Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 3

Intellectual property and competition act

Intellectual Property (IP) law fosters innovation and creativity by awarding limited monopolies.

Competition law seeks to provide consumer benefit by providing a free and fair market. There is
an inherent tension, when the grantee of the intellectual property right (IPR) monopoly seeks to
engage in abuse of this monopoly. In a landmark consent agreement Google Inc. has agreed to
change some of its busi-

ness practices related to how it dealt with its patented technologies in response to the United
States FTC complaint and subsequent investigations. Companies in the information technology
and telecommunications industries frequently ensure in-teroperability of their products through
voluntary standard setting organizations (SSOs). The SSOs publish technology standards which
encourage adoption of common platforms among rival producers which in turn benefits
consumers by increasing competition, innovation, product quality and choice. Problems arise
when a patented technology is adopted by a SSO as a technology standard. Before a standard is
adopted, several players are competing to get their technology accepted as a standard.
However, once a particular technology is accepted as a standard, most of the other players will
have to necessarily make substantial investments to adopt the standard. This may at times also
include a significant switching cost from their own technology to the standard. Entire industries
may get locked in to a particular technology. If this technology is patented, it gives the patent
holder massive market power and the ability to demand excessive royalties, where the royalties
do not reflect the actual market value of the technology, but the opportunity cost and switching
cost of moving away from the standard technology. The high royalties are eventually passed on
to the end consumers. The increased value that can be extracted by the patentee due to
switching costs on its patents is known as “hold-up value”. Besides harming competition, hold-
up value undermines the entire institution of SSOs and decreases the incentive to participate in
the standard-setting process.It is for this reason, that when SSOs designate a particular
technology as a “standard” it requires the patent holder to license its standard essential patents
(SEPs) on fair, reasonable and non-discrimina-tory (FRAND) terms to any willing licensee, thus
relinquishing its right to exclude a willing licensee from using its patented technology. SSOs
when determining which technology to designate as a standard, take into account if the
patentee is committed to license its SEPs on FRAND terms. If the patentee refuses to license its
patent on FRAND terms, the SSO will not include such a technology in a standard. Google is a
global technology company and through its subsidiary Motorola owns an extensive patent
portfolio including patents that cover technology standards in wireless cellular voice and data
communications, wireless local area LANs and video compression. Google actively participates
in various SSOs and Motorola has been a longstanding member of SSOs. Manufacturers of
mobile phones, tablet computers and other “smart devices” providing internet access such as
gaming systems, laptops, set top boxes must typically comply with one or more of the
technology standards.

The FTC alleged that Motorola, after promising to license its SEPs on FRAND terms, wrongfully
sought injunctions and exclusion orders against willing licensees of its SEPs. Google continued
Motorola’s practice after its acquisition of Motorola in May 2012.

According to the FTC, Motorola/Google enjoyed monopolistic power since the inclusion of
Motorola/Google’s patents in the technology standards eliminated any possible alternatives for
competitors of Google/Motorola. To determine whether a firm enjoys monopolistic power, it is
essential to determine the relevant market where this power is being appraised. According to
FTC the relevant product market in this case was the technology covered by any Google owned
SEP and all substitutes of that technology. Such monopolistic behavior would likely have the
anti-competitive effects such as depriving end-consumers of competing products at lower costs,
undermining efficiency of the standard setting process, raising costs of competitors’ products
and dampening competition. The FTC did not find any pro-competitive benefits or any
justification to outweigh the anti-competitive effects of Google’s con-duct. To remedy this
concern, Google agreed to a Consent order which restricts Google from seeking injunc-tions on
SEPs against potential licensees who are willing to enter into a license on FRAND terms. As a
result, Google is prohibited from seeking injunctions, or obtaining or enforcing existing claims
for injunctive relief, for FRAND-encumbered SEPs.

On the other side of the Atlantic, the European Commission has opened a formal investigation
against Samsung and Motorola to assess whether the companies have used certain of its SEPs
to distort competition abusively and in contravention of a commitment to an SSO. This case
highlights the inherent tension between Competition law and Intellectual Property law and is an
instance where antitrust law steps in when social welfare is at risk due to the conduct of the
intellectual property holder. Also, this case highlights the international and cross border effects
of an-titrust/ competition law. It has been a constant leitmotif of most investigations and
prosecutions, that when one company or a particular industry is investigated in one jurisdiction,
chances are that similar investigations will also commence in other jurisdictions across the
globe.

Aamir Khan Productions Pvt. Ltd. v. Union of India 59 is a landmark judgment delivered by the
Bombay High Court wherein the Court while dealing with a matter pertaining to the issue of IPR
held that CCI has the jurisdiction to deal with all cases concerning competition law and IPR. In
Kingfisher v. Competition Commission of India60 also, the Court reiterated that the CCI is
competent to deal with all the issues that come before the Copyright Board. Such cases
enumerate the fact that the Indian Courts are ready for dealing with emerging cases of
competition law involving IPR.
In the case of FICCI Multiplex Association of India v. United Producers/Distributors Forum
(UPDF),the petitioner (FICCI) filed a complaint against the UPDF alleging the formation of
market cartels in the film industry. This was deliberately done by UPDF to boost their revenue,
and thus, it had refused to strike deal with the multiplex owners. This has direct and drastic
effect on the multiplexes as their business is wholly dependent on the film industry.

Consequently, this resulted in anti-competitive practice of refusal to deal leading to distortion of


competition adversely for gaining profits. Further, defendants held 100 per cent share in the
industry and thus indulging in limitation of supply of films in the market qualifies as an anti-
competitive practice. It qualified as a violation of S. 3(3) the Competition Act too. The parties on
delivery of the show cause notice filed a petition in Bombay High Court on the pretext of lack of
jurisdiction of CCI to decide a matter pertaining to IPR. The Court citing S. 3(5) of the
Competition Act 2002 read with S. 3(1) held that the latter section cannot curtail the right to
sue for infringement under IPR, and further CCI has jurisdiction to entertain all matters that can
be presented before the Copyright Board.

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi