Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 13

See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.

net/publication/311855879

Status of Electricity Act, 2003: A systematic review of literature

Article  in  Energy Policy · March 2017


DOI: 10.1016/j.enpol.2016.12.001

CITATIONS READS

2 4,115

3 authors, including:

Shilpi Mukherjee Dr. Tarun Dhingra

2 PUBLICATIONS   2 CITATIONS   
University of Petroleum & Energy Studies
46 PUBLICATIONS   88 CITATIONS   
SEE PROFILE
SEE PROFILE

Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:

Port performance of India View project

Asset maintenance policy formulation and practice in a large gas utility of India View project

All content following this page was uploaded by Shilpi Mukherjee on 27 October 2017.

The user has requested enhancement of the downloaded file.


Energy Policy 102 (2017) 237–248

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Energy Policy
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol

Status of Electricity Act, 2003: A systematic review of literature MARK


a b,⁎ c
Shilpi Mukherjee , Tarun Dhingra , Anirban Sengupta
a
Department of Power Management CoMES, UPES, Dehradun, Uttarakhand, India
b
Department of Strategic Management CoMES, UPES, Dehradun, Uttarakhand, India
c
Dean, CoMES, UPES, Dehradun, Uttarakhand, India

A R T I C L E I N F O A BS T RAC T

Keywords: The Electricity Act 2003 was a landmark Act which promised to remove the maladies which afflict the Indian
Electricity Act 2003 Power Sector and that too at a time when the sector was ridden with problems. With concepts such as open
Indian Power Sector access, multiple distribution licensees, wheeling of electricity etc, the said Act intended to encourage
Systematic Literature Review competition which in turn was meant bring a paradigm shift in the sector. The paper undertakes a systematic
Reform
literature review to find the status of review of the promising Act. More than a decade has passed since its
Restructuring
enactment and amendments are due with the legislative body of India but none of the literature reviewed gives a
comprehensive view encompassing all the objectives of the Act. Moreover, these documents study either the
probable impact or the impact on a particular segment only. It has important implications for the Power sector
which highlights a significant gap in literature and provides a basis on which future research can be built upon.

1. Introduction national plan outlay (Sharma et al., 2005). With energy deficit of 8.8%
and peak deficit of 12.2%, the power supply position in the country was
no better than 1991 when the reform and restructuring started. The
lack of investment was further deteriorating the operational inefficien-
“One of the great mistakes is to judge policies and programmes by
cies and hindered capacity addition. Initiatives like delicensing of
their intentions rather than their results.”
generation and IPP (Independent Power Producers) amendment, to
- Milton Friedman
encourage private investment, had done little to improve the scenario.
The Electricity Act 2003 (EA 2003 or the Act) was the ray of hope The foreign investors were apprehensive after the Enron debacle. But a
for the ailing electricity sector of India. It intended to change the massive 1,00,000 MW was required within a decade to meet the
fundamentals of the sector, bringing in competition and making it demand which amounted to doubling the installed capacity added in
viable. There were huge expectations from the Act, whose number and the last half century, requiring an investment of Rs 8,00,000 crores
reach was unprecedented in the history of Indian power sector (Reineberg, 2006).
development (Ranganathan and Rao, 2004; Singh, 2006). The Act It was against the backdrop of such dire conditions that the EA
aimed at restructuring the complete industry, making it technically and 2003 was enacted. Many like Bhattacharyya (2005) questioned its
financially viable. However, reforms did not yield successful results capacity to transform the Indian Power Sector while others like
every time (Sioshansi, 2006). The intention of the Act was welcomed Godbole (2003) questioned the wisdom and highlighted a number of
but with a concern (Singh, 2010). issues that were likely to pose problems. Reineberg (2006) quoted it as
Availability of electrical energy is one of the accelerating factors for “The most important piece of legislation to become law…. to meet the
improving the quality of life & the economic growth of the country. But challenges of 21st century”. He explicitly says that the Act is aimed at
the operational and financial inefficiencies of the State Electricity rectifying the financial conditions of the SEBs which were hindering the
Boards (SEBs), which were constituted for the development of the growth of the electricity sector.
electricity industry, had plagued the economic growth of the country. But even after a decade of its enactment, the energy deficit is 2.1%
These vertically integrated monopolies, which were responsible for with peak deficit at 3.2% and AT & C (Aggregate Technical &
providing electricity to the people, were in a precarious financial Commercial) losses of 25.38% every year (CEA, 2015, 2013; CERC,
condition with payment dues exceeding Rs 41,000 crores (Ministry of 2016). With blackouts and brownouts a common occurrence in many
Power, 2003). This is in spite of the substantial share of 13–18% of the parts of India, quality power a distant dream and 75 million house-


Corresponding author.
E-mail addresses: shilpi.mjee@gmail.com (S. Mukherjee), replytarun@gmail.com (T. Dhingra), asengupta@ddn.upes.ac.in (A. Sengupta).

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2016.12.001
Received 13 April 2016; Received in revised form 17 October 2016; Accepted 1 December 2016
0301-4215/ © 2016 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
S. Mukherjee et al. Energy Policy 102 (2017) 237–248

holds without access to electricity, per capita consumption far below installed capacity, transmission network and distribution to various
the world average, we need to assess whether EA 2003 has been areas across the length & breadth of the country. But over a period
successful in its endeavour or not. The progress of the Act, if any, also time, a number of problems surfaced. The SEBs became financially sick
needs to be ascertained before planning further. and ridden with huge debts. The cumulative amount due to the various
We, thus, need to know the present status of the landmark Act and agencies, from SEBs, exceeded Rs 41,000 crores, seriously impacting
the milestones achieved in order to plan further improvements for the the borrowing capacities of these SEBs (Ministry of Power, 2014;
sector because planned reforms may not produce their intended results Ministry of Power, 2003). The demand supply gap was huge. The
in developing countries (Zhang and Parker, 2006). quality as well as quantity of power was poor. The vote bank politics
This paper, thus, proposes the following research questions: compelled the tariff to be kept artificially low for the agricultural sector
RQ: What is the status of review of the Electricity Act 2003? which prevented the rationalisation of tariff (Joseph, 2010). The power
‘Status’ can be defined as 'the situation at a particular time during a sector of India was crying for reforms. Reforms and restructuring
process'. The authors investigate the reviews of the EA 2003 carried out became the need of the hour.
by other researchers and any other authority or agency in order to The foundation for reforms was created in the 1990s with Private
ascertain the progress made in attaining the objectives of the Act, i.e, Sector Participation being encouraged in Generation (Historical
the “Status” of the Act through all published documents inclusive of Background, n.d.), PTC (Power Trading Corporation) being created
research papers and grey literature. A systematic review of literature for Power Trading and various other initiatives. The last foundation
will help us to synthesize the existing knowledge on review of the EA stone was the Electricity Regulatory Commission Act 1998 (ERC Act
2003. 1998), the sole purpose of which was to distance the Government from
Section 2 describes the evolution of Indian Power Sector. Section 3 Tariff Determination. According to the ERC Act, Central Electricity
elaborates the methodology followed in this paper while Section 4 Regulatory Commission (CERC) was set up at the central level and
discusses the results obtained. The authors discuss the Research State Electricity Regulatory Commission (SERC) at the state level to
Question in Section 5, in view of the results obtained. Section 6 gives determine the tariff and formulate regulations for the power sector.
a glimpse of the present scenario of the sector. The authors present the The first attempt for a comprehensive Act was made in the year
concluding remarks in Section 7. 2000. But it was only in the year 2003, after lots of discussions, debates
and modifications, that the Electricity Act received President’s ascent
on May 26, 2003, published in the official gazette on 2nd June 2003
2. Evolution of Indian Power Sector
and became effective from 10th June 2003, i.e., (Electricity Act, 2003;
Chatterjee, 2012; Bhattacharyya, 2005; Thakur et al., 2005).
India has come a long way since its first commercial hydro power
All previous Acts, i.e., IEA 1910, ESA 1948 and ERC Act 1998 were
station in 1897. The journey has been shown in Fig 1.
repealed. The EA 2003 was a consolidated Act – it consolidates the
Pre- independence, i.e., before 1947, electricity generation and
Laws relating to generation, transmission, distribution, trading and use
supply was concentrated in the hands of private electricity suppliers
of electricity. The preamble of EA 2003 explicitly says:
and largely in urban areas. In order to regulate the generation, supply
and use of electricity, the first legislation enacted was the Electricity Act “An Act to consolidate the laws relating to generation, transmission,
of 1887, which was subsequently replaced by Indian Electricity Act distribution, trading and use of electricity and generally for taking
1903 (IEA 1903). The IEA 1903 was clearly recognized to be a measures conducive to development of electricity industry, promot-
somewhat tentative measure and many practical, electro-technical & ing competition therein, protecting interest of consumers and
commercial difficulties were realized during the period 1903–1909. supply of electricity to all areas, rationalisation of electricity tariff,
The IEA 1903 was repealed & re-enacted with necessary modifications ensuring transparent policies regarding subsidies, promotion of
as the Indian Electricity Act, 1910 (IEA 1910) (Indian Electricity Act, efficient and environmentally benign policies, constitution of
1910) (IEA 1910 (with Short Notes), 1910). Central Electricity Authority, Regulatory Commissions and estab-
The IEA 1910 provided the basic framework for supply and use of lishment of Appellate Tribunal and for matters connected therewith
electrical energy. The sector, being at a nascent stage, required huge or incidental thereto.”
investments which were envisaged to be fulfilled by private licensees.
The objectives of the EA 2003 may, thus, be segregated as follows:
Generating plants were built near metropolitan cities like Calcutta
(renamed Kolkata) and Bombay (renamed Mumbai).
i. To consolidate the laws relating to generation, transmission,
With Independence, the priorities changed and electrification was
distribution, trading and use of electricity
planned to be extended across the length and breadth of the country.
ii. For taking measures conducive to development of electricity
The Electricity Supply Act 1948, based on the UK Electricity Supply Act
industry,
1926, mandated the creation of SEBs in every state and Central
iii. For promoting competition
Electricity Authority (CEA) at the central level (Regultory and Policy
iv. Protecting interest of consumers
Environment, n.d.).
v. Supply of electricity to all areas,
There was substantial growth in the power sector, in terms of
vi. Rationalisation of electricity tariff
vii. Ensuring transparent policies regarding subsidies
viii. Promotion of efficient and environmentally benign policies
ix. Constitution of Central Electricity Authority, Regulatory
Commissions and establishment of Appellate Tribunal

The EA 2003 resulted in a complete overhaul of the power sector of


India. The results expected were revolutionary. With unbundling of
SEBs, privatisation of generation & distribution companies, corpor-
atisation, open access, multiple licensees etc., there was a complete
restructuring of the Indian power sector. There was a provision of
choice of suppliers for consumers. The Act attempted to create a multi
buyer, multi seller model. Power trading was given a distinct identity
Fig. 1. Evolution of Indian Power Sector (not to scale). and power exchanges were established. Appellate Tribunal was set up

238
S. Mukherjee et al. Energy Policy 102 (2017) 237–248

to hear appeals against the decisions of CERC and SERCs. impact of EA 2003. The initial search revealed 824 scholarly and peer
reviewed articles but after removing duplicity, the number of articles
3. Methodology reduced to 176 in Stage 2. Most of these were from Energy Policy
enlisted in Science Direct. The other two prominent journals were The
3.1. Systematic review of literature Electricity and EPW which are a part of Science Direct and Jstor
respectively.
Systematic review of literature has been undertaken in this paper, In stage 3, all the articles which had just a passing mention of EA
with a thoroughgoing study of the EA 2003 and the power sector of 2003 were excluded. As the Act brought a paradigm shift the power
India. In a systematic review, all articles pertaining to a particular sector structure and functioning, most of the papers about the power
research question are collected and analysed. It helps to keep the sector of India referred to it. 91 such articles were found and removed
review unbiased and transparent. It’s exhaustive and not as haphazard further pruning the number of articles to 85.
as traditional review (Bryman, 2012; Choong, 2013; Shephard, et al., In order to have a complete picture, a web search was conducted for
2006). non-peer reviewed journals, reports and other grey literature. 18 such
The scope and purpose of this review are defined with the help of documents were found to be relevant and were, thus, included in the
research question which helps to seek out the relevant studies. Further list. Thus, in stage 4, the total number of relevant articles increased to
appraisal of the studies is conducted by applying inclusion and 103.
exclusion criteria. The resultant studies are reviewed and analysed In stage 5, the articles were further filtered based upon the content.
which leads to the synthesis of the results (Bryman, 2012). 91 articles which did not discuss about EA 2003 in detail were
excluded. Although no document explicitly tells us the impact of EA
3.2. Question formulation 2003 on the power sector of India, articles which mention even a part
of it have been retained.
The research questions are formulated based on the researcher’s Finally, after all the inclusions and exclusions, 19 articles were
intent to know the status of review of the EA 2003 a decade after its found to be of substantial value for the research. The researchers
enactment. believes that a vast majority of articles and relevant documents,
RQ: What is the status of review of the Electricity Act 2003? although it might not be an exhaustive one, were reviewed which
The RQ requires us to review the studies on EA 2003 in totality would ascertain the present status of EA 2003 and its impact on the
including an in depth study of the various objectives outlined in the power sector of India.
Act. All articles and other published documents need to be reviewed In the sixth stage, the articles are categorized based on the theme as
pertaining to the research question following the steps of systematic it would be the most appropriate method for this paper. Each selected
review outlined above. article was thoroughly read and analysed by the author for its relevance
to the topic. Although no document discusses the progress in attaining
3.3. Article search procedure the objectives or the impact of EA 2003 explicitly, the researcher makes
a thoroughgoing study of the selected documents. The articles were
Articles were searched from the electronic databases of EBSCO, classified, by the author, into relevant categories, i.e.
Science Direct, Jstor and Emerald with the procedure of systematic
review (Matthews and Marzec, 2012; Choong, 2013; Pino et al., 2007). A. Review/Analysis of the Act with/without suggestions
A detailed study was also undertaken for the regulatory framework of This includes the papers where the author/s have reviewed and/
India, encompassing the EA 2003, CERC Regulations and other policy or analysed any part or the complete Act with/ without suggestions.
documents (reports) pertaining to the power sector of India. Apart B. Impact of the Act
from that, ‘grey literature’ such as reports, conference proceedings etc.
was also explored as its importance was emphasised by Bryman (2012) This category of papers includes those which discuss the actual
and Petticrew and Roberts (2006). impact of any part or the complete Act. None of these papers review the
The search was conducted across the selected databases with the Act as a whole; hence, partial analysis of the impact of the Act on any
following terms: ‘electricity act 2003’, ‘electricity act India’, ‘power segment of the Indian Power Sector has been included.
sector India’, ‘power sector reforms’ and ‘restructuring power sector’. These selected articles would help the author to arrive at a
The terms power and electricity were interchanged so as to obtain an conclusion so as to the present status of EA 2003 and its impact on
exhaustive list of articles as shown in Table 1. Articles were searched the power sector of India.
from 2003–2015 as the said Act, whose progress and impact needed to
be studied, was enacted in June 2003. The articles where the search 4. Results and Discussion
terms coincided with the keywords or the title were considered as
otherwise any paper even briefly mentioning about the power sector of The selected articles exhibit the present status of EA 2003 to
India would include the above mentioned search term(s) and that varying degrees and in a non-comprehensive manner. Hence, the
would increase the total number of articles to an enormous 32178 out author discusses the articles and other documents, as shown in
of which very few would be actually focusing on the progress and/or Table 2, systematically based on these two categories.

Table 1
Summary of systematic review process (adapted from Choong 2013).

Stage 1 Stage 2 Stage 3 Stage 4 Stage 5 Stage 6

Identify databases Identify search terms Exclusion analysis Internet search Identify Relevant articles Categorize articles

Key Results Key Results Key Results Key Results Key Results Key Results
• Databases (4) • All articles found (824) • Total articles removed • Websites (18) • Total articles removed (91) • Categorize relevant
• Journals (16) • Non Duplicate Articles (91) • Total number of relevant • Total number of relevant articles into themes
found (176) • Total number of relevant
articles becomes 85
articles increases to 103 articles reduced to (19)

239
Table 2
Categorization of the selected papers.

Sl No Title Author/s Central Argument A B

1 Electricity Act, 2003: Questionable Wisdom Godbole (2003) The paper highlights a number of issues in the EA 2003 which deserved closer attention & might pose
S. Mukherjee et al.


problems in future. Unbundling of SEBs as promoted by World Bank should be a selective approach rather
than a mantra and no final date has been set for the abolition of SEBs. The Act gives an impression that the
subject of electricity is in the Central List instead of the Concurrent List. The financial implications of captive
generation, Open Access and other provisions need to be reconsidered so that the burden on state budget is
sustainable. Multiple Distribution Licences would be necessary in the long run but introducing it at this stage
might slow down the pace of privatisation. Most importantly, the Act should not remain on paper only.
2 Electricity Act 2003: Moving to a Competitive Environment Ranganathan (2004) The author discusses the major aspects of EA 2003- its aim to introduce competition in generation and ✓
privatize distribution. But the Act leaves many issues unattended in the journey of the power sector towards a
competitive environment. Discussion of issues such as impact of surcharge, definition of cross subsidy,
exactness of transmission loss and cost figures, regulatory risk in case of year to year tariff and metering of
agricultural consumers has been undertaken by the author as the areas of concern.
3 Electricity Act, 2003: Agenda for Review Rejikumar (2004) This article brings forth a few issues that need to be addressed during the review of EA 2003. It questions the ✓
universal approach of unbundling & privatisation stating examples where the reverse was true. It discusses
the emerging trends in reform of utilities in other countries and lays emphasis on the Ivorian model in west
Africa. It specifies the sections of the Act that needs to be amended. Eg: Section 19 & 20 can lead to litigation
and JERC (Joint Electricity Regulatory Commission) should be made mandatory for smaller states according
to section 83.
4 Power Sector Reforms in India Ranganathan and Rao (2004) This Round Table proceeding, consisting of excerpts from the papers and presentations at the workshop, takes ✓
stock of the reform efforts leading up to the Electricity Act and raises many salient concerns that merit
attention in the next phase of reforms. The participants highlighted the importance of public sector
investment, the steps taken by Ministry of Power as correctives, Delhi privatisation experience, Karnataka
distribution privatisation, requirement for accountability of regulator, agricultural tariff, trading and open
access.

240
5 Power Sector Reforms in Bajaj (2004) This Round Table proceeding brings forth various areas of lacunae that have not been addressed by the EA ✓
India: Regulatory Issues 2003 and the various steps that need to be taken for proper functioning of the ERCs. Eg: Cross subsidy should
be defined, Regulators should be made accountable and judicial functioning of regulation should be
consultative.
6 Electricity Act 2003: dark Shadows over a bright vision Sankar (2004) EA 2003 presents a bold and beautiful picture for the future of Indian Power Sector but certain controversial ✓
provisions regarding open access, cross subsidy & surcharge need to be clarified or modified or removed in
order to prevent legal tangles and uphold the spirit of the Act. The term surcharge needs to be defined in
quantifiable terms. The author opines that multiple distribution licensee would lead to cherry-picking by the
second licensee and can be mitigated by an informal ‘surcharge equalization procedure’ adjusted at the end of
the year. Moreover, the MYT (Multi Year Tariff) can reduce the ‘regulatory risk’ or ‘regulatory uncertainty’ and
encourage investments.
7 What's new in India's Energy sector? Joshi (2004) The two major developments in India’s Energy Sector have been discussed, one of which is the enactment and ✓
enforcement of EA 2003. But for the impact to actualize, transmission grids need to be expanded, suitable
mechanism formulated for agricultural subsidy to be politically acceptable and economically supportable,
political will for reduction of distribution loss (theft) and proper formulation and enforcement of regulations
at central and state level will have to be taken into consideration.
8 Impact assessment of the Electricity Act 2003 on the Indian power sector Thakur et al., (2005) Various provisions of the Electricity Act 2003 and its likely impacts on different segments of the country’s ✓
power sector have been discussed. The Act leaves certain policy issues unresolved like network pricing
complexities, mechanism of pricing till open access is allowed, settlement complexities in case of cash
shortage, transmission bottlenecks negating open access, environmental concerns and restructuring policies.
The Act has partially addressed issues such as market dominance of few dominant generators and mechanism
for preventing sharp trading prices. The deregulated regime and liberalization will benefit consumers in the
long run. It might increase the cost for the low tension consumers in the short term because of cross subsidy. It
will take time for liberalization and open access to reap benefits but a strict time table should be maintained
for implementation.
9 The Electricity Act 2003: Will it transform the Indian power sector? Bhattacharyya (2005) This paper reviews the Electricity Act 2003 and analyses its ability to transform the Indian Power Sector. The ✓
Act makes entry into generation and captive generation relatively easier and seeks to create a multi buyer,
multi seller system. Gencos and Discoms might reintegrate. Open Access would facilitate IPPs in generation.
The regulatory framework envisaged in the Act is termed credible by the author. The flexibility in tariff
(continued on next page)
Energy Policy 102 (2017) 237–248
Table 2 (continued)

Sl No Title Author/s Central Argument A B

determination and MYT Regime have been provided by the Act but the tariff making process would still be a
challenging one because of cross subsidies. The author predicts that the discoms would suffer due to unviable
S. Mukherjee et al.

tariff as increasing the tariff of “residential and other low voltage consumers would remain a politically
sensitive issue.” The Act does not require the selection of regulators to be transparent which might give rise to
political manipulations. The Govt’s say in the use of funds might also be used to hinder the regulatory
independence.
10 Power sector reform in India: Current issues and prospects Singh (2006) The steps taken for Indian Power Sector Reforms from 1991 to 2004 have been discussed in this paper. ✓
Regulatory reforms gave rise to tariff rationalisation, transparency and consumer participation. Multiple
Licensees and open access holds promise for increasing competition in the sector but the transition has to be
managed very carefully, balancing between social obligations and commercial goals.
11 India’s Electricity Sector in Transition: Can Its Giant Goals Be Met? Reineberg (2006) This paper discusses the political, regulatory and economic scenario of India w.r.t. power sector and the giant ✓
goals it has set for itself. The doubts of the author are aggravated because to reform the power sector of India,
huge investments are required but global investors are apprehensive after the Enron debacle. The EA
2003attempts to introduce competition in the sector. Being the eighth most indebted nation, financing such
massive improvements might be difficult but the World Bank providing a loan of $9 billion might instil
confidence of the investors.
12 Sustainability of power sector reform in India: what does recent Bhattacharyya (2007) This paper presents a systematic approach to analyse the sustainability of the reform model and the ✓ ✓
experience suggest? experience in implementing it. It argues that the reforms to date have not produced desirable political,
economic, financial, social or environmental outcomes. Private investment is elusive and demand supply gap
is yet to be bridged. Reformed utilities have also not performed well. The “imported ideas” have not yielded
expected results and “locally accepted solutions” might provide us with a sustainable reform. Moreover,
political stability is required to instil confidence of private investors.
13 Jurisdictional Limits of Electricity Regulatory Commissions Shah (2007) The author studies almost 36 case laws of appeals before the Appellate Tribunal under Section 110 of the ✓ ✓
Electricity Act which helps to determine the jurisdictional limit of the Regulatory Commissions. E.g.: It cannot
interfere in the internal management of the licensees; it is of the same statute as the commissions and thus has
no authority to examine the validity of the regulations framed by the commissions and many other limits of the

241
Appellate Tribunal.

14 The Politics of Power: Electricity Reform in India Joseph (2010) The paper discusses the role of Politics in changing the electricity scenario of India and how political parties ✓ ✓
are unable to push through the reform process successfully.
But a dual track economy where the industrial customers are being lured with captive generation and open
access and adopting reforms that have little or no impact on the rural and agricultural consumers ensure the
support of both the constituencies. The industrial consumer’s decision to exit is in direct response to the
poor quality of power rather than the price. The author anticipates that this partial reform might further
cripple the rural power sector. The author questions the effectiveness of this strategy in improving the
conditions of Indian power sector and in realizing the goal of ‘Power for all by 2012′.
15 Current status and analysis of renewable promotional policies in Indian Singh and Sood (2011) The current policies are reviewed for its effect on renewable energy in the country. Although RE programmes ✓ ✓
restructured power sector—A review have been in existence more than three decades, the commercial demand is still low. Consumer desired
features in design and sales package, usage in distributed generation, being a part of regulatory framework,
incorporation into development programmes, encouraging private participation and industry collaboration in
R & D, integration with liberalization of energy markets and other measures have been suggested by the author
based on the analysis of various policies in order to develop the RE Technologies at a faster rate.
16 Towards a competitive market for electricity and consumer choice in the Singh (2010) The provisions of the EA 2003 are necessary but not sufficient condition for competition. Short term ✓ ✓
Indian power sector challenges in the Indian power market are technological efficiency and financial performance while in the long
term, efficient price discovery and cost effective choice to consumers should be accomplished. Competition in
wholesale market would improve the efficiency and reduce the cost of generation while in retail market, it may
offer greater array of products. It would be beneficial for the Regulatory institutions to prepare a roadmap for
increasing competition in the long term. Transitionary issues like open access will remain.
17 Analysis of competition and market power in the wholesale electricity Shukla and Thampy (2011) This paper analyses the market structure and competitiveness in Wholesale Electricity Market in India and ✓ ✓
market in India found that Indian Electricity Market in India is not concentrated except in eastern and north eastern regions.
Divestiture of generating facilities, adequate transmission capacity, fixing the maximum price cap, reducing
the demand supply gap would increase the competition in the wholesale power market of India.
18 More Power to India Pargal and Banerjee (2014) This report reviews the Indian Power Sector since EA 2003 with a focus on distribution. It analyses the ✓
multiple sources of weakness in distribution and shows that multiple stakeholders need to play their role to
improve the scenario. The Central Government needs to fine tune their strategies, lenders have to show due
(continued on next page)
Energy Policy 102 (2017) 237–248
S. Mukherjee et al. Energy Policy 102 (2017) 237–248


B
A 4.1. Category A: Review/Analysis of the Act

Most of these papers, reviews the EA 2003, focusing on the gaps not

This report published by Central Electricity Authority provides the progress of the reform measures state wise
in accordance with EA 2003. It includes Regulatory Measures, Protection of Consumer interests and quality
monitoring and proper data collection are also crucial for the improvement of the power sector. Corporate
addressed by the Act along with suggestions for improving the Act.
diligence and regulators need to fulfil their mandates in a transparent and accountable manner. Timely

Some authors have reviewed the Electricity Act 2003 emphasizing


the ambitious nature of the Act while some term it as too ambitious
(Reineberg, 2006; Godbole, 2003; Bhattacharyya, 2005). Some of the
articles give a critical analysis of the Act along with the objectives,
features, how it plans to change the power sector of India and the
issues that it has left unattended (Thakur et al., 2005). It encourages
competition by attempting to create a multi buyer multi seller model
and promotes competition through de-licensing of generation, open
access in transmission, recognizing ‘trading’ as a distinct activity and
multiple licensing in distribution (Electricity Act, 2003). Bajaj (2004)
remarks that some lacunae or confusion still exist in the Act.

4.1.1. Consolidation of Laws


The EA 2003 repealed all the previous Acts, i. e., IEA 1910, ESA
1948 and ERC Act 1998. The ERC Act 1998 started the process of
distancing the Government from regulations which finally culminated
in the EA 2003. It has a holistic approach in restructuring and
Governance would also help state utilities.

reforming the power sector of India (Chatterjee, 2012). While genera-


tion has been dealt in Section 7–11, the provisions for transmission
have been consolidated in Section 25–41 of the Act. Similarly, Section
42–60 details out the provisions related to distribution. The laws,
related to trading and use of electricity, have also been explicitly
mentioned in the Act (Electricity Act, 2003). Hence, the EA 2003 has
Central Argument

successfully consolidated the laws relating to all the concerned


sections, i.e., generation, transmission, distribution, trading and use
of electricity.
standards.

4.1.2. Unbundling/ Restructuring and Privatisation of SEBs


Most of the authors are apprehensive of unbundling/ restructuring
and privatisation of SEBs but would prefer a selective approach rather
Central Electricity Authority

than a mantra for reforms. They suggest that some of the best run
electricity utilities in the world are still vertically integrated and the
private sector does not have the capability to take over the entire
electricity business from the SEBs even in the next two decades as there
are very few private organisations which are resourceful enough to take
Author/s

over and manage distribution business efficiently. Moreover, private


(2014)

entities can participate in generation as well as distribution but that


would mean denying a level playing field to SEBs as they would
compulsorily have to be unbundled (Rejikumar, 2004; Godbole, 2003).
Bhattacharyya (2005) was apprehensive that some states that have
Status of implementation of progress of reforms under Electricity Act

good centre state relationship might delay the restructuring procedure.

4.1.3. Reform measures


Some of the authors are sceptical of India fulfilling its power sector
goals. Reineberg (2006) highlights the investment that would be
required for the “Giant Goals” which might be difficult after the
Enron debacle while Bhattacharyya (2005) questions the ability of
the Act to transform the Indian Power Sector. Thakur et al (2005)
suggests fixing up a timeframe and adhering to a strict timetable for the
success of policy initiatives.
The authors agree that the EA 2003 has the potential for bringing
about sweeping reforms in the electricity sector of India (Godbole,
2003) leading to “deepening of reforms” (Singh, 2010) and a “phase
shift in the reform process”. They feel that the Act would provide the
essential impetus to the distribution sector (Singh, 2006).
Some of the authors emphasise the need for political stability for
Table 2 (continued)

reform characterised by privatisation as well as locally acceptable


Title

2003

solutions rather than the imported ones (Bhattacharyya, 2007). They


also bring forth the fact that it was the allurement of external sources of
finance like World Bank, Asian Development Bank etc. that were
Sl No

19

causing the reforms rather than the conviction that reforming would
improve the sector (Godbole, 2003).

242
S. Mukherjee et al. Energy Policy 102 (2017) 237–248

Apart from a few loopholes and challenges, they agree that the EA correct economic signals and help in developing the power market in
2003 has the potential to reform the Indian Power Sector. the country and relieve congestion.
The authors highlight loopholes like computation of loss percen-
4.1.4. Renewable energy tages and suggest steps to be taken to alleviate transmission bottle-
The authors review that the Act lays special emphasis on promotion necks.
of renewable sources of energy and assigns the responsibility to the
respective SERCs (Singh and Sood, 2011). They also highlight the fact 4.1.7. Open Access
that the Act envisages a National Policy with distributed generation for Vadra (2012) opines that non-discriminatory open access would be
rural electrification and no license would be required for generation required for the creation of power market. Some of the authors have a
and distribution in rural areas which would give a boost to Renewable view that open access would help captive generators wherein the
Energy (Thakur et al., 2005). generating stations can be built at substantial distances for the point
of intended use, even in another state (Joshi, 2004) and enable
4.1.5. Generation optimum utilization of the under-utilized captive generation capacity
The authors remark that delicensing of generation (except hydro- (Singh, 2010).
electric projects) would reduce the administrative hurdles for the While Singh (2006) anticipates an increase in tariff, Thakur et al
potential investors (Sharma et al., 2013; Singh, 2006; Thakur et al., (2005) foresees a reduction in the price of electricity, after an initial
2005) which would in turn be beneficial for the generation segment. upsurge, but more than a decade would be required for it.
The authors find that the Act has eased the entry barriers for The other reviewers predict that implementation of open access
Captive Power Plants (Thakur et al., 2005) and has been defined quite would be tough and no time frame has been specified by the Act for
liberally (Ranganathan, 2004). Even the industries have responded allowing the same (Thakur et al., 2005). Open access can be successful
quite positively to it (Ranganathan, 2004). They also find that it might only if transparency is ensured in trading of power (Rejikumar, 2004).
reduce the energy shortage and create a bulk market thereby increasing Moreover, introduction of open access might be politically postponed
competition (Joshi, 2004; Joseph, 2010; Bhattacharyya, 2005). being left to the SERCs (Ranganathan, 2004).
But these advantages are accompanied by some challenges and The biggest hurdle, according to the papers reviewed, in the
loopholes. The author (Bhattacharyya, 2005) anticipates that the bias successful implementation of open access is the cross subsidy sur-
of the Act towards captive power generation over IPPs might have charge which hinders the very purpose of open access- promoting
adverse repercussions on the stability of the grid. Suitable regulations competition (Sankar, 2004; Rejikumar, 2004; Ranganathan, 2004). HT
by the SERCs would be required for supporting captive power plants consumer desirous of availing open access will have to pay the cross
(Joshi, 2004). Moreover, states like Karnataka have levied taxes on it subsidy surcharge even if he is not using the state network (Sankar,
neutralizing the advantage for the industries (Ranganathan, 2004). The 2004). Moreover, cross subsidy surcharge has to be paid by subsidizing
author (Godbole, 2003) states that 16 states levied State Electricity as well as subsidized consumers. This rationale that subsidized
Duty (SED) but is apprehensive of more states charging the same or consumers would not opt out cannot be warranted as they might do
increasing the rates in the prevalent states for captive or other private so because of other factors like quality, etc (Ranganathan, 2004). The
power generators which would hinder the very purpose of liberalizing nuances like the component of transmission charge, whether it should
captive power plants. be based on average cost, marginal cost or congestion cost should be
The Act, thus, promotes Captive Power Plants but needs to fill up a properly ruled out for successful implementation of open access as
few loopholes to achieve the goal. Delicensing has also been a welcome changing these variables will significantly change the ‘surcharge’ but
step in generation. the Act does not specify as to how the ‘surcharge’ would be determined
(Sankar, 2004) (Ranganathan, 2004).
4.1.6. Transmission Most of the authors agree that open access is crucial for competition
The Act, according to the reviews, brought clarity into the operation in the sector but there are numerous obstacles in its successful
and management as the transmission activities have been separated implementation.
from trading activities. The author appreciates the measure that a
separate Government company would act as the system operator 4.1.8. Distribution
(Bhattacharyya, 2005). The improvement in the distribution segment of the power sector is
The challenges and loopholes in the transmission segment have crucial to the long term and sustained growth of the power sector
been highlighted by few of the authors. The transmission grids need to (Singh, 2006). The Act provides a positive environment to the
be expanded and upgraded to enable the concepts of open access, distribution sector which would increase competition in the medium
power trading and wheeling (Joshi, 2004). One of the major objectives to long term and would reach a stage where discoms would have to
of the Act was to introduce competition which is being hindered due to devise strategies to retain customers (Thakur et al., 2005).
transmission congestion, which in turn, can give rise to localized One of the authors (Joseph, 2010) highlight the scenario that power
market power by creating isolated geographic markets, distorting tariff remains unchanged, hardly any meters have been installed and
competition. It might adversely affect the grid discipline also (Shukla power theft continues to plague the sector.
and Thampy, 2011; Singh, 2006; Singh, 2010). Bhattacharyya (2005) The authors agree that multiple distribution licensees would be
and Thakur et al (2005) focuses on the need for capacity addition in the necessary in the long run in order to promote competition but
transmission sector while one of the authors (Singh, 2010) suggest implementing it in the current conditions might adversely affect the
tradable transmission rights in order to alleviate transmission conges- privatisation initiatives (Godbole, 2003; Bhattacharyya, 2005). It could
tion. give rise to the problem of ‘cherry-picking’ wherein the distribution
The author warns of inefficient use of the transmission and licensees would choose the high paying industrial customers over the
distribution infrastructure due to isolated networks of the captive others adversely affecting the cross subsidy balance. It should be
operators (Bhattacharyya, 2005). Also, the standard definitions of loss resolved by the national tariff policy so that no licensee can take undue
percentages need to be defined by the Act to prevent its misuse or advantage of the provision (Sankar, 2004).
manipulation. The figures of T & D loss reduction can be easily fudged Segregation of distribution and supply would be necessary although
otherwise (Ranganathan, 2004). Singh (2010) suggests changing the the Act does not have provisions for the same (Bhattacharyya, 2005).
transmission pricing from regional postage stamp method to a pricing The possibility of relaxation in metering for specific areas or specific
regime based on nodal or zonal pricing scheme which would provide class of consumers might defeat the purpose of mandatory metering.

243
S. Mukherjee et al. Energy Policy 102 (2017) 237–248

The author suggests the use of pre-paid meters (Bhattacharyya, 2005). 4.1.11. Competition
Bhattacharya (2005) states that the procedure for supply discon- It was the EA 2003 that brought competition to the forefront and
nection (for default in payment) has been made simpler in the Act. This “ushered in a competitive era” through open access, multiple licensees
would benefit the power utilities and prevent further revenue losses of and various other provisions (Shukla and Thampy, 2011; Singh, 2010,
the discoms. 2006). CERC, constituted by the EA 2003, provided the regulatory
Distribution is the weakest link in the power sector and as per the framework for Open Access, Indian Electricity Grid Code, Availability
reviews lot of effort would be required to remove the maladies and Based Tariff and Power Exchanges which are essential for imbibing
progress. competition (Shukla and Thampy, 2011). The single buyer model has
been done away with, providing the generators with an option to sell
4.1.9. Consumer Protection their power to multiple buyers. It also set the stage for opening up of a
The Act lays special emphasis on protecting the consumers through power exchange increasing competition further (Singh, 2010).
various provisions and the authors are positive in their reviews. The author warns of the pitfalls in the competitive bidding process
The authors (Thakur et al., 2005) expect improvement in customer which might make it counterproductive resulting in a scenario worse
services due to the increase in competition. Shah (2007) highlights the than cost plus regime. The cross subsidy surcharge and additional
right of the consumer to approach other adjudicating authorities apart surcharge would keep distorting competition until they are eliminated
from ERCs according to Section 42(8) of the Act. (Singh, 2010).
The authors bring to light the loopholes in the Act. They say that the
4.1.10. Tariff Act provides for retail competition but does not provide any timeline
Resolution of the issues related to tariff is vital for the ailing power for the same (Bhattacharyya, 2005). Also, it does not provide for the
sector of India. Bhattacharyya (2005) is sceptical because similar tariff creation a liquid spot market for power although it does not prevent the
guidelines existed before the enactment of EA 2003 but were not creation of the same (Bhattacharyya, 2005; Ranganathan, 2004).
successful in increasing the financial viability of the sector while
Thakur et al (2005) is hopeful that cessation of SEBS would lead to 4.1.12. Financial aspects
market determined tariff structure. Joshi (2004) suggests devising a Most of the authors are quite hopeful on the positive impact of the
suitable mechanism which would be viable, both politically as well as Act on the financial aspects. Thakur et al (2005) expects huge
economically. investments and Singh (2006) expects the financial condition of the
There are various schools of thought regarding cross subsidy. Some power sector to improve with gradual reduction in the cross-subsidy
authors such as Godbole (2003) highlight the fact that agricultural and increase in the operational and commercial efficiency. Sankar
subsidies are prevalent in USA and some other developed countries (2004) says that investment in the generation and distribution sector
while the World Bank insists on eliminating it in India. Sankar (2004) are likely. Joshi (2004) suggests tailor-made financial instruments for
also feels that the poor consumers can be spared from this ‘tariff-shock’ financing the electricity sector along with suitable financial and
and suggests a mechanism for the same. Contrastingly, Bhattacharyya commodities regulator. Sankar (2004) assures that delicensing of
(2007) opines that free electricity to farmers does more harm than generation will not hinder future investments in the generation sector
good. Hence, a solution should be provided for low ROI and risk but provide a strong basis for new investments.
protection mechanisms devised for the farmers. The reviewer also states that a balance between commercial goals
Rationalisation of electricity tariff is one of the core objectives of the and social obligations would be difficult but essential (Singh, 2006).
EA 2003. Reducing the level of cross subsidy would help in rationalisa-
tion of tariff. This would increase the tariff for the subsidized 4.1.13. CEA
consumers which in turn would keep the demand for electricity in The highly controversial Enron power project raised a question on
check. But it might also result in excess generation capacity in some the independence of CEA, which is still an advisor to the Government,
areas (Bhattacharyya, 2005). CERC and SERCs. The author is suspicious of the decisions pro-
The amount of cross subsidy has also been declining over the years, nounced by the Authority (Godbole, 2003).
from 41.7% in 1992-93 to 16.7% in 2000-01. The exodus of the
commercial and industrial consumers will put the burden of subsidy on 4.1.14. Electricity Regulatory Commissions (ERCs)
the state exchequer. It is also not clear how long would the state The ERCs have been said to be the pillars for the power sector
government share the load of risks and subsidies as the Act does not lay reform as envisaged by the EA 2003 (Shah, 2007). The manner, in
down a definite timeframe for abolition of cross subsidies (Godbole, which the Act would be implemented, according to Joshi (2004), will
2003) (Thakur et al., 2005). depend on the regulations framed by CERC and SERCs.
Some authors have suggested solution to the problem. The ERCs were formed to distance the Government from regulatory
Ranganathan and Rao (2004) suggest cost-of-service based rates that functions but the facts, as stated by the authors, say otherwise. The
would help in eliminating subsidies and generation capacities allocated authors say that the selection process is highly bureaucratic and non-
by contract to consumer segments would improve the financial viability transparent, being prone to political influences. Moreover, the policies
of the SEBs. They found that power priced at average cost of provision and regulations need to align with the directives of the Government
would not be viable for farmers. The cost-of-service based rates of which might prove as a hindrance to the main purpose of distancing the
power supplied to the farmers wouldn’t be as high as the average two entities (Bhattacharyya, 2005; Sankar, 2004). Thakur et al (2005)
consumer because of the supply at off peak periods. Thus, uninter- states “the Act makes electricity regulators subservient to the govern-
rupted power would ultimately reduce the cost of supply. Joshi (2004) ments that appoints, renews their term, making them vulnerable to
suggests small scale captive power plants in order to reduce the burden political pressures” and hopes that they would be regulated by an
of agricultural sector on the distribution entities. independent forum. Bhattacharyya (2005) opines that fund mechanism
The other loopholes and challenges, with regard to cross subsidy, should not hinder the financial independence of the state commissions.
have been itemized by other authors. Cross subsidy, not being defined The issues between the Govt and ERCs are unresolved even after
in the Act, might create confusion in cross subsidy surcharge and thus, the Act (Bajaj, 2004; Ranganathan and Rao, 2004; Shah, 2007). The
should be defined in the national tariff policy (Bajaj, 2004; Singh, Act surprisingly says that the Govt. can give policy directives to the
2006). The promotion of rural electrification, liberalization of captive Commissions in matters of tariff determination that might jeopardize
power plants and the mission of electricity for all by 2012 would the very purpose of it (Ranganathan, 2004). Moreover, no time frame
further aggravate the problem (Bhattacharyya, 2007). has been specified for the transfer of functions from the Government to

244
S. Mukherjee et al. Energy Policy 102 (2017) 237–248

the regulators (Thakur et al., 2005). (2004) bilateral trade with open access would be a better option. They
Shah (2007) states that the commission needs specific guidelines. expect low liquidity in the market till the migration of prevailing
The jurisdiction of ERCs are not clear in the Act. The SERCs are contracts to the market which would help in generating negawatts. The
required to follow some guidelines made by CERC which could restrict authors suggest increasing the transmission capacity, divestiture of
the autonomy of the former. generating facilities, fixing the maximum price and reducing the
Godbole (2003) states that political approvals have more risk of shortage of electricity generation (Shukla and Thampy, 2011).
being disowned than regulatory contracts. Regulatory Contract ap- Reducing the license period of 25 years for inducing flexibility and
proach may have serious consequences and thus, should be adapted to liquidity of the power trading market and promoting long term
Indian conditions (Godbole, 2003). contracts is also suggested (Rejikumar, 2004; Bhattacharyya, 2005).
Bajaj (2004) suggests a consumer body to balance the forces Singh (2006) says that liquidity and efficiency along with a complete set
between utilities and consumers in the regulatory arena and conduct of products would be necessary for a competitive power market in
a Regulatory Impact Analysis (RIA) to filter out regulations that have India.
more cost than benefits. Moreover, rather than pronouncing judge-
ments as in adversarial position as in courts, a consultative process 4.1.18. Environmental concerns
would be better. The Act recognizes environmental concerns as one of its objectives
but does not specify the policy directives for it. The authors are afraid
4.1.15. Rural Electrification and Rural markets that it might take a backseat and be dependent on individual regulators
Electrifying the rural areas has been one of the prime considera- for taking appropriate steps (Thakur et al., 2005).
tions of the EA 2003. The authors foresee that the rural electrification
programme would be expedited as the Appropriate Government would 4.2. Category B: Impact of the Act
be obliged to do so by the Act (Thakur et al., 2005).
The Act says that one does not require license to generate and The number of papers, in this category, is extremely few which
supply power in specific rural areas but market structure is not show that very few authors have studied the actual impact of the Act.
specified for the same. It would probably benefit the rural population, Even amongst them, only prominent topics such as renewable energy,
encourage innovative arrangements and promote decentralized gen- competition and the likes have been researched upon (Shukla and
eration but some issues like consumer protection against monopoly of Thampy, 2011; Singh, 2010). Although none of the papers study the
suppliers and poor quality of power remain unanswered in such complete impact of the Act, a World Bank Report and a CEA Report
context (Bhattacharyya, 2007, 2005). presents the information to some extent (Central Electricity Authority,
2014; Pargal and Banerjee, 2014).
4.1.16. Electricity Theft
Theft of electricity has been a major concern causing revenue losses. 4.2.1. Renewable sources of generation
Joshi (2004) says that political will would be required to enforce the The authors bring to light that SERCs have devised various schemes
penal provisions in the Act. Another author reviews that the provisions and policies in order to promote renewable energy. One of them is
regarding electricity theft are stricter than the previous Acts but does Renewable Portfolio Standards (RPS/RPO) mandating each state to
not provide protection to the consumer in case of its misuse by generate/ procure a percentage of its electricity from renewable
suppliers or licensees. Moreover, the transaction cost of appealing in sources. The author highlights that more than 17 states have an-
the Appellate Tribunal is too high (Bhattacharyya, 2005). nounced the policies for attracting private sector investment for
Some of the authors also highlight the fact that the two categories renewable sources. The policies for wind power development have
‘dishonest use’ and ‘unauthorized use’ have not been distinguished been declared by the ERCs of Andhra Pradesh, Madhya Pradesh,
clearly and are left at the discretion of the assessing officer Karnataka and Maharashtra (Singh and Sood, 2011).
(Bhattacharyya, 2005) (Rejikumar, 2004). Although, the initial set up of manufacturing base alongwith
infrastructure has been created, commercial demand for these tech-
4.1.17. Power Market nologies is still low (Singh and Sood, 2011).
Power market is a necessary component for increasing competition. According to these reviews, steps are being taken to promote
Some authors opine that delicensing of generation, non-discriminatory renewable energy but not at a great pace.
open access, giving trading a distinct identity, constituting ERCs and
multiple licensees would help in developing the power market and 4.2.2. Subsidy issues
create a competitive environment in the sector (Singh, 2006; Shukla The EA 2003, according to Bhattacharyya (2007), tightened the
and Thampy, 2011; Thakur et al., 2005) while some say that open provision for subsidies but the re-introduction of free power for
access and pricing rules for the state transmission systems are the agriculture in some states like Andhra Pradesh, Maharashtra, Tamil
actual enablers for open trading environment (Ranganathan and Rao, Nadu and Haryana deteriorated the situation 2004 onwards. Singh
2004). Consumers would have choice of supplier and reliable supply at (2010) says that Cross Subsidy Surcharge and Additional Surcharge
a competitive tariff. It would change the present single-buyer model to distort competition. Therefore, subsidy issues are still prevalent after
multi-buyer model (Thakur et al., 2005), promoting bulk power market the implementation of the Act.
and allowing large consumers to choose their suppliers (Singh, 2010).
Bhattacharyya (2005) states that recognizing trading as a separate 4.2.3. Distribution
activity is a step in the right direction but functions of traders have not The author states that distribution reforms would not yield proper
been described explicitly. The author expects minimum licensing results, even with increase in tariff, unless strict actions are taken to
requirements, for traders, being a potentially competitive activity and curb theft and all categories of consumers are metered. He posits that
anticipates that PTC would remain a dominant player adversely theft of power is also disguised as subsidized power which cannot be
affecting competition in the segment. verified in the absence of meters (Joseph, 2010). A World Bank Report
The papers also highlight that spot markets can lead to price specifies the need for improvement in the distribution sector with
increases and volatility due to scarcity of supply (Ranganathan and regard to finances, rising gap between cost and revenue, issue of
Rao, 2004). The Act does not address these issues or have mechanisms subsidies etc. It also says that Government’s role should be limited
to prevent the same (Thakur et al., 2005). It would hinder competition while regulator’s role should be increased. It suggests increasing
(Shukla and Thampy, 2011). So, according to Ranganathan and Rao competition that would in turn, increase the efficiencies of the utilities

245
S. Mukherjee et al. Energy Policy 102 (2017) 237–248

(Pargal and Banerjee, 2014). Mukherjee et al. (2016) reviews the Act based on the Core
In essence, the Act has not been able to improve the distribution Indicators for electricity sector reform in developing countries but
sector to an extent it was expected to. comprises of “Sector Endowments and Characteristics” and “Key
Reform Steps” only.
4.2.4. Trading
Trading has received special emphasis with the EA 2003. Quite a 4.2.8. Competition
few players have entered the traders market and according to Singh One of the prime agenda of the Act has been to introduce
(2010), CERC had issued 19 inter-state trading licences and fixed the competition in the sector. Singh (2010) says that competitive bidding
margin for trading power. In spite of such huge efforts, between Aug of inter-state generation projects and short term competitive procure-
2008 and Oct 2009, a meagre 7.8% of the total power generated was ment of power is being carried out but the absence of foreign investors
traded out of which 0.7% was through power exchanges garnering 8.5% from these bidding processes (except as equipment manufacturers) is a
of the power market (51.5% Bilateral Transactions and 40% UI). The matter of concern. The author further illustrates that only states like
growth of power trading is being hindered by lack of generation margin Gujarat have been able to choose their suppliers through open access
and number of operational and regulatory concerns like shortage of while states like Tamil Nadu, West Bengal and Orissa, have kept the
transmission capacity, open access regulations and liquidity concerns open access charges unreasonably high which proves to be a major
(Singh, 2010). obstacle.
According to Shukla and Thampy (2011), the power exchanges
could neither decrease the price of electricity nor its volatility. The
5. RQ: What is the status of review of the Electricity Act
weighted average price of electricity increased more than three times
2003?
between 2004‐05 to 2008‐09 and the upper ceiling of UI (Unscheduled
Interchange) by more than two times between 2001 and 2009.
A systematic review and thorough study of the selected papers show
Singh (2010) animadverts that regulatory framework did not favour
that none of these give a complete review of the actual impact of the
the short term transactions of electricity. Priority of transmission rights
Act. In spite of extensive search and review, the researcher does not
follows the order- existing long-term contracts, long-term open access
find the status of the landmark Act. Some of them give the likely impact
contracts and then the short-term open access contracts according to
on various segments of the power sector while some review a certain
the orders issued by ERCs. Congestion charge of Rs 3/kWh had to be
segment only, such as competition or renewable generation. Most of
paid because of the congestion in the inter-regional transmission links
the papers had to be grouped in category A which comprises of the
of Northern and Eastern region as imposed by CERC.
papers reviewing the probable impact of the Act on the Power Sector.
The papers in Category B review the actual impact but do not give a
4.2.5. Open Access
comprehensive review. The review comprises of a part only, such as,
Open access is an essential component of the EA 2003. The SERCs
renewable policies or competition. Few of them like Pargal and
have issued regulations for phased open access in the distribution
Banerjee (2014) and CEA (2014) gives the status to some extent but
network in their respective states depending on the size of the load. But
none of them give a comprehensive one, encompassing all the
quite a few states have kept the cross subsidy surcharge very high
objectives of the Act. The former review is with respect to the initial
which adversely affects open access (Singh, 2010).
reforms commencing 1991 and focuses on distribution while the latter
covers a part of the objectives of the Act.
4.2.6. Electricity Regulatory Commissions
Therefore, we can say that the literature is insufficient to answer
Bajaj (2004) says that the two positive effects of regulatory
this question and needs further studies.
commissions has been transparency and consumer awareness while
Joseph (2010) opines that most of the regulatory agencies are
ineffective. Measures have to be undertaken in order to achieve the 6. Glimpse of present scenario of power sector
goal for which these commissions were established.
The author brings forth various cases where the ERCs, as estab- Table 3 gives a glimpse of the present scenario of the power sector
lished by the Act, have pronounced decisions beyond its jurisdictional
boundaries (Shah, 2007). So, the jurisdictional boundary of the ERCs Table 3
Technical and financial parameters for indian power sector.
needs to be explicitly defined in order to prevent such cases in future. Sources: (Ministry of Power, 2016; Power Finance Corporation Ltd, 2015; Power Finance
Corporation Ltd, 2016).
4.2.7. Reform measures
The reform has been termed as ‘‘Partial Reform” by Joseph (2010), Parameters Present Status
creating a competitive electricity market along with a state run Installed Capacity 288664.97 MW (as on 29th Feb 2016)
segment. State utilities could not finance the necessary infrastructural Generation 1102 BU (2015–16)
improvements adversely affecting the quality of power which is of a Energy Deficit 2.1% (2015–16)
prime concern for the industrial consumers. These consumers are Peak Deficit 3.2% (2015–16)
Per Capita Consumption 1010a (2014–15)
compelled to set up captive power plants because of inconsistent and
T & D Losses 21.46% (2013–14)
unreliable power supply, rather than the price of electricity. It could be AT & C Losses 22.58% (2013–14)
termed as a dual track economy which protected the interests of the PLF of Thermal Power Stations 64.5% (2014–15)
industrial as well as the agricultural consumers. It created a competi- Rural Electrification 579012 (96.91%) (as on 1st Apr 2015)
tive market for power but did not jeopardize the vote bank of the Book Losses (Accrual Basis) Rs 63,355 (2014–15)
Losses (Accrual Basis) as %age of 15.9% (2014–15)
politicians. Such partial reforms and subsidy issues prevail even after Revenue
the enactment of the Act preventing the improvement in quality of Outstanding Loans of Utilities Rs 6,73,057 crore (as on 31st Mar
power (Joseph, 2010). 2015)
CEA (2014) compiles the status of few of the steps as envisioned in Net Worth of Power Utilities Rs 2,43,023 crore (as on 31st Mar
2015)
the EA 2003 like unbundling of SEBs, setting up of Consumer
Average Cost of Supply (ACS) Rs 5.20/kWh (2014–15)
Grievance Redressal Forum, appointment of Ombudsman etc state Gap on Subsidy Received Basis Rs 0.60/ kWh (2014–15)
wise but it neither covers all the objectives of the Act nor does it give a
a
comprehensive picture. Provisional.

246
S. Mukherjee et al. Energy Policy 102 (2017) 237–248

expatiating Key Financial & Technical Parameters. While the installed face legal actions if it does not provide connection within a month of
capacity, power supply scenario & Rural Electrification registers application or fails to meet the required standards as prescribed by the
significant growth, the technical parameters such as T & D Act or ERCs. The Act formalizes the procedure for grievances redressal
(Transmission & Distribution) losses & PLF (Plant Load Factor) mechanism of the consumer/s through Consumer Grievance Redressal
show little progress. The energy deficit and peak deficit respectively, Forum constituted by the Distribution Licensee. In case of non-
has reduced from 7.1% and 11.2% in 2003-04 to 2.1% and 3.2% in redressal of the grievance/ dispute, the consumer may approach the
2015–16 (Ministry of Power, 2004a, 2004b; Ministry of Power, 2016). Ombudsman (appointed by SERCs). Other provisions such as payment
Per capita consumption has almost doubled but lags far behind the of interest on security deposit etc. have also been provided to safeguard
world average necessitating further effort in this regard. The financial the interest of consumers (The Electricity Act, 2003). Appellate
parameters are also not very encouraging either. But electricity is one Tribunal (Aptel) has been constituted, with circuit benches in Delhi,
of the three sectors which has contributed to the recovery of the Kolkata, Mumbai and Chennai, according to the Act, to hear appeals
industrial sector in 2014-15 (April- Dec) (KPMG , 2015). against the orders of the CERC/ SERCs (Ministry of Power, 2004a,
Competition has, undoubtedly, received a boost as intended by the 2004b; Ministry of Power, 2012). As on 30th Nov 2015, Aptel has
Act. Generation, which had increased from 1362 MW in 1947 to disposed-off 6149 out of 7002 appeals/ petitions/ matters etc (Ministry
126238.98 MW in 2003-04 increased significantly to 288664.97 in of Power, 2016). The initiatives, as well as the results, on consumer
2015-16 (Ministry of Power, 2016; Ministry of Power, 2015). protection front are thus significant.
Delicensing of generation (except Hydro power plants) has removed The amount of cross subsidy given to domestic and agricultural
the barrier for entry of firms into generation which has yielded good sector has increased from Rs 40,362 crore in 2001-02 (AP) to Rs
results. During the period from 2006‐07 to 2015‐16, share of state 1,07,437 crore in 2013-14 (AP) while the cross subsidy received from
sector in the total installed generation capacity declined from 56% to subsidizing sectors has increased from Rs 5743.55 crore in 2001-02
34% and share of central sector has declined from 32–25%, while share (AP) to Rs 27,427 crore in 2013–14 (AP). The ratio of Average Billing
of private sector increased from 13% to 41%. However, the public Rate (ABR) to Average Cost of Supply (ACoS), as calculated by most
sector continues to be the largest owner, holding 59% share in 2015– SERCs, increased from 67.79% in 2001-02(AP) to 80.26% in 2011-12
16 (CERC, 2016). Transmission Sector as on 31st Mar 2016 has 21 (Actual) and 88.43% in 2013-14 (AP) for Domestic and Agricultural
licensees (CERC, 2016) while the count of Discoms is 36 including 14 consumers (PricewaterhouseCoopers Private Ltd., 2015; Planning
Private ones (Central Electricity Authority, Power for All Monitoring Commission, Power and Energy Division, 2002; Planning
Division, 2016). The Act has, thus, been able to attract private Commission, Power and Energy Division, 2014). The Act and the
investment considerably in generation and to some extent in distribu- Policies suggest it to lie within ± 20% of the ACoS, and gradually reflect
tion while transmission is mainly with the public sector. Tariff based Cost of Supply (CoS) rather than ACoS. Thus, we find that, although the
competitive bidding and automatic approval with 100% FDI in gen- amount of cross subsidy has increased, the percentage of ABR to ACoS
eration, transmission, distribution & trading has further enhanced reflect that it is decreasing over the years moving towards a cost
competition (Ministry of Power, 2016). reflective price and tariff rationalisation.
The growth in revenue from sale of energy in the state power sector The new regime of governance has initiated some path-breaking
increased from Rs 1,38,508 cr in 2007-08 to Rs 3,29,278 crores in initiatives in power, coal and renewable energy segments. "Presently,
2013-14 (Power Finance Corporation Ltd, 2015; Power Finance under 'one nation, one grid, one frequency', the Available Transfer
Corporation Ltd, 2010). As of now, there are two power exchanges Capacity (ATC) of southern Indian states such as Andhra Pradesh,
(IEX and PXIL), 40 Inter-state Trading Licensees (as in March 2016), Karnataka, Kerala, Tamil Nadu, Telangana and Puducherry has
short term power trading increased by 75% from 65.90 BU in 2009-10 increased by 71% to 5900 MW from 3450 MW in 2013–14. The price
to 115.23 BU in 2015-16, presently 10% of total electricity generated of power in the southern region, which used to be as high as Rs 16-Rs
which was 2.16% in 2004-05 is traded short term at competitive prices. 18 a unit, is not more than Rs 4–5 now. Usually, power is available
Giving a distinct identity to power trading has further increased under Rs 3/kWh and with the launch of Vidyut Pravah, energy deficit
competition. The weighted average price of electricity transacted & peak deficit have touched the lowest level ever. The Financial
through traders and power exchanges respectively declined from Rs Restructuring Scheme for DISCOMs—UDAY (Ujwal DISCOM
7.29/kWh and Rs 7.49/kWh in 2008-09 to Rs 4.11/kWh and Rs 2.72/ Assurance Yojana) intends to turnaround the ailing distribution
kWh respectively in 2015–16 (CERC, 2016). companies for which bonds of Rs 1Lakh crore have already been
CERC has formulated Indian Electricity Grid Code (IEGC) and issued. State Specific Action Plans for “24×7 Power For All” states and
Deviation Settlement Regulations, amending it from time to time, in union territories is also being considered. Coal production has in-
order to maintain grid discipline. The permissible frequency range has creased by 7.4cr tonnes & all power plants had more than 25 days coal
been tightened from 49.0 - 50.5 Hz in 2003 to 49.70 - 50.10 Hz in 2016 stock (as on 26 April 2016) which had earlier reduced to 7 days or less
(as in July 2016) . The maximum & minimum frequency in 2015-16 for as many as two third of the coal based thermal power plants. Apart
was 50.32 and 49.64 Hz respectively with the average being 49.98 Hz. from conventional sources, largest ever wind capacity addition of
POSOCO, the Central Transmission Utility of India, has deployed Wide 3,300 MW (2015-16) has been established while solar has increased
Area Measurement Systems (WAMS) through synchro phasor technol- by 157% since 2014. 11, 209 MW of solar projects have been awarded
ogy since May 2010 to monitor the small signal oscillations in order to while 32 solar parks 19,400 MW have been sanctioned in 20 states. Rs
further the cause of grid stability (Power System Operation Corporation 38000 cr Green Energy Corridor is being set up to evacuate renewable
Ltd, 2016). One of the largest synchronous grids suffered blackouts in energy. Rural Electrification is also being carried out in full swing,
2012 but natural disasters such as earthquake in Nepal region in April electrifying 7108 villages in 2015-16 and a target to electrify the
2015, Hindu Kush region in October 2015 and North Eastern part of remaining 18,452 by 2019 in order to achieve complete electrification
India in January 2016 have not seen any such adverse effect on the of all rural villages and hamlets (K, 2016; Airy, Energy Infra Post,
grid. National Power Committee (NPC) has also been established to 2016; Airy, Business Insider, 2016).
address issues related to security & reliability of the Grid (Ministry of If we try to ascertain the success of the Act on the systemic
Power, 2013). We are yet to have a highly stable grid but the stability configuration, rather than the variables impacting the Act, we find
has improved over the years and is expected to improve further with that the centre & state have come together on various aspects such as
the efforts being put in. UDAY (wherein 18 states and 1 union territory already signed
Consumer Protection has been emphasised in the EA 2003. agreements or have agreed to join) and State Specific Action Plans
Accordingly, the Distribution Licensee would have to pay penalty or for 24×7 ‘Power For All’ schemes (already signed with 19 states and

247
S. Mukherjee et al. Energy Policy 102 (2017) 237–248

union territories) (Airy, Energy Infra Post, 2016). Matthews, R.L., Marzec, P.E., 2012. Social capital, a theory for operations management:
a systematic review of the evidence. Int. J. Prod. Res..
The Electricity Amendment Bill 2014 proposes to segregate the Ministry of Power, 2003. Annual Report 2002-03. Ministry of Power, New Delhi.
‘carriage’ and ‘content’ of the distribution segment of power sector Ministry of Power, 2004a. Ministry of Power – Annual Report 2003-04.
which would eliminate the chances of inefficient use of T & D networks Ministry of Power, 2004b. Notification: Appellate Tribunal for Electricity. Retrieved from
Appellate Tribunal for Electricity: 〈http://aptel.gov.in/pdf/N1.pdf〉.
as warned by some authors. At present, no such evidence of inefficient Ministry of Power, 2012. Notifications: Appellate Tribunal for Electricity. Retrieved from
use is available as there are only three cases of multiple licensees in Appellate Tribunal for Electricity: 〈http://aptel.gov.in/pdf/notification_15052012.
India (Mumbai, Noida & New Delhi) (Singh, 2016). Moreover, pdf〉.
Ministry of Power, 2013. Establishment of National Power Committee. Order –
wheeling of electricity, in practice, would also prevent such occur- Establishment of National Power Committee (Mar 25). Ministry of Power,
rences. Government of India, New Delhi, India.
Ministry of Power, 2014. Annual Report 2013-14. Ministry of Power, New Delhi.
Ministry of Power, 2015. Growth of Electricity Sectorin India from 1947 to 2015.
7. Conclusion
Ministry Of Power. Government of India, Ministry of Power, Central Electricity
Authority, New Delhi.
EA 2003 was a landmark Act affecting every segment of the power Ministry of Power, 2016. Annual Report 2015-16. New Delhi: ministry of Power.
sector. Each and every reviewed paper acknowledges this fact. In spite Government of India.
Mukherjee, S., Dhingra, T., Sengupta, A., 2016. Electricity Act 2003: Review of Select
of having such a massive scope and being an Act which promised a Indicators. International Conference on Management of Infrastructure, (pp. E 212–
paradigm shift in the Indian Power Sector, there are very few papers E 229). Dehradun.
which review it. An extensive search could only find 19 documents, Pargal, S., Banerjee, S.G., 2014. More Power to India. World Bank.
Petticrew, M., Roberts, H., 2006. Systematic Reviews in Social Sciences. Blackwell
including research articles, reports and round table proceedings. Publishing.
Even these documents were insufficient to comprehensively review Pino, F.J., García, F., Piattini, M., 2007. Software process improvement in small and
the Act as most of them discussed the probable impact and not the medium software enterprises: a systematic review. Softw. Qual. J..
Planning Commission, Power & Energy Division, 2002. Annual Report – Working of
actual one. The remaining ones, which empirically analysed the impact State Electricity Boards & Electricity Departments. Planning Commission, Power &
of the Act, were on a specific segment such as competition or renewable Energy Division.
energy. Hence, we do not find the status of all the objectives of the Act. Planning Commission, Power & Energy Division, 2014. Annual Report – Working of
State Power Utilities & Electricity Departments. Planning Commission.
Moreover, most of these have been published by 2006 and thus, do not
Power Finance Corporation Ltd, 2010. Performance of State Power Utilities for the years
study the impact of the Act after a considerable period of time. 2007-08 to 2009-10. Power Finance Corporation Ltd..
Amendments to the Act are due to be approved in the legislative Power Finance Corporation Ltd, 2015. The Performance of State Power Utilities for the
years 2011-12 to 2013-14. Power Finance Corporation Ltd..
bodies but we do not have any comprehensive account as to the actual
Power System Operation Corporation Ltd, 2016. Report on Low Frequency Oscillation In
status of the Act, i. e., to what extent the Act has been successful in its Indian Power System. Power System Operation Corporation Ltd., New Delhi.
endeavour, that is based on empirical data or some indicators for the PricewaterhouseCoopers Private Ltd, 2015. Report on roadmap for reduction in cross
specific purpose. A comprehensive review, so as to know the status of subsidy. Forum Regul..
Ranganathan, V., 2004. Electricity act 2003: moving to a competitive environment. Econ.
the landmark Act, needs further research and can be a further scope of Political Wkly..
study. Ranganathan, V., Rao, N.D., 2004. Power sector reforms in India. (March)IIMB Manag.
Rev..
Regultory & Policy Environment. (n.d.). Retrieved April 11, 2016, from Dun &
References bradstreet: 〈http://www.dnb.co.in/IndiasEnergySector/Regu_Power.asp〉
Reineberg, H.H., 2006. India's Electricity Sector in Transition: can its Giant Goals be
Airy,A., 2016. Business Insider. Retrieved from 〈http://www.businessinsider.in/Modi- met?. Elsevier.
two-year-report-card-Heres-how-power-ministry-fared/articleshow/52040810. Rejikumar, R., 2004. Indian electricity act 2003: agenda for review. Econ. Political Wkly..
cms〉. Sankar, T.L., 2004. Electricity act 2003: dark shadows over a Bright vision. Econ.
Airy, A., 2016. Energy Infra Post. Retrieved from energyinfrapost.com: 〈http:// Political Wkly..
energyinfrapost.com/performance-check-power-sector-two-years-modi-govt/〉. Shah, V., 2007. Jurisdictional limits of electricity Regulatory Commissions. ICFAI J.
Bajaj, J.L., 2004. Power Sector Reforms in India: Regulatory Issues. IIMB Management Infrastruct..
Review. Sharma, D.P., Nair, P.S., Balasubramanian, R., 2005. Performance of Indian power
Bhattacharyya, S.C., 2005. The Electricity Act 2003: Will it transform the Indian Power sector during a decade under restructuring: a critique. Energy Policy, 563–576.
Sector. Utilities Policy. Sharma, N.K., Tiwari, P.K., Sood, Y.R., 2013. A comprehensive analysis of strategies,
Bhattacharyya, S.C., 2007. Sustainability of power sector reform in India: what does policies and development of hydropower in India: special emphasis on small
recent experience suggest? J. Clean. Prod.. hydropower. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev., 460–470.
Bryman, A., 2012. Social Research Methods. Oxford Publishers. Shephard, J., Harden, A., Rees, R., Brunton, G., Garcia, J., Oliver, S., Oakley, A., 2006.
CEA, 2013. Annual Report 2012-13. CEA, New Delhi. Young people and healthy eating: a systematic review of research on barriers and
CEA, 2015. Executive Summary. Power Sector, New Delhi. facilitators. HEALTH Educ. Res., 239–257.
Central Electricity Authority, 2014. Status of implementation of progress of reforms Shukla, U.K., Thampy, A., 2011. Analysis of competition and market power in the
under Electricity Act 2003. CEA. wholesale electricity market in India. Energy Policy.
Central Electricity Authority, Power for All Monitoring Division, 2016. REliability Index Singh, A., 2006. Power sector reform in India: current issues and prospects. Energy
of the Cities /Towns/villages - Discom Wise. Central Electricity Authority. Policy.
CERC, 2016. Short Term Power Market in India 2015-16 (Economics Div). CERC. Singh, A., 2010. Towards a competitive market for electricity and consumer choice in the
Chatterjee, S.K., 2012. Commentary on the Electricity Laws of India. Delhi Law House, Indian power sector. Energy Policy, 4196–4208.
Delhi. Singh, D., 2016. Retrieved from Centre for Policy Research India: 〈http://www.cprindia.
Choong, K.K., 2013. Has this large number of performance measurement publications org/research/papers/competition-and-choice-electricity-distribution-india〉
contributed to its better understanding? A systematic review for research and Singh, R., Sood, Y.R., 2011. Current status and analysis of renewable promotional
applications. Int. J. Prod. Res. (2003). Electricity Act. New Delhi. Retrieved from policies in Indian restructured power sector – a review. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev.,
〈http://powermin.nic.in/upload/pdf/The%20Electricity%20Act_2003.pdf〉. 657–664.
Godbole, M., 2003. Electricity Act 2003. Questionable Wisdom. Sioshansi, F., 2006. Electricity market reform: what have we learnt? What have we
Indian Electricity Act, 1910. 1910 (with short notes).. Delhi: Universal Law Publishing gained. Electr. J..
Co. Pvt Ltd. Retrieved April 12, 2016, from 〈http://files.pspcl.in/1910.pdf〉 Thakur, T., Deshmukh, S., Kaushik, S., Kulshrestha, M., 2005. Impact assessment of the
Joseph, K.L., 2010. The Politics of Power: Electricity Reform in India. Energy Policy. Electricity Act 2003 on the Indian power sector. Energy Policy.
Joshi, P., 2004. What's New in India's Energy Sector. J. Struct. Proj. Financ.. Vadra, R., 2012. State Level initiatives of Power Sector Reforms in India.
K, D., 2016. The Hindu. Retrieved from The Hindu: 〈http://www.thehindu.com/news/ Zhang, Y.F., Parker, D. a., 2006. Electricity sector reform in developing countries: an
national/two-years-of-modi-government-a-review/article8640603.ece〉 econometric assessment of the effects of Privatisation, competition and regulation.
KPMG, 2015. Indian Economic Survey 2014-15 – Key Highlights. KPMG. ECPR/CRI Conf., Front. Regul.: Assess. Sch. Debates Policy Chall..

248

View publication stats

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi