Vous êtes sur la page 1sur 24

Towards a Positive Theory of the Determination of Accounting Standards

Author(s): Ross L. Watts and Jerold L. Zimmerman


Source: The Accounting Review, Vol. 53, No. 1 (Jan., 1978), pp. 112-134
Published by: American Accounting Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/245729 .
Accessed: 04/12/2014 17:59

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Accounting Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
Accounting Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
THE ACCOUNTING REVIEW
Vol. Lill, No. I
January 1978

Towards a Positive Theory of the


Determinationof Accounting
Standards
Ross L. Watts and Jerold L. Zimmerman

ABSTRACT: This article provides the beginnings of a positive theory of accounting by


exploring those factors influencing management's attitudes on accounting standards
which are likely to affect corporate lobbying on accounting standards. Certain factors
are expected to affect a firm's cashflows and in turn are affected by accounting standards.
These factors are taxes, regulation, management compensation plans, bookkeeping costs,
and political costs, and they are combined into a model which predicts that large firms
which experience reduced earnings due to changed accounting standards favor the
change. All other firms oppose the change if the additional bookkeeping costs justify the
cost of lobbying. This prediction was tested using the corporate submissions to the
FASB's Discussion Memorandum on General Price Level Adjustments. The empirical
results are consistent with the theory.

ACCOUNTING standards in the United boards.


States have resulted from a com- Ultimately, we seek to develop a posi-
plex interaction among numerous tive theory of the determination of ac-
parties including agencies of the Federal counting standards.' Such a theory will
government (notably the Securities and help us to understand better the source
Exchange Commission and Treasury of the pressures driving the accounting
Department), state regulatory commis- standard-setting process, the effects of
sions, public accountants, quasi-public various accounting standards on different
accounting standard-setting boards (the groups of individuals and the allocation
Committee on Accounting Procedures of resources, and why various groups are
(CAP), the Accounting Principles Board willing to expend resources trying to
(APB), and the Financial Accounting affect the standard-setting process. This
Standards Board (FASB)), and cor- understanding is necessary to determine
porate managements. These parties have, if prescriptions from normative theories
in the past, and continue to expend re- We wish to thank members of the Finance Workshop
sources to influence the setting of ac- at the University of Rochester, members of the Account-
counting standards. Moonitz [1974], ing Seminar at the University of Michigan and, in par-
ticular, George Benston, Ken Gaver, Nicholas Gonedes,
Horngren [1973] and [1976], Armstrong Michael Jensen, Keith Leffler,Martin Geisel, Cliff Smith
[1976] and Zeff [1972] document the and an anonymous referee for their helpful suggestions.
sometimes intense pressure exerted on ' See Jensen [1976] and Horngren [1976].
the "private" accounting standard-set-
ting bodies (i.e., CAP, APB, FASB). Ross L. Watts and Jerold L. Zimmer-
These pressures have led to several re- man are Assistant Professors of Account-
organizations of the standard-setting ing at the University of Rochester.
112

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Wattsand Zimmerman 113

(e.g., current cash equivalents) are feasi- lobbies on accounting standards based
ble. on its own self-interest. For simplicity,
Watts [1974] and [1977] has started to (since this is an early attempt to provide
develop such a theory. This paper ex- a positive theory) it could be argued that
pands on this initial work by focusing on we should assume that management's
the costs and benefits generated by ac- self-interest on accounting standards is
counting standards which accrue to congruent with that of the shareholders.
managements, thereby contributing to After all, that assumption has provided
our understanding of the incentives of hypotheses consistent with the evidence
management to oppose or support vari- in finance (e.g., the risk/return relation-
ous standards. Management, we believe, ship of the various capital asset pricing
plays a central role in the determination models). However, one function of finan-
of standards. Moonitz supports this cial reporting is to constrain manage-
view: ment to act in the shareholders' interest.
(For example, see Benston [1975], Watts
Management is central to any discussion of
financial reporting, whether at the statutory [1974], and Jensen and Meckling
or regulatory level, or at the level of offi- [1976a].) Consequently, assuming con-
cial pronouncements of accounting bodies. gruence of management and shareholder
[Moonitz, 1974, p. 64] interests without further investigation
Hence, it seems appropriate that a pre- may cause us to omit from our lobbying
condition of a positive theory of stan- model important predictive variables. To
dard-setting is understanding manage- reduce this possibility, we will examine
ment's incentives. next the effects of accounting standards
The next section introduces those fac- on management's self-interest without
tors (e.g., tax, regulatory, political con- the congruence assumption. The purpose
siderations) which economic theory leads of the examination is to identify factors
us to believe are the underlying determin- which are likely to be important predic-
ants affecting managements' welfare and, tors of lobbying behavior so that we can
thereby, their decision to consume re- include them in our formal model.
sources trying to affect the standard- The assumption that management se-
setting process. Next, a model is pre- lects accounting procedures to maximize
sented incorporating these factors. The its own utility is used by Gordon [1964,
predictions of this model are then tested p. 261] in an early attempt to derive a
using the positions taken by corporations positive theory of accounting. There have
regarding the FASB's Discussion Mem- been several attempts to test empirically
orandum on General Price Level Adjust- Gordon's model, or variants of it, which
ments (GPLA). The last section contains we call the "smoothing" literature.3
the conclusions of the study. Problems in the specification of the em-
FACTORS INFLUENCING MANAGEMENT 2 Many economic models assume a rather limited
version of economic man. In particular, they assume that
ATTITUDES TOWARDS FINANCIAL man maximizes his own welfare when he is constrained
ACCOUNTING STANDARDS to play by certain rules and in certain institutional set-
tings, ignoring his incentives to avoid or change the
In this paper, we assume that individ- rules. setting. etc. Meckling [1976] analyzes this issue.
uals act to maximize their own utility. In 3 Ball and Watts [1972]; Barefield and Comiskey
doing so, they are resourceful and in- [1972]; Barnea, Ronen and Sadan [1975]; Beidleman
t1973]; Copeland [1968]; Cushing [1969]; Dasher and
novative.2 The obvious implication of Malcom [1970]; Gordon [1964]; Gordon, Horwitz and
this assumption is that management Meyers [1966].

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
114 The Accounting Review, January 1978

pirical tests in the smoothing literature through i) taxes, ii) regulatory procedures
leave the Gordon model essentially un- if the firm is regulated, iii) political costs,
confirmed.4 Also, certain aspects of the iv) information production costs, and
Gordon model contribute to the model's directly via v) management compensa-
lack of confirmation. Essentially, Gordon tion plans. The first four factors increase
[1964] assumed that shareholder satis- managerial wealth by increasing the
faction (and, presumably, wealth) is cashflows and, hence, share price. The
solely a positive function of accounting last factor can increase managerial wealth
income. This assumption avoids the con- by altering the terms of the incentive
flict between shareholders and manage- compensation. Each of these five factors
ment by implying that increases in stock are discussed in turn.
prices always accompany increases in
Factors Affecting Management Wealth'
accounting income. However, recent re-
search casts serious doubt on the ability Taxes. Tax laws are not directly tied to
of management to manipulate directly financial accounting standards except in
share prices via changes in accounting a few cases (e.g., the last-in-first-out in-
procedures.5 ventory valuation method). However, the
We assume that management's utility indirect relationship is well documented
is a positive function of the expected Zeff [1972] and Moonitz [1974]. The
compensation in future periods (or adoption of a given procedure for finan-
wealth) and a negative function of the cial accounting does not decrease the
dispersion of future compensation (or likelihood of that procedure's being
wealth). The question is how do account-
ing standards affect management's 4 For these defects see Ball and Watts [1972], Gonedes
[1972] and Gonedes and Dopuch [19741.
wealth?6 Management's total compensa- 5 Fama [1970] and Goedes and Dopuch [19741.
tion from the firm consists of wages, in- Further, the results of studies by Kaplan and Roll [19721,
centive compensation (cash bonuses and Ball [1972] and Sunder [1975] which address the specific
issue support the hypothesis that the stock market can
stock or stock options), and nonpecuni- discriminate between real events and changes in account-
ary income, including perquisites (dis- ing procedures. Given that the market can on average
cussed in Jensen-Meckling, 1976a). Since discriminate, then it must be concluded that managers
(on average) expect the market to discriminate. Obvious-
it is unclear what role accounting stan- ly, managers do and will attempt to influence their share
dards play in the level of nonpecuniary price by direct accounting manipulation, but if these
income, we exclude it and focus on the attempts consume resources, then incentives exist to
eliminate these inefficient allocations.
first two forms of compensation. To the 6 For earlier discussions of this question see Watts
extent that management can increase [1974] and Gonedes [1976].
either the level of incentive compensa- We have purposefully excluded from the set of fac-
tors being examined the information content effect of an
tion or the firm's share price via its choice accounting standard on stock prices. We have done this
of accounting standards, they are made because at present the economic theories of information
better off. and capital market equilibrium are not sufficiently de-
veloped to allow predictions to be made regarding the
This analysis distinguishes between influence an accounting standard on the capital market's
mechanisms which increase manage- assessment of the distributions of returns (see Gonedes
ment's wealth: 1) via increases in share and Dopuch, 1974). We believe that a theory of the
determination of account ng standards can be developed
price (i.e., stock and stock options are and tested ignoring the information content factor. If at
more valuable) and 2) via increases in in- some future date, the information content factor can be
centive cash bonuses. The choice of ac- specified and included in the theory, then the predictions
and our understanding of the process will be improved.
counting standards can affect both of But we see no reason to delay the development of a
these forms of compensation indirectly theory until information content is specified.

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Watts and Zimmerman 115

adopted in future Internal Revenue the public's association of high reported


codes, and more likely, will increasethe profits and monopoly rents, manage-
chance of adoption. To the extent that ment can reduce the likelihood of adverse
managementexpects a proposed finan- political actions and, thereby, reduce its
cial accounting procedure to influence expected costs (including the legal costs
future tax laws, their lobbying behavior the firm would incur opposing the politi-
is affected by the future tax law effects. cal actions). Included in political costs
Regulation.8 Most public utility com- are the costs labor unions impose through
missions base their rate-settingformulas increased demands generated by large
on accountingdeterminedcosts. A new reported profits.
accounting standard which reduces a The magnitude of the political costs is
utility'sreportedincome may provideits highly dependent on firm size.12 Even as
managementwith an "excuse"to argue a percentage of total assets or sales, we
for increased rates. Whether the utility would not expect a firm with sales of $100
commission grants the increasedepends million to generate the same political
on whether groups opposed to the rate costs (as a percentage of sales) as a firm
increase(e.g., consumergroups)are able with $10 billion of sales. Casual empiri-
to exert political pressure on the com- 8 We deal in this paper with public utility regulation
mission.9 This depends on such factors and the forms of rate regulation employed. Other in-
as information costs (to be discussed dustries (e.g., banking and insurance) are regulated dif-
later). However,to the extent that there ferently and these industries are ignored in this paper to
simplify the analysis.
is some probabilityof a rate (and hence ' For the economic theory of regulation upon which
cashflow) increase (either temporaryor this discussion is based see Stigler [1971], Posner [1974]
permanent)as the resultof an accounting and Peltzman [1975]. Also, Horngren [1976].
10 Stigler [1971], Peltzman [1975], and Jensen and
standardschange,utilitieshave an incen- Meckling [1976b]. An example of an industry facing such
tive to favor that change. Similarly,they action is the oil industry.
have an incentive to oppose changes in l' For an alleged example of this, see Jack Anderson,
Syndicated Column, United Features (New York, April
accounting standardswhich might lead 10. 1976).
to a rate decrease. 12 Several studies document the association between

Political Costs. The politicalsectorhas size and anti-trust [Siegfried 1975]. In proposed anti-
trust legislation, size per se has been mentioned specifical-
the power to effect wealth transfersbe- ly as a criterion for action against corporations. See the
tween various groups. The corporate "Curse of Bigness," Barron's, June 30, 1969. pp. 1 and 8.
sector is especially vulnerable to these Also see a bill introduced into the Senate by Senator
Bayh (U.S. Congress, Senate, Subcommittee on Anti-
wealth redistributions.Certaingroupsof trust and Monopoly (1975), pp. 5-13) would require
voters have an incentiveto lobby for the divesture for oil firms with annual production and/or
nationalization,expropriation,break-up sales above certain absolute numbers. In the hearings on
that bill, Professor Mencke of Tufts University argued
or regulationof an industryor corpora- that absolute and not relative accounting profits are the
tion.'0 This in turn providesan incentive relevant variable for explaining political action against
for elected officials to propose such ac- corporations.
Menke said, "Nevertheless, precisely because the
tions. To counterthese potentialgovern- actions of large firms are so visible, the American public
ment intrusions,corporationsemploy a has always equated absolute size with monopoly power.
number of devices, such as social re- The major oil companies are among the very largest and
most visible companies doing business in the United
sponsibility campaigns in the media, States.
governmentlobbyingand selectionof ac- Huge accounting profits, but not high profit rates, are
counting procedures to minimize re- an inevitable corollary of large absolute firm size. This
makes these companies obvious targets for public
portedearnings." By avoidingthe atten- criticism." (U.S. Congress, Senate, Subcommittee on
tion that "high"profitsdraw becauseof Anti-trust and Monopoly (1976), p. 1893).

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
116 The AccountingReview,January1978

cism suggests that Superior Oil Com- ers and nonmanaging directors have
pany (1974 sales of $333 million) incurs more incentive to adjust for and control
considerably less costs from anti-trust, increases in reported earnings due to
''corporate responsibility,'' affirmative changes in accounting standards than do
action, etc., than Exxon with sales of $42 politicians and bureaucrats.
billion.
Incentives for Various Groups to Adjust
InformationProduction(i.e., bookkeep-
for a Change in Accounting Standards
ing) Costs. Changes in accounting pro-
cedures are not costless to firms. Ac- An individual (whether a shareholder,
counting standard changes which either nonmanaging director, or politician) will
increase disclosure or require corpora- adjust a firm's accounting numbers for a
tions to change accounting methods in- change in accounting standards up to the
crease the firms' bookkeeping costs (in- point that the marginal cost of making
cluding any necessary increases in the adjustment equals the marginal bene-
accountants' salaries to compensate for fits. Consider the incentives of the outside
additional training).13 directors to adjust bonus compensation
Management Compensation Plans. A plans due to a change in accounting
major component of management com- standards. If these directors do not adjust
pensation is incentive (bonus) plan in- the plans, management compensation
come (Conference Board [1974]), and rises and share price falls by the full dis-
these plans are based on accounting in- counted present value of the additional
come. Our survey of 52 firms in our compensation."7 Each outside director's
sample indicates that the majority of the wealth declines to the extent of his owner-
companies formally incorporate account- ship in the firm and there is a greater
ing income into the compensation plan. 4 chance of his removal from the board. 18
Hence, a change in accounting standards
13 We are assuming that any change in accounting
which increase the firm's reported earn-
standards does not reduce the firm's information produc-
ings would, ceteris paribus, lead to greater tion costs. Although there may be cases where a firm is
incentive income. But this would reduce using a costly procedure which is eliminated by a simpler,
the firm's cashflows and share prices cheaper procedure, information production costs in this
case may decline, but we expect these situations to be
would fall. As long as the per manager rare.
present value of the after tax incentive 14 The frequency is 69 percent.
'5 At this early stage in the development of the theory,
income is greater than the decline in each we assume that management of the firm is composed of
manager's portfolio, we would expect homogeneous (i.e., identical) individuals to simplify the
management to favor such an accounting problem.
16 Our examination of the description of 16 manage-
change. 5 But this assumes that the share- ment compensation plans indicated that all the plans
holders and nonmanager directors do not were administered by the nonmanaging directors.
oppose such an accounting change or do 17 Likewise, we would expect the outside directors to

not adjust the compensation plans for the adjust the incentive compensation targets in those cir-
cumstances when it is in the shareholders' interest to
change in earnings. 6 In fact, the in- report lower earnings (e.g., LIFO), thereby not reducing
creased cashflows resulting from the the managers' incentive via bonus earnings to adopt
political costs, regulatory process and LIFO.
18 Our analysis indicates that outside (nonmanaging)
tax effects of an accounting change as- directors are "efficient" monitors of management, Watts
sumes that various politicians/bureau- 11977].If this were not the case, the capital market would
crats (i.e., the electorate) do not fully quickly discount the presence of outside directors. As far
as we can determine, firms are not required by the New
adjust for the change. A crucial assump- York Stock Exchange listing requirements or Federal
tion of our analysis is that the sharehold- regulations to have outside directors. Paragraph 2495G

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Wattsand Zimmerman 117

If nonmanaging directors did not con- For small rate increases, the per capita
trol management (including adjusting coalition costs each consumer (or some
the compensation plans for changes in group of consumers) would bear lobby-
accounting standards), the decline in ing for the regulator's removal would
firm value offers incentives for an out- vastly outweigh the small per capita bene-
sider or group to tender for control of the fits they would receive via lower regulated
firm and install outside directors who rates. Hence, rational consumers would
will eliminate those managerial activities not incur large monitoring costs of their
which are not in the best interest of the regulators and other politicians (Downs
shareholders.19 This group would then [1957]; Alchian [1969]; and Alchian
gain a proportionate share of the full and Demsetz [1972]). Knowing this, it is
capitalized value of the eliminated abuses not in the regulators' and politicians'
(e.g., the present value of the incremental interests to adjust changes in accounting
compensation resulting from the change standards as fully as if they were con-
in accounting standards). Therefore, the fronted with the same change in account-
benefits for shareholders and nonman- ing standards in the role of outside di-
aging directors to adjust compensation rectors or shareholders in the firm. The
plans for changes in accounting stan- benefits of adjusting for changes in ac-
dards are immediate and direct, if there is counting standards are lower in the politi-
an efficient capital market for equity cal sector than in the private sector.2'
claims. Hence, there is a greater likelihood that a
However, for the politicians and bu- given accounting standard change will
reaucrats, our analysis suggests that the result in increased tax, regulatory, and
lack of a capital market which capitalizes political benefits than will the same
the effects on the voters' future cashflows change result in increased management
reduces the benefits accruing to the compensation. For a given accounting
politicians of monitoring accounting standard change, managers should expect
standards, and the result is that they will their own shareholders and outside di-
perform less adjustments for changes in
accounting standards.20 For example,
of Commerce Clearing House, Volume 2, New York
what are the benefits accruing to a utility Stock Exchange encourages listed firms to appoint out-
regulator for adjusting a utility's account- side directors. "Full disclosure of corporate affairs for the
ing numbers for a change in standards? information of the investing public is, of course, normal
and usual procedure for listed companies. Many com-
In the previous case of an outside direc- panies have found this procedure has been greatly aided
tor, the share price will fall by the dis- by having at least two outside directors whose functions
counted presented value of the increased on the board would include particular attention to such
matters.- This listing statement is consistent with our
compensation resulting for an incom- observation that outside directors provide monitoring
plete (or inaccurate) adjustment of the benefits.
compensation plan. But if the regulator 19 This assumes, of course, that such takeovers earn
a fair rate of return net of transactions costs.
does not completely adjust for a change 20 See Zimmerman [ 1977] and Watts [ 19771for further
in accounting standards and allows the discussion of this issue.
utility's rates to increase (resulting in a 21 It could also be argued that politicians and regu-

wealth transfer from consumers to the lators have a higher marginal cost of adjusting than do
shareholders, nonmanaging directors, and other capital
utility's owners), then the only cost the market participants since the former group does not
regulator is likely to incur is removal necessarily have a comparative advantage of adjusting
from office due to his incomplete adjust- financial statements, whereas, existing capital market
participants probably have a comparative advantage at
ment. He incurs no direct wealth change. such activities.

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
118 The Accounting Review, January 1978

rectors to make a more complete adjust- have an incentive to oppose the standard
ment than politicians. since their bonus compensation plans will
Given this analysis, we predict that have to be adjusted (a costly process), if
managers have greater incentives to their incomes are to remain unchanged
choose accounting standards which re- by the new standard. Above size E, the
port lower earnings (thereby increasing political, regulatory, and tax benefits of
cashflows, firm value, and their welfare) reporting lower earnings due to the new
due to tax, political, and regulatory con- standard are assumed to dominate the
siderations than to choose accounting incentive compensation factor.
standards which report higher earnings The benefits (costs) of a proposed ac-
and, thereby, increase their incentive counting standard are expected to vary
compensation. However, this prediction with the firm's size. This relationship can
is conditional upon the firm being regul- exist for two reasons: (1) the magnitude
ated or subject to political pressure. In of the reported income change may be
small, (i.e., low political costs) unregul- larger for larger firms and (2) for an in-
ated firms, we would expect that man- come change of a given magnitude, the
agers do have incentives to select ac- benefits (costs) vary with firm size.23
counting standards which report higher Hence, the present value of the stream of
earnings, if the expected gain in incentive benefits (or costs) to the firm, GB, are an
compensation is greater than the fore- increasing function of firm size.24
gone expected tax consequences. Finally, Information production costs, curve
we expect management also to consider IC, are also expected to vary to some ex-
the accounting standard's impact on the tent with firm size due to the increased
firm's bookkeeping costs (and hence complexity and volume of the larger
their own welfare).
The next section combines these five 22 The expected effect of an accounting standard could

factors into a model of corporate lobby- vary over time (i.e., it could increase current reported
income and decrease some future reported income). In
ing standards. that case, the analysis is slightly more complex, but the
criterion is still the same (i.e., the effect on the manager's
A POSITIVE THEORY OF MANAGEMENT wealth). However, for simplicity, the remainder of the
paper refers to standards increasing or decreasing re-
LOBBYING ON ACCOUNTING STANDARDS ported income as though the whole time series of future
Given a proposed accounting stan- income shifts uLp or down.
23 Whether the magnitude of the income change does
dard, management's position depends on vary with firm size depends on the particular accounting
the size of the firm (which affects the standard in question. For certain accounting standards
magnitude of the political costs) and (e.g., requiring all firms to report depreciation based on
current replacement costs) it is apparent a priori that
whether the proposed standard increases there will be a correlation between the income change
or decreases the firm's reported earn- and firm size. For other standards (e.g., general price level
ings.22 Figure I separates the standard's accounting) a priori, it is not obvious that a relationship
will exist (e.g., net monetary gains may offset depreciation
impact on earnings into decreases (1A) in larger firms). However, since political costs depend on
and increases (IB). The curve GB in firm size then we expect the benefits (costs) of standard
Figure IA (earnings decrease) denotes changes to vary with firm size. For example, if all firms'
earnings decline by $1 million (due to a standards
the proposed accounting standard's pres- change) then we would expect larger firms to incur larger
ent value to management including the benefits since the likelihood of anti-trust actions are
tax, regulatory, political, and compensa- expected to be associated with firm size.
24 We would expect firms in different industries to be
tion effects as a function of firm size. For subject to different political pressures, tax structures, and
small firms (below size E), not subject to regulation. Hence, Figure 1 is developed for firms in the
much political pressure, these managers same industry that only differ by size.

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Watts and Zimmerman 119

FIGURE I

A MODEL OF FIRMS' SUBMISSIONS TO THE FASB

IA. Accounting Earnings Decrease


GOB
Expected
Present
Value/

~~~~~NB
_ - C IC
_~~~~~~~~~~wo-0
/

I A

t0, I
Size
Unfavorable INo I Favorable
Submission Submission | Submission
No
Submission

Firm
IB. Accounting Earnings Increase
ENB
ExpectedENCS
Present EBC
Value
Ah ~~~~~~IC

D'
0
AM-
~~~~~~~~~wo-A Size

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
120 The Accounting Review, January 1978

firm's accounting system. The difference the amount CS, ENB-CS. A firm will
between the gross benefits, GB, and the make a submission if ENB-CS is posi-
additional information costs, IC, yields tive. This occurs in the regions DA,
the net benefits curve, NB. where opposing submissions occur, and
If the firm size is in the region OB, the beyond C, where favorable submissions
net benefits curve, NB, is negative, and are made. Between 0 and D and between
the firm will consider making an un- A and C no submissions are made.
favorable submission to the FASB. Be- In Figure 1B, the proposed standard
fore the firm makes a submission, man- increases reported income. This case is
agement holds beliefs regarding the like- similar to the previous one except the
lihood the FASB will adopt the standard gross benefits are only positive for small
and the likelihood the FASB will adopt firms where the management compensa-
the standard if the firm makes an oppos- tion plans are expected to dominate the
ing submission.25 The difference between tax, political, and regulatory factors.
these beliefs is the change in the adoption Beyond size E' gross benefits are nega-
likelihood if management makes a nega- tive since, for those firms, the income
tive submission. The product of this increases are expected to increase gov-
difference and the negative net benefits, ernmental interference (political costs),
NB, (i.e., the present value26 of the cash- raise future tax payments, and lead the
flows arising from the five factors) is the public utility commission to reduce the
expected present value of the net benefits firm's revenues (if the firm is regulated).
curve, ENB. For example, a firm will The net benefits curve is again the
incur negative net present value benefits algebraic sum of GB (gross benefits) and
of $100,000 if the standard is adopted. IC (information costs) and the submis-
They believe the likelihood of adoption sion's expected net benefits less sub-
is .60. By making a negative submission mission costs, ENB-CS, cuts the axis
to the FASB the likelihood falls to .59. at A'. Accordingly, firms with asset sizes
The expected net present value of the in the interval OA' make no submissions
benefits of the submission is then and firms of sizes beyond A' make un-
+ $1000. favorable submissions.
Firms larger than size B face positive
net benefits if the standard is adopted. 25 In this situation, it is possible that management will

They will consider supporting the stan- lobby on an accounting standard because of secondary
(or gaming) effects (i.e., vote trading thereby influencing
dard to the FASB, thereby increasing subsequent FASB pronouncements). We chose not to
the standard's likelihood of adoption.27 introduce gaming because it complicates the model and
Hence, the expected net benefits curve is such complication is only justified if it improves or is
likely to improve the empirical results. We are able to
also positive beyond point B since it is predict corporate behavior without considering gaming.
the product of a positive net benefit and and we do not consider it likely to improve these results.
26 The firm is discounting the future cashflows with
a positive change in the FASB's likeli- the appropriate, risk-adjusted discount rate. Further-
hood of adoption given a favorable sub- more. we are assuming that this discount rate is not in-
mission. creasing in firm size which is consistent with the avail-
able evidence.
If the cost of the submission is $CS, 27 We are assuming that the likelihood of the FASB
consisting primarily of the opportunity adopting the standard, if the firm makes a submission,
cost of the manager's time, then the total is independent of firm size. This is unrealistic since large
firms, we expect, would have more influence with the
expected net benefits of a submission Board. However, inclusion of this additional dependency
given the submission cost is a vertical does not change the results; in fact, it strengthens the
downward shift in the ENB curve by predictions.

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Watts and Zimmerman 121

When we consider the implications of When an accounting standard in-


both figures, we see that larger firms creases net income and decreases operat-
(firms larger than size C in Figure 1) ing earnings of utilities, as does price-
will make favorable submissions if their level adjustments [See Davidson and
incomes are decreased by the accounting Weil, 1975b], we would not necessarily
standard, and unfavorable submissions expect the relationship between man-
if their incomes are increased. Smaller agement's attitude to the standard and
firms (firms smaller than size C in firm size to be as we specified above (i.e.,
Figure 1) will either not submit or make larger firms favoring or opposing the
unfavorable submissions. standard depending upon the effect on
While Figures 1A and 1B reflect the net income and smaller firms opposing
general tendency of costs and benefits of the standard). As a consequence, we
an accounting standard to vary with concentrate on testing that relationship
firm size, there will be exceptions to this for unregulated firms.
relationship. We have omitted variables, Another omitted variable is the politi-
some of which we recognize. In particu- cal sensitivity of the firm's industry
lar, regulation costs borne by utilities de- which clearly affects the political cost of
pend not only on net income but also on an accounting standard change. We do
operating earnings.28 The effect of an not have a political theory which pre-
accounting standard on operating earn- dicts which industries Congress singles
ings may vary with firm size. out for wealth transfers (For example,
The increment to a regulated firm's why was the oil industry subject to inten-
value of an accounting change which re- sive Congressional pressure in early 1974
duces operating earnings is increasing in and not the steel industry?29 Conse-
firm size. Most public utility commis- quently, we do not consider it formally
sions set revenues according to the fol- in our model. As we shall see, political
lowing type of equation: sensitivity has an impact on our results
Revenues = Operating Expenses (only one steel company submitted on
price-level accounting compared to seven
+ Depreciation + Taxes + r Base (1) oil companies submitting), but it does
where r is the accepted rate of return not eliminate the general relationship
allowance on the investment base (usu- between firm size and management's
ally the historic cost of net plant and accounting lobbying behavior.
working capital) [Haskins and Sells EMPIRICALTESTS
1974.] Interest is not directly included in Data
the rate-setting formula. The approach is
to work on a return to total assets. Since On February 15, 1974, the FASB is-
all the terms on the right-hand side of sued the discussion memorandum "Re-
equation (1) are highly correlated with 28 Operating earnings, although
explicitly defined by
each public utility commission, are generally, utility
firm size, any accounting standard that revenues less operating expenses, including depreciation
increases reported operating expenses, but excluding interest and taxes. We assume that the
depreciation, or the recorded value of the adoption of GPLA would mean that price-adjusted de-
preciation would affect operating earnings while the gain
asset base proportionally will, in gen- or loss on monetary assets would be treated like interest
eral, result in an increase in the utility's and would only affect net income.
revenues. And these increments to the 29 This does not mean we do not have any ideas as to
which variables are important. For example, in the case
utility's cashflows will, in general, be in- of consumer goods industries, we suspect that the rela-
creasing in firm size. tive price change of the product is important.

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
122 The Accounting Review, January 1978

porting the Effects of General Price- tained from the COMPUSTAT tape and the
Level Changes in Financial Statements" 1974 Moody Manuals. In addition, data
and scheduled a public hearing on the on the existence of management incen-
topic for April 25, 1974. Public com- tive compensation plans was obtained by
ments and position papers were solicited. a questionnaire mailed to the chief
One hundred thirty-three accounting
firms, public corporations, industry or- TABLEI

ganizations, and government agencies TO THE FASB ON


FIRMSMAKING SUBMISSIONS
GENERALPRICELEVEL,ADJUSTMENTS*
filed written comments.
We assume the submission indicates Firms Adcocating Firms Opposing
the position of corporate management. GPLA GPLA
Clearly, this assumption could introduce
Regulated FirmVs
some error into our tests. For example, AT&T Aetna Life & Casualty (M)
some controllers of corporations may Commonwealth Edison Commerce Bank of Kansas
submit not because of corporate effects, Consumer Power (M) City
Detroit Edison Liberty Corporation (M)
but because they receive nonpecuniary Duke Power Northeast Utilities
income from the submission (e.g., if Indiana Telephone Peoples Gas
they are officers in their local chapter of Iowa Illinois Gas & Electric Southern Natural Re-
Northwestern Telephone sources (M)
the National Association of Accoun- Southern Company Pennzoil
tants). However, we expect the error to Texas Eastern Transmis-
be random. Ignoring this error biases our sion (M)
Texas Gas Transmission
tests of management's attitudes on ac-
UnregulatedFirms
counting standards towards rejecting the
theory. Exxon (M) Continental Oil (M)
Gulf Oil (M) Standard Oil of Indiana (M)
Almost all the corporations making Shell Oil (M) Texaco (M)
submissions (49 out of 53) were New Standard Oil of California Rockwell International (M)
York Stock Exchange firms. Of the re- (M) United Aircraft (M)
CaterpillarTractor Automated Building
maining four firms, one was listed on the Dupont E. I. DeNemours Components
American Stock Exchange, one was (M) Copeland Corporation (M)
traded over the counter, and the other General Motors (M) General Electric (M)
Ford Motor Company (M) General Mills (M)
two were not traded. Of the 53 firms, 18 Marcor(M) Gillette
submitted opinions expressing favorable W. R. Grace (M)
Harsco (M)
views on general price level adjustments Inland Steel (M)
whereas 34 expressed opinions ranging International Harvester (M)
from strong objection to discussions of American Cyanamid (M)
IT&T (M)
the merits of current costing to skepticism Eli Lilly & Co. (M)
and feelings that GPLA was premature. Masonite (M)
These 34 were classified as opposing Merck (M)
GPLA. For one firm, Transunion, an Owens-Illinois, Inc. (M)
Reliance Electric (M)
opinion could not be ascertained, and Seagrams Sons, Inc. (M)
this firm was subsequently dropped from Sears Roebuck (M)
Texas Instruments (M)
the sample. The firms making submis- Union Carbide (M)
sions and their position on the issue are
listed in Table 1. * Transunion Corporation made a submission, but
they did not state a position on GPLA. It made two
Once the sample of firms was identified technical comments.
from their submissions to the FASB, M denotes the firm has a management compensation
1972 and 1973 financial data was ob- plan.

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Wattsand Zimmerman 123

financial officer of each firm. Missing previous series of studies by Davidson


data on the nonresponses (30 percent of and Weil (1975a and 1975b) and David-
the firms) was obtained from the firms' son, Stickney, and Weil (1976) developed
proxy statements and annual reports. If an adjusting procedure which relies solely
no mention of an incentive plan was on published financial statements and
found, we assumed the firm did not have GNP deflators. Using either their pub-
one. Firms classified as having manage- lished figures for 1973 financial state-
ment incentive compensation plans based ments or using their procedures, we were
on accounting earnings30 are denoted by able to obtain estimates of the direction
an (M) in Table 1. of change in reported price-level in-
The precise impact of reported earn- come.3 '
ings on executive incentive compensation In addition to using the Davidson and
is difficult to estimate simply because the Weil results or procedures, we con-
firm has such a plan. The most common structed proxy variables based on un-
procedure companies use is to take some adjusted depreciation and net monetary
fraction of reported earnings after de- assets. Both of these variables have a
ducting a return on invested capital as a direct negative impact on GPLA earn-
pool out of which incentive compensa- ings (i.e., the larger depreciation or net
tion is paid. However, most companies monetary assets, the lower the adjusted
do not pay out all of this pool each year. income and the smaller or more negative
The important point, though, is that the difference between GPLA adjusted
managers in firms with management income and unadjusted income). If we
compensation plans which report higher assume that our sample of firms has the
adjusted earnings will not suffer a decline same age distribution of depreciable
in their incentive compensation and it property, then (cross-sectionally) depreci-
may actually increase their compensation ation and net monetary assets can serve
(depending on the monitoring by the out- as a surrogate for the effect of GPLA
side directors). earnings.32 Those numbers are readily
Methodology 30 If the firm had an incentive plan, but it was not tied
to reported earnings then this firm was coded as not
The FASB's General Price Level Ad- having an incentive plan (Gillette).
justment (GPLA) standard would require 31 1973 was a period of high inflation. If firms based
supplementary price adjusted statements. their FASB lobbying position on the price adjustments
produced by high unexpected inflation without consider-
Even though the supplementary state- ing more "typical" years, then this would introduce
ments will not replace conventional re- errors into the data and finding a statistically significant
ports, users of the information will obvi- result becomes more difficult. If these errors are syste-
matic with respect to firm size, then our results could be
ously make comparisons [See Ijiri, 1976] biased. We do not expect this to be the case. To control
and if adjusted income is above (below) partially for this, statistical tests are performed which are
unadjusted income, we expect our previ- independent of the magnitude of the price change. Net
monetary assets in 1973 may still be abnormally small
ous reasoning to hold, and we assume the (large) due to the high rate of inflation, but these pre-
effect is the same as an increase (decrease) liminary tests suggest that our results are not dependent
in reported income. upon 1973 being atypical.
32 The assumption that the age distribution of de-
A price-level adjusted income figure preciable property is the same across our firms is reason-
does not exist for all firms in our sample. able. The firms who submitted to the FASB on the GPLA
Since only a few firms voluntarily pub- issue, generally, were large, capital-intensive and long-
established firms. Moreover, the results using these sur-
lished GPLA statements, income proxies rogates are consistent with the results using Davidson
must be constructed. Fortunately, a and Weil's estimates.

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
124 The Accounting Review, January 1978

available for our sample. in their net income and ranked by their
Davidson and Weil [1975c] also esti- asset size (Table 2). Of the 26 firms with
mate the effect of GPLA on income for income decreases, eight voted yes and
1974 (which was in the future at the time 18 no.34 The eight yes votes came from
of the submissions). Even though the the larger firms, thus supporting our pre-
adjustment procedure was slightly dif- diction. To test the null hypothesis that
ferent, only two of our 19 firms in the the eight firms which voted yes are drawn
combined samples reverse the direction from the same population of firms (with
of the income effect between 1973 and respect to size) as the 18 that voted no,
1974. Similarly, all of the utilities, (24), we performed a Mann-Whitney U test.
and 35 of the 50 other companies in their Our tables indicate that we can reject the
sample have income effects of the same null hypothesis at the .001 level.35
sign in both years. Since the effects of Of the eight firms with income in-
income changes in the immediate future creases or no changes in net income,
are less heavily discounted, these results seven voted no. Thus, the general ten-
suggest that the error introduced by our
assumption of stationary income changes 3 In this case, firm size is measured by the firm's
is not likely to be severe. Fortune 500 rank in assets. The results are identical when
rank in sales is used. Furthermore, the intent of govern-
ment intervention depends on the metric used by the
Tests of the Theory courts, legislators, and regulators. Market share, con-
In the reported tests, we use asset size centration and size are among the commonly used indi-
cators. Absolute size is important in explaining govern-
as the surrogate for firm size.33 Based on ment regulation for both theoretical and empirical rea-
our model, we can make predictions sons. An implication of Peltzman's (1975, p. 30) theory
about the relationship between asset size of regulation is that the amount of wealth redistributed
from firms by government intervention is a positive func-
and firm submissions. We predict that tion of economies of scale. Since we expect large firm size
firms whose earnings are increased by to indicate the presence of economies of scale, implica-
GPLA will oppose GPLA regardless of tion of Peltzman's theory is that government interven-
tion will be greater for larger firms. Empirically, we ob-
their size (i.e., there will be no association serve numerous cases of politicians and regulators echo-
between size and submission). However, ing the conventional wisdom of certain segments in
for firms whose earnings are decreased by society, that big business is inherently bad. (See, "Curse
of Big Business," Barron's June 16, 1969 and footnote
GPLA, we predict that they will either 12).
support GPLA or will not make a sub- 3 We use the term "vote" to mean responding to a
mission depending on where asset size discussion memorandum by issuing a corporate opinion.
5 Siegel [1956], p. 274. Even after any reasonable
C (Figure 1) occurs in their industry. adjustment for the degrees of freedom lost due to pre-
Since we cannot determine the asset size vious statistical analysis, this result is still significant.
corresponding to point C, we are in An intuitive idea of the strength of the relationship
between management's attitude and firm size can be ob-
a position analogous to being able to tained by considering an analogy. Suppose we put 26
predict the sign of a regression coefficient balls in an urn representing the firms with earnings de-
but not its magnitude. Consequently, our creases; eight red balls representing the firms that voted
yes; and 18 black balls, representing the firms that voted
test of the model does not include asset no. Now, we randomly draw 13 balls out of the urn with-
size C (analogous to the magnitude of the out replacement representing the largest 13 firms (out of
coefficient). The test is only of the pre- the 26). The probability that we draw eight red balls
(analogous to the probability of the eight firms voting
diction that there is a positive relation- yes being the "large" firms if the null hypothesis of no
ship between asset size and submission association between votes and size is correct) is .001.
for firms with income decreases. If the votes of firms are not independent, as in the case
of gaming, this analogy is inappropriate. But we do not
Firms making submissions were classi- have any evidence of vote dependence (via gaming or
fied according to the direction of change otherwise).

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
125
Watts and Zimmerman

TABLE 2
ASSET SIZE, DIRECTIONOF EARNINGSEFFECTAND CORPORATEPOSITIONON GPLA

Corporate Position, Classified


hY Earnings Changet
Rank in
Rank on Fortune 500 Increase or
Asset Si-e Firm (1973) no change Decrease

I Exxon 1 Yes
2 General Motors 2 Yes
3 Texaco 3 No
4 Ford 4 Yes
5 Sears Roebuck (Rank I in retail sales) 7 No
6 IT&T 8 No
7 Gulf Oil 9 Yes
8 Standard Oil of California 10 Yes
9 General Electric 11 No
10 Standard Oil of Indiana 12 No
11 Shell Oil 16 Yes
12 Dupont E.I Nemours 18 Yes
Point C*
13 Union Carbide 22 No
14 Continental Oil 26 No
15 Marcor (Rank 2 in retail firms) 33 Yes
16 International Harvester 34 No
17 Caterpillar Tractor 47 Yes
18 Rockwell International 54 No
19 W. R. Grace 55 No
20 Owens-Illinois 80 No
21 Inland Steel 85 No
22 American Cyanamid 92 No
23 United Aircraft 107 No
24 Seagrams Sons Inc. 108 No
25 Eli Lilly & Co. 135 No
26 Merck 143 No
27 General Mills 156 No
28 Texas Instruments 164 No
29 Gillette 167 No
30 Reliance Electric 332 No
31 Harsco 368 No
32 Masonite 386 No
33 Automated Building Components Not Ranked No
34 Copeland Corporation Not Ranked No
* Point C in Figure I is determined by minimizing the number of misclassifications.
t Yes = Favored GPLA
No = Opposed GPLA

dency of these firms is to vote no as pre- had decreases in income as a result of


dicted by our model. price-level adjustments. If management
The results in Table 2 are consistent compensation dominates tax and politi-
with the implications of our model in- cal factors, then firms with increases in
cluding our assumption that the manage- income would be more likely to support
ment compensation factor is dominated price-level adjustments than firms with
by political and tax considerations. Of decreases. In fact, the reverse is true. The
the 31 unregulated firms with manage- frequency of firms with income decreases
ment compensation plans, eight had in- which support price-level adjustment is
creases or no change in income and 23 seven out of 23 (30 percent) while the

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
126 The Accounting Review, January 1978

frequency of firms with income increases tively larger regulated firms favor GPLA.
that support price-level adjustments is If we assume our model is correct and
one out of eight (12.5 percent). that asset size C is the same for all indus-
The above results support the relation- tries, we can estimate C by minimizing
ship between management's attitudes on the number of prediction errors (analog-
GPLA and firm size for the 23 unregu- ous to estimating a regression coefficient
lated firms. However, if we assume that by minimizing the sum of squared errors).
firm size and the direction of the income This estimate provides information on
change are independent (Table 2 supports the relative importance of political and/or
this assumption), then (if there is no size tax costs for different size firms. Given the
effect) the average size of firms support- data, C is between the 18th and 22nd
ing GPLA should be the same as the largest firms in the Fortune 500 in 1973
average size of firms opposing. Thus we (see Table 2). This suggests that reduced
can use the voting behavior of all 52 political and/or tax costs outweigh infor-
firms in our sample to test the size rela- mation production and/or management
tionship. compensation factors in determining
Table 3 presents the median rank on management's position on GPLA only
asset size for both regulated and unregu- for very large firms. For most other firms,
lated firms favoring and opposing GPLA. information production costs dominate.
The median rank in the Fortune 500 of Are the major benefits of reporting
the nine unregulated firms supporting lower adjusted incomes derived from tax
GPLA is 10. The median rank of the 25 or political considerations? It is very
unregulated firms opposing GPLA is 92. difficult to differentiate between these
two factors, but one possible way is the
TABLE 3 following. Is the change in adjusted in-
MEDIAN RANKS OF FIRM SIZE BY REGULATION AND come proportional to firm size? If it is,
POSITION ON GPLA*
then both the tax and political factors
may be operating. But if there is no asso-
Regulated (N = 18) Unrequlated(N = 34)
ciation between firm size and the magni-
In Favor Against In Favor Against tude of the income change, then the tax
(9) (9) (9) (25) effect cannot explain why larger firms
Median fdvor GPLA. Therefore, this result could
Rank 13 38 10 92 only be due to political costs. We can
* Fortune [Mayand July, 1974]. obtain estimates of the income effect of
GPLA for 11 of the firms whose incomes
For regulated firms, there also appears would be reduced by GPLA (six sup-
to be a relationship between size and porting, five opposing).36 The average
management attitudes. The net incomes reduction in income for the six firms
for all the utilities investigated by David- which supported GPLA is $177.7 mil-
son and Weil [1975b] are increased by lion, while the average reduction for the
GPLA suggesting none of the utilities five which opposed GPLA is $38.5
should favor GPLA. However, as noted million. Thus, it appears that the income
in the preceding section, operating earn- change does vary with size and the pre-
ings are relevant to rate determination. 36 This test was performed on 11 firms with income de-

Those earnings fall for all the utilities creases which Davidson and Weil reported 1973 ad-
justed earnings. Firms which were manually adjusted by
investigated by Davidson and Weil us for Table 2 were excluded from this test since only the
[1975b] and this could explain why rela- sign of the earnings change was calculated.

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Wattsand Zimmerman 127

ceding results are consistent with both agement's attitudes on accounting stan-
the tax and political costs affecting man- dards. Although we are not able to ex-
agement's attitudes. plain some of the notable nonsubmitting
The preceding results test only whether firms' decisions, we would point out that
the size effect exists for firms which did most of the firms submitting are large,
submit to the FASB. It is interesting to and the likelihood of submission in-
examine the effect of GPLA on firms creases with asset size (12 of the 18 firms
which did not submit. In particular, the ranked 1-1 8 in the Fortune500 submitted,
firms of asset size above our estimated C four of the 18 firms ranked 19-36 sub-
which did not submit are of interest since mitted, two of the 18 firms ranked 37-54
our model predicts they would submit on submitted, one of the 18 firms ranked
the basis of the income effect. Dupont is 55-72 submitted, etc.).
the last firm above asset size C in Table 2
to vote. It is ranked 18th in the Fortune Discriminant Analysis
500 in 1973. There are seven firms ranked The preceding tests were based on the
higher than 18th which did not make a direction of the earnings change, not the
submission to the FASB. They are IBM magnitude of the change. A discriminant
(ranked 5th), General Telephone (6th), analysis is conducted including manage-
Mobil Oil (7th), U.S. Steel (13th), Chrys- ment compensation, depreciation, and
ler (14th), Tenneco (15th), and Atlantic net monetary assets as independent vari-
Richfield (17th). ables, and using data on 49 of the 53
The size of the income change is crucial firms making submissions to ensure con-
to determining why these seven firms did sistency of the Davidson and Weil pro-
not submit. If changes are not associated cedures.
with firm size, the expected benefits of a The change in price-adjusted income is
submission could be very small and may correlated with the magnitudes of depre-
not exceed the submission costs. Unfor- ciation and net monetary assets. The
tunately, Davidson and Weil only esti- larger both of these variables in unad-
mated the change in earnings in 1973 for justed terms, the larger will be the decline
three of these seven firms: IBM, U. S. (in absolute dollars) in adjusted net in-
Steel, and Chrysler. All three have in- come. We do not perform an actual price-
come reductions with GPLA and their level adjustment, but rely on the unad-
average reduction is $88 million. This is justed magnitudes of depreciation and net
less than the average reduction for the six monetary assets.
firms with income reductions which did 3 A more likely explanation of U.S. Steel's failure to

submit ($177 million), but it is not trivial. submit is the fact that the steel industry was not as politi-
cally sensitive as the oil industry (for example) at the
Further, the reductions for two of the time. In other words, a given earnings effect has less politi-
three nonsubmissions (IBM and General cal cost or benefit. This possibility is not included in our
Telephone) exceed the reductions for four model. This could also explain Chrysler's failure to sub-
mit. As number three after General Motors and Ford they
of the six submissions. Consequently, it is may be subject to less political pressure (and hence cost).
difficult to attribute the fact that the In addition, the "free rider" effect may explain some of
three firms did not submit to the lack of these nonsubmissions.
While we can only expect a positive theory to hold on
an income effect.37 average, the failure of IBM to submit is puzzling. That
In summary, these tests confirm the firm has anti-trust suits outstanding and some economists
relationship between size and manage- allege that it earns monopoly profits. For a discussion of
one of these suits and statements by economists that IBM
ment attitudes on GPLA. Political costs earns monopoly profits, see "The Breakup of IBM"
and, perhaps, tax effects influence man- Datamation, October 1975, pp. 95-99.

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
128 The Accounting Review, January 1978

The general form of the discriminant function we estimate is38

Pi = 1 + C2 MKTVL + C2 MKTVL + X3 (SALES') CHGi

+ 4TSALES) CHGi + 5 MCOMPi + C6 REG (2)


where
Number of opposing firms if the ith firm favored GPLA
Total firms in sample
Pi- Number of supporting firms
if the ith firm opposed GPLA
Total firms in sample
MKTVLi the market value of the firm's equity (number of common shares out-
=
standing x average share price)
1 if the ith firm was regulated
O otherwise
1 if the ith firm had a management incentive scheme
MCOMP=1 0 otherwise
DEPi = unadjusted depreciation expense in 1973 for the ith firm
NMAi=net monetary asset position in 1973 for the ith firm
I
+ I if price-level adjusted income is below unadjusted income or if
CHGi= the firm is regulated
|-1 if price-level adjusted income is above unadjusted income
1 0 otherwise
SALESi = Sales of the ith firm
TSALESi =Total sales of the Compustat firms with the same SIC code as firm i.
SALES, =
a proxy variable for market share
TSALESi
38 Northwestern Telephone, Commerce Bank of Kan-
Table 4 presents the results of various sas City, and Indiana Telephone were dropped from the
functional forms of equation (2) fitted sample due to a lack of data.
3 The discriminant function is estimated using ordi-
over various subsets of the data.39 The nary least squares. t-statistics on the coefficients are
first two terms, reported. The usual t-tests cannot be performed since the
dependent variable is not normally distributed nor can
NMA DEP asymptotic properties of large samples be used. However,
and the t-statistic is still useful as an index of the relative im-
MKTVL MKTVL
portance of the independent variable.
4 Normalizing by the market value of the common
normalize the unadjusted figures by the stock introduces some error since we are not including
market value of the equity40 and the esti- the market value of the debt or preferredstock. However,
mated coefficients measure the extent to since the market value of the common is highly correlated
with total market value of the firm, we do not expect
which an increase in relative depreciation serious problems except that there may be some syste-
or net monetary assets affect voting be- matic, negative understatement of normalized net mone-
havior. These coefficients, which should tary assets.

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Watts and Zimmerman 129

TABLE4
DISCRIMINANTANALYSIS
Coefficients (t-statistics)

Yates
Model SALES Adjusted
Num- DEP/ NMA/ SALES TSALES Chli
her N Sample Constant MKTVL MKTVL x CHG CHG MCOMP REG R2 Square*

1 49 total -.0241 122.6 -38.9 .000044 -.4131 -.2355 -.3443 .358 9.25
sample (-.12) (.60) (-1.62) (3.67) (-1.11) (-1.42) (-1.29)
2 49 total -.0855 160.4 - 14.2 .000043 - .4381 - .1619 .332 9.25
sample (-.44) (.79) (-.98) (3.53) (-1.17) (-1.03)
3 49 total -.0973 143.0 -15.6 .000034 -.1601 .311 9.25
sample (-.50) (.70) (-1.07) (3.58) (- 1.02)
4 34 unregulated .0431 74.0 -36.5 .000044 - .3271 -.2186 .366 19.96
firms (.19) (.27) (-1.06) (3.58) - .89) (-.89)
5 34 unregulated .0412 86.2 -35.3 .000038 -.2335 .347 13.16
firms (.18) (.32) (-1.03) (3.73) (-.96)
6 49 total -.0079 215.3 .000033 -.2365 .0077 .293 11.74
sample (-.04) (1.09) (3.44) V 1.39) (.05)
7 49 total - .0662 .000033 .201 5.98
sample (- 1.03) (3.44)
* The Yates correction for continuity is useful in establishing a lower bound on the X2 statistic.

capture the tax effects, are predicted to are proxies for political costs. These two
be positive under that hypothesis (the variables, assume that political costs are
larger the depreciation and net monetary symmetric for both earnings increases
assets the greater the decline in adjusted and decreases. The multiplicative dum-
income and the greater the tax benefits). my, CHG, is positive if earnings decline
The sign on normalized depreciation (based on the Davidson-Weil [1975a]
is as predicted, but normalized net mone- results) or if the firm is regulated.42
tary assets is of the wrong sign. One of The sign on SALES x CHG is as pre-
the following three hypotheses explain dicted, positive, and in addition has the
this result: the tax effect is only operating highest t-statistic of all the independent
via depreciation;41 depreciation and net variables. In addition, the coefficient on
monetary assets, being inversely related SALES x CHG is the most stable co-
(correlation coefficient ranging from efficient across various realizations and
-.41 to -.55), are entering the regres- subsamples which leads us to conclude
sion with opposite signs; or the tax effect that firm size is the most important vari-
is not an explanatory factor. Since our able. The sign of
sample is very small, it is not possible to
use a holdout subset to distinguish be- 4' That is, this sample of firms does not expect the
tween these hypotheses. tax laws to be changed to include in taxable income gains/
The next two variables, losses on net monetary assets.
42 Since the regulatory commission bases rates on
depreciation, net monetary assets are not expected to be
(SALES) CHG and ALES) CHG, an important consideration, hence operating earnings
decline for regulated firms.

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
130 The Accounting Review, January 1978

increases, and the discriminatory power


SALES x CHG of the model improves from a Chi-
Square of 9.25 to 11.74. However, the
is of the wrong sign. But this is probably multicolinearity between
due to the crude metric of market share,
SALES REG, MCOMP, and NMA
MKTVL
TSALES
this variable is attempting to measure.43 precludes our drawing any conclusions
When the market share proxy is elimi- regarding the impact of management
nated, the model's predictive ability is compensation or regulation on lobbying
not impaired. behavior.
MCOMP, a dummy variable for man- Models 4 and 5 are fitted using only
agement compensation schemes is ex- the unregulated firms (N = 34). REG and
pected to have a negative sign regardless then
of the change in earnings. Prior research SALES
indicates that executive compensation is TSALES
more highly associated with operating
income (which includes depreciation) have been deleted. The R2 statistic still
than net income (which includes gains/ remains high and the Yates adjusted Chi
losses on monetary assets).44 Therefore, Square is significant at the I percent level.
MCOMP is not multiplied by CHG. The In fact, Model 4 correctly classifies the
sign of MCOMP being negative is con- voting behavior for 32 out of the 34 firms.
sistent with our predictions. The constant should be capturing the
If the firm is regulated, the dummy vari- partial effect of information production
able, REG, is one. Regulated firms' price- costs after controlling for the other fac-
level adjusted operating incomes decline, tors. When the total sample is used in the
unambiguously, and therefore these firms estimation, the constant is negative as ex-
should tend to favor GPLA if the regula- pected. When the regulated firms are
tory factor is operating. Yet, the sign of excluded, the constant is positive. But in
the coefficient of REG is negative in 43 Our measure of industry sales does not include firms
Model 1. This sign is negative because in the industry not on the COMPUSTAT tape and
REG is inversely related to furthermore all the firm's sales are assumed to be in the
firm's dominant SIC category.
44 Our examination of management compensation

MCOMP and MKTVL plans indicates that although the minimum and maxi-
mum amounts transferred to the bonus pool depend on
the final net income number, we find that the actual
(correlation coefficients of -.60 and bonus paid is most highly associated with operating or
current income (depreciation is included, but extraordi-
-.86 respectively). When nary gains and losses are excluded). We correlated the
NMA change in management incentive compensation expense
for 271 COMPUSTAT firms with changes in operating
MKTVL income and changes in net income after extraordinary
items. The correlation coefficient for changes in operating
is deleted from the model (Model 6), the income exceeded that for changes in net income after
extraordinary items for over two-thirds of the firms.
sign of REG reverses, the importance of Gains or losses on monetary assets are not included in
operating income. Consequently, only adjusted depreci-
DEP ation (ignoring inventory adjustments) are expected to
affect management compensation and the effect is to
MKTVL reduce management pay.

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Watts and Zimmerman 131

all models the constant is close to zero. rectly through possible governmental in-
The estimated discriminant functions tervention (antitrust, price controls, etc.),
are consistent with the tests of the theory. can affect their future cashflows by dis-
All of the discriminant functions are couraging government action through
statistically significant and the inter- the reporting of lower net incomes. The
vening variable driving these findings is empirical evidence with respect to the
firm size. In fact, firm size explains over position 52 firms took before the FASB
half the explained variance in voting on price level restatements is consistent
behavior (Model 7). with respect to this hypothesis.
These results are consistent with those The single most important factor ex-
using the Davidson and Weil findings. plaining managerial voting behavior on
The discriminant functions indicate that General Price Level Accounting is firm
the political cost factor is more important size (after controlling for the direction
than the tax factor in affecting manage- of change in earnings). The larger firms,
ment's attitudes. ceteris paribus, are more likely to favor
The major empirical problem in the GPLA (if earnings decline). This finding
discriminant analysis is the rather small is consistent with our government inter-
sample size which precludes using a hold- vention argument since the larger firms
out sample and, furthermore, does not are more likely to be subjected to govern-
allow more sophisticated econometric mental interference and, hence, have
techniques to control for the multi- more to lose than smaller corporations.
colinearity. Hence, it is difficult to con- The existence of costs generated by
trol for the interaction between the under- government intervention may have more
lying factors. However, these preliminary fundamental and important effects on
results are encouraging and suggest that the firm's decisions than just its lobbying
additional research in this area is war- behavior on financial accounting stan-
ranted. dards. Not only would we expect the firm
to manage its reported earnings, but also
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS to alter its investment-production deci-
We have focused in this paper on the sions if the potential costs of government
question of why firms would expend interference become large. For example,
resources trying to influence the determi- government intervention costs may lead
nation of accounting standards. The his- the firm to select less risky investments in
tories of the Committee on Accounting order to eliminate the chance of high
Procedures, the Accounting Principles returns which then increase the likeli-
Board, and FASB are replete with exam- hood of government intervention. If the
ples of managements and industries exert- total risk of these less risky investments
ing political pressure on the standard- tends to be positively correlated with the
setting bodies. systematic risk of the firm, then we would
A possible answer to this question is expect the beta (the estimate of the co-
provided by the government intervention variance between the return on the stock
argument, namely, that firms having and the market return normalized by the
contact (actual or potential) with govern- variance of the market) on the common
ments, directly through regulation (pub- stock to be significantly below one (aver-
lic utility commissions, Interstate Com- age risk) for those firms facing large
merce Commission, Civil Aeronautics government intervention costs. The evi-
Board, etc.) or procurement, or indi- dence from the sample of firms making

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
132 The Accounting Review, January 1978

submissions to the FASB on GPLA is will be met by corporate lobbying. The


consistent with this hypothesis. The aver- Committee on Accounting Procedures
age ftis .67. Furthermore, firms favoring and the Accounting Principles Board
GPLA tend to have lower betas than the could not withstand the pressure. The
firms in opposition.45 former Chairman of the FASB also has
Our findings, in a preliminary exten- complained of the political lobbying, and
sion of these results, tend to confirm the the FASB has been forced to defer the
decline in systematic risk as firm size controversial GPLA topic. The SEC
increases and as government intervention has, until recently, avoided direct in-
costs rise. These tentative findings are volvement in the setting of accounting
suggestive of fertile research possibilities standards. One could hypothesize that
of examining the effects of politically this was in their own interest. By letting
motivated factors on the maximizing the American Institute of Certified Pub-
behavior of firms' managements and lic Accountants be the scapegoat, the
shareholders. Securities and Exchange Commission
We believe that the general findings in could maintain their "credibility" with
this paper, if confirmed by other studies, Capitol Hill and the public.
have important implications for the set-
ting of financial accounting standards in 4 The average betas of various subclasses are:
a mixed economy. As long as financial U11-
accounting standards have potential ef- Requalted requalted Combined
fects on the firm's future cashflows, Firms opposing GPLA .67 .72 .71
Firms favoring GPLA .50 .65 .59
standard setting by bodies such as the
Accounting Principles Board, the Finan- Combined .59 .70 .67
cial Accounting Standards Board, or the Note that as a firm grows via diversification its beta
Securities and Exchange Commission should tend to one.

REFERENCES
Alchian, A. A., "Corporate Management and Property Rights," in Economic Policy and th/e Rcgulation
of Corporate Securities (H. Manne, ed.), (American Enterprise Institute, 1969).
and H. Demsetz, "Production, Information Costs and Economic Organization," American
Economic Review (December 1972), pp. 777-795.
Armstrong, Marshall S., "The Politics of Establishing Accounting Standards," A speech before the Third
Annual Securities Regulation Institute in San Diego, California, January 16, 1976, as reported in
Arthur Andersen & Co., Executive News Briefs, (February 1976), p. 1.
Ball, R., "Changes in Accounting Techniques and Stock Prices," Empirical Research in Accounting:
Selected Studies, 1972. Supplement to Journal of Accounting Research (1972), pp. 1-38.
and Ross Watts, "Some Time Series Properties of Accounting Income," Journal of Finance
(June 1972), pp. 663-82.
Barefield, R. M., and E. E. Comiskey, "The Smoothing Hypothesis: An Alternative Test," THE ACCOUNT-
ING REVIEW (April 1972), pp. 291-298.
Barnea, A., J. Ronen, and S. Sadan, "The Implementation of Accounting Objectives-An Application to
Extraordinary Itens," THE ACCOUNTING REVIEW (January 1975), pp. 58-68.
Beidleman, C. R., "Income Smoothing: The Role of Management," THE ACCOUNTING REVIEW (October
1973), pp. 653-667.
Benston,. George J., "Accountants Integrity and Financial Reporting,' Financial Executive (August
1975), pp. 10-14.
The Conference Board, Top Executive Compensation (Conference Board, 1974).
Copeland, Ronald M., "Income Smoothing," Empirical Research in Accounting: Selected Studies. Sup-
plement to Journal ofA counting Research 1968, pp. 101- I 16.

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Watts and Zimmerman 133

Cushing, B. E., "An Empirical Study of Changes in Accounting Policy," Journal of Accounting Research
(Autumn 1969), pp. 196-203.
Dasher, B. E. and R. E. Malcom, "A Note on Income Smoothing in the Chemical Industry," Journal of
Accounting Research (Autumn 1970), pp. 253-259.
Davidson, Sidney, Clyde P. Stickney and Roman L. Weil, Inflation Accounting (McGraw-Hill, 1976).
and Roman L. Weil, "Inflation Accounting: What Will General Price Level Adjusted Income
Statements Show?" Financial Analysts Journal, (January-February 1975a) pp. 27-3 1; 70-8 1.
and Roman L. Weil, "Inflation Accounting: Public Utilities," Financial Analysts Journal, (May-
June 1975b), pp. 30-34; 62.
and Roman L. Weil, "Inflation Accounting: Some 1974 Income Measures," Financial Analysts
Journal, (September-October 1975c), pp. 42-54.
Downs, A., An Economic Theoryof Democracy," (Harper and Row, 1957).
Fama, Eugene F., "Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work,' Journal of
Finance, (May 1970), pp. 383-417.
Gonedes, N., "Income-smoothing Behavior Under Selected Stochastic Processes," Journal of Business
(October 1972), pp. 570-584.
, "Class Discussion Notes: Section 8," unpublished manuscript, University of Chicago (January
1976).
and N. Dopuch, "Capital Market Equilibrium, Information Production, and Selecting Account-
ing Techniques: Theoretical Framework and Review of Empirical Work," Studies on Financial Ac-
counting Objectives. 1974. Supplement to Journal of Accounting Research (1974).
Gordon, M. J., "Postulates, Principles and Research in Accounting," THE ACCOUNTING REVIEW (April
1964), pp. 251-263.
, B. N. Horwitz, and P. T. Meyers, "Accounting Measurements and Normal Growth of the Firm,"
Research in Accounting Measurement, eds. Jaedicke, Ijiri and Nielsen (American Accounting Associa-
tion, 1966), pp. 221-231.
Haskins and Sells. Public Utilities Manual (New York, 1974).
Horngren, Charles T., "The Marketing of Accounting Standards," Journal of Accountancy (October
1973), pp. 61-66.
, "Setting Accounting Standards in 1980," unpublished speech before the Arthur Young Professors
Roundtable (March 30-31, 1976).
Ijiri, Yuji, "The Price-Level Restatement and its Dual Interpretation," THE ACCOUNTING REVIEW,
(April 1976), pp. 227-243.
Jensen, Michael C., "Reflections on the State of Accounting Research and the Regulation of Account-
ing," Presented at the Stanford Lectures in Accounting, May 21, 1976.
, and William H. Meckling, "Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and
Ownership Structure," Journal of Financial Economics (October 1976a), pp. 305-360.
, and William H. Meckling, "Can the Corporation Survive?" Public Policy Working Paper Series,
PPS76-4, Graduate School of Management, University of RocIester, (April, 1976b).
Kaplan, R. S., and R. Roll, "Investor Evaluation of Accounting Information: Some Empirical Evi-
dence," Journal of Business (April 1972), pp. 225-57.
Meckling, William H., "Values and the Choice of the Model of the Individual in Social Sciences," Revue
Suisse d' Economic Politique et de Statistique (December 1976).
Moonitz, Maurice, Obtaining Agreement on Standards. Studies in Accounting Research No. 8 (Sarasota,
Florida: American Accounting Association, 1974).
Peltzman, S., "Toward a More General Theory of Regulation," Journal of Law and Economics, (August
1976), pp. 221-240.
Posner, Richard A., "Theories of Economic Regulation," The Bell Journal of Economics and Management
Science, (Autumn 1974), pp. 335-358.
Siegel, Sidney, Nonparametric Statistics (McGraw-Hill, 1956).
Siegfried, John, "Determinants of Antitrust Activity," Journal of Law and Economics (October 1975),
pp. 559-581.
Stigler, G. J., "The Theory of Economic Regulation," The Bell Journal of Economics and Management
Science, (Spring 1971), 3-21.
Sunder, S., "Empirical Analysis of Stock Price and Risk as They Relate to Accounting Changes in In-
ventory Valuation," THE ACCOUNTING REVIEW (April 1975), pp.305-315.

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
134 The Accounting Review, January 1978

U.S. Congress, Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust and Monopoly of the Committee on the Judiciary,
Hearings, The Petroleum Industry, Part I, 9th Congress, 1st Session, 1975.
U.S. Congress, Senate, Subcommittee on Antitrust and Monopoly of the Committee on the Judiciary,
Hearings, The Petroleum Industry, Part III, 9th Congress, 1st Session, 1976.
Watts, Ross, "Accounting Objectives," Working Paper Series No. 7408, Graduate School of Manage-
ment, University of Rochester, (April 1974).
Watts, Ross, "Corporate Financial Statements: Product of the Market and Political Processes," Austral-
ian Journal of Management(April 1977), pp. 53-75.
Zeff- Stephen, Forging Accounting Principles in Five Countries: A Historv and an Analysis of Trends,
Arthur Andersen Lecture Series (Stipes Publishing Company, 1972), pp. 110-268.
Zimmerman, Jerold, "The Municipal Accounting Maze: An Analysis of Political Incentives," Supple-
ment to the Journal of Accounting Research (1977).

This content downloaded from 202.43.95.117 on Thu, 4 Dec 2014 17:59:04 PM


All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

Vous aimerez peut-être aussi