Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 9

Hindawi Publishing Corporation

Abstract and Applied Analysis


Volume 2014, Article ID 395089, 8 pages
http://dx.doi.org/10.1155/2014/395089

Research Article
A Generalized Solow-Swan Model

Donghan Cai, Hui Ye, and Longfei Gu


College of Mathematics and Statistics, Wuhan University, Wuhan 430072, China

Correspondence should be addressed to Donghan Cai; dhcai@whu.edu.cn

Received 7 January 2014; Accepted 3 March 2014; Published 2 April 2014

Academic Editor: Josef Diblı́k

Copyright © 2014 Donghan Cai et al. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License,
which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.

We set up a generalized Solow-Swan model to study the exogenous impact of population, saving rate, technological change, and
labor participation rate on economic growth. By introducing generalized exogenous variables into the classical Solow-Swan model,
we obtain a nonautomatic differential equation. It is proved that the solution of the differential equation is asymptotically stable if
the generalized exogenous variables converge and does not converge when one of the generalized exogenous variables persistently
oscillates.

1. Introduction of the generalized exogenous variables persistently oscillates.


Therefore, the economy presents fluctuation when one of the
In the classical Solow-Swan model, saving rate, technological generalized exogenous variables is persistent oscillation.
level, capital depreciation, and population growth rate are Secondly, we inquire the impact of the main three
assumed to be fixed positive constants [1–3]. However, they factors on the economic growth. The first one is the change
vary in the process of the economic growth and appear in of the population and we mainly study the effect of the
different forms in the different periods. The growth rate of variable population growth rate and labor participation on
population presents an inverted-U form in the demographic the economic growth. It is obtained that the economy with
transition [4–9], the growth of technology appears in the S- low population growth rate has higher per capita capital
shape in some periods [10], and the saving rate varies with the than that with high population growth rate and the economy
age structure [11, 12]. tends stable if the population growth rate tends to a stable
In this paper, a generalized Solow-Swan model is set up by level. On the other hand, we obtain that the economy with
introducing generalized exogenous variables into the classical high labor participation rate has higher per capita capital
Solow-Swan model, which is described by a nonautomatic than that with low labor participation rate. This implies
differential equation. We use this model to inquire the effect that there exists “demographic dividend” in the late stage of
of exogenous short-term shocks and long-term fluctuation on the demographic transition in which the population growth
the economic growth. rate declines and the labor force participation rate increases
Firstly, we analyze the dynamics of the generalized Solow- and the population aging will slow down the economic
Swan model. It is proved that the right maximal interval growth. If the population growth or labor participation
of the nonautomatic differential equation is [0, ∞) and a rate is persistent oscillation, the economic fluctuation will
comparison theorem is provided. The solution of the differ- appear.
ential equation is Lyapunov asymptotically stable when the In the classical Solow-Swan model, the saving rate is a
generalized exogenous variables converge, which implies that fixed parameter and the shock of the saving rate change on the
the short-term exogenous shocks have no substantial impact economic growth is studied by Romer [2]. The saving rate is
on the long-term economic growth. assumed to be a variable of time in this paper and it is proved
The case that the differential equation has oscillational that the economy with higher saving rate will grow faster
solution is also discussed in this paper. It is obtained that than that with lower saving rate and the economy presents
the solution of the equation does not converge when one fluctuation when the saving rate is persistent oscillation.
2 Abstract and Applied Analysis

The effect of different types of technological change on Proof. (1) It is only to prove that there exits 𝛿 > 0 such that
the economic growth is inquired by using the generalized
Solow-Swan model. It is proved that the economy with higher ̃𝑘 (𝑡) > 𝑘 (𝑡) , 𝑡 ∈ (0, 𝛿) . (5)
technological level has higher per capita capital than that
with lower technological level under the Hicks or Solow Let 𝜙(𝑡) = ̃𝑘(𝑡) − 𝑘(𝑡); then 𝜙(0) ≥ 0 and 𝜙󸀠 (0) > 0. Therefore,
neutral technology. For the Harrod neutral technology, we (5) holds.
obtain that the per capita capital of the economy with higher (2) It is directly derived by the differential inequality [13].
final technological growth rate will exceed that with lower
final technological growth whatever how high the initial
per capita capital or technological level the latter has. This
2.3. The Right Maximal Interval of the Solution. For the
implies that a developing economy can catch up a developed
classical Solow Model, we have the following lemma.
economy if it keeps a higher technological growth rate.
When the technological level (under Hicks or Solow neutral Lemma 2 (see [1]). The right maximal intervals of the solu-
technology) or the technological growth rate (under Harrod tions, 𝑘𝑖 (𝑡), 𝑖 = 1, 2, of the initial value problems
neutral technology) is persistent oscillation, the economy
presents long-term fluctuation. 𝑘̇ 𝑖 = 𝑎𝑖 𝑓 (𝑘𝑖 ) − 𝑏𝑖 𝑘𝑖 , 𝑘𝑖 (0) = 𝑘0 > 0, 𝑖 = 1, 2 (6)
Finally, a brief summery is given in Section 6.
are [0, ∞) and
2. The Generalized Solow-Swan Model
lim 𝑘 (𝑡) = 𝑘𝑖∗ , min {𝑘0 , 𝑘𝑖∗ } ≤ 𝑘𝑖 (𝑡) ≤ max {𝑘0 , 𝑘𝑖∗ } ,
𝑡→∞ 𝑖
2.1. Set up the Model. The classical Solow-Swan model is
given by 𝑖 = 1, 2,
(7)
𝑘̇ = 𝑠𝑓 (𝑘) − (𝛿 + 𝑛 + 𝑔) 𝑘, (1)
where 𝑘𝑖∗ , 𝑖 = 1, 2, are the nonzero solutions of the equations
where 𝑠, 𝑛, and 𝑔 are saving rate, population growth rate, and 𝑎𝑖 𝑓(𝑘𝑖 ) − 𝑏𝑖 𝑘𝑖 = 0, 𝑖 = 1, 2.
the technological change rate, respectively, and 𝑓(𝑘) is the
intensive production function satisfying Theorem 3. The solution of the initial value problem

𝑓 (0) = 0, 𝑓 (∞) = ∞, 𝑓󸀠 (0) = ∞, 𝑘̇ = 𝑎 (𝑡) 𝑓 (𝑘) − 𝑏 (𝑡) 𝑘,


(8)
󸀠 󸀠 󸀠󸀠 𝑘 (0) = 𝑘0 > 0
𝑓 (∞) = 0, 𝑓 (𝑘) > 0, 𝑓 (𝑘) < 0, (2)

𝑘 > 0. exists on the interval [0, ∞).

