Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 9

Forest Policy and Economics 49 (2014) 34–42

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Forest Policy and Economics


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/forpol

Actor-centred power: The driving force in decentralised community


based forest governance☆,☆☆
Max Krott, Axel Bader, Carsten Schusser ⁎, Rosan Devkota, Ahmad Maryudi,
Lukas Giessen, Helene Aurenhammer
Chair of Forest and Nature Conservation Policy, Georg-August University Goettingen, Buesgenweg 3, D-37077 Goettingen, Germany

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Community forestry has been described as a decentralised mode of forest governance that only partly lives up
Received 2 November 2012 to its expectations. The power of important actors to misuse the community forestry approach for their
Received in revised form 22 April 2013 self-interests has been reported as a major obstacle to comprehensive success. Hence, this article aims at de-
Accepted 29 April 2013
veloping an analytical, theory-based and empirically applicable framework for assessing an actor's power
Available online 25 June 2013
using community forestry as an illustrative case. The actor-centred power approach (ACP) analysis aims to
Keywords:
provide a scientific answer to the question of who are the politically most powerful actors in community for-
Community Forestry (CF) estry practices. In making use of suitable components of power theories it builds strongly upon the social re-
Power lations of actors, organisational aspects and power sources, as described by Weber, Dahl, Etzioni and their
Actors adherents. Actor-centred power approach (ACP) is defined as a social relationship in which actor A alters
Coercion the behaviour of actor B without recognising B's will. In our framework we distinguish between three core
Incentives elements: coercion, (dis-)incentives and dominant information. These make up the basis for observable
Information facts that involve not only physical actions but also threats by power elements and the very sources of said
power elements. Theoretical considerations show that, despite the focus being on actors, by looking to
their power sources a considerable part of structural power can be more tangible at least in part, like rules,
discourse or ideologies. Furthermore, the paper shows how the actor-centred power approach distinguishes
power from other influences on forest management and contributes to the identification of the group of
powerful actors on an empirical basis. Due to the focus on actors and well-defined and observable elements
of power, the actor-centred power approach (ACP) could serve not only as a basis for research but also as a
tool for quick assessment of power networks, delivering valuable preliminary information for designing
forest policy in practice.
© 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

1. Forest governance, community forestry and actors' power vein we understand forest governance to comprise all public and
private regulatory structures concerning the utilisation and conser-
The ways in which forests are governed and related changes in vation of forests, as well as the interactions between public and pri-
forest governance at multiple levels have recently been intensively vate actors therein. Both types of approaches, normative as well as
scrutinised (e.g. Glück et al., 2005; Agrawal et al., 2008; Hogl et al., analytical ones, were shown to be useful in assessing different as-
2008; Werland, 2009; Arts and Buizer, 2009; Rametsteiner, 2009; pects of forest governance, its dynamics and (for normative ones)
Arts, 2012; Giessen et al., 2009; Cashore and Stone, 2012; Pettenella also its performance against normative criteria. In the analytical
and Brotto, 2012; Ojha et al., 2009; Howlett et al., 2009; Buttoud, realm the following, broader empirical trends in forest governance
2012, Ed., Böcher et al., 2009). The concepts used for analysing forest have been described, which, as a whole, are in favour of voluntary,
governance within this research programme are either of a normative self-regulatory or market-based mechanisms (Glück et al., 2005;
(e.g., Rametsteiner, 2009 on good governance) or an analytical nature Hogl et al., 2008; Agrawal et al., 2008; Arts and Visseren-Hamakers,
(e.g., Giessen, 2009; 2010a,b on regional forest governance). In this 2012):

• Marketisation through the promotion of market incentives, forest


certification, and payment for environmental services
☆ This article belongs to the Special Issue: Assessing Forest Governance. • Decentralisation including devolution, new roles for the state as
☆☆ This research has been supported by the German Research Foundation (DFG).
⁎ Corresponding author. Tel.: +49 551 39 33410, +49 170 6876123(mobile);
meta-governor through incentives and evaluations, participation,
fax: +49 551 39 33415. community-based forest governance and community forestry, for-
E-mail address: cschuss@gwdg.de (C. Schusser). est self-organisation and opening of traditional actor networks

1389-9341/$ – see front matter © 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2013.04.012
M. Krott et al. / Forest Policy and Economics 49 (2014) 34–42 35

• Internationalisation of forests as an issue, including international force, which makes it difficult to deal with in practical politics. If
deliberations, national forest programmes and other vertical coor- scientific analysis were to break down “power” into elements de-
dination efforts scribing the specific processes that constitute it, one could better
• Cross-sectoralisation of policies, including cross-sector linkages and understand what power is and how it could be manipulated or
horizontal coordination with other sectors and their policies. amplified. For example, if power is based on physical sources,
like weapons, it is easier to detect it and to find ways to deal
Within all these broad trends in forest governance the power of with it.
important political actors has been reported to be a decisive factor to ⁎ Linking power to specific actors
help explain them comprehensively (Brockhaus et al., 2012; Agrawal The aim of describing the potential of a specific actor requires the
et al., 2008; Giessen et al., 2009; Giessen, 2010a,b). Additionally, in power concept to identify results for specific actors. Identifying a
the particular field of community forestry as a new and decentralised power process would not be sufficient; it is also necessary to de-
mode of forest governance, the power of actors has been identified as a scribe the part of the power that has a link to a given actor.
crucial factor that calls for closer scrutiny (Agrawal and Gibson, 1999; Here, one would hope to ascertain how much power a given
Edmunds and Wollenberg, 2003; Shackleton et al., 2002; Pérez-Ciera actor has, in comparison to other actors.
and Lovett, 2006; Medina et al., 2009; Agrawal et al., 2008; Devkota, ⁎ Differentiating between “power” and other capabilities that
2010; Maryudi, 2011; Schusser, 2012a,b; Yufanyi Movuh, 2012; actors may have
Yufanyi Movuh and Schusser, 2012) An actor influences forestry problems in many ways. He can techni-
There is, however, a lack of theory-based, yet empirically appli- cally modify the forest by cutting or planting trees; he can improve
cable, well operationalised analytical frameworks in forest policy re- decisions with new and better knowledge about the forest, e.g.,
search for assessing actors' power as a driving force in community about the ecological needs of trees; he can participate in discourse
forestry (Devkota, 2010; Maryudi, 2011; Maryudi et al., 2012; Schusser, or he can sell or buy timber. Influencing forests by means of these di-
2012a,b; Yufanyi Movuh, 2012; Yufanyi Movuh and Schusser, 2012). verse capabilities is linked to power but it does not make sense to
This lack of academic work is taken as the point of departure for sum up all capabilities into the resulting power. Rather, the capabil-
this article. Therefore, the aim of this study is to develop an analytical, ities of an actor merely provide the basis of power but would only
theory-based and empirically applicable framework for assessing become power if they are used purposely to change the behaviour
actors' power, using community forestry as an illustrative case. The of another actor. The challenge is to specify the power and to distin-
following section will develop this objective in more detail. guish it from the general capabilities an actor might have.
⁎ Observing empirical incidences suggesting the presence of
2. Actors' power: uncovering the hidden capabilities of political power
actors by means of forest governance research We do not expect power to be visible directly and often. Therefore,
we need to make observations that may suggest the presence and
The high aspiration of returning the forest to the hands of local magnitude of this otherwise invisible force. This concept should
people in order to implement sustainable management is often asso- bridge well-defined power and empirical findings.
ciated with the concept of community forestry, but it was achieved
only in part (Wollenberg et al., 2008; Sikor and Nguyen, 2007). In designing a concept that meets these aims we will rely on existing
Apparently, and in accordance with the concept, local actors gained political theory. First, we will explain how we make use of theory, then
influence over their forests, but some of the local and even extra- we will select suitable theoretical building blocks for our concept and fi-
local elites acquired dominant influence and proceeded to misuse nally, we will elaborate it. Examples from community forestry are used
the community forest for their own specific interests (Devkota, to illustrate theoretical arguments. Devkota (2010), Maryudi (2011),
2010; Maryudi et al., 2012). In the practical discourse, the questions Schusser (2012a,b), Yufanyi Movuh (2012) and Yufanyi Movuh and
of who causes failure and who has the potential to improve commu- Schusser (2012), have applied the actor-centred power approach in
nity forestry practices are discussed heatedly and with much contro- five case studies of community forestry in Nepal, Indonesia, Namibia,
versy (e.g., National Conference on Forest–People Interaction 2010, Germany and Cameroon already, but presenting these results in detail
Nepal, International Workshop Burbach, Germany 2011). Policy anal- would exceed the intended length of this paper. Focused on our goal
ysis could provide a scientifically sound knowledge base for answer- of describing the power of specific actors, we will speak of an
ing these questions, especially by analysing the actors' power and “actor-centred power analysis”.
its use as a driving force of community forestry.
Political research can help identify the capabilities specific actors 3. The relevant power theories
may have for solving problems in community forestry politics. Specifi-
cally, an important part of this is making the power of said actors, 3.1. Diverse and contested power theories
which is often hidden, visible empirically. Awareness of the power rela-
tions helps to find the right actors who can support a specific solution Dealing with power means looking at one of the old core topics in
politically. Therefore, one goal in achieving the aim of the paper is to de- political science. In grounding our concept in these political theories
sign a concept for assessing the power of actors in any given land use we hope to make use of the analytical strength of numerous political
issue. We have developed our concept by doing research on community thinkers and, additionally, to build on the vast empirical findings
forestry. Consequently, the study makes use of such research, but due to which were used in theory-based analysis of power processes world-
the general basis of our theoretical approach, the concept may be useful wide (de Jong et al., 2012). Forest policy researchers have little doubt
for analysing power within other land use issues. The concept is that power is a key factor in forest politics as well as in scientific anal-
designed as an analytical, theory-based and empirically applicable ysis and in practice. But in certain research concepts and results, the
framework for assessing actors' power using community forestry as power factor often disappears. For example, forest policy authors
an illustrative case. In more detail, the notion of actor-centred power use the terms “influence” and “capacity” to address processes similar
should meet the following specific requirements: to power (Silva, 1997; Winkel and Sotirov, 2011). In contrast, Arts
and van Tatenhove (2004) addresses power explicitly, and offers a
⁎ Specifying the power process and its elements comprehensive overview of power theories that gives us a good starting
To start with, we assume power as the capability of an actor to point. It becomes clear that the power debate is very diverse. The differ-
influence other actors. “Power” is a general term for an invisible ent power concepts generate different terms, overlap, and parts of them
36 M. Krott et al. / Forest Policy and Economics 49 (2014) 34–42

are contested. Trying to structure and synthesise these theories would the formulation and implementation of a policy (Schneider, 2009, p.
be too ambitious a task for our paper. Instead, we will check theories 192)”. The actor “acts” in regard to a policy. For example, within the pol-
to see whether they contribute to the five requirements for the scientific icy of community forestry all entities are relevant as actors that take
concept of power that we have formulated above. part in its formulation and/or implementation. Formulation and imple-
Valuable contributions will be taken not necessarily from whole mentation are seen as the results of actors' interventions. These actors
theories; portions of them might be used as source for ideas on how might be single individuals or groups. The groups can be collectives
to design our own theory. Such a selection is well in line with the crit- built of internally coordinated individuals, or corporative actors acting
ical realist approach of theory building (Modell, 2009). Theories can as an organisation as a whole, e.g., state administrations or associations.
be designed based on different sources of information, among which Our basic assumption is that power is applied by an entity within a
are other theories. The sources themselves will never determine social relation to at least one other entity. Such an actor-oriented
whether a new theory is right or wrong; the final proof must be empir- power term was also applied by Dahl (1957) and developed further
ical evidence exclusively. Therefore, existing theories or parts of them by many scholars (Arts and van Tatenhove, 2004).
might be used as a pool of ideas, but not to determine the quality of The main critics argue that the actor-oriented approach overlooks
one's own theory. We acknowledge that the critical realist approach the structural power that is based in the rules, discourses or settings
is not shared among all the theories about power that we want to at a societal level. Lukes (1974) shows in his three “faces” of power
look at. Consequently, we are searching for ideas that fit our aims, the importance of decision and non-decision making at a governmen-
even within theories that do not agree basically with our approach. tal level. Even more important are ideologies. Bachrach and Baratz
From the point of view of such authors with different epistemologies (1977) stress the relevance of non-decision making, meaning that
our selection will not be sufficient. Nevertheless, critical realists can keeping an issue outside the realm of political decision creates a
get ideas from such theories. power structure that supports the agenda of strong actors and ne-
From a critical realist approach an important requirement for the- glects others. We acknowledge that power structures matter and
ories are well-defined terms that can be linked directly or indirectly argue that actor-oriented power analysis is capable of examining a
to observations (Krott, 2012). We avoid terms from the theoretical relevant portion of power structures. This will be discussed in detail
discourse that have only a vague connection to observations, and within the chapter about our model.
we do not use observation directly to characterise power. Instead, a The three-layer model of power by Arts and van Tatenhove (2004,
power term should be defined which comprises a vast amount of p. 350) solves the dichotomy of actor and structure by expanding the
empirical observations. A basic requirement of our concept is the theory of power, adding two different layers: one for agents in inter-
avoidance of internal contradictions. This simple standard of theory actions to achieve policy outcomes and one for structuring arrange-
is rather difficult to achieve within the power discourse due to the ments respectively. A third layer is in between, dealing namely with
huge variability of definitions used by power analysts. the position of agents in arrangements. Arts and van Tatenhove stress
Arts and van Tatenhove (2004, p.347) sort the power theories that structures, e.g., rules or discourse positions, do not act on their
along important dichotomies: Some power theories “situate power own, without actors, but that nevertheless they define power as a
at the level of the acting agent, while others situate power at the part of structural layers. In our concept, power is directly linked to
level of structures”. From the point of view of our aim to identify specific actors, therefore defining power as part of structure is outside
the power of specific actors, the focus on the acting agent is the the scope of our definition and we cannot follow the three-layer
right choice. To start with, this leads us directly to Max Weber. The concept.
question remains of what to do with structural power. A similar di- Nevertheless, actor-oriented power analysis does not ignore struc-
chotomy is organisational versus discursive power. Actors are closer tures. We look at them from the point of view of the actor. This means
to the organisational aspect and, again, the integration of discourses that structure, like a position in arrangements as described in rules,
into our power concept has to be specified. Yet another dichotomy cannot be power in and of itself, but rather a power source for an
is dispositional versus relational power. The first is directly linked to actor. The actor can make use of rules, arguments in discourse, ideol-
“having resources”, whereas the second looks merely at achieving ogies or other structures in order to strengthen his power. The actor
outcomes. The outcomes can be conflict-oriented zero-sum games, can also find allies within a power network. Such support is defined
in which one party acquires something at another's cost. This transi- as a source of power but not directly as the power of the actor. In
tive power is contrasted with intransitive power, meaning that all line with actor-oriented institutionalism we argue that, by focusing
achieve something in a collective effort. Finally, power concepts can on actors and looking from their perspective at structures and how
be dispositional, based on resources or relational, targeting influence they use them, a big part of structural factors is covered (Scharpf,
for its own sake. Following these dichotomies helps to identify the 2000). Structural power aspects become part of our actor-centred
major relevant statements within the huge number of power theo- power approach by defining it as a power source, an idea that will
ries. We use this guidance in showing the roots of actor-centred be elaborated further later on.
power analysis. Most power theories link the power of an actor with his sources of
influence and with the achievement of outcomes. Giddens (1984),
3.2. Theoretical roots of actor-centred power analysis and referring to him, Arts and van Tatenhove (2004, p. 347), integrate
the outcome fully into the definition of power, meaning that part of
Looking for the power of actors means that power theories power is achieving policy outcomes. From the actors' point of view,
that focus on acting agents and organisational power are relevant. the link to outcomes cannot be integrated fully into the definition of
Weber (2000) places agents at the centre of his power theory, defining power. The problem is that outcomes in forest policy are caused by
power as the probability that one actor within a social relationship will a complex set of factors, like the technology used, reaction of the eco-
be in a position to carry out his own will despite resistance, regardless of system, and economic intervention (Krott, 2005, p. 282). The activi-
the basis on which this probability rests. An actor can do something spe- ties and power of an actor are only two among many highly diverse
cific with power. This is exactly the subject which our concept should factors causing a specific outcome. A naturally occurring forest fire
analyse well. The organisational dimension draws the attention to the can destroy the forest, and though the ecological outcome will be
problem of distinguishing an actor from other social entities like rules, negative it will have resulted without any influence by an actor. It
resources or bargaining processes. Actor-oriented institutionalism has might be that an actor with very little intervention achieves the
elaborated the term “actor” well (Scharpf, 2000). The actor is a basic fac- desired outcome, whereas an actor intervening powerfully achieves
tor in policy analysis and is defined as “acting entity that is involved in little, due to other changing factors like bad weather or a drop in
M. Krott et al. / Forest Policy and Economics 49 (2014) 34–42 37

demand and prices of timber, which shape the outcome strongly and power, this behavioural concept avoids Offe's paradox. How can the
may override the influence of a specific actor. Therefore, if we aim to threat of power be measured? Etzioni (1975) proposes that we exam-
define power as an ability of a specific actor, we have to keep the ine the actors' resources and instruments for coercion. Historical
achieved outcome separate from power. This does not mean that experiences of the use of these resources and instruments would
one neglects the outcome fully. Looking to Weber's definition of allow us to estimate future uses. Observations of power resources
carrying out one's own will against the will of others, power can be can be made that could suggest threats indicative of a power process.
restricted to enforcing a position within a social relationship, mean- Thus, power potential is verifiable beyond its simple exercise, as
ing that another person has to adapt a specific activity. This has the pointed out by Krott (1990, pp. 90–93).
purpose of achieving a desired outcome or at least increasing the like- By looking at the resources of power, Etzioni goes even further in
lihood of achievement, but whether this happens depends on many differentiating it (1975, p. 5). He develops a threefold typology of
factors, among which power and the social relations are only a part. power: coercive, remunerative, and normative. Relying on Weber's
The focus on social interaction was already part of Dahls (1957, conception, he defines power as ‘an actor's ability to induce or influ-
p.202) theory of power, which states that A has power over B. It ence another actor to carry out his directives or any other norms he
makes possible a close link to actors and has the advantage that supports’. Etzioni holds that we can differentiate among types of
power becomes discernible from other factors that may influence power by examining the means a potentate employs to make a subor-
outcomes, like technical intervention. dinate comply. These means can be physical, material, or symbolic.
According to this typology, Etzioni defines coercive power as the ap-
4. Conceptual framework: Developing and defining plication of, or threat to apply, physical sanctions. Remunerative
actor-centred power power entails the control of material resources. Finally, normative
power rests on the allocation and manipulation of symbolic rewards.
The theoretical considerations above argue that a power concept Etzioni's threefold typology classifies the means by which a subordi-
that answers the relevant practical question of who the most power- nate is made to comply. This concept meets our aims of differentiat-
ful is should focus on well-defined actors, on organisational aspects ing power and of making it better observable.
and on having and activating power sources in social relations. Etzioni's typology was ‘chosen as a point of departure’ by Bemelmans-
Despite being considered as separate, the aspects of structure, dis- Videc, Rist, and Vedung (1998, p.29). Here, the authors intend to reveal
courses, and achieved outcomes can be integrated in part by looking policy instruments classed as ‘regulations, economic means, and infor-
at them from the point of view of an actor. Following this argument, mation’. In more colloquial terms, they state that ‘government may either
we suggest the following definition: “actor-centred power is a social force us, pay us or have us pay, or persuade us.’ (Vedung, 1998, p. 29). The
relationship in which actor A alters the behaviour of actor B without concept of force and paying in order to alter the behaviour of a sub-
recognising B's will”. The definition is based on Weber (2000) and ordinate fits well into the definition of actor-centred power. We will dif-
Dahl (1957) and is used explicitly in environmental policy analysis ferentiate physical force from incentives and in doing this expand the
by Hasanagas (2004). In elaborating it we will show how integration meaning of payment to comprise all benefits that could be used to influ-
of other aspects mentioned above is possible in part and how power ence the subordinate. In addition, we will explain further in which case
can be specified and made observable. “information” becomes an element of power. Not all information works
The model considers a social relationship between actor A and without recognising the subordinates' will that is required for it to qualify
actor B. In most cases both actors try to alter each other's behaviour, as a power element according to our definition. Most information does
and one actor resists the other's efforts to a degree. For analytical sim- quite the opposite, namely, it addresses the will of another actor. With
plicity we call the actor who alters the behaviour of another actor these three elements we form the social relation we call, as a general
“potentate” and the other actor “subordinate”. Every actor plays, in term, “actor-centred power”. These elements shed light onto the specific
different social relations, sometimes the role of potentate and some- social processes involved between potentate and subordinate and link
times the role of subordinate, depending on the specific issue. them to observable facts, as shown in the following table:
Social relations in which power is exercised are part of complex po-
litical processes. They involve actors engaged in policy formulation as 4.1. Coercion
well as in implementation. This can happen at all levels, from local to
national and international, and could be, for example, formal or infor- Coercion builds on the power source of force and is defined as
mal bargaining in a group or bilateral public discourse, forest manage- “altering the behaviour of the subordinate by force”. Force works
ment under the supervision of public administration, receiving advice without recognising the will of the subordinate, therefore we call
and extension service or paying for work. The actor-centred power ap- the social process “induced power” (Hayek, 1960, p. 20). Force is
proach does not assume that most political power is applied in political caused by physical actions, like taking the subordinate into any type
bargaining but rather, that stronger power is exercised in day-to-day of custody or harming his body using weapons. Separating the
implementations at the local level in the forest. Formulating legally subordinate's body from the forest by physical means, e.g., a fence,
binding guidelines on how community forests should be managed is is also considered to be force. Force triggers counterforce from the
one power process, and guiding the implementation in the forest strict- subordinates. In our example, people often try to climb the fence or
ly in accordance with the guidelines is another, one which probably has destroy it. If the fence breaks, the person can enter the forest and fulfil
a stronger impact on the behaviour of subordinates. his will independently from the person who builds the fence. In this
A major requirement for our model is to make power observable. case, the fence builder is weaker than the other person, and the
Power itself is invisible. It may occur in the imagination of the actors, person entering the forest plays the role of potentate. As mentioned
but as critical realists we demand observations to verify the theoret- before, our model looks mainly at whose force prevails, and describes
ical terms. From this point of view, Weber's definition has some the amount of dominance as power. Using this simplification we draw
weaknesses. In his concept, power can be verified only in the pres- the attention to power and we avoid looking into the technical details
ence of resistance and the use of coercion to break this resistance. involved in forceful actions.
As Offe (1977, p. 10) has pointed out, in the case of absent resistance When speaking about force it is important to remind ourselves
influence cannot be verified. The better power ‘works’ in everyday that we consider all types of actors to be relevant. One actor heavily
life, as Offe argues, the less verifiable it is. However, even Weber grounded in force is the state, acting through different state adminis-
(1972, p. 28) mentioned that the option of exercising power might trative offices. At a formal level, the state nearly monopolises political
be seen as an equivalent to power. With the help of the threat of force (Weber, 1921). State force is implemented internally by police
38 M. Krott et al. / Forest Policy and Economics 49 (2014) 34–42

and externally by the military. As one considers these forces it cutting trees. This is done by means of technical force in our model.
becomes obvious that the threat of force is highly important. Our Only if the subordinate keeps the illegal intervention hidden from
model considers the threat of force to be as much a form of power the forest guards does a power process happen, because he then pre-
as the actual use of force would be. For example, the state forest vents the guards from altering his, the subordinate's, behaviour,
administration forces people to obey forest law mainly by means of namely, by stopping his illegal logging. The importance of this distinc-
threats when there is disobedience. In most cases the threat of force tion is that ecologic–technical potentials can be better analysed by
alone suffices to cause the political power process to take place. The natural sciences, whereas the topic of the potential to alter behaviour
direct implementation of force is more rare but not impossible, as is the competence of social sciences.
police activities in the forest have shown. The distinction between ecologic–technical influences and coer-
The effect of threat depends on the visibility of the sources of the cive power is of special importance because, due to the physical
force of the potentate and on the imagination of the subordinate. If means of coercion, the ecologic–technical influence can be easily mis-
the subordinate believes that the potentate has huge sources of taken for power. By applying the criteria that a behaviour change, due
power, the potentate can already establish power on this belief, to the use of coercion has happened both forces can now be distin-
even if in reality his force is weak. We consider that a bluff about guished well.
the level of force held is very much a form of coercion. The definition and observation of coercion is strongly based on
To sum up, we argue that our definition of coercion as “altering actors, but some aspects of structure can be included too. There is
behaviour with force” includes the threat of force and even bluffing no restriction to one single actor and an expansion to include
about force that does not really exist. Of importance is also the link networks of actors is possible (Raab, 2007, p. 187–200). The term
of force to actual physical actions or to physical actions that are an- “network” may cover many structural aspects that are based on a
nounced or expected. In the literature, the concept of force is often group of actors. Most important is that a network shows the allies
extended to include the realm of psychological harm (Popitz, 1992). of a specific actor and these allies provide him with additional sources
Such a broad definition of force is not useful for us because it conceals of power. The network of allies comprises formal and informal allies
the difference between physical action, which alters the behaviour of who make a broad field of power options visible. For example, legal
human bodies physically, and psychological action, which influences regulations which are seen as structural power often will be de-
the mind of the subordinate without physical means. Such psycholog- scribed fully by the formal network of implementation which is for-
ical processes we will consider to be incentives or disincentives. In mulated in the law. The law provides specific state actors with the
the case of the threat of force, the focus on physical action exists right of control and application of sanctions. Their cooperation and
too, even if it is only in the imagination. The key impact of physical sources are fully covered by the formal power network of actors
force is that it alters the body without recognising the will. who are responsible for implementation. Additionally, illegal support
Force caused by physical actions provides a basis for observations. can be spotted in the same way if actors threaten with physical harm
Physical actions can be spotted in the field often. Those relevant for within illegal structures.
forest policy are, for example, building and maintaining a fence, run-
ning a forest guard system equipped with weapons, felling trees 4.2. Disincentives and incentives
unobserved, and selling timber secretly. In addition, one can also
find empirical hints to force originating in threats. Some threats can A disincentive is based on disadvantage and defined as “altering
be observed directly if they are announced in the political process, the behaviour of the subordinate by means of disadvantages or advan-
either in public or in closed discourses. Forestry laws often include tages”. Disadvantages cause a power process because the potentate al-
sanctions that involve physical force. The state threatens with the ters the behaviour of the subordinate without recognising his will. He
ultimate sanction of incarcerating the subordinate or of using state implements disadvantages until the subordinate changes his behav-
managers to manage the forest in case of disobedience. These rules iour in the direction of the goals of the potentate. The potentate ob-
are indicative of the use of force. serves the behaviour and the effect of the disadvantages but he does
The threat of force can also be identified by the physical means not even know the will of the subordinate. Examples of disadvantages
that the potentate has. As long as one partner has stronger physical are penalties for illegal logging or bad planting or ecologically harmful
means than the other, the threat of force exists and power plays an logging operations. The subordinate can avoid the penalties only by al-
important role in the social relation in question. This does not neces- tering his behaviour in line with the wishes of the state, as formulated
sarily mean that the interests of the subordinate are harmed. Our def- in law or binding guidelines. His own will does not count. Altering be-
inition states that in a power process the will of the subordinates is haviour by means of disincentives is linked to coercive power, often
merely not recognised. Therefore, it could happen that the potentate forcing the subordinate to accept the disadvantages. For example,
decides against or in favour of the subordinate. The crucial point is the amount of a penalty determines the disadvantage but it will
that the potentate enforces his decision. For example, a state forester work only if the potentate acquires sufficient information about the
who manages a community forest for its members through a compul- misbehaviour of the subordinate and forces him to pay. This link to a
sory process is relying on force even if he has the members' best coercive component does not mean that the amount of the penalty is
interests in mind. not of specific importance as a disincentive.
Physical means can influence the subordinate or nature directly. The definition includes advantages too because the power process
For example, the potentate can threaten or hurt the subordinate is similar as when using disadvantages. Offering advantages the po-
with a knife in order to impose his will, or he can cut a branch off a tentate buys a specific behaviour that is independent in principle
tree directly. The latter process we do not call “power” because no from the behaviour preferred by the subordinate. Only the number
human behaviour is altered, but rather, the tree is directly manipulat- of advantages – the price – will go up in cases where the subordinate
ed by means of the knife. We consider the effects of physical means strongly prefers a specific behaviour. But depending on the sources of
acting upon nature to be important for achieving policy outcomes. the advantages – financial reserves – that the potentate mobilises, he
But these effects are caused by ecologic–technical forces and not by can influence the behaviour according to his will. Such a process
forces within social relationships, which is a precondition for the fulfils the requirements of our power definition even if it might
presence of power in accordance with our definition. Using this dis- seem much more comfortable than the use of physical force. Comfort
tinction we meet the specific goal formulated by our concept, that or discomfort is not a criterion for the presence of power. Comfortable
of distinguishing power from other potential in actors. For example, power might be even more effective in altering behaviour and
an actor who owns a chain saw can influence the forest strongly by overruling the will of subordinates.
M. Krott et al. / Forest Policy and Economics 49 (2014) 34–42 39

Incentives are an important element of economic theory (Starr, subordinate's behaviour without recognising his will. For example, a
1988 p. 171). Economic theory provides significant insights into subordinate receives the information that the tree species B will
how the mechanisms of incentives work. The opportunistic behaviour grow well, he trusts the information, and based on it decides to
of humans can be altered by incentives and sanctions (Eisenhardt, plant tree species B. His will is to plant a well-growing tree but the
1989 p. 63). We do not follow the model of opportunistic behaviour potentate was lying when he promoted tree B, and the subordinate
fully but rather we look at behaviour from the point of view of both has now planted tree B. This he would have never done had he
the potentate and the subordinate. Both have wills that tell them known that tree B would not grow. By supplying erroneous informa-
how to proceed, but the potentate can push his will through because tion trusted by the subordinate, the potentate has altered the behav-
he refers to sources of incentives whereas the subordinate does not iour of the subordinate without recognising his will. In this manner,
have this option. This is not because there is less importance or and according to our definition, power can be based in “dominant in-
lower value attached to his will but because of the lack of sources to formation”, as we call it.
offer incentives. Sources, and not the agreement, will change the Simon (1981 p.155) has drawn attention to power in regard to
behaviour and therefore we recognise this as a power process. unverified information. If the subordinate uses information from the
Even if the subordinate follows the incentive he keeps his own will potentate and does not check it fully, he has become dependent on
in mind. This means that if he were to find greater incentive sources of the potentate. Not checking information can be voluntary or compul-
his own, he would no longer follow the will of the potentate. Economic sory. It is voluntary if the subordinate is guided by his confidence in
theory fully integrates the incentives offered into an overall evaluation the potentate's good will. In the politically important case of ideolog-
by the subordinate. It assumes that the evaluation allows him to add ical discourses the option of withdrawing confidence is small only.
up his own preferences and incentives offered externally within one Ideologies demand from subordinates that they follow key arguments
dimension, resulting in an overall new (opportunistic) preference. In and prevent them from checking the truths of these arguments. They
contrast, the actor-centred power approach relies more strongly on provide a strong basis for dominant information in the interests of the
the actors and their wills. Incentives offered by the potentate are potentate. For example, a core demand of forest ideology is the con-
considered external to the subordinates' will about what to do in the cept that multiple forest management will best serve all forest func-
forest. He may adapt his behaviour but the conflict between the incen- tions for society (Glück, 1987). The ideology makes it difficult to
tives and his prior will remains. This becomes clear in case of disincen- question the links between forest management and timber produc-
tives, like penalties. The subordinate does not agree with penalties tion and other forest functions, like providing biodiversity. The forest
created by the state and therefore will not support them with his ideology creates dominant information about forest management,
will. Nevertheless, he may follow them if the disadvantages are high. providing forest managers and owners with power as consequence.
He has no choice due to the sources of the state, which indicate a For example, Schusser et al. (2013) mention this as a finding of
power process. their community forestry case study in Germany. They refer to the
The main difference between economic theory about incentives case of a field research observation (observation 5), where the re-
and the actor-centred power theory is how the sources of the actors searcher was present during one meeting with the head of the region-
are looked at. Economic theory assumes that the actors' sources are al administration and the local forester and was then present during a
present independently from the specific freedom of decision as to second meeting between the foresters and the members of a commu-
how the sources should be used. The actor-centred power theory as- nity forest. During the first meeting the foresters agreed to give the
sumes that, within a power-free environment, all actors would have members of the community wrong information about the possible
free access to all sources. Limiting the sources of specific actors is a amount of commercially harvestable wood. They did so because
power process and without such limitation the value decision of the they knew about the members' fear that the sale of commercial
actor would be different. Therefore decisions are not only value- wood would limit their firewood harvesting possibilities. According
driven but power-driven as well. to the foresters this would have no influence, but if the amount
As with the case of coercion, the sources of (dis-)incentives make were to appear too high the members of the community forest
the power process more apparent. We discriminate between material would not accept the annual management plan. What they needed
and immaterial (dis-)incentives. Material incentives are money and was the approval. They knew that after this action the harvestable
also all technical sources like machines, plants or food. Even support amount of commercial wood could easily be increased, since nobody
in labour counts as material sources. Immaterial sources are manifold would really understand the figures in the management plan. The ob-
too. They offer social or psychological advantages, like advantages servation was confirmed during the second meeting and the verifica-
grounded in moral demands or triggered by erotic impulses (Olson, tion of the management plan.
1971, p. 61). Morality labels a certain behaviour as being commonly The compulsory abstinence from checking information is even
regarded as right. These resources work as disincentives, like financial more important than the voluntary processes. The subordinate is
cuts for subsidies or declaring certain actions as being detrimental to forced, by lack of direct relevant information or lack of methods or
social convention. sources, to accept the information given to him. Certainly, profession-
By looking at morality or subsidy we integrate structures into the al foresters possess more knowledge on forest management than lay-
model. A considerable part of the rules of the game deals with moral- men, which is what most forest users are. Foresters are experts on
ity or subsidies. The discourse in public and among professionals forests. They have received professional training and have passed sev-
communicates moral demands and demands of public policy to a eral monitored exams. Larson (1977) calls this setup “professional
great extent. The potentate uses statements within the discourse as closure”. The expert knowledge causes a power process because the
sources of power that are, of course, selectively guided by his will. experts are the only ones who can check the information (Freidson,
1986). The forest user has to accept the dominant information be-
4.3. Dominant information cause he is often not able to organise a checking process. He lacks
sources to engage experts who might provide counterarguments, or
Information looks positive and soft when compared to coercion to acquire the educational wherewithal to follow the arguments of
and disincentives. Nevertheless, we identify a power process founded the experts. The findings of Ribot (2001) illustrate the power by
on information and define it as “altering the behaviour of the subordi- dominant information. “The claims of ‘scientific forestry’ manage-
nate by means of unverified information”. If the subordinate does not ment have served to consolidate control by the state over commer-
verify the information received from the potentate and makes a deci- cially valuable natural resources and the profits that flow from
sion based on this information the potentate will have altered the there, and to exclude the majority of rural dwellers and resource
40 M. Krott et al. / Forest Policy and Economics 49 (2014) 34–42

users form such lucrative sources of income”. Despite the negative The restriction on altering the behaviour of the subordinate ex-
outcome for the subordinate, in this case it is worth noting that the cludes all forces from the term “power” which directly influence
power process does not mean that dominant information is always problem-solving, like managing the forest, for example. It ex-
used against the best interests of the subordinate. It might be that cludes all ecologic–technical forces that intervene in the forest.
the forest user gets the right expert advice that helps him. But never- These can be described and explained much better by ecologic–
theless, his behaviour is influenced according to the will of the expert, technical research than by political science. Another important as-
which means that there is a power process underway. pect is that the sources an actor possesses become power only if
In addition, the forest expert could use his superior knowledge to they are used to alter the behaviour of other actors. As long as
select specific information which supports his interests only and they are used to manage the forest only they are considered to
which works against the interests of the forest user. For example, be increasing the actor's ecologic–technical potential. For exam-
the expert is the only one who knows how much timber is in the ple, the access to good soil, machines, fertiliser or plants affect for-
wood and can be harvested. He can inform using the right data or est management to a great degree. Due to the restrictive nature of
he can make a cautious estimate that offers much less timber to the the term “actor-centred power”, ecologic–technical influence can
user. Especially when it comes to biodiversity, expert knowledge is be analysed and optimised without confusing it with the complex
the only way to get the data. Due to the complexity of the subject issue of power.
matter, the subordinate is not able to check information and to ⁎ Actor-centred power is linked to actors in specific issues directly.
make his own decisions. The process of the subordinate checking in- They play the role of potentate or subordinate, depending on
formation offers many opportunities for observation. The sources of their power sources and the specific issue at hand. The most pow-
information of the potentate and the subordinate can be analysed erful actors can be identified by accumulating their roles as poten-
and compared. In all cases in which the potentate is better informed tates. This can be done within the framework of a power network,
and does not deliver the full information to the subordinate, he has distinguishing a group of powerful actors from a group of weak
power. The decision process by the subordinate can be observed ones (Devkota, 2010; Maryudi, 2011). The model does not assume
too. If he neglects to check information due to confidence, lack of that the powerful actors are always most powerful, because in spe-
time, knowledge or whichever other causes, he is exposed to the cific relations they might be forced to the subordinate side. This hy-
power of the potentate (Devkota, 2010). pothesis fits in with many observations where a specific actor is
Despite looking closely at the actors, structures are partly integrat- dominant most of the time but not always or in all relations.
ed into dominant information. The expert discourse and ideologies ⁎ Actor-centred power specifies three elements of the general term
were already mentioned as important structural sources for building “power” (see Table 1). Power is assumed only if the behaviour is
up dominant information. Discourses put the spotlight on only parts altered by force, (dis-)incentives or dominant information. This
of the broader possibilities for dealing with a specific issue (Hajer, specification enables us to separate power from other social rela-
1995). The potentate can refer to the discourse and receive support tions that alter the behaviour of actors. Communication based on
for his selected information as long as the subordinate's attention is verified information is of the greatest importance. If two actors ex-
diverted by the highlighting of tangential portions of the discourse. change information that is checked by both they build up a social
Additionally, actors can provide information, and the network of po- relationship that is the opposite of a power-based relationship.
tential and actual actors delivering information is part of a network This kind of communication constitutes political bargaining in
that can be analysed, relying on actors and covering some structural which both can make informed decisions as long as all information
aspects. is shared. Open bargaining about sources means to offer to the
other actors what they most urgently demand for themselves, at
5. Conclusion: power pinned down to an applicable concept least in part. As we have discussed, we regard (dis-)incentives as
power because the will of the subordinate with regard to his
We developed a theory-based, empirically applicable framework prior sources is neglected by the potentate implementing (dis-)in-
for assessing actor-centred power as a driving force in community centives. For example, the subordinate receives money for plant-
forestry and as a decentralised mode of forest governance. This ing trees as long as he overrules his prior will to plant corn. The
framework was shown to be useful in assessing the presence of differ- amount of the power source of money decides on the choice of
ent empirical forms of power used by political actors. Future research crops, and not the will of the subordinate. The three elements of
should demonstrate its usefulness in other empirical fields of forest power interact in practice. The power process is highly complex,
governance as well. Summing up the actor-centred power approach making the interrelation between the three elements complex
(ACP), we argue that it makes the power factor in community forestry too. We have not yet developed the concept further to cover the
or in other land use issues, which are often blurred, well applicable in interaction in detail. Therefore the analysis is restricted to looking
research and practice. The four specific requirements for a scientific at the three elements separately at this point. It is a highly impor-
concept stated in the beginning of the paper are met by the tant future task to tackle the interrelations of the three elements
actor-centred power approach (ACP) in the following way: theoretically and in empirical research.
⁎ The specified power elements are linked to observable facts (see
⁎ Actor-centred power is specified as a specific social relation dis- Table 1). They include the action of power but also threats and
tinct from other influences that produce outcomes in the forest. sources. The sources of power offer the best opportunity for

Table 1
Definition of core elements and observation and examples of actor-centred power.

Element Definition Observable facts Example

Coercion Altering behaviour Physical action, threat for physical action or Decision based on threat about the removal of forest
by force sources for physical action user rights
(Dis-)incentives Altering behaviour by Providing of, or threat with, sources of material Financial support to carry out a natural resource assessment
(dis-)advantage or immaterial benefit or detriment
Dominant information Altering behaviour by Providing of, or threat with, sources of information Expert knowledge about how to manage forest resources
unverified information unverified due to lack of will or ability sustainably in a participatory community forestry project
M. Krott et al. / Forest Policy and Economics 49 (2014) 34–42 41

collecting empirical data. They are specific and observable, like all Giessen, L., 2010. Regional forest governance — Forstliche Potentiale und politische
Kräfte in der integrierten ländlichen Entwicklung. (Potentials for forestry and po-
kinds of weapons, economic sources or information. litical drivers in integrated rural development policy). Goettingen University Press.
Giessen, L., 2010. Regional Governance für ländliche Räume — innovativer Ansatz,
politischer Gegenwind und der Weg vorwärts. Raumforschung und Raumordnung
The concept of actor-centred power provides a suitable basis for 68 (1), 3–14.
both research and consulting activities. Due to the clear-cut defini- Giessen, L., Kleinschmit, D., Böcher, M., 2009. Between power and legitimacy —
tions and links to observable facts it can be applied in qualitative discourse and expertise in forest and environmental governance. Forest Policy
and Economics vol. 11 (5–6), 452–453.
and quantitative research (Devkota, 2010; Maryudi, 2011; Schusser
Glück, P., 1987. Das Wertesystem der Forstleute. Centralblatt für das gesamte
et al., 2012). The power elements can be identified in forest re- Forstwesen vol. 104, 44–51.
lated politics around the world. Five case studies in community for- Glück, P., Rayner, J., Cashore, B., 2005. Changes in the governance of forest resources.
estry, Nepal (Devkota, 2010), Indonesia (Maryudi, 2011), Namibia In: Mery, G., Alfaro, R., Kanninen, M., Lobovikov, M. (Eds.), Forests in the Global
Balance — Changing Paradigms. IUFRO World Series, Wien, pp. 51–74.
(Schusser, 2012a,b), Germany (Schusser et al., 2013), Cameroon Hajer, M., 1995. The Politics of Environmental Discourse: Ecological Modernization and
(Yufanyi Movuh, 2012; Yufanyi Movuh and Schusser, 2012) have ap- the Policy Process. Oxford University Press.
plied the actor-centred power approach successfully already. Due to Hasanagas, Nicolaos D., 2004. Power Factor Typology through Organisational and
Network Analysis. Ibidem-Verlag, Stuttgart.
the general applicability of the power term, more cases are being Hayek, Friedrich A., 1960. The Constitution of Liberty. University of Chicago Press,
analysed in Africa (e.g., Schusser, 2012a,b; Yufanyi Movuh, 2012; Chicago.
Yufanyi Movuh and Schusser, 2012) and Europe (Schusser et al., Hogl, K., Nordbeck, R., Nußbaumer, E., Pregernig, M., 2008. New Modes of Governance for
Sustainable Forestry in Europe (research report). (http://www.boku.ac.at/GoFOR/).
2012) as well. The aim is a comparative power analysis of community Howlett, M., Rayner, J., Tollefson, C., 2009. From government to governance in forest
forestry. The hope is that the actor-centred power approach (ACP) planning? Lessons from the case of the British Columbia Great Bear Rainforest
might provide the common hypothesis that is required for compara- Initiative. Forest Policy and Economics vol. 11 (5–6), 383–391.
Krott, Max, 1990. Öffentliche Verwaltung im Umweltschutz: Ergebnisse einer
tive research. Finally, a future application of the actor-centred
behördenorientierten Policy-Analyse am Beispiel Waldschutz, Wien.
power approach (ACP) will be to design a checklist to identify the Krott, Max, 2005. Forest Policy Analysis. Springer.
group of powerful actors in specific cases quickly. From the example Krott, Max, 2012. Value and risks of the use of analytical theory in science for forest
policy. In: Arts, B., de Jong, W., Krott, M. (Eds.), Political Theory in Forest Policy
of community forestry we learned that such preliminary information
Science: Forest Policy and Economics, vol. 16, pp. 35–42.
about power would serve well the need for developing concepts for Larson, Mangali Sarfatti, 1977. The Rise of Professionalism (Berkeley).
community forestry in practice. Furthermore, the concept may apply Lukes, Steven, 1974. Power: A Radical View (London).
well to the analysis of other land use issues too. Maryudi, A., 2011. The contesting aspirations in the forest. Actors Interests and Power
in Community Forestry in Java, Indonesia, Universitätsverlag Göttingen.
Maryudi, A., Devkota, R., Schusser, C., Yufanyi, C., Salla, M., Aurenhammer, H.,
References Rotchanaphatharawit, R., Krott, M., 2012. Back to basics: considerations in evaluating
the outcomes of community forestry. Forest Policy and Economics vol. 14 (1), 1–5.
Agrawal, A., Gibson, C., 1999. Enchantment and disenchantment: the role of communi- Medina, G., Pokorny, B., Weigelt, J., 2009. The power of discourse: hard lessons for
ty in natural resource conservation. World Development 27, 629–649. traditional forest communities in the Amazon. Forest Policy and Economics.
Agrawal, A., Chhatre, A., Hardin, R., 2008. Changing governance of the world's forests. vol. 11 (5–6), 392–397.
Science 320, 1460–1462. Modell, S., 2009. In defense of triangulation: a critical realist approach to mixed methods
Arts, B., 2012. Forests policy analysis and theory use: overview and trends. Forest Policy research in management accounting. Management Accounting Research 20, 208–221.
and Economics 16, 7–13. Offe, Claus, 1977. Einleitung. In: Bachrach, Peter, Baratz, Moroton (Eds.), Macht und
Arts, B., Buizer, M., 2009. Forests, discourses, institutions. A discursive-institutional Armut. Frankfurt, pp. 7–34.
analysis of global forest governance. Forest Policy and Economics 11 (5–6), Ojha, H.R., Cameron, J., Kumar, C., 2009. Deliberation or symbolic violence? The governance
340–347. of community forestry in Nepal. Forest Policy and Economics vol. 11 (5–6), 365–374.
Arts, B., van Tatenhove, J., 2004. Policy and power: a conceptual framework between Olson, M., 1971. The Logic of Collective Behavior: Public Goods and the Theory of
the ‘old’ and ‘new’ policy idioms. Policy Sciences vol. 37 (3–4), 339–356. Goods. Harvard.
Arts, B., Visseren-Hamakers, I., 2012. Forest governance: mainstream and critical views. Pérez-Ciera, V., Lovett, J., 2006. Power distribution, the external environment and com-
In: Broekhoven, Guido, Savenije, Herman, von Scheliha, Stefanie (Eds.), Moving mon property forest governance: a local user groups model. Ecological Economics
Forward with Forest Governance. ETFRN News 53, Wageningen, pp. 3–10. vol. 9, 341–352.
Bachrach, P., Baratz, M., 1977. Macht und Armut. Eine theoretisch-empirische Untersuchung, Pettenella, D., Brotto, L., 2012. Governance features for successful REDD+ projects
Frankfurt. organization. Forest Policy and Economics 18, 46–52.
Bemelmans-Videc, Marie-Louise, Rist, Ray C., Vedung, Evert (Eds.), 1998. Carrots, Popitz, Heinrich, 1992. Phänomene der Macht. 2, Stark erw. Aufl. Mohr Siebeck,
sticks, and sermons. Policy Instruments and Their Evaluation, New Jersey. Tübingen.
Discourse and expertise in forest and environmental governance. In: Böcher, M., Giessen, Raab, J., Kenis, P., 2007. Taking stock of policy networks: do they matter? In: Fischer,
L., Kleinschmit, D. (Eds.), Forest Policy and Economics 11 (5–6), 309–458 (149 pp.). Frank, Miller Gerald, J., Sidney, Mara S. (Eds.), Handbook of Public Policy Analysis.
Brockhaus, M., Obidzinski, K., Dermawan, A., Laumonier, Y., Luttrell, C., 2012. An over- CRC Press, Boca Raton, pp. 187–200.
view of forest and land allocation policies in Indonesia: is the current framework Rametsteiner, E., 2009. Governance concepts and their application in forest policy
sufficient to meet the needs of REDD+? Forest Policy and Economics 18, 30–37. initiatives from global to local level. Small-scale Forestry vol. 8 (2), 143–158.
Buttoud, G., 2012. From PES to REDD. Making policy tools and economic mechanisms Ribot, J.C., 2001. Integral local development: “accommodating multiple interests”
interact for a better forest governance. Forest Policy and Economics vol. 18, 1–3. through entrustment and accountable representation. International Journal of
Cashore, B., Stone, M.W., 2012. Can legality verification rescue global forest gover- Agricultural Resources, Governance and Ecology vol. 1 (34), 1–22.
nance? Analyzing the potential of public and private policy intersection to amelio- Scharpf, F.W., 2000. Interaktionsformen: Akteurszentrierter Institutionalismus in der
rate forest challenges in Southeast Asia. Forest Policy and Economics 18, 13–22. Politikforschung. Opladen.
Dahl, R.A., 1957. The concept of power. Behavioral Science vol. 2 (3), 201–215. Schneider, V., 2009. Akteurskonstellationen und netzwerke in der Politikentwicklung.
de Jong, W., Arts, B., Krott, M., 2012. Political theory in forest policy science. In: Arts, B., In: Schubert, K., Bandelow, N.C. (Eds.), Lehrbuch der Politikfeldanalyse 2.0.
de Jong, W., Krott, M. (Eds.), Political theory in forest policy science: Forest Policy Oldenbourg Verlag, München, pp. 191–219.
and Economics, vol. 16, pp. 1–6. Schusser, C., 2012. Who determines biodiversity? An analysis of actors' power and in-
Devkota, R.R., 2010. Interest and Power as Drivers of Community Forestry. Universitätsverlag terests in community forestry in Namibia. Forest Policy and Economics. http://
Göttingen. dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.forpol.2012. 06.005.
Edmunds, D., Wollenberg, E., 2003. Whose devolution is it anyway? Divergent con- Schusser, C., 2012. Community forestry: a Namibian case study. In: Broekhoven, G.,
structions, interests and capacities between the poorest forest users and states. Savenije, H., von Scheliha, S. (Eds.), Moving Forward with Forest Governance.
In: Edmunds, S., Wollenburg, E. (Eds.), Local Forest Management: The Impacts of Trobenbos International, Wageningen, pp. 213–221.
Devolution Policies. Earthscan Publications, pp. 150–165. Schusser, C., Krott, M., Devkota, R., Maryudi, M., Salla, M., Yufanyi Movuh, M.C., 2012.
Eisenhardt, Kathleen M., 1989. Agency theory. An assessment and review. Academy of Sequence design of quantitative and qualitative surveys. Allgemeine Forest und
Management Review 14 (1), 57–74. Jagdzeitung vol. 183 (3/4), 75–83.
Etzioni, A., 1975. A Comparative Analysis of Complex Organizations: On Power, Schusser, C., Krott, M., Logmani, J., 2013. The applicability of the German community
Involvement, and Their Correlates. Free Press, New York. forestry model to developing countries. Forstarchiv 84, 24–29.
Freidson, E., 1986. Professional Powers: A Study of the Institutionalization of Formal Shackleton, S.C., Wollenberg, E., Edmunds, D., 2002. Devolution and community-based
Knowledge. University of Chicago Press, Chicago. natural resource management: creating space for local people to participate and
Giddens, Anthony, 1984. The Constitution of Society: Outline of the Theory of Structur- benefit? Natural Resource Perspectives 76, 1–6.
ation. Polity Press, Cambridge. Sikor, T., Nguyen, T.O., 2007. Why may forest devolution not benefit the rural poor?
Giessen, L., 2009. Regional governance in rural development programmes — which role Forest entitlements in Vietnam's central highlands. World Development vol. 35
for forestry? Folia Forestalia Polonica vol. A-51 (1), 54–60. (11), 2010–2025.
42 M. Krott et al. / Forest Policy and Economics 49 (2014) 34–42

Silva, Eduardo, 1997. The politics of sustainable development. Native forest policy in Werland, S., 2009. Global forest governance — bringing forestry science (back). Forest
Chile, Venezuela, Costa Rica and Mexico. Journal of Latin American Studies vol. 29, Policy and Economics vol. 11 (5–6), 446–451.
457–493. Winkel, G., Sotirov, M., 2011. An obituary for national forest programmes? Analyzing
Simon, Herbert A., 1981. Entscheidungsverhalten in Organisationen. Eine Untersuchung and learning from the strategic use of “new modes of governance” in Germany
von Entscheidungsprozessen in Management und Verwaltung, Landsberg am Lech. and Bulgaria. Forest Policy and Economics 13, 143–154.
Starr, Philip C., 1988. Economics: Principles in Action. Wadsworth Publishing Company, Wollenberg, E., Iwan, R., Limberg, G., Moeliono, M., 2008. Locating social choice in for-
Belmont. est co-management and local governance: the politics of public decision making
Vedung, Evert, 1998. Policy instruments: typologies and theories. In: Bemelmans-Videc, and interests. In: Sikor, T. (Ed.), Public and Private in Natural Resource Gover-
Marie-Louise, Rist, Ray C., Evert, Vedung (Eds.), Carrots, sticks, and sermons. Policy in- nance: A False Dichotomy? Earthscan Research Editions, London, pp. 27–43.
struments and their evaluation. Transaction Publishers, New Jersey, pp. 21–59. Yufanyi Movuh, M.C., 2012. The Colonial heritage and post-Colonial influence, entan-
Weber, Max, 1921. Die Wirtschaft und die gesellschaftliche Ordnungen und Mächte glements and implications of the concept of community forestry by the example
Tübingen. of Cameroon. Forest Policy and Economics 15, 70–77.
Weber, Max, 1972. Die protestantische Ethik. Johannes Winckelmann, München and Yufanyi Movuh, M.C., Schusser, C., 2012. Power, the hidden factor in development co-
Hamburg. operation. An example of community forestry in Cameroon. Open Journal of For-
Weber, Max, 2000. Basic Concepts in Sociology. Citadel Press, New York. estry 2 (4), 240–251.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi