 5 years. 05), PO (80-06), MU (81-13), LB (82-13),
tors rate - deposit rate VE (84-13), CB, ID, PE (86-13), MY (87-
13), HN (89-13), HK (90-13), SJ, BL (91-
13), EO, CT (92-13), LN (93-10), CZ, LV,
MX, SX, UR, VI (93-13), AG, RM, AA
(94-13), RS (95-13), BR (97-13), PK (04-
13), SX (08-13), SJ (09-13), UA (80-84 &
91-01), QA (80-94 & 04-13), TU (80-89).
TW, TK, SI non available.
Deposit rate World Bank, World Interest Rates, Deposit in- Missing values have been replaced by linear interpolation 1980-2013 except for UA (80-84 & 99-01),
Development Indica- terest rate (%) => lending when there was a lack of less than 5 years. TU (80-88), GR (80-05), MC (80-91 & 98-
tors rate - deposit rate 13), SJ (80 -09), MU (81), LB (82), IS (83-
12), VE (84), CB (86), SI (87-08), PE (88),
PO (89-06), HK (90), BL, SJ (91), CT (92),
LN (93-10), SX (93-08), CZ, LV, UR, VI
27
Figure A.1 – Vulnerability regimes - Central government interest payments (% of public revenues)
interest payments of 3,7% and 13,8% of public revenues (see Table 5). Green (respectively red) cells correspond to observations characterized by lower (respectively higher) interest payments
as a share of public revenues."NA" observations are those for which information on interest payments is not available.
203
204
Amundi Investment Strategy Collected Research Papers
Figure A.2 – Vulnerability regimes - Domestic savings (% of GDP)
Note : The table reports the regime to which the observations belong to, for each country and each year. For the "domestic savings" model, the three regimes (0, 1 and 2) are delimited by
domestic savings of 21,7% and 24,6% of GDP (see Table 5). Green (respectively red) cells correspond to observations characterized by higher (respectively lower) domestic savings as a share
of GDP."NA" observations are those for which information on domestic savings is not available.
Amundi Investment Strategy Collected Research Papers
Figure A.3 – Vulnerability regimes - Foreign reserves (% of short-term external debt)
Note : The table reports the regime to which the observations belong to, for each country and each year. For the "foreign reserves" model, the two regimes (0 and 1) are delimited by foreign
reserves of 78,5% of short-term external debt (see Table 5). Green (respectively red) cells correspond to observations characterized by higher (respectively lower) foreign reserves as a share
of short-term external debt."NA" observations are those for which information on foreign reserves is not available.
205
206
Amundi Investment Strategy Collected Research Papers
Figure A.3 – Vulnerability regimes - Foreign reserves (% of short-term external debt)
Note : The table reports the regime to which the observations belong to, for each country and each year. For the "foreign reserves" model, the two regimes (0 and 1) are delimited by foreign
reserves of 78,5% of short-term external debt (see Table 5). Green (respectively red) cells correspond to observations characterized by higher (respectively lower) foreign reserves as a share
of short-term external debt."NA" observations are those for which information on foreign reserves is not available.
Amundi Investment Strategy Collected Research Papers
Figure A.4 – Vulnerability regimes - External debt (% of exports)
Note : The table reports the regime to which the observations belong to, for each country and each year. For the "external debt" model, the three regimes (0, 1 and 2) are delimited by
external debt of 126,8% and 258,3% of exports (see Table 5). Green (respectively red) cells correspond to observations characterized by lower (respectively higher) external debt as a share
of exports."NA" observations are those for which information on external debt is not available.
207
References
[1] I. Andréou, G. Dufrénot, A. Sand-Zantman & A. Zdzienicka-Durand. A forewarning indicator system for financial
crises : the case of six-central and eastern European countries. Journal of economic integration 24, 1 (2009), pp.
87-115, June 2008.
[2] E. Baldacci, J. McHugh & I. Petrova. Measuring Fiscal Vulnerability and Fiscal Stress : A Proposed Set of
Indicators. IMF Working Paper, WP/11/94, April 2011.
[3] D. T. Beers & J-S. Nadeau. Introducing a New Database of Sovereign Defaults. Bank of Canada Technical report
N0.101, February 2014.
[4] H. J. Blommestein & J. Santiso. New strategies for emerging domestic sovereign bond markets. OECD Develop-
ment Centre, Working Paper No.260, April 2007.
[5] D. Cohen & C. Valadier. The Sovereign Debt Crisis that Was Not. Sovereign Debt and the Financial Crisis : Will
This Time Be Different ? (Edited by Carlos A. Primo Braga and Gallina A. Vincelette), Part 1, Chapter 1, 2011.
[6] A. Gonzalez, T. Terasvirta & D.v. Dijk. Panel Smooth Transition Regression Models. Quantitative Finance
Research Centre, Research Paper 165, August 2005.
[7] A. Kraay & V. Nehru. When is external debt sustainable ? World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3200,
February 2004.
[8] P. Manasse, N. Roubini, A. Schimmelpfennig. Predicting Sovereign Crises.IMF Working Paper, WP/03/221,
November 2003.
[9] M. S. Mohanty. Fiscal policy, public debt and monetary policy in EMEs : an overview. Bank of International
Settlements Papers, No 67, October 2012.
[10] A. Mehl & J. Reynaud. The determinants of « domestic »original sin in emerging market economies. European
Central Bank Working Paper Series No.560, December 2005.
[11] Rabobank, Economic Research Department. The Rabo Sovereign Vulnerability Index. Special Report, 2011/07,
April 2011.
[12] C. M. Reinhart, M. Goldstein, G. Kaminsky. Assessing financial vulnerability, an early warning system for emer-
ging markets : Introduction. Munich Personal RePEc Archive Paper No. 13629, 2000.
[13] C. M. Reinhart & K. S. Rogoff. Serial Default and the « Paradox »of Rich-to-Poor Capital Flows. American
Economic Review, 94(2), 53-58, 2004.
[14] C. M. Reinhart, K. S. Rogoff. Financial and Sovereign Debt Crises : Some Lessons Learned and Those Forgotten.
IMF Working Paper, WP/13/266, December 2013.
[15] C. M. Reinhart, K. S. Rogoff & M. A. Savastano. Debt Intolerance. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No.
1 (2003), pp. 1-62, Vol. 2003.
[16] J. D. Sachs. Resolving the Debt Crisis of Low-Income Countries. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 1
(2002), pp. 257-286, Vol. 2002.
March 2015
What was discredited as a plague or even identified as the very symbol for the intoxication of
the financial markets in 2008 and 2009, has recovered remarkably since. The asset- and
mortgage-backed securities in Europe, abbreviated by ABS usually and worth one-and-a-half
trillion euro in all, are back at more reasonable credit spread levels, under 3% on average,
down from 9% in the heat of the financial crisis. Confidence seems restored and excessive
liquidity shortfalls have ceased.
Two major structural reforms are debit to this, as Jeanniard (2011) points out. Firstly the
stakeholders operating on the European ABS markets have changed since the crisis. The bulk
of investors who were refinancing long-term assets with short-term positions and got caught
out by the rupture in market liquidity, have given way to longer-term investors. And secondly
the structure of certain instruments has been simplified making the asset class more
transparent as a result. Certain safety nets embedded in the instruments have been tested for
real, which has sparked the market confidence. With that the sting has been taken out of the
asset class in Europe. This is not necessarily the case in the United States where unresolved
issues remain, in particular in connection with the insolvency position of the nationalized loan
corporations Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. There is no equivalent for this in Europe, instead
mortgage-backed securities bear the credit risk themselves through a pooling-and-tranching
system very much like the American asset-backed instruments..
In this study we look at the European asset- and mortgage-backed securities market and
compare their investment profile with that of Euro Area sovereign bonds. We do this in the
standard mean-variance framework, both in absolute return terms and in a relative
benchmark-enhancement setup. We measure by how much the investment opportunity of a
bond investor is set to expand by including these assets.
Among the European ABS markets we have selected those who are best suited for a mean-
variance analysis. For that matter we have retained the most senior tranches only with an
Table 1 Test bed: nine European ABS indices and four Euro Treasury indices
Index # WAL/duration spread vs swap euro swap yield to maturity
issues in years (a) in bp (b) in bp (c) in bp (d)
EU Auto loans 26 1.0 34 38 72
EU CMBS 18 2.0 198 45 243
EU RMBS 283 5.2 59 102 161
Spanish RMBS 135 6.7 208 143 351
Spanish SME CLO 13 1.7 173 45 218
Italian RMBS 41 3.5 178 81 259
Portuguese RMBS 22 8.2 268 161 429
Dutch RMBS 74 4.0 59 81 140
UK PRMBS 31 1.3 54 38 92
The historical volatility levels of the ABS returns are compared with those of sovereigns in
Exhibit 2. The ones given in the Table have been measured over the entire observation period,
which comprises two crises: the ABS liquidity crisis in 2008-2009 and the euro sovereign
debt crisis that peaked in 2010-2011. The volatility levels were thus higher than they are
nowadays now that both crises have calmed down.
In Exhibit 2 the volatility levels have been measured over a one-year trailing time-window
and are compared over time for three indices: the Spanish RMBS, Spanish Treasuries and
German Treasuries. It can be seen that the Spanish RMBS became twice as volatile over the
first crisis years and that the volatility of Spanish Treasuries sparked over the second crisis
years. The other ABS indices have gone through very much the same orbit as Spanish RMBS,
while among the sovereigns the divide was general between core and peripheral countries.
In the portfolio optimizations we have carried out, we have taken the prudent stance to retain
the relatively high volatility levels measured over the entire observation period as given in
Exhibit 2, as the expected volatilities. By that we incorporate the possibility of a new ABS
crisis into the risk forecasts. Such scenario is conservative compared to the more realistic
situation that the ABS liquidity crisis has faded and is not likely to reoccur.
ote that the asset-backed securities are on the whole less volatile than sovereigns
notwithstanding the two crises, which leads to higher return-to-risk ratios.
II. . o elatio
The return correlations measured over the entire observation period are given in Table 3. ote
that the correlation between the two asset classes, in the off-diagonal blocks, is close to zero.
It means that there is little price influence between ABS and sovereigns, giving much scope
for risk diversification between them. We have verified that the inter-class correlation remains
nil during the two crisis periods. This can be seen in the Appendix where correlation tables
have been measured over two sub-periods, from 2007 to 2009 and from 2010 to 2013.
RM
EC
BS
s
an
BS
BS
RM
SM
se
BS
lo
RM
RM
BS
BS
y
e
ĐŽƌƌĞůĂƚŝŽŶ
M
to
an
gu
ish
sh
CM
RM
ce
n
PR
Au
h
rt u
rm
i
ain
lia
an
an
tc
an
ly
ϮϬϬϳͲϮϬϭϯ
Du
UK
Ge
EU
EU
EU
It a
It a
Po
Sp
Sp
Sp
Fr
EU Auto loans ϭ Ϭ͕ϯϭ Ϭ͕ϰϭ Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕ϰϬ Ϭ͕Ϭϲ Ϭ͕Ϯϭ Ϭ͕ϯϱ Ϭ͕ϯϱ Ϭ͕Ϭϭ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕ϬϮ
EU CMBS Ϭ͕ϯϭ ϭ Ϭ͕ϰϯ Ϭ͕ϯϳ Ϭ͕Ϯϰ Ϭ͕ϭϵ Ϭ͕Ϯϯ Ϭ͕Ϯϵ Ϭ͕ϯϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϭ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ
EU RMBS Ϭ͕ϰϭ Ϭ͕ϰϯ ϭ Ϭ͕ϴϳ Ϭ͕ϰϵ Ϭ͕ϱϴ Ϭ͕ϱϰ Ϭ͕ϲϮ Ϭ͕ϯϳ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕ϭϬ Ϭ͕Ϭϭ
Spanish RMBS Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕ϯϳ Ϭ͕ϴϳ ϭ Ϭ͕ϰϰ Ϭ͕ϯϯ Ϭ͕ϯϭ Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕Ϯϰ Ϭ͕ϭϯ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ Ϭ͕ϭϲ Ϭ͕Ϭϵ
Spanish SME CLO Ϭ͕ϰϬ Ϭ͕Ϯϰ Ϭ͕ϰϵ Ϭ͕ϰϰ ϭ Ϭ͕ϭϱ Ϭ͕Ϯϱ Ϭ͕ϯϭ Ϭ͕Ϯϴ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕Ϭϱ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕ϬϮ
Italian RMBS Ϭ͕Ϭϲ Ϭ͕ϭϵ Ϭ͕ϱϴ Ϭ͕ϯϯ Ϭ͕ϭϱ ϭ Ϭ͕ϰϬ Ϭ͕Ϯϴ Ϭ͕ϭϴ ͲϬ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕Ϭϯ Ϭ͕Ϭϳ ͲϬ͕Ϭϵ
Portuguese RMBS Ϭ͕Ϯϭ Ϭ͕Ϯϯ Ϭ͕ϱϰ Ϭ͕ϯϭ Ϭ͕Ϯϱ Ϭ͕ϰϬ ϭ Ϭ͕Ϯϰ Ϭ͕ϭϵ ͲϬ͕ϭϴ ͲϬ͕ϭϲ ͲϬ͕ϭϭ ͲϬ͕Ϭϴ
Dutch RMBS Ϭ͕ϯϱ Ϭ͕Ϯϵ Ϭ͕ϲϮ Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕ϯϭ Ϭ͕Ϯϴ Ϭ͕Ϯϰ ϭ Ϭ͕ϰϳ Ϭ͕ϬϬ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕ϬϬ
UK PRMBS Ϭ͕ϯϱ Ϭ͕ϯϭ Ϭ͕ϯϳ Ϭ͕Ϯϰ Ϭ͕Ϯϴ Ϭ͕ϭϴ Ϭ͕ϭϵ Ϭ͕ϰϳ ϭ Ϭ͕ϬϬ Ϭ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϳ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ
France Ϭ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕ϭϯ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕ϭϴ Ϭ͕ϬϬ Ϭ͕ϬϬ ϭ Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕ϯϴ Ϭ͕ϴϱ
Spain ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕Ϭϱ ͲϬ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕ϭϲ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕ϯϲ ϭ Ϭ͕ϴϬ Ϭ͕ϭϰ
Italy Ϭ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕ϭϬ Ϭ͕ϭϲ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕Ϭϳ ͲϬ͕ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕Ϭϳ Ϭ͕ϯϴ Ϭ͕ϴϬ ϭ Ϭ͕ϭϬ
Germany Ϭ͕ϬϮ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϵ Ϭ͕ϬϮ ͲϬ͕Ϭϵ ͲϬ͕Ϭϴ Ϭ͕ϬϬ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕ϴϱ Ϭ͕ϭϰ Ϭ͕ϭϬ ϭ
Ϭ͕ϲ
Ϭ͕ϰ
Ϭ͕Ϯ
Ͳ
ͲϬ͕ϲ
EU Auto EU CMBS EU RMBS Spanish Spanish Italian Portuguese Dutch UK PRMBS France Spain Italy Germany
loans RMBS SME CLO RMBS RMBS RMBS
Ϭ͕ϴ
Ϭ͕ϲ
Ϭ͕ϰ
Ϭ͕Ϯ
Ͳ
ͲϬ͕Ϯ
10
Given that the four components are statistically significant and have an intuitive interpretation
we retain them as factors, denoted , in a linear-factor model. The other PCA components are
neither significant nor intuitive. We have retained the residual variances of the assets as well,
denoted V i2 , that remain after subtracting the common factor returns. Formally we specify the
Di ¦
4
it 1
Ei t H it (1)
°¦
4
Ei V 2 E i iz
®
1
cov(i, ) (2)
°̄¦
4
1
E i V 2 E i V i2 i i
We obtain the modelled correlations as given in Table 5. We make the assumption that this
correlation structure is persistent going forward. The model fits the data well as can be seen
by the resemblance with the observed correlation given in Table 3.
RM
EC
BS
s
an
BS
BS
RM
SM
se
BS
lo
RM
RM
BS
BS
y
e
ŵŽĚĞůůĞĚ
M
to
an
gu
ish
sh
CM
RM
ce
n
PR
Au
h
rt u
rm
i
ain
lia
an
an
tc
an
ly
ĐŽƌƌĞůĂƚŝŽŶ
Du
UK
Ge
EU
EU
EU
It a
It a
Po
Sp
Sp
Sp
Fr
EU Auto loans ϭ Ϭ͕ϰϬ Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕ϯϭ Ϭ͕ϱϳ ͲϬ͕ϭϯ Ϭ͕Ϭϱ Ϭ͕ϲϮ Ϭ͕ϲϯ Ϭ͕Ϭϴ ͲϬ͕ϭϮ ͲϬ͕Ϭϵ Ϭ͕ϭϮ
EU CMBS Ϭ͕ϰϬ ϭ Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕Ϯϳ Ϭ͕ϯϰ Ϭ͕ϭϭ Ϭ͕ϭϮ Ϭ͕ϰϮ Ϭ͕ϯϲ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕Ϭϭ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ
EU RMBS Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕ϯϲ ϭ Ϭ͕ϲϬ Ϭ͕ϰϱ Ϭ͕ϱϰ Ϭ͕ϯϴ Ϭ͕ϲϮ Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϴ Ϭ͕ϬϬ
Spanish RMBS Ϭ͕ϯϭ Ϭ͕Ϯϳ Ϭ͕ϲϬ ϭ Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕ϯϰ Ϭ͕Ϯϭ Ϭ͕ϰϳ Ϭ͕Ϯϴ Ϭ͕ϮϮ Ϭ͕ϭϭ Ϭ͕ϭϲ Ϭ͕ϭϵ
Spanish SME CLO Ϭ͕ϱϳ Ϭ͕ϯϰ Ϭ͕ϰϱ Ϭ͕ϯϲ ϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϳ Ϭ͕ϭϰ Ϭ͕ϱϰ Ϭ͕ϰϲ Ϭ͕Ϭϵ ͲϬ͕ϭϭ ͲϬ͕Ϭϴ Ϭ͕ϭϯ
Italian RMBS ͲϬ͕ϭϯ Ϭ͕ϭϭ Ϭ͕ϱϰ Ϭ͕ϯϰ Ϭ͕Ϭϳ ϭ Ϭ͕ϯϳ Ϭ͕ϮϮ ͲϬ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕ϮϬ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕Ϭϵ ͲϬ͕Ϯϱ
Portuguese RMBS Ϭ͕Ϭϱ Ϭ͕ϭϮ Ϭ͕ϯϴ Ϭ͕Ϯϭ Ϭ͕ϭϰ Ϭ͕ϯϳ ϭ Ϭ͕ϮϮ Ϭ͕Ϭϱ ͲϬ͕Ϯϳ ͲϬ͕Ϯϱ ͲϬ͕ϮϮ ͲϬ͕Ϯϭ
Dutch RMBS Ϭ͕ϲϮ Ϭ͕ϰϮ Ϭ͕ϲϮ Ϭ͕ϰϳ Ϭ͕ϱϰ Ϭ͕ϮϮ Ϭ͕ϮϮ ϭ Ϭ͕ϱϳ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕Ϭϯ
UK PRMBS Ϭ͕ϲϯ Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕Ϯϴ Ϭ͕ϰϲ ͲϬ͕Ϭϯ Ϭ͕Ϭϱ Ϭ͕ϱϳ ϭ ͲϬ͕Ϭϯ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕Ϭϳ ͲϬ͕Ϭϲ
France Ϭ͕Ϭϴ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕ϮϮ Ϭ͕Ϭϵ ͲϬ͕ϮϬ ͲϬ͕Ϯϳ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ ͲϬ͕Ϭϯ ϭ Ϭ͕ϯϵ Ϭ͕ϯϴ Ϭ͕ϵϭ
Spain ͲϬ͕ϭϮ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕ϭϭ ͲϬ͕ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ ͲϬ͕Ϯϱ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕ϯϵ ϭ Ϭ͕ϴϱ Ϭ͕ϭϮ
Italy ͲϬ͕Ϭϵ Ϭ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϴ Ϭ͕ϭϲ ͲϬ͕Ϭϴ Ϭ͕Ϭϵ ͲϬ͕ϮϮ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ Ϭ͕Ϭϳ Ϭ͕ϯϴ Ϭ͕ϴϱ ϭ Ϭ͕ϭϬ
Germany Ϭ͕ϭϮ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕ϬϬ Ϭ͕ϭϵ Ϭ͕ϭϯ ͲϬ͕Ϯϱ ͲϬ͕Ϯϭ ͲϬ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕Ϭϲ Ϭ͕ϵϭ Ϭ͕ϭϮ Ϭ͕ϭϬ ϭ
11
In the next section we carry out Markowitz (1952) optimization analyses in the traditional
Capital Asset Pricing Model framework, see Sharpe (1964). This established analysis
technique has its known limitations, which we discuss briefly for the case of asset-backed
securities.
All variables are based on estimations which may be erroneous. The precautions we make to
avoid this are stipulated in this section. For the expected returns in particular we make note
that they are based on the current yields-to-maturity and as such represent expected carry
performance only. A possible tightening or loosening of the credit spreads is not considered.
The asset returns are assumed to be normally distributed. Based on the stable price behaviour
of the ABS over the last five years we make the pro ection that this will continue going
forward. The selection of senior, Triple A tranches has been made deliberately to favour this
situation.
Practical issues in particular market liquidity is not taken into account. There are the two sides
to consider. The sell side is since the easing of the crisis in 2009 no longer an obstacle. The
ma ority of ABS sales take place through bids-wanted-in-competition vehicles (BWIC) which
are fluid. The buy side for ABS has become slow, since the securities are in ma ority held by
long-term investors. The risk related to this situation is to miss investment opportunity, which
is not the same severity of risk five years ago when investors got caught out by the sudden
market drought.
In order to evaluate the absolute benefit of mixing ABS and sovereigns in an investment
portfolio, we carry out absolute risk/return optimizations given the return potential of the
assets (in Table 1), their volatility levels (in Table 2) and the covariance structure (in Table 5).
We build long-only and fully-invested portfolios while varying the aversion to risk and by
that trace the efficient frontier. The resulting portfolios are given in Figure 6.
12
Considering a more realistic situation where the investments are being compared with a given
benchmark, we take the case of an investor whose performance is compared with the Euro
Treasuries bond index. ence, the portfolio risk, defined as the tracking error (TE), is nil
when holding the index positions and increases as more active positions are being added to
the portfolio. In the same way the portfolio return is measured to the extent that it can beat the
benchmark (add alpha). In this setting we do the same exercise as is done above, we vary the
risk aversion while optimizing the alpha with respect to the tracking error and by that trace the
efficient frontier of optimal portfolios. The results are in Figure 7.
13
alpha 0 44 257
TE 0 1.0 7,0
The minimum-risk portfolio D is the benchmark, and the maximum-return portfolio F is the
same as portfolio C. Portfolio E maximizes the relative return-to risk profile, the Information
Ratio (IR). It is plotted onto the absolute return and risk axes in Figure 6 and is displayed in
Figure 8. The portfolio beats the benchmark both in terms of risk and return. By adding 14
of ABS to a sovereign-invested portfolio the overall risk reduces from 4.7 to 4.2 , while
the return potential increases from 158 to 216 basis points. As a result, under the hypothesis
of a risk-free return at 0.15 (the 1-year German sovereign yield), the Sharpe ratio increases
from 0.30 to 0.48.
14
In a last experiment we run a stress test, by which we measure what would happen to the
optimized portfolio E in case a new ABS crisis would reoccur. If the crisis would manifest in
the same magnitude as in 2007-2009, the correlation within the ABS class would double, their
volatility levels would double as well yet there would be little to no contagion to the
sovereign bonds (see Appendix). In that situation the volatility of the optimized portfolio
would rise. The risk with respect to the benchmark, the tracking error, would increase from
0.9 to 1.1 . The increase is limited due to the fact that the ABS pocket is relatively small
and that there is no contagion.
IV. Conclusion
We make the observation that five years after the financial crisis, the asset- and mortgage-
backed securities in Europe compared to euro sovereigns (i) yield higher, (ii) are less volatile
and (iii) are less correlated, both between themselves and with respect to sovereigns. This is
the interest of our paper. It comes to no surprise that with those favourable features the ABS
take a predominant position in the return-to-risk optimal portfolio.
References
Jeanniard, R. (2011) “How have asset-backed securities gone from one crisis to another, from
a plague to a safe haven security”, Amundi Cross asset investment strategy n 11.
Sharpe, W. (1964) “Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of
risk”, o al o i a ce 19 (3).
15
In the Table below are the correlations that have been measured over two sub-periods: one
from 2007 to 2009 over the ABS crisis and one from 2010 to 2013 which includes the
sovereign debt crisis.
It is relevant to note that
i. the correlation structure remains stable over the entire period, in particular the
correlations between the two asset classes remain close to zero in both sub-periods.
ii. the correlation within the ABS class doubles in the ABS crisis period,
iii. the average correlation between the sovereign bonds falls sharply during the sovereign
debt crisis (between core and peripheral countries),
RM
EC
BS
s
an
BS
BS
RM
SM
se
BS
lo
RM
RM
BS
BS
y
e
ĐŽƌƌĞůĂƚŝŽŶ
M
to
an
gu
sh
sh
CM
RM
ce
n
PR
Au
h
rt u
rm
i
ain
lia
an
an
tc
an
ly
ϮϬϬϳͲϮϬϬϵ
Du
UK
Ge
EU
EU
EU
It a
It a
Po
Sp
Sp
Sp
Fr
EU Auto loans ϭ Ϭ͕ϯϳ Ϭ͕ϱϱ Ϭ͕ϰϴ Ϭ͕ϱϬ Ϭ͕ϭϰ Ϭ͕ϰϴ Ϭ͕ϯϵ Ϭ͕ϯϳ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕Ϭϱ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ
EU CMBS Ϭ͕ϯϳ ϭ Ϭ͕ϰϲ Ϭ͕ϰϭ Ϭ͕Ϯϵ Ϭ͕ϭϵ Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕ϯϯ Ϭ͕ϯϯ ͲϬ͕Ϭϰ ͲϬ͕Ϭϴ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ
EU RMBS Ϭ͕ϱϱ Ϭ͕ϰϲ ϭ Ϭ͕ϴϴ Ϭ͕ϰϴ Ϭ͕ϱϱ Ϭ͕ϲϭ Ϭ͕ϳϰ Ϭ͕ϰϮ Ϭ͕Ϭϱ Ϭ͕Ϭϱ Ϭ͕ϭϮ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ
Spanish RMBS Ϭ͕ϰϴ Ϭ͕ϰϭ Ϭ͕ϴϴ ϭ Ϭ͕ϰϯ Ϭ͕Ϯϴ Ϭ͕ϯϮ Ϭ͕ϰϱ Ϭ͕Ϯϴ Ϭ͕ϭϱ Ϭ͕ϭϮ Ϭ͕ϮϬ Ϭ͕ϭϯ
Spanish SME CLO Ϭ͕ϱϬ Ϭ͕Ϯϵ Ϭ͕ϰϴ Ϭ͕ϰϯ ϭ Ϭ͕ϭϬ Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕ϯϰ Ϭ͕ϯϱ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕ϬϬ Ϭ͕ϭϯ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ
Italian RMBS Ϭ͕ϭϰ Ϭ͕ϭϵ Ϭ͕ϱϱ Ϭ͕Ϯϴ Ϭ͕ϭϬ ϭ Ϭ͕ϱϳ Ϭ͕ϯϳ Ϭ͕Ϯϱ ͲϬ͕ϭϮ ͲϬ͕Ϭϴ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ ͲϬ͕ϭϲ
Portuguese RMBS Ϭ͕ϰϴ Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕ϲϭ Ϭ͕ϯϮ Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕ϱϳ ϭ Ϭ͕ϰϵ Ϭ͕ϯϰ ͲϬ͕ϮϬ ͲϬ͕ϭϴ ͲϬ͕ϮϬ ͲϬ͕ϭϳ
Dutch RMBS Ϭ͕ϯϵ Ϭ͕ϯϯ Ϭ͕ϳϰ Ϭ͕ϰϱ Ϭ͕ϯϰ Ϭ͕ϯϳ Ϭ͕ϰϵ ϭ Ϭ͕ϱϬ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕Ϭϳ ͲϬ͕Ϭϯ
UK PRMBS Ϭ͕ϯϳ Ϭ͕ϯϯ Ϭ͕ϰϮ Ϭ͕Ϯϴ Ϭ͕ϯϱ Ϭ͕Ϯϱ Ϭ͕ϯϰ Ϭ͕ϱϬ ϭ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕ϭϭ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ
France Ϭ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕Ϭϱ Ϭ͕ϭϱ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ ͲϬ͕ϭϮ ͲϬ͕ϮϬ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ ϭ Ϭ͕ϵϰ Ϭ͕ϴϱ Ϭ͕ϵϴ
Spain ͲϬ͕Ϭϱ ͲϬ͕Ϭϴ Ϭ͕Ϭϱ Ϭ͕ϭϮ Ϭ͕ϬϬ ͲϬ͕Ϭϴ ͲϬ͕ϭϴ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕ϵϰ ϭ Ϭ͕ϴϳ Ϭ͕ϵϭ
Italy Ϭ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕ϭϮ Ϭ͕ϮϬ Ϭ͕ϭϯ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ ͲϬ͕ϮϬ Ϭ͕Ϭϳ Ϭ͕ϭϭ Ϭ͕ϴϱ Ϭ͕ϴϳ ϭ Ϭ͕ϳϳ
Germany Ϭ͕Ϭϰ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ Ϭ͕ϭϯ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ ͲϬ͕ϭϲ ͲϬ͕ϭϳ ͲϬ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕ϵϴ Ϭ͕ϵϭ Ϭ͕ϳϳ ϭ
16
BS
LO
RM
EC
BS
s
an
BS
BS
RM
SM
se
BS
lo
RM
RM
BS
BS
y
e
ĐŽƌƌĞůĂƚŝŽŶ
M
to
an
gu
sh
sh
CM
RM
ce
n
PR
Au
h
rt u
rm
i
ain
lia
an
an
tc
an
ly
ϮϬϭϬͲϮϬϭϯ
Du
UK
Ge
EU
EU
EU
It a
It a
Po
Sp
Sp
Sp
Fr
EU Auto loans ϭ Ϭ͕Ϯϱ Ϭ͕Ϭϳ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ Ϭ͕Ϭϳ ͲϬ͕Ϭϵ Ϭ͕Ϭϲ Ϭ͕ϭϳ Ϭ͕Ϯϰ ͲϬ͕Ϭϯ Ϭ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕ϬϬ
EU CMBS Ϭ͕Ϯϱ ϭ Ϭ͕ϯϯ Ϭ͕Ϯϱ Ϭ͕ϭϮ Ϭ͕ϮϮ Ϭ͕ϮϬ Ϭ͕Ϯϭ Ϭ͕ϯϳ Ϭ͕Ϭϴ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ Ϭ͕Ϭϵ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ
EU RMBS Ϭ͕Ϭϳ Ϭ͕ϯϯ ϭ Ϭ͕ϴϲ Ϭ͕ϱϬ Ϭ͕ϲϮ Ϭ͕ϱϴ Ϭ͕ϯϰ Ϭ͕Ϯϵ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ ͲϬ͕Ϭϱ Ϭ͕ϭϬ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ
Spanish RMBS Ϭ͕Ϭϯ Ϭ͕Ϯϱ Ϭ͕ϴϲ ϭ Ϭ͕ϰϲ Ϭ͕ϰϭ Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕ϭϲ Ϭ͕ϭϴ Ϭ͕ϭϮ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕ϭϱ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ
Spanish SME CLO Ϭ͕Ϭϳ Ϭ͕ϭϮ Ϭ͕ϱϬ Ϭ͕ϰϲ ϭ Ϭ͕ϮϮ Ϭ͕Ϯϯ Ϭ͕Ϯϯ ͲϬ͕Ϭϱ Ϭ͕ϬϮ ͲϬ͕Ϭϵ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕ϬϬ
Italian RMBS ͲϬ͕Ϭϵ Ϭ͕ϮϮ Ϭ͕ϲϮ Ϭ͕ϰϭ Ϭ͕ϮϮ ϭ Ϭ͕ϯϰ Ϭ͕ϭϲ Ϭ͕ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕ϭϭ ͲϬ͕Ϭϯ
Portuguese RMBS Ϭ͕Ϭϲ Ϭ͕ϮϬ Ϭ͕ϱϴ Ϭ͕ϯϲ Ϭ͕Ϯϯ Ϭ͕ϯϰ ϭ Ϭ͕ϭϮ Ϭ͕ϭϴ ͲϬ͕ϭϴ ͲϬ͕ϭϱ ͲϬ͕Ϭϴ ͲϬ͕Ϭϰ
Dutch RMBS Ϭ͕ϭϳ Ϭ͕Ϯϭ Ϭ͕ϯϰ Ϭ͕ϭϲ Ϭ͕Ϯϯ Ϭ͕ϭϲ Ϭ͕ϭϮ ϭ Ϭ͕Ϯϳ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ ͲϬ͕Ϭϲ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ Ϭ͕Ϭϱ
UK PRMBS Ϭ͕Ϯϰ Ϭ͕ϯϳ Ϭ͕Ϯϵ Ϭ͕ϭϴ ͲϬ͕Ϭϱ Ϭ͕ϭϭ Ϭ͕ϭϴ Ϭ͕Ϯϳ ϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕Ϭϳ Ϭ͕ϭϭ Ϭ͕ϬϮ
France ͲϬ͕Ϭϯ Ϭ͕Ϭϴ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕ϭϮ Ϭ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕ϭϴ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ ϭ Ϭ͕ϭϴ Ϭ͕ϭϴ Ϭ͕ϳϲ
Spain Ϭ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕Ϭϱ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ ͲϬ͕Ϭϵ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ ͲϬ͕ϭϱ ͲϬ͕Ϭϲ Ϭ͕Ϭϳ Ϭ͕ϭϴ ϭ Ϭ͕ϳϵ ͲϬ͕ϭϯ
Italy Ϭ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕Ϭϵ Ϭ͕ϭϬ Ϭ͕ϭϱ ͲϬ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕ϭϭ ͲϬ͕Ϭϴ Ϭ͕Ϭϯ Ϭ͕ϭϭ Ϭ͕ϭϴ Ϭ͕ϳϵ ϭ ͲϬ͕ϮϬ
Germany Ϭ͕ϬϬ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ ͲϬ͕Ϭϭ Ϭ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕ϬϬ ͲϬ͕Ϭϯ ͲϬ͕Ϭϰ Ϭ͕Ϭϱ Ϭ͕ϬϮ Ϭ͕ϳϲ ͲϬ͕ϭϯ ͲϬ͕ϮϬ ϭ
1. .
17
SOFIANE ABOURA,
Associate Professor – Paris-Dauphine University
DIDIER MAILLARD,
Professor - Cnam, Senior Advisor, Amundi
January 2015
In order to remedy the assumption of a Gaussian marginal distribution for the underlying
asset returns in the classical Black-Scholes-Merton model, three principal approaches are
proposed in the literature: stochastic volatility models1 , jump-diffusion process for the price
dynamics2 , and stochastic volatility with a jump-diffusion process3 . There are also more
general non-Gaussian alternative classes for the underlying asset4 .
Despite the large number of published works on the issue of pricing derivatives during stress
periods, the idea to consider a weakly non-Gaussian distributions with an exact formula that
allows for skewness and excess kurtosis, to our best knowledge, has been so far ignored. Here
we aim to address this issue by deriving a weakly-non Gaussian distribution to price option
contracts. We believe that pricing option contracts during financial stress periods induces
a trade-off between sophistication (to account for marketplace stylized facts) and simplicity
(to avoid any type of risk arising from the model). Most of the aforementioned papers have
probably underestimated this trade-off, either because the model is too complex and risky
Edgeworth and Gram-Charlier expansions.
Fortunately, the use of Cornish-Fisher expansion helps with avoiding two main typical pit-
falls in these series expansions. First and most important, the area of the domain of validity,
expressed in actual skewness and kurtosis, seems to give sufficient room for manoeuvre in
most circumstances, which is not necessarily the case for other expansions. This is a major
point for avoiding the case of negative probabilities, typical for higher order expansions,
when pricing far-from the money option contracts. What can be shown is that the domain
of validity of the Cornish-Fisher is much wider than in the Gram-Charlier case. Second, the
transformation gives a simple relation between the skewness and kurtosis parameters and
the Value-at-Risk or Expected Shortfall measures.
Finally, our formula provides simple and flexible ways to fit a large variety of skewness and
kurtosis data. Indeed, it is written in a simple form, following Corrado and Su (1996a,b),
where the third and fourth moments are additional parameters that correct the Black-
Scholes-Merton formula. This simplifies the costly numerical analysis, as the model is easy
to estimate but also simple to interpret.
This research is relevant for three principal reasons. First, it addresses the issue of option
pricing with a weakly non-Gaussian model that accounts for explicit skewness and kurtosis
having a large domain of validity. Second, it addresses the issue of option pricing in a context
of financial stress. To our best knowledge, no existing studies compare their model’s per-
formance during stress periods using intra-day data and short-term out-the-money options,
which are the major sources of mispricing. In contrast, our database is mainly composed by
short-term out-the-money contracts. Third, our model compares the model’s performance
to a well-known trading rule, that is used as a benchmark, while the vast majority of the
existing studies do comparisons with the Black-Scholes (1973) model or its extensions. This
The main contribution of this paper is to derive a weakly non-Gaussian European-style op-
tion pricing model, allowing for explicit third and fourth moments estimated implicitly from
the derivatives market. To our knowledge, no research paper has addressed the issue of
pricing option with a Cornish-Fisher transformation.
The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 displays the characteristics of the novel model;
Section 3 exposes the empirical results; and Section 4 summarizes and concludes.
s k s
Z = z + (z 2 − 1) × + (z 3 − 3z) × − (2z 3 − 5z) × (1)
6 24 36
s and k are parameters which determine skewness and kurtosis, but except for very low
values, they do not coincide with effective skewness s∗ and kurtosis k∗ . The parameters will
be computed to achieve the effective skewness and kurtosis:
M3
s∗ = (2)
M21.5
M1 = 0
M2 = 1 + 961 k2 + 1296
25 4
s − 361 ks2
76 3 85 5
M3 = s − 216 s + 1296 s + 14 ks − 144
13
ks3 + 321 k2 s (4)
M4 = 3 + k + 167 k2 + 323 k3 + 3072
31 4
k − 2167 4
s − 48625 6 21665 8
s + 559872 s
7 2 113 4 5155 6 7 2 2 2455 2 4 65 3 2
− 12 ks + 452 ks − 46656 ks − 24 k s + 20736 k s − 1152 k s
As Z is non-standard (zero mean but variance slightly different from one), we will use the
transformation leading to a new definition of Z by retaining:
Obviously, this new definition has the same higher moments than the initial transformation.
Recall that both the Cornish-Fisher and Gram-Charlier expansions are means of transform-
ing a Gaussian distribution into a non-Gaussian distribution, the skewness and the kurtosis of
which can be controlled if the transformations are properly implemented. Their expansions
differ in that the Cornish-Fisher is a transformation of quantiles, whereas the Gram-Charlier
is a transformation of a probability density. Both transformations must be implemented
with care, as their domain of validity does not cover the whole range of possible skewness
and kurtosis coefficients. Figure 1 exhibits the domain of validity of both expansions in the
skewness-kurtosis plane. What is most appealing, in the Cornish-Fisher expansion, is that
its domain of validity is much wider than in the Gram-Charlier case. This characteristic
reveals, unambiguously, how much more realistic the Cornish-Fisher expansion is, as com-
pared to the Gram-Charlier expansion; judging by the magnitude of the skewness-kurtosis
domain, which potentially encapsulates most of the tradable assets.
z2
1 e− 2
Φ(Z) = √ k s2 2 (6)
2π z 2 8 − 6 + z 3s + 1 − k8 + 5s36
with:
√ √
3 −q+ Z + (q− Z )2 + 4 p3 3 −q+ Z − (q− Z )2 + 4 p3
z = a3 + b
2
b 27
+ b
2
b 27
a = k −ss2
8
−3
k s2
b= 24
− 18
2 s2
1− k8 + 5s
p= k 2
36
− 13 36
2
−s
24 18
( 24 − s18 )2
k
k 5s2 s3
−s s(1− 8 + 36 )
q= k s2
− 181 k 2 − 272 216
2
8
−3 ( 24 − s18 )2 k
( 24 − s18 )3
We use the weakly non-Gaussian probability density Φ(.), derived from the Cornish-Fisher
expansion, to control for skewness and excess kurtosis. Φ(Z) is the density evaluated on the
random variable Z. Assuming risk-neutrality, we derive theoretical European call option for-
mula as the value of the expected payoff, discounted by the risk-free rate rf at the contract’s
time to maturity (T − t). For a call option CCF with strike K and underlying asset price ST
at maturity T , the value will be given by:
+∞
CCF = e−rf (T −t) (ST − K)+ Φ(Z)d(Z) (7)
−∞
If the skewness and the excess kurtosis are zero, this model reduces to the Black-Scholes
(1973) model with CCF = CBS when s∗ = 0 and k∗ = 0.
Figure 2 reproduces volatility smiles according to various levels of kurtosis and skewness.
First, the deeper is the kurtosis, the higher is the volatility curvature. Second, the impact
of skewness leads to a rotation in the smile where a negative skewness induces a negative
slope.
6
We would like to thank Sebastien Valeyre for having provided us with this data set that comes from
Liffe-Nyse-Euronext.
Nt
e2K,t (9)
K=1
With eK,t again representing the normalized difference between the market call option prices
and the call option prices computed by the Cornish-Fisher model for the K th strike price
with K = 1, ..., NT and the underlying stock index price St at date t. The set of esti-
mated parameters (σ, s∗ , k∗ ) are computed from the in-the-sample calibration and remain
constant for the one-day ahead out-the-sample pricing; this assumption is reasonable since
these parameters are relatively stable for short horizons. Hence, during the out-the-sample
procedure, we re-compute option prices of the current day using the previous day’s implied
volatility, implied skewness, and implied kurtosis; the interest rate r is set constant for the
period. Therefore, only the underlying stock index price St and the time to maturity (T − t)
change.
The Cornish-Fisher average implied skewness s∗ is -1.72 (ranging from -2.42 to -0.37), while
the average implied kurtosis k∗ is 7.80 (ranging from 1.23 to 16.64). Under these circum-
stances, a larger domain of validity is paramount since it allows the model to capture strong
market swings that affect these three structural parameters (σ, s, k) within a short interval
of time.
Figure 4 illustrates the ranges of values for the three parameters estimated during October
2008. Given the volatile nature of this month, the implied skewness and kurtosis may appear
relatively stable in general.
To assess the out-of-sample forecasting (see column "Pricing") performance of the Cornish-
Fisher model, we set constant the implied volatility σt−1 , implied skewness st−1 , and implied
kurtosis kt−1 calibrated from the previous trading day t−1, in order to price option contracts
for the day t. It appears that the sum of squared errors made by the Cornish-Fisher model
represent two thirds (76.59%) of the error made by the sticky strike model.
Overall, we conclude that the Cornish-Fisher model has improved calibration and pricing
accuracy during the most volatile month of the 2008 financial crisis. This can be explained
that this weakly non-Gaussian model has a larger domain of validity than comparable models
(Gram-Charlier, Edgeworth etc.) and is easier to estimate and more stable than the stochas-
tic volatility models. The day of October 17 represents the biggest stock index price swing of
the period, characterized by the highest volatility (71.89%), the highest kurtosis (16.64), the
4 Conclusion
This paper derives a new option pricing model based on a weakly non-Gaussian risk-neutral
probability density. This density relies on a Cornish-Fisher transformation with an exact
formula allowing for heavy-tails in the presence of non-normal skewness and kurtosis. An
in and out-the-sample analysis is carried out on intra-day data from the FTSE 100 stock
index options during October 2008, which was the most volatile month of the 2008 financial
crisis. We conclude that the Cornish-Fisher model has improved calibration and pricing
performance, as comparison to the sticky strike model. This improvement is due to its larger
domain of validity. It is worth emphasizing that this weakly non-Gaussian model is eas-
ier to implement than the stochastic volatility models or other alternative classes of stable
non-Gaussian models. This work can be applied to large data sets or extended to risk man-
agement measures, such as VaR and Expected Shortfall.
References
[1] Bakshi, G., C., Cao, and Z., Chen, 1997, Empirical performance of alternative option pricing models,
Journal of Finance, 52, 2003-2049.
[2] Barton, D.E., and K.E., Dennis, 1952, The conditions under which Gram-Charlier and Edgeworth
curves are positive definite and unimodal, Biometrika, 39, 425-427.
[4] Blinnikov, S., and R., Moessner, 1998, Expansions for nearly Gaussian distributions, Astronomy and
Astrophysics, 130, 193-205.
[5] Borland, L., 2002, A theory of non-Gaussian option pricing, Quantitative Finance, 2, 415-431.
[6] Borland, L., and J.P., Bouchaud, 2004, A non-Gaussian option pricing model with skew, Quantitative
Finance, 4, 499-514.
[7] Bouchaud, J-P., D., Sornette, and M., Potters, 1997, Option pricing in the presence of extreme fluctu-
ations, Mathematics of Derivative, Cambridge University Press, 112-125.
[8] Camara, A., and S., Heston, 2008, Closed-Form option pricing formulas with extreme events, Journal
of Futures Markets, 28, 213-230.
[9] Carr, P., H., Geman, D., Madan, and M., Yor, 2003, Stochastic volatility for Levy processes, Mathe-
matical Finance, 13, 345-382.
[10] Ciliberti, S., J-P. Bouchaud, and M., Potters, 2009, Smile dynamics, a theory of the implied leverage
effect, Wilmott Journal, 1, 87-94.
[11] Cornish, E., and R., Fisher, 1937, Moments and cumulants in the specification of distributions, Revue
de l’Institut International de Statistiques 5, 307-320
[12] Corrado, C., and T., Su, 1996a, Skewness and kurtosis in S&P 500 index returns implied by option
prices, Journal of Financial Research, 19, 175-92.
[13] Corrado, C., and T., Su, 1996b, S&P 500 index option tests of Jarrow and Rudd’s approximate option
valuation formula, Journal of Futures Markets, 16, 611-30.
[14] Daglish, T., J., Hull, and W., Suo., 2007, Volatility surfaces: theory, rules of thumb and empirical
evidence, Quantitative Finance, 7, 507-524.
[15] Derman, E., and I., Kani, 1994, Riding on a smile, Risk, 7, 32-39.
[18] Duffie, D., J., Pan, and K., Singleton, 2000, Transform analysis and asset pricing for affine jump
diffusions, Econometrica, 68, 1343-1376.
[19] Dumas,B., J., Fleming, and R., Whaley, 1998, Implied volatility functions : empirical tests, The Journal
of Finance, 53, 2059-2105.
[21] Hagan, P., D., Kumar, A.S., Lesniewski, and D.E., Woodward, 2002, Managing smile risk, Wilmott
Magazine, 1, July, 84-108.
[22] Heston, S.L., 1993, A closed-form solution for options with stochastic volatility with applications to
bond and currency options, Review of Financial Studies, 6, 327-343.
[23] Hull, J., and A., White, 1987, The pricing of options on assets with stochastic volatility, Journal of
Finance, 42, 281-300.
[24] Kleinert, H., 2004, Option pricing for non-Gaussian price fluctuations, Physica A, 338, 151-269.
[25] Leon A., J., Mencia, and E., Sentana, 2007, Parametric properties of semi-nonparametric distributions
with applications to option valuation, working paper, University of Alicante
[26] Maillard, D., 2012, A User’s guide to the Cornish-Fisher expansion, SSRN Working Papers Series.
[27] Maillard, D., 2013, More on Cornish-Fisher: Distribution density and boundary conditions, SSRN
Working Papers Series.
[28] Markose, S., and A., Alentorn, 2005, Option pricing and the implied tail index with the Generalized
Extreme Value (GEV) distribution, working paper, University of ESSEX.
[29] Merton, R.C, 1973, Theory of rational option pricing, Bell Journal of Economics and Management
Science 4, 141-183.
[30] Merton, R.C, 1976, Option pricing when underlying stock returns are discontinuous, Journal of Finan-
cial Economics, 3, 125-144.
[31] Rockinger, M., and E., Jondeau, 2001, Gram-Charlier densities, Journal of Economic Dynamics and
Control, 25, 1457-1483.
December 2014
Non normal distributions are a fact of life. In the financial world, many
distributions display tail risk, i.e. (negative) skewness and excess kurtosis.
Being able to model such risk is useful in various and important fields: risk
measurement, fund management performance evaluation, asset pricing…
One way to model tail risk is to introduce discontinuities, such as jumps,
to describe the distribution of values or returns. It is however possible, and
often convenient, to model tail risk in a continuous space. Both Cornish-
Fisher and Gramm-Charlier expansions (which is the simple form of a
family of Edgeworth expansions) are means to transforming a Gaussian
distribution into a non-Gaussian distribution, the skewness and the kurtosis
of which can be controlled if the transformations are properly implemented.
This may be useful for modelling distributions for a wide range of issues,
especially in risk assessment and asset pricing. The expansions differ in
their nature: Cornish-Fisher is a transformation of a random variable, or of
quantiles, meanwhile Gramm-Charlier is a transformation of a probability
density. Both transformations must be implemented with care, as their
domain of validity does not cover the whole range of possible skewnesses
and kurtosis. It appears that the domain of validity of Cornish-Fisher is
much wider that the domain of validity of Gramm-Charlier. This, and the
fact that Cornish-Fisher provides easily the quantiles of the distribution,
gives it an advantage over Gramm-Charlier in several configurations.
The Cornish Fisher expansion is a way of transforming a Gaussian distribution into a non-
Gaussian distribution, the skewness and the kurtosis of which can be controlled if the
transformation is properly implemented (Maillard, 2012). The Gramm Charlier expansion is
also a way of transforming a Gaussian distribution into a non-Gaussian one, with the desired
skewness and kurtosis.
Those expansions may prove very useful to model uncertain variables or events which
obviously are not normally distributed. In the field of finance, one observes that return or
changes in asset prices distributions display (generally negative) skewness and (generally
positive) excess kurtosis. These moments should be taken into account when risk is assessed,
and in asset pricing.
Gramm-Charlier has been used in option pricing, for instance in a seminal paper by Corrado
& Sue (1996). Cornish-Fisher has been used in several papers considering the risk of asset
returns: see for example Cao & alii (2010), or Fabozzi & alii (2012). Maillard (2013b) uses
Cornish-Fisher to estimate the cost of tail risk in a managed portfolio according to a
manipulation-proof performance measure. Aboura & Maillard (2014) use Cornish-Fisher for
the purpose of option pricing.
Cornish-Fisher and Gramm-Charlier expansions are not about the same object. The Cornish-
Fisher expansion is a transformation of a standard Gaussian random variable z into a non-
Gaussian variable Z, such that:
S K S2
(CF ) Z z ( z 2 1) ( z 3 3z ) (2 z 3 5 z )
6 24 36
ª S K º ª S K º
(GC ) ) ( z ) M ( z ) «1 H 3 ( z ) H 4 ( z )» M ( z ) «1 ( z 3 3 z ) ( z 4 6 z 2 3)»
¬ 6 24 ¼ ¬ 6 24 ¼
z2
1
M ( z) e 2
2S
d n x2 / 2
(1) n e x
2
/2
H n ( z) e
dx n
Note that the term of « expansion » is related to the fact that the probability laws derived from
the Cornish-Fisher or Gramm-Charlier expansions are « approximations » of any probability
law displaying the same four moments. But they are not in themselves approximate
probability laws, provided they lie within a certain domain of validity.
3 – Moments
Moments are easy to compute in the case of Gramm-Charlier (see for example Jondeau and
Rockinger (2001), or Appendix).
It ensues that volatility is unitary and that skewness and excess kurtosis 1 are equal to the S
and K parameters respectively:
(GC )
V 1
Sˆ S
Kˆ K
1
We mean by excess kurtosis the difference between kurtosis and 3, which is the kurtosis of a Gaussian
distribution.
(CF )
1 2 25 4 1
V 1 K S KS 2
96 1296 36
76 3 85 5 1 13 1
S S S KS KS 3 K 2 S
Sˆ 216 1296 4 144 32
1.5
§ 1 2 25 4 1 ·
¨1 K S KS 2 ¸
© 96 1296 36 ¹
ª 7 2 3 3 31 7 4 25 6 21665 8 7 2º
«3 K 16 K 32 K 3072 K 216 S 486 S 559872 S 12 KS »
4
« »
« 113 KS 4 5155 KS 6 7 K 2 S 2 2455 K 2 S 4 65 K 3 S 2 »
«¬ 452 46656 24 20736 1152 »¼
Kˆ 2
3
§ 1 2 25 4 1 2·
¨ 1 K S KS ¸
© 96 1296 36 ¹
Except for very small (absolute) values for S and K, volatility differs (slightly) from 1, and
skewness and kurtosis differ (sometimes hugely) from the skewness and kurtosis parameters.
It is thus possible to build distributions with the desired four first moments with both
expansions. Choosing the parameters is straightforward in the Gramm-Charlier case. It is
somewhat more arduous in the Cornish-Fisher case: one has to compute the S and K
parameters by reversing the two expressions giving the actual skewness and kurtosis (which
must be done numerically), and then correct the Cornish-Fisher expansion by dividing by the
value of volatility, to obtain a random variable with unitary variance and the desired skewness
and volatility.
4 – Probability densities
The probability density corresponding to Cornish-Fisher may be computed from the definition
of the random variable (see Maillard (2013a)), but its expression is somewhat more complex:
M ( z)
(CF ) ) ( Z )
§K S · 2
S K 5S 2
z 2 ¨¨ ¸¸ z 1
©8 6 ¹ 3 8 36
with:
q ' Z / a 3 q'Z / a 3 2 4 3
p q ' Z / a 3 q'Z / a 3 2 4 3
p
3 27 3 27
z ] SK ( Z ) a ' 0 / 3
2 2
s K S
a 3 k 2s a' 0
2
k s
k 2s 2 24 6
1 3k 5s 2 1 s2 s 1 s (1 3k 5s 2 ) 2 s3
p q'
k 2s 2
3 k 2s 2
2
k 2s 2
3 k 2s 2 2
27 k 2s 2
3
Though complex, this formula may be encapsulated into a single spreadsheet cell.
It is possible to plot the density function and its deformation according to kurtosis (see
Maillard (2013a) for more details), for the whole distribution.
The impact of skewness (here positive skewness) is less visible on the whole distribution,
Those probability densities are useful for computing numerically integrals, for instance in
issues of option pricing, and this seems to confer Gramm-Charlier an advantage of simplicity.
However, such integrals may also be computed using the quantiles of the distribution (by
The impact of skewness (here positive skewness) is less visible on the whole distribution,
Those probability densities are useful for computing numerically integrals, for instance in
issues of option pricing, and this seems to confer Gramm-Charlier an advantage of simplicity.
However, such integrals may also be computed using the quantiles of the distribution (by
5 – Domain of validity
This is a very important point. Any system of probability should present two features:
- Non-negativity: any possible event should have a probability equal or superior to zero,
- Unitary sum: the probabilities of all possible events should add to one.
ª S K º ª S K º
(GC ) ) ( z ) M ( z ) «1 H 3 ( z ) H 4 ( z )» M ( z ) «1 ( z 3 3 z ) ( z 4 6 z 2 3)» t 0 z
¬ 6 24 ¼ ¬ 6 24 ¼
f
³ )( z )dz
f
1
It is easy to show (see Appendix, moment M0) that the second condition is fulfilled. As for the
first one, a 4th-order polynomial has to be always positive. The condition therefore has been
studied in particular by Jondeau & Rockinger (2001).
They prove that the boundary of the domain of validity has a parametric definition given by:
H 3 ( z)
Sˆ ( z ) 24
z 6 3z 4 9 z 2 9
H 2 ( z)
Kˆ ( z ) 72 6
z 3z 4 9 z 2 9
It is possible to plot this boundary in the skewness/kurtosis plane. The domain of validity is
the inner part of the boundary.
It appears that kurtosis cannot exceed 4, and skewness 1.05 in absolute value. The domain of
validity is thus quite limited. It is not rare to observe in returns distribution kurtosis in excess
of 4 and skewnesses in excess of 1 in absolute terms 2.
2
Gramm-Charlier is the simplest (lowest polynomial order) of a family of density expansions known as the
Edgeworth expansions. The higher order expansions are also subject to nonnegativity problems. In addition, their
sum does not necessarily equal 1.
The condition for that to hold is that S and K are subject to the following inequality:
S2 § K S 2 ·§ K 5S 2 ·
4¨¨ ¸¨1 ¸d0
9 ©8 6 ¸¹¨© 8 36 ¸¹
This result is known for a long time. It is interesting to rewrite it (see Maillard (2012), with a
presentation of the derivation) as:
K S
9k 2 (3 33s 2 )k 30 s 4 7 s 2 d 0 k s
24 6
1 11s 2 s 4 6 s 2 1 1 11s 2 s 4 6 s 2 1
dkd
6 6
It implies that S cannot exceed 2.485 (for the square root to be real), and it gives an equation
of the boundary in the (S,K) plane.
14
12
10
Kurtosis parameter K
8
K'
K"
6
0
-2,5 -2 -1,5 -1 -0,5 0 0,5 1 1,5 2 2,5
Skew ness param eter S
However, one should remember at this stage that the skewness and kurtosis parameters are not
the actual skewness and kurtosis. The equation of the boundary in the ( Ŝ , K̂ ) plane could be
obtained by reversing the relationship but it is not easily tractable.
However, one can obtain a parametric representation of the boundary using S as a parameter.
S leads to Ŝ , and to K̂ through K.
This gives in Chart 3 the boundary of the domain of validity of the Cornish-Fisher
transformation.
The domain of validity is much wider in the Cornish-Fisher case, as may be seen in chart 4.
There have been proposals to extend the domain of validity of the transformation by
“rectifying” them: see in the case of Gramm-Charlier Jondeau & Rockinger (2001), or more
generally Chernozhukov & alii (2007). Their aim is to correct the breaches of non-negativity.
Those rectifications lead to new distribution laws, which may not be as parsimonious in their
implementation as Cornish-Fisher or Gramm-Charlier.
VaR1D ZD
It may be shown easily (see Maillard (2012)), using a Cornish-Fisher expansion, that:
S S2 K
VaR1D vD (1 vD2 ) (5vD 2vD3 ) (vD3 3vD )
6 36 24
It is also easy to obtain another, more consistent, measure of risk, the conditional value at risk
(CVaR)
ª S S2 Kº
CVaR1D yD «1 vD (1 2vD2 ) (1 vD2 ) »
¬ 6 36 24 ¼
zD2
1 1
where yD e 2 is the conditional value-at-risk in the Gaussian case.
D 2S
Cornish-Fisher provides thus a simple method for correcting risk measures that would prevail
in a Gaussian situation for skewness and kurtosis.
A caveat: The expressions of VaR and CVaR depend on the skewness and kurtosis
parameters. Those should be obtained by reversing the two expressions giving the actual
skewness and kurtosis as a function of the skewness and kurtosis parameters.
Due to its much wider domain of validity, Cornish-Fisher should be preferred in most cases. It
has also the advantage of giving a simple expression of the quantiles, which may be quite
useful in numerical simulations.
Aboura, Sofiane and Didier Maillard, 2014, “Option Pricing under Skewness and Kurtosis
using a Cornish Fisher Expansion”, Working Paper
Cao, Zhiguang, Richard D.F. Harris and Jian Shen, 2010, “Hedging and Value at Risk: A
Semi-Parametric Approach”, Journal of Future Markets 30(8), 780-794
Cornish, E., and R. Fisher, 1937, “Moments and Cumulants in the Specification of
Distributions”, Revue de l’Institut International de Statistiques 5, 307-320
Corrado, Charles J. and Tie Su, 1996, “Skewness and Kurtosis in S&P 500 Index Returns
implied by option prices”, The Journal of Financial Research, Vol. XIX, N° 2 pages 175-192
Fabozzi, Frank. J, Svetlovar T. Rachev and Stoyan V. Stoyanov, “Sensitivity of portfolio VaR
and Cvar to portfolio return characteristics”, Working Paper, Edhec Risk Institute, January
2012
Leon, Angel, Javier Mencia and Enrique Santana, “Parametric Properties of Semi-
Nonparametric Distributions, with Applications to Option Valuation”, Journal of Business &
Economic Statistics, April 2009, Vol. 27, No. 2
Maillard, Didier, 2012, “A User’s Guide to the Cornish Fisher Expansion”, Working Papers
Series, SSRN n° 1997178, February 2012
Maillard, Didier, 2013b, “Manipulation-Proof Performance Measure and the Cost of Tail
Risk”, SSRN Working Paper n°2276050
Spiring, Fred, “The Refined Positive Definite and Unimodal Regions for the Gram-Charlier
and Edgeworth Series Expansion”, 2011, Advances in Decision Sciences, Research Paper
No 463097
Gramm-Charlier moments
f f
ª S i 3 K º
³ z )( z)dz ³ «¬
Bien plus que des documents.
Découvrez tout ce que Scribd a à offrir, dont les livres et les livres audio des principaux éditeurs.
Annulez à tout moment.