In this paper, we consider the following nonautomatic Proof. Let 𝑘(𝑡) be the solution of the initial value problem (8)
differential equation: with the right maximal interval [0, 𝑏); then, by

𝑎1 𝑓 (𝑘) − 𝑏1 𝑘 ≤ 𝑎 (𝑡) 𝑓 (𝑘) − 𝑏 (𝑡) 𝑘 ≤ 𝑎2 𝑓 (𝑘) − 𝑏2 𝑘 (9)


𝑘̇ = 𝑎 (𝑡) 𝑓 (𝑘) − 𝑏 (𝑡) 𝑘, (3)
and Theorem 1, we have 𝑘1 (𝑡) ≤ 𝑘(𝑡) ≤ 𝑘2 (𝑡), 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑏), and it
where 𝑎(𝑡), 𝑏(𝑡) are continuous functions on [−𝑐, ∞) and stays in the set Ω = {(𝑡, 𝑘) | 0 ≤ 𝑡 < 𝑏, 𝑘1 (𝑡) ≤ 𝑘 ≤ 𝑘2 (𝑡)} for
satisfy 𝑎1 ≤ 𝑎(𝑡) ≤ 𝑎2 , 𝑏2 ≤ 𝑏(𝑡) ≤ 𝑏1 , 𝑎𝑖 , 𝑏𝑖 , 𝑖 = 1, 2, and 𝑐 𝑡 > 0.
are positive constants. If 𝑏 < ∞, let 𝐸𝜖 = {(𝑡, 𝑘) | −𝜖 < 𝑡 < 𝑏 + 𝜖, min{𝑘0 , 𝑘1∗ , 𝑘2∗ } −
𝜖 < 𝑘 < max{𝑘0 , 𝑘1∗ , 𝑘2∗ } + 𝜖}; then, for small enough 𝜖, the
2.2. The Comparison Theorem function 𝑎(𝑡)𝑓(𝑘) − 𝑏(𝑡)𝑘 satisfies Lipschitz condition on 𝐸𝜖 .
By Extension Theorem [13], the solution of (8) will reach the
Theorem 1. If 𝑘(𝑡), ̃𝑘(𝑡) are the solution of (3) and boundary of 𝐸𝜖 , which is a contradiction since Ω is a proper
subset of 𝐸𝜖 and 𝑘(𝑡) ∈ Ω, 𝑡 > 0. Therefore, 𝑏 = ∞.
𝑘̇ = 𝑎̃ (𝑡) 𝑓 (𝑘) − ̃𝑏 (𝑡) 𝑘 (4)
2.4. The Asymptotic Stability
with the initial values 𝑘(0), ̃𝑘(0), ̃𝑘(0) > 𝑘(0) > 0, then
Theorem 4. If lim𝑡 → ∞ 𝑎(𝑡) = 𝑎, lim𝑡 → ∞ 𝑏(𝑡) = 𝑏, and 𝑎, 𝑏 are
(1) 𝑘(𝑡) < ̃𝑘(𝑡), 𝑡 > 0 on a common interval of existence two positive constants, then the solution of (8) converges to 𝑘∗ ,
when 𝑎1 ≤ 𝑎(𝑡) < 𝑎̃(𝑡) ≤ 𝑎2 , 𝑏2 ≤ ̃𝑏(𝑡) ≤ 𝑏(𝑡) ≤ 𝑏1 or where 𝑘∗ is the nonzero solution of the equation 𝑎𝑓(𝑘)−𝑏𝑘 = 0.
𝑎1 ≤ 𝑎(𝑡) ≤ 𝑎̃(𝑡) ≤ 𝑎2 , 𝑏2 ≤ ̃𝑏(𝑡) < 𝑏(𝑡) ≤ 𝑏1 ;
Proof. For any given 𝜖 > 0, there exist 𝑎𝑖 , 𝑏𝑖 , 𝑖 = 1, 2, such that
(2) 𝑘(𝑡) ≤ ̃𝑘(𝑡), 𝑡 > 0, on the common interval of existence 0 < 𝑎1 < 𝑎 < 𝑎2 , 0 < 𝑏2 < 𝑏 < 𝑏1 , and the nonzero solutions
when 𝑎1 ≤ 𝑎(𝑡) ≤ 𝑎̃(𝑡) ≤ 𝑎2 , 𝑏2 ≤ ̃𝑏(𝑡) ≤ 𝑏(𝑡) ≤ 𝑏1 . of 𝑎𝑖 𝑓(𝑘)−𝑏𝑖 𝑘 = 0, 𝑘𝑖∗ , 𝑖 = 1, 2, satisfy 𝑘1∗ −𝜖/2 < 𝑘∗ < 𝑘2∗ +𝜖/2,
Abstract and Applied Analysis 3

where 𝑘𝑖∗ , 𝑖 = 1, 2, are the nonzero solutions of 𝑎𝑖 𝑓(𝑘) − 𝑏𝑖 𝑘 = such that 𝑑𝑇𝑖 − 𝑐𝑇𝑖 > 𝛿1 , 𝑖 = 1, 2, and one of the following
0, 𝑖 = 1, 2. inequalities holds:
Since lim𝑡 → ∞ 𝑎(𝑡) = 𝑎, lim𝑡 → ∞ 𝑏(𝑡) = 𝑏, there exists 𝑇1
min 𝑎 (𝑡) − 2max2 𝑎 (𝑡) > 𝜖,
such that 𝑎1 < 𝑎(𝑡) < 𝑎2 , 𝑏2 < 𝑏(𝑡) < 𝑏1 , 𝑡 ≥ 𝑇1 . Let ̃𝑘𝑖 (𝑡), 𝑐𝑇1 ≤𝑡≤𝑑𝑇1 𝑐𝑇 ≤𝑡≤𝑑𝑇
𝑖 = 1, 2, and ̃𝑘(𝑡) be the solutions of (6) and (8) with the initial (14)
̃𝑘 (0) = ̃𝑘 (0) = ̃𝑘(0) = 𝑘(𝑇 ); then, from lim ̃ min 𝑎 (𝑡) − 1max1 𝑎 (𝑡) > 𝜖.
1 2 1 𝑡 → ∞ 𝑘1 (𝑡) = 𝑐𝑇2 ≤𝑡≤𝑑𝑇2 𝑐𝑇 ≤𝑡≤𝑑𝑇
∗ ̃ ∗ ̃ ̃ ̃
𝑘1 , lim𝑡 → ∞ 𝑘2 (𝑡) = 𝑘2 , and 𝑘2 (𝑡) < 𝑘(𝑡) < 𝑘1 (𝑡), 𝑡 > 0, there
exists 𝑇2 such that Lemma 8. If the generalized variables 𝑎(𝑡) are persistent
oscillation, then, for any given constants 𝑐, 𝑇, 𝑇 > 0, there exist
𝜖 ̃ 𝛿1 > 0 and 𝑡𝑇 > 𝑇 such that one of the following inequalities
𝑘∗ − 𝜖 < 𝑘1∗ − < 𝑘1 (𝑡) ≤ ̃𝑘 (𝑡) ≤ ̃𝑘2 (𝑡)
2 holds:
(10)
𝜖 𝜖 𝜖
< 𝑘2∗ + < 𝑘∗ + 𝜖, 𝑡 > 𝑇2 ; 𝑎 (𝑡) − 𝑐 > , 𝑐 − 𝑎 (𝑡) > (15)
2 2 2
on the interval [𝑡𝑇 − 𝛿1 /2, 𝑡𝑇 + 𝛿1 /2].
that is, |̃𝑘(𝑡) − 𝑘∗ | < 𝜖, 𝑡 > 𝑇2 .
𝑘(𝑡), 0≤𝑡≤𝑇1 ,
Let 𝑢(𝑡) = { ̃𝑘(𝑡−𝑇 ), 𝑇 ≤𝑡<∞, and then 𝑢(𝑡) is a solution of Proof. Assume that the first inequality of (14) holds; then one
1 1
(8) with the initial 𝑢(0) = 𝑘0 and 𝑢(𝑡) = 𝑘(𝑡), 𝑡 > 0, by the of the following inequalities holds:
uniqueness of the solution of (8). Therefore, |𝑘(𝑡) − 𝑘∗ | < 𝜖, 𝜖 𝜖
min 𝑎 (𝑡) − 𝑐 > , − 2max2 𝑎 (𝑡) + 𝑐 > . (16)
𝑡 > 𝑇1 + 𝑇2 , and the theorem holds. 𝑐𝑇1 ≤𝑡≤𝑑𝑇1 2 𝑐𝑇 ≤𝑡≤𝑑𝑇 2

From the above theorem, we have following lemma. Without loss of the generality, we assume that the first
inequality above holds and we have
Lemma 5. If lim𝑡 → ∞ 𝑎(𝑡) = 𝑎, lim𝑡 → ∞ 𝑏(𝑡) = 𝑏, 𝑢𝑖 (𝑡), 𝑖 = 𝜖
1, 2, are the solution of (8) with the initial values 𝑢10 > 𝑢20 > 0, 𝑎 (𝑡) − 𝑐 > , 𝑡 ∈ [𝑐𝑇1 , 𝑑𝑇1 ] . (17)
2
then lim𝑡 → ∞ |𝑢1 (𝑡) − 𝑢2 (𝑡)| = 0.
Taking 𝑡𝑇 = (𝑑𝑇1 + 𝑐𝑇1 )/2, then (15) holds for [𝑡𝑇 − 𝛿1 /2, 𝑡𝑇 +
Theorem 6. If lim𝑡 → ∞ 𝑎(𝑡) = 𝑎, lim𝑡 → ∞ 𝑏(𝑡) = 𝑏, then the 𝛿1 /2] ⊂ [𝑐𝑇1 , 𝑑𝑇1 ].
solution of (8) is Lyapunov asymptotically stable. Similarly, we can prove the case that the second inequality
holds. This completes the proof of the lemma.
Proof. For any given 𝜖 > 0, choose 𝑢10 = 3𝑘0 /2 and 𝑢20 =
𝑘0 /2; then, from Lemma 5, there exists 𝑇 > 0 such that the Theorem 9. If one of the generalized variables is persistent
solutions, 𝑢𝑖 (𝑡), 𝑖 = 1, 2, with the initial values 𝑢𝑖0 , 𝑖 = 1, 2, of oscillation and the other converges, then the solution of the
(8) satisfy |𝑢1 (𝑡) − 𝑢2 (𝑡)| < 𝜖, 𝑡 ≥ 𝑇. differential equation (8) does not converge.
Denote that
Proof. Assume that 𝑎(𝑡) is persistent oscillation and
𝐺 (𝑡, 𝑘) = 𝑎 (𝑡) 𝑓 (𝑘) − 𝑏 (𝑡) 𝑘; (11) lim𝑡 → ∞ 𝑏(𝑡) = 𝑏.
If the solution 𝑘(𝑡) of the differential equation (8) con-
then 𝜕𝐺/𝜕𝑘 is continuous on the compact set verges, then there exists a 𝑘∗ > 0 such that lim𝑡 → ∞ 𝑘(𝑡) = 𝑘∗ .
Therefore, for given 𝜖1 > 0, there exists 𝑇1 > 0 such that
M = {(𝑡, 𝑘) | 0 ≤ 𝑡 ≤ 𝑇, 𝑢1 (𝑡) ≤ 𝑘 ≤ 𝑢2 (𝑡)} . (12) |𝑓(𝑘(𝑡)) − 𝑓(𝑘∗ )| < 𝜖1 , |𝑐 − (𝑘(𝑡)/𝑓(𝑘(𝑡)))𝑏(𝑡)| < 𝜖1 , 𝑡 > 𝑇1 ,
where 𝑐 = (𝑘∗ /𝑓(𝑘∗ ))𝑏.
Let 𝑀 = max(𝑡,𝑘)∈M (𝜕𝐺(𝑘, 𝑡)/𝜕𝑘), 𝛿1 = min{𝜖𝑒−𝑀𝑇 , 𝑘0 /2}, Let 𝑐1 = min{𝑓(𝑘∗ ) − 𝜖1 , 𝑓(𝑘∗ ) + 𝜖1 }; then, from (8) and
Lemma 8, there exists 𝜖 > 0, such that
and ̃𝑘(𝑡) be the solution of (8) with the initial value ̃𝑘0 ∈ (𝑘0 −
𝛿1 , 𝑘0 + 𝛿1 ); then, by the Gronwall inequality [13], we have 󵄨󵄨 𝛿 𝛿 󵄨󵄨󵄨
󵄨󵄨
󵄨󵄨𝑘 (𝑡𝑇 + 1 ) − 𝑘 (𝑡𝑇 − 1 )󵄨󵄨󵄨
󵄨󵄨 2 2 󵄨󵄨
󵄨󵄨̃ 󵄨 󵄨 󵄨
󵄨󵄨𝑘 (𝑡) − 𝑘 (𝑡)󵄨󵄨󵄨 < 󵄨󵄨󵄨̃𝑘0 − 𝑘0 󵄨󵄨󵄨 𝑒𝑀𝑇 < 𝜖, 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇] . (13) 󵄨󵄨 𝑡𝑇 +𝛿1 /2
󵄨 󵄨 󵄨 󵄨 󵄨
= 󵄨󵄨󵄨󵄨∫ 𝑓 (𝑘 (𝑠)) [𝑎 (𝑠) − 𝑐] d𝑠
Since 𝑢2 (𝑡) < 𝑘(𝑡) < 𝑢1 (𝑡), 𝑢2 (𝑡) < ̃𝑘(𝑡) < 𝑢1 (𝑡), 𝑡 > 0, we 󵄨󵄨 𝑡𝑇 −𝛿1 /2
have |̃𝑘(𝑡) − 𝑘(𝑡)| < |𝑢1 (𝑡) − 𝑢2 (𝑡)| < 𝜖 for 𝑡 ≥ 𝑇. Therefore, 𝑡𝑇 +𝛿1 /2
𝑘 (𝑠)
󵄨󵄨
󵄨
the solution of (8) is Lyapunov asymptotically stable [14] by +∫ 𝑓 (𝑘 (𝑠)) [𝑐 − 𝑏 (𝑠)] d𝑠󵄨󵄨󵄨󵄨 (18)
𝑡𝑇 −𝛿1 /2 𝑓 (𝑘 (𝑠)) 󵄨󵄨
Lemma 5. This completes the proof of the theorem.
𝑐1 𝜖𝛿1
≥ − (𝑓 (𝑘∗ ) + 𝜖1 ) 𝜖1 𝛿1
2.5. Oscillation 2
𝑐1 𝜖𝛿1
Definition 7. The generalized exogenous variables 𝑎(𝑡) (or ≥
𝑏(𝑡)) are called persistent oscillation if, for any given 𝑇 > 0, 4
there exist 𝑐𝑇𝑖 , 𝑑𝑇𝑖 , 𝑖 = 1, 2, 𝑐𝑇1 < 𝑑𝑇1 < 𝑐𝑇2 < 𝑑𝑇2 , and 𝜖 > 0, 𝛿1 > for 𝑇 > 𝑇1 , provided 𝜖1 < min{𝑐1 𝜖/4(𝑓(𝑘∗ ) + 1), 1}.
4 Abstract and Applied Analysis

Since lim𝑡𝑇 → ∞ |𝑘(𝑡𝑇 + 𝛿1 /2) − 𝑘(𝑡𝑇 − 𝛿1 /2)| = 0, the 3. Variable Population Growth
inequality above does not hold for big enough 𝑇1 . This is a
contradiction and the theorem holds. Suppose that 𝑁(𝑡) and 𝐿(𝑡) are the numbers of population and
labor of an economy at time 𝑡 and the labor force participation
Lemma 10. If generalized variable 𝑎(𝑡) (or (𝑏(𝑡)) which does rate is 𝜆(𝑡), 0 < 𝜆(𝑡) < 1; then, 𝐿(𝑡) = 𝜆(𝑡)𝑁(𝑡). We further
not equal constant is a periodical function with the period 𝜔 > assume that the population growth rate, 𝑛(𝑡), is bounded; that
0, then it is persistent oscillation. is, −𝑛1 ≤ 𝑛(𝑡) ≤ 𝑛2 , where 𝑛𝑖 ≥ 0, 𝑖 = 1, 2.
Let 𝑘 = 𝐾/𝑁; then
Proof. Since 𝜔 > 0, there exists 𝑡1 , 𝑡2 ∈ (0, 𝜔), 𝑡1 < 𝑡2 such
that 𝑎(𝑡1 ) ≠ 𝑎(𝑡2 ). Let 𝜖 = |𝑎(𝑡1 ) − 𝑎2 (𝑡2 )|/2; then there exists 𝐾̇ 𝑁 𝐾̇ 𝐾̇
𝛿 > 0 such that 0 < 𝑡1 −𝛿/2 < 𝑡1 +𝛿/2 < 𝑡2 −𝛿/2 < 𝑡2 +𝛿/2 < 𝜔 𝑘̇ = ( − ) 𝑘 = ( − 𝑛 (𝑡)) 𝑘 = − 𝑛 (𝑡) 𝑘. (25)
𝐾 𝑁 𝐾 𝑁
and one of the following inequalities holds:
min 𝑎 (𝑡) − max 𝑎 (𝑡) > 𝜖, From 𝐾̇ = 𝑠𝐹(𝐾, 𝐿) − 𝛿𝐾, we obtain the Solow-Swan
𝑐1 ≤𝑡≤𝑑1 𝑐2 ≤𝑡≤𝑑2 model with the variable population growth rate and labor
(19) participation rate below:
min 𝑎 (𝑡) − max 𝑎 (𝑡) > 𝜖,
𝑐2 ≤𝑡≤𝑑2 𝑐1 ≤𝑡≤𝑑1
𝑘̇ = 𝑠𝐹 (𝑘, 𝜆 (𝑡)) − [𝛿 + 𝑛 (𝑡)] 𝑘. (26)
where 𝑐𝑖 = 𝑡𝑖 − 𝛿/2, 𝑑𝑖 = 𝑡𝑖 + 𝛿/2, 𝑖 = 1, 2.
For any given 𝑇 > 0, there exists positive integer 𝑀𝑇 such
that 𝑀𝑇 𝜔 > 𝑇. Let 𝑐𝑇𝑖 = 𝑀𝑇 𝜔 + 𝑡𝑖 − 𝛿/2, 𝑑𝑇𝑖 = 𝑀𝑇 𝜔 + 𝑡𝑖 + 𝛿/2, 3.1. Changeable Population Growth Rate. Assume that the
𝑖 = 1, 2; then, from (19), the conditions in Definition 7 hold labor participation is positive constant, that is, 𝜆(𝑡) = 𝜆 0 , and
for 𝑎(𝑡) is the period function with period 𝜔. This completes let 𝑓(𝑘) = 𝐹(𝑘, 𝜆 0 ); then, from (26), we obtain the Solow-
the proof of the lemma. Swan model with variable population growth rate

From Lemma 10, we have the following theorem. 𝑘̇ = 𝑠𝑓 (𝑘) − [𝛿 + 𝑛 (𝑡)] 𝑘,


(27)
Theorem 11. If one of the generalized variables is periodical 𝑘 (0) = 𝑘 (0) > 0.
oscillation and the other converges, then the solution of the
differential equation (8) does not converge. Let 𝑎(𝑡) = 𝑠, 𝑏(𝑡) = 𝛿 + 𝑛(𝑡); then, from Theorems 4 and
6, we have the following theorem.
Example 12. If the intensive productive function is the Cobb-
Douglas productive function, then the differential equation Theorem 13. If 𝑛1 + 𝛿 > 0, then, the extension interval
(3) becomes of the solution of the differential equation (27) is [0, +∞);
furthermore, if lim𝑡 → +∞ 𝑛(𝑡) = 𝑛0 , then the solution of the
differential equation (27) is Lyapunov asymptotically stable
and converges to the nonzero equilibrium of the differential
𝑘̇ = 𝑎 (𝑡) 𝑘𝛼 − 𝑏 (𝑡) 𝑘. (20) equation
1−𝛼
Let 𝑧(𝑡) = 𝑘 ; then the equation above is reduced by
𝑘̇ = 𝑠𝑓 (𝑘) − [𝛿 + 𝑛0 ] 𝑘. (28)
𝑧̇ = −𝑏1 (𝑡) 𝑧 + 𝑎1 (𝑡) (21)
which is a linear differential equation, where 𝑎1 (𝑡) = (1 − Remark 14. Theorem 19 provided by Guerrini [15] is a special
𝛼)𝑎(𝑡) and 𝑏1 (𝑡) = (1 − 𝛼)𝑏(𝑡), and its solution is given by case of the above theorem (there, 𝑛(𝑡) is required to be a
monotone decreasing function).
𝑡 𝑡 𝑠
𝑧 (𝑡) = 𝑒− ∫0 𝑏1 (𝑠)d𝑠 [𝑧0 + ∫ 𝑎1 (𝑠) 𝑒∫0 𝑏1 (𝜏)d𝜏 d𝑠] . (22)
0 One of the most distinct characteristics in population
change is the demographic transition, which has occurred in
Therefore, the solution of (20) is
almost all developed countries and most developing coun-
𝑡 1/(1−𝛼)
𝑡 𝑠 tries [11]. The population growth rate in demographic tran-
𝑘 (𝑡) = [𝑒− ∫0 𝑏1 (𝑠)d𝑠 (𝑘01−𝛼 + ∫ 𝑎1 (𝑠) 𝑒∫0 𝑏1 (𝜏)d𝜏 d𝑠)] . sition appears in an inverted-U form and can be described by
0
(23) a function of time 𝑡, satisfying
When 𝑎1 (𝑡) = 𝑎1 + 𝑎2 sin 𝑥, 𝑏1 (𝑡) = 𝑏, the solution of the 𝑛 (0) = 𝑛0 > 0, 𝑛󸀠 (𝑡) > 0,
differential equation (20) is given by
𝑎1 (1 + 𝑏2 ) − 𝑎2 𝑏 0 < 𝑡 < 𝑡1 , 𝑛󸀠 (𝑡) < 0, 𝑡 > 𝑡1 , (29)
𝑘 (𝑡) = [(𝑘01−𝛼 − )𝑒 −𝑏𝑡
𝑏 + 𝑏2 lim 𝑛 (𝑡) = 0.
𝑡→∞
(24)
1/(1−𝛼)
𝑎 + 𝑎1 𝑏2 − 𝑎2 𝑏 cos 𝑡 + 𝑎2 𝑏2 sin 𝑡 Corollary 15. The growth of the economy which has under-
+ 1 ] , gone the demographic transition is stable and its per capita
𝑏 + 𝑏3
capital converges to the steady state of the economy with the
which approaches periodical oscillation. zero population growth rate.
Abstract and Applied Analysis 5

From Theorems 1 and 9, we have the following. Theorem 23. If 𝜆(𝑡) is persistent oscillation, then the solution
of (31) does not converge.
Corollary 16. If 𝑘𝑖 (𝑡), 𝑖 = 1, 2, are the solution of following
equations: Corollary 24. If the labor participation of an economy is
persistent oscillation, then its economic growth is not stable.
𝑘̇ = 𝑠𝑓 (𝑘) − [𝛿 + 𝑛𝑖 (𝑡)] 𝑘, 𝑖 = 1, 2, (30)
Remark 25. For the variable population growth rate, (31)
with same initial value 𝑘1 (0) = 𝑘2 (0) = 𝑘0 > 0 and 𝑛1 (𝑡) >
becomes
𝑛2 (𝑡) > 𝑛1 , then 𝑘2 (𝑡) > 𝑘1 (𝑡), 𝑡 > 0.
𝑘̇ = 𝜆1−𝛼 (𝑡) 𝑓 (𝑘) − [𝛿 + 𝑛 (𝑡)] 𝑘. (34)
Corollary 16 implies that an economy with higher popula-
tion growth rate has lower per capita capital and consumption From Theorems 1, 3, 4, 6, and 9, we derive that the eco-
than that with lower population growth rate. nomic growth speeds up when the labor force participation
rate increases and the population growth rate declines. There-
Theorem 17. If 𝑛1 + 𝛿 > 0 and 𝑛(𝑡) is persistent oscillation, fore, there exists “demographic dividend” in the late stage of
then the solution of (27) does not converge. demographic transition, in which the population growth rate
declines and labor force participation rate increases.
Corollary 18. If the population growth is persistent oscillation
of an economy, then its economic growth is not stable.
4. Variable Saving Rate
3.2. Changeable Labor Force Participation. There are two Assume that the saving rate varies with time, the population
major reasons that result in the change of the labor force growth rate is a constant 𝑛0 , and 0 < 𝑠1 ≤ 𝑠(𝑡) ≤ 𝑠2 < 1; then
participation: one is the changes in the age structure and the the classical Solow-Swan model changes into
other is the population aging [16]. Here, we suppose that the
aggregate population is stable; that is, 𝑁(𝑡) is a constant and 𝑘̇ = 𝑠 (𝑡) 𝑓 (𝑘) − (𝛿 + 𝑛0 ) 𝑘. (35)
𝐹(𝐾, 𝐿) is the Cobb-Douglas production function 𝐴𝐾𝛼 𝐿1−𝛼 ;
From Theorems 1, 3, 4, 6, and 9, we have the following.
then 𝑛(𝑡) = 0 and (26) turns into
𝑘̇ = 𝜆1−𝛼 (𝑡) 𝑓 (𝑘) − 𝛿𝑘, (31) Theorem 26. The extension interval of the solution of
the differential equation (35) is [0, +∞); furthermore, if
where 𝑓(𝑘) = 𝑠𝐴𝑘𝛼 . lim𝑡 → +∞ 𝑠(𝑡) = 𝑠0 > 0, then the solution of the differential
From Theorems 1, 3, 4, 6, and 9, we have the following. equation (35) is Lyapunov asymptotically stable and converges
to the nonzero equilibrium of the differential equation
Theorem 19. The extension interval of the solution of
the differential equation (31) is [0, +∞); furthermore, if 𝑘̇ = 𝑠0 𝑓 (𝑘) − (𝛿 + 𝑛0 ) 𝑘. (36)
lim𝑡 → +∞ 𝜆(𝑡) = 𝜆 0 > 0, then the solution of the differential
equation (31) is Lyapunov asymptotically stable and converges Theorem 27. If 𝑘𝑖 (𝑡), 𝑖 = 1, 2, are the solutions of the
to the nonzero equilibrium of the differential equation differential equations

𝑘̇ = 𝜆1−𝛼 𝑘̇ = 𝑠𝑖 (𝑡) 𝑓 (𝑘) − 𝛿𝑘, 𝑖 = 1, 2, (37)


0 𝑓 (𝑘) − 𝛿𝑘. (32)
Theorem 20. If 𝑘𝑖 (𝑡), 𝑖 = 1, 2, are the solutions of the with the same initial 𝑘0 and 𝑠2 (𝑡) > 𝑠1 (𝑡), 𝑡 ≥ 0, then 𝑘2 (𝑡) >
differential equations 𝑘1 (𝑡), 𝑡 > 0.

𝑘̇ = 𝜆1−𝛼 (𝑡) 𝑓 (𝑘) − 𝛿𝑘, 𝑖 = 1, 2 (33) Corollary 28. The economy with higher saving rate has higher
𝑖
per capita capital than that with lower saving rate under the
with the same initial 𝑘0 and 𝜆 2 (𝑡) > 𝜆 1 (𝑡), 𝑡 ≥ 0, then 𝑘2 (𝑡) > same other conditions; furthermore, the per capita capital of an
𝑘1 (𝑡), 𝑡 > 0. economy tends stably to a higher steady state when the saving
rate tends to a higher stable level.
Corollary 21. The economy with higher labor force partic-
ipation has higher per capita capital than that with lower Theorem 29. If 𝑠(𝑡) is persistent oscillation, then the solution
labor force participation under the same other conditions; of (35) does not converge.
furthermore, the per capita capital of an economy with higher
labor force participation tends stably to a higher steady state Corollary 30. If the saving rate of an economy is persistent
when the labor force participation tends to a stable level. oscillation, then its economic growth is not stable.

One of the distinct characteristics in population aging is 5. Exogenous Technological Change


the decline of the labor force participation [16] and we have
the following. 5.1. The Hicks Neutral Technology. The Hicks neutral techno-
logical production function [1] is given by
Corollary 22. The economic growth of an economy is slowed
down by population aging. 𝑌 = 𝐹 (𝐾, 𝐿, 𝑡) = 𝑇 (𝑡) 𝐹 (𝐾, 𝐿) , (38)
6 Abstract and Applied Analysis

where 𝑇(𝑡) is an index of the state of the technology, and 𝑇̇ ≥ Theorem 37. The extension interval of the solution of
0. the differential equation (43) is [0, +∞); furthermore, if
Under this production function, the Solow-Swan model lim𝑡 → +∞ 𝑔(𝑡) = 𝑔 > 0, then the solution of the differential
turns into equation (43) is Lyapunov asymptotic stable and converges to
equilibrium of the differential equation
𝑘̇ = 𝑠𝑇 (𝑡) 𝑓 (𝑘) − (𝛿 + 𝑛) 𝑘, (39)
which is a special case of the generalized Solow-Swan model 𝑘̇ = 𝑠𝑓 (𝑘) − (𝛿 + 𝑔 + 𝑛) 𝑘. (44)
(3). Therefore, from Theorems 1, 3, 4, 6, and 9, we have the Remark 38. The special case of this theorem has been proved
following theorems and corollaries. by Zhou et al. [17]; there the function 𝑔(𝑡) is given by 𝑎 + 𝑔 −
𝑢(𝑡), and 𝑢(𝑡) is the solution of the logistic equation 𝑢̇ = 𝑢(𝑎 −
Theorem 31. If 𝑇(𝑡) is bounded and 𝑇(0) > 0, then the
𝑏𝑢).
extension interval of the solution of the differential equation
(39) is [0, +∞); furthermore, if lim𝑡 → +∞ 𝑇(𝑡) = 𝑇 > 0, Lemma 39. If 𝑔𝑖 (0) ≥ 0, lim𝑡 → ∞ 𝑔𝑖 (𝑡) = 𝑔𝑖 , 𝑖 = 1, 2, and
then the solution of the differential equation (39) is Lyapunov 𝑔2 > 𝑔1 , then, for any given positive constant 𝐵, there exists a
asymptotically stable and converges to the nonzero equilibrium 𝑡
time 𝑇 such that ∫0 [𝑔2 (𝜏) − 𝑔1 (𝜏)]d𝜏 > 𝐵, 𝑡 > 𝑇.
of the differential equation
𝑡
𝑘̇ = 𝑠𝑇𝑓 (𝑘) − (𝛿 + 𝑛) 𝑘, (40) Proof. Let ℎ(𝑡) = ∫0 [𝑔2 (𝑠) − 𝑔1 (𝑠)]d𝑠; then, from
lim𝑡 → ∞ ℎ(𝑡) = ∞, the lemma holds.
where 𝑇 = lim𝑡 → ∞ 𝑇(𝑡).
Theorem 40. Let 𝑘𝑖 (𝑡), 𝑖 = 1, 2, be the solutions of the
Theorem 32. If 𝑇𝑖 (𝑡), 𝑖 = 1, 2, are bounded, 𝑇2 (𝑡) > 𝑇1 (𝑡), 𝑡 ≥ differential equations
0, 𝑇1 (0) > 0, and 𝑘𝑖 (𝑡), 𝑖 = 1, 2, are the solutions of the
differential equations 𝑘̇ = 𝑠𝑓 (𝑘) − [𝛿 + 𝑔𝑖 (𝑡) + 𝑛] 𝑘, 𝑖 = 1, 2, (45)
𝑘̇ = 𝑠𝑇𝑖 (𝑡) 𝑓 (𝑘) − 𝛿𝑘, 𝑖 = 1, 2, (41) with the initial values 𝑘𝑖0 , 𝑖 = 1, 2.
with the same initial 𝑘0 , then 𝑘2 (𝑡) > 𝑘1 (𝑡), 𝑡 > 0. (1) If 𝑘10 = 𝑘20 and 𝑔2 (𝑡) > 𝑔1 (𝑡), 𝑡 ≥ 0, then 𝑘2 (𝑡) < 𝑘1 (𝑡),
𝑡 > 0.
Corollary 33. The economy with higher technological level has
(2) If 𝑔2 = lim𝑡 → ∞ 𝑔2 (𝑡) > 𝑔1 = lim𝑡 → ∞ 𝑔1 (𝑡), then there
higher per capita capital than that with lower technological
level under the same other conditions; furthermore, the per exists a time 𝑇, such that ̃𝑘2 (𝑡) > ̃𝑘1 (𝑡), where ̃𝑘𝑖 (𝑡), 𝑖 =
capita capital of an economy tends stably to a higher steady state 1, 2, are the per capita capital 𝐾𝑖 (𝑡)/𝐿 𝑖 (𝑡), 𝑖 = 1, 2.
when its technological level tends to a higher stable level.
Proof. (1) It is directly deduced by Theorem 1.
𝑡
Theorem 34. If 𝑇(𝑡) is persistent oscillation, then the solution (2) Since ̃𝑘 (𝑡) = 𝐴 (𝑡)𝑘 (𝑡) = 𝐴 𝑒∫0 𝑔𝑖 (𝜏)d𝜏 𝑘 (𝑡), 𝑖 = 1, 2,
𝑖 𝑖 𝑖 𝑖0 𝑖
of (39) does not converge.
̃𝑘 (𝑡) 𝐴 𝑘 (𝑡) ∫𝑡 [𝑔 (𝜏)−𝑔 (𝜏)]d𝜏 𝐴 𝑘 (𝑡) ℎ(𝑡)
Corollary 35. If the technological level of an economy is
2
= 20 2 𝑒 0 2 1
= 20 2 𝑒 , (46)
̃𝑘 (𝑡) 𝐴 10 𝑘1 (𝑡) 𝐴 10 𝑘1 (𝑡)
persistent oscillation, then its economic growth is not stable. 1

where 𝐴 𝑖0 , 𝑖 = 1, 2, are initial technological levels.


Remark 36. In the case of Solow neutral technology (capital Let 𝑘𝑖∗ , 𝑖 = 1, 2, be the positive solutions of the following
augmenting technology) [1] and Cobb-Douglas production equation:
function, that is, 𝐹(𝐾𝐵(𝑡), 𝐿) = (𝐾𝐵(𝑡))𝛼 𝐿1−𝛼 , the Solow-
Swan model turns into 𝑠𝑓 (𝑘) − [𝛿 + 𝑔𝑖 + 𝑛] 𝑘 = 0, 𝑖 = 1, 2, (47)
𝑘̇ = 𝑠𝐵𝛼 (𝑡) 𝑘𝛼 − (𝛿 + 𝑛) 𝑘 = 𝑎 (𝑡) 𝑓 (𝑘) − (𝛿 + 𝑛) 𝑘, (42) respectively; then, from lim𝑡 → ∞ 𝑘𝑖 (𝑡) = 𝑘𝑖∗ , 𝑖 = 1, 2, there
where 𝑎(𝑡) = 𝑠𝐵𝛼 (𝑡), 𝑓(𝑘) = 𝑘𝛼 , and we have similar theorems exists 𝑇1 such that 𝑘2 (𝑡) > 𝑘2∗ /2, 𝑘1 (𝑡) < 3𝑘1∗ /2, 𝑡 > 𝑇1 . Hence,
̃𝑘 (𝑡)/̃𝑘 (𝑡) > (𝐴 𝑘∗ /3𝐴 𝑘∗ )𝑒ℎ(𝑡) .
and corollaries above. 2 1 20 2 10 1
By Lemma 39, there is a time 𝑇 such that ℎ(𝑡) >
5.2. The Harrod Neutral Technology. For the Harrod Neutral ln(3𝐴 10 𝑘1∗ /𝐴 20 𝑘2∗ ), 𝑡 > 𝑇. Therefore, ̃𝑘2 (𝑡)/̃𝑘1 (𝑡) > 1, 𝑡 >
technology [1], the production function is given by 𝑌 = max{𝑇, 𝑇1 }. This completes the proof of the theorem.
𝐹(𝐾, 𝐿𝐴(𝑡)), which is also called the labor-augmenting tech-
nological progress, and the Solow-Swan model becomes Remark 41. This theorem implies that a developing economy
can catch up and surpass a developed economy provided it
𝑘̇ = 𝑠𝑓 (𝑘) − [𝛿 + 𝑔 (𝑡) + 𝑛] 𝑘, (43) maintains a higher technological growth rate than the latter
one.
where 𝑘 = 𝐾/𝐿𝐴(𝑡) is the capital stock per unit of effective
̇ is the technological growth rate.
labor and 𝑔(𝑡) = 𝐴/𝐴 Corollary 42. (1) An economy with lower technological
From Theorems 1, 3, 4, 6, and 9, we have the following. growth rate has higher per capita capital of effective labor than
Abstract and Applied Analysis 7

that with higher technological growth rate under the same other technology) grows faster than that with lower technological
conditions. level. The per capita capital of an economy tends to a stable
(2) The per capita capital of an economy with higher final level if the technological level tends to a stable level and the
technological growth rate will excess that with lower final economy presents long-term fluctuation if the technologic
technological growth rate. level is persistent oscillation.
For the Harrod neutral technology, we show that the per
Theorem 43. If 𝑔(𝑡) is persistent oscillation, then the solution capita of an economy with higher technological growth rate
of (43) does not converge. will excess that with lower technological growth whatever
how high initial per capita capital the latter had and how
Corollary 44. If the technological growth rate of an economy high technological growth rate in the early stage the latter
with the labor-augmenting technological progress is persistent had. This result implies that a developing economy can catch
oscillation, then its economic growth is not stable. up a developed economy provided it maintains a higher
technological growth rate than the latter in long term.
6. Summary If the technological growth rate is persistent oscillation,
the economic growth is not stable and the economy presents
From the analysis in Section 2, we see that the stability long-term fluctuation.
of the nonautomatic differential equation depends on the
generalized exogenous variables. If they converge, then the Appendix
solution of the equation is Lyapunov asymptotically stable
and does not converge if one of the generalized exogenous Some Cited Definitions, Theorems, and
variables is persistent oscillation. Therefore, the economy
described by the model stably grows when the generalized
the Details of the Proof
exogenous variables tend to a stable level and presents Theorem A.1 (differential inequality [13]). Let 𝑈(𝑡, 𝑢),
fluctuation when one of the generalized exogenous variables 𝑢(𝑡0 ) = 𝑢0 on an open (𝑡, 𝑢)-set 𝐸 and 𝑢 = 𝑢0 (𝑡) the
is persistent oscillation. maximal solution of 𝑢̇ = 𝑈(𝑡, 𝑢), 𝑢(𝑡0 ) = 𝑢0 . Let V(𝑡) be a
In Section 3, we analyze the effect of the demographic continuous function on [𝑡0 , 𝑡0 + 𝑎] satisfying the conditions
factors on the economic growth. One demographic factor is V(𝑡0 ) ≤ 𝑢0 , (𝑡, V(𝑡)) ∈ 𝐸, and V(𝑡) has a right derivative 𝐷𝑅 V(𝑡)
the change of population growth rate in the period of demo- on 𝑡0 ≤ 𝑡 < 𝑡0 + 𝑎. Then, on a common interval of existence of
graphic transition. There does not exist substantial effect on 𝑢0 (𝑡) and V(𝑡), V(𝑡) ≤ 𝑢0 (𝑡).
the economic growth in long term for the population growth
rate tends to zero after the demographic transition. However, Theorem A.2 (Extension Theorem [13]). Let 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑦) be con-
the economic growth speeds up in the later period of the tinuous on an open (𝑡, 𝑦)-set 𝐸 and let 𝑦(𝑡) be a solution of
demographic transition in which the labor force participation 𝑦̇ = 𝑓(𝑡, 𝑦) on some interval. Then 𝑦(𝑡) can be extended (as a
rate rises and the population growth rate decreases. This solution) over a maximal interval of existence (𝜔− , 𝜔+ ). Also, if
implies that the “demographic dividend” appears in this (𝜔− , 𝜔+ ) is a maximal interval of existence, then 𝑦(𝑡) tends to
period and theoretically confirms the evidence provided by the boundary 𝜕𝐸 of 𝐸 as 𝑡 → 𝜔− and 𝑡 → 𝜔+ .
Bloom et al. [11] through empirical analysis.
The other demographic factor affecting economic growth Theorem A.3 (Gronwall’s inequality [13]). Let 𝑢(𝑡), V(𝑡) be
that we inquired is population aging. The distinct characteris- nonnegative, continuous functions on [𝑎, 𝑏]; 𝐶 ≥ 0 a constant;
tic of population aging is that the labor force participation rate and
declines when the total population is stable. From the analysis 𝑡
in Section 3.2, we see that population aging slows down the V (𝑡) ≤ 𝐶 + ∫ V (𝑠) 𝑢 (𝑠) d𝑠, 𝑎 ≤ 𝑡 ≤ 𝑏. (A.1)
economic growth. 𝑎
The third demographic factor is unstable population
Then
growth rate and unstable labor force participation rate. If one
𝑡
of them is persistent oscillation, then the economy presents
long-term fluctuation. V (𝑡) ≤ 𝐶 exp (∫ 𝑢 (𝑠) d𝑠) , 𝑎 ≤ 𝑡 ≤ 𝑏; (A.2)
𝑎
The effect of the saving rate change on economic growth is
discussed in Section 4. The per capita capital of the economy in particular, if 𝐶 = 0, then V(𝑡) ≡ 0.
with higher final saving rate will excess that with lower final
saving rate. Under the same initial per capita capital, the per Definition A.4 (Lyapunov Stability [14]). Let 𝑥∗ (𝑡) be a given
capita capital of the economy with higher saving rate is bigger real or complex solution vector of the n-dimensional system
than that with lower saving rate in whole period of economic 𝑥̇ = 𝑋(𝑥, 𝑡). Then we have the following.
growth. If the saving rate is persistent oscillation, then the (i) 𝑥∗ (𝑡) is Lyapunov stable for 𝑡 ≥ 𝑡0 if and only if to
economy presents long-term fluctuation. each value of 𝜖 > 0, however small, there corresponds
Three types of variable neutral technology with time are a value of 𝛿 > 0 (where 𝛿 may depend only on 𝜖 and
put into the model to analyze their effects on the economic 𝑡0 ) such that
growth. It is obtained that the economy with higher tech-
󵄩󵄩 󵄩 󵄩 󵄩
󵄩󵄩𝑥 (𝑡0 ) − 𝑥 (𝑡0 )󵄩󵄩󵄩 < 𝛿 󳨐⇒ 󵄩󵄩󵄩𝑥 (𝑡) − 𝑥 (𝑡)󵄩󵄩󵄩 < 𝜖
∗ ∗
nological level (Hicks neutral technology or Solow neutral (A.3)
8 Abstract and Applied Analysis

for all 𝑡 > 𝑡0 , where 𝑥(𝑡) represents any other References


neighbouring solution.
[1] J. R. Barro and X. Sala-i-Martin, Economic Growth, McGraw-
(ii) If the given system is autonomous, the reference to 𝑡0 Hill, New York, NY, USA, 1995.
in (i) may be disregarded; the solution 𝑥∗ (𝑡) is either [2] D. Romer, Advanced Macroeconomics, McGraw-Hill, New York,
Lyapunov stable or not, for all 𝑡0 . NY, USA, 2006.
[3] R. M. Solow, “A contribution to the theory of economic growth,”
(iii) Otherwise the solution 𝑥∗ (𝑡) is unstable in the sense Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 70, pp. 65–94, 1956.
of Lyapunov. [4] D. E. Bloom and J. G. Williamson, “Demographic transitions
and economic miracles in emerging Asia,” The Word Bank
Definition A.5 (uniform stability [14]). If a solution is stable Economic Review, vol. 12, pp. 419–455, 1998.
for 𝑡 ≥ 𝑡0 , and the 𝛿 of Definition A.4 is independent of 𝑡0 , [5] O. Galor and D. N. Weil, “From Malthusian stagnation to
the solution is uniformly stable on 𝑡 ≥ 𝑡0 . modern growth,” The American Economic Review, vol. 89, pp.
150–154, 1999.
Definition A.6 (asymptotic stability [14]). Let 𝑥∗ be a stable [6] O. Galor and D. N. Weil, “Population, technology, and growth:
(or uniformly stable) solution for 𝑡 ≥ 𝑡0 . If additionally there from Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and
exists 𝜂(𝑡0 ) > 0 such that beyond,” The American Economic Review, vol. 90, pp. 806–828,
2000.
󵄩󵄩 󵄩 󵄩 󵄩 [7] O. Galor, “The demographic transition and the emergence of
󵄩󵄩𝑥 (𝑡0 ) − 𝑥 (𝑡0 )󵄩󵄩󵄩 < 𝜂 󳨐⇒ lim 󵄩󵄩󵄩𝑥 (𝑡) − 𝑥 (𝑡)󵄩󵄩󵄩 = 0, (A.4)
∗ ∗
𝑡→∞ sustained economic growth,” Journal of the European Economic
Association, vol. 3, pp. 494–504, 2005.
then the solution is said to be asymptotically stable (or [8] H. Strulik, “Demographic transition, stagnation, and demoe-
uniformly and asymptotically stable). conomic cycles in a model for the less developed economy,”
Journal of Macroeconomics, vol. 21, pp. 397–413, 1991.
[9] K. Tabata, “Inverted 𝑈-shaped fertility dynamics, the poverty
Derivation of Formula of (13). Since the solutions 𝑘(𝑡), ̃𝑘(𝑡) trap and growth,” Economics Letters, vol. 81, no. 2, pp. 241–248,
2003.
satisfy
[10] H. Pan, “Dynamic and endogenous change of input-output
structure with specific layers of technology,” Structural Change
𝑡
and Economic Dynamics, vol. 17, pp. 200–223, 2006.
𝑘 (𝑡) = 𝑘0 + ∫ 𝐺 (𝜏, 𝑘 (𝜏)) d𝜏, 𝑡 > 0,
0 [11] D. E. Bloom, D. Canning, and J. Sevilla, “Economic growth and
(A.5) the demographic transition,” NBER Working Paper 8685, 2001.
𝑡
̃𝑘 (𝑡) = ̃𝑘 + ∫ 𝐺 (𝜏, ̃𝑘 (𝜏)) d𝜏, 𝑡 > 0, [12] T. Lindh, “Age structure and economic policy: the case of saving
0
0 and growth,” Population Research and Policy Review, vol. 18, no.
3, pp. 261–277, 1999.
we have [13] P. Hartman, Ordinary Differential Equations, John Wiley &
Sons, New York, NY, USA, 1964.
󵄨󵄨̃ 󵄨
󵄨󵄨𝑘 (𝑡) − 𝑘 (𝑡)󵄨󵄨󵄨 [14] D. W. Jordan and P. Smith, Nonlinear Ordinary Differential
󵄨 󵄨 Equations—An Introduction for Scientists and Engineers, Oxford
󵄨 󵄨 𝑡
󵄨 󵄨 University Press, New York, NY, USA, 2007.
≤ 󵄨󵄨󵄨󵄨̃𝑘0 − 𝑘0 󵄨󵄨󵄨󵄨 + ∫ 󵄨󵄨󵄨󵄨𝐺 (𝜏, ̃𝑘 (𝜏)) − 𝐺 (𝜏, 𝑘 (𝜏))󵄨󵄨󵄨󵄨 d𝜏 (A.6) [15] L. Guerrini, “The Solow-Swan model with a bounded popula-
0
tion growth rate,” Journal of Mathematical Economics, vol. 42,
𝑡
󵄨 󵄨 󵄨 󵄨 no. 1, pp. 14–21, 2006.
≤ 󵄨󵄨󵄨󵄨̃𝑘0 − 𝑘0 󵄨󵄨󵄨󵄨 + 𝑀 ∫ 󵄨󵄨󵄨󵄨̃𝑘 (𝜏) − 𝑘 (𝜏)󵄨󵄨󵄨󵄨 d𝜏. [16] R. W. McQuaid, “The aging of the labor force and globalization,”
0
in Globalization and Regional Economic Modeling, Advances in
Spatial Science, pp. 69–85, 2007.
By Gronwall’s inequality, we obtain [17] M. Zhou, D. Cai, and H. Chen, “A Solow-Swan model with
technological overflow and catch-up,” Wuhan University Journal
󵄨󵄨̃ 󵄨 󵄨 󵄨
󵄨󵄨𝑘 (𝑡) − 𝑘 (𝑡)󵄨󵄨󵄨 < 󵄨󵄨󵄨̃𝑘0 − 𝑘0 󵄨󵄨󵄨 𝑒𝑀𝑇 < 𝜖, 𝑡 ∈ [0, 𝑇] . (A.7) of Natural Sciences, vol. 12, no. 6, pp. 975–978, 2007.
󵄨 󵄨 󵄨 󵄨

Conflict of Interests
The authors declare there is no conflict of interests regarding
the publication of this paper.

Acknowledgment
This work is supported by National Natural Science Founda-
tion of China (70871094, 71271158).
Advances in Advances in Journal of Journal of
Operations Research
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
Decision Sciences
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
Applied Mathematics
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
Algebra
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
Probability and Statistics
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014 http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014 http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014 http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014 http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

The Scientific International Journal of


World Journal
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
Differential Equations
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014 http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Submit your manuscripts at


http://www.hindawi.com

International Journal of Advances in


Combinatorics
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
Mathematical Physics
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014 http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Journal of Journal of Mathematical Problems Abstract and Discrete Dynamics in


Complex Analysis
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
Mathematics
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
in Engineering
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
Applied Analysis
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
Nature and Society
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014 http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014 http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014 http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014 http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

International
Journal of Journal of
Mathematics and
Mathematical
Discrete Mathematics
Sciences

Journal of International Journal of Journal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporation Hindawi Publishing Corporation Volume 2014


Function Spaces
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
Stochastic Analysis
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
Optimization
Hindawi Publishing Corporation
http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014 http://www.hindawi.com http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014 http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014 http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